You are on page 1of 10

ARTICLE IN PRESS

Energy Policy 35 (2007) 4381–4390


www.elsevier.com/locate/enpol

Towards a contemporary approach for understanding consumer


behaviour in the context of domestic energy use
Adam Faiers,1, Matt Cook, Charles Neame
School of Applied Sciences, Cranfield University, Silsoe, Beds. MK43 0AL, UK
Received 23 July 2006; accepted 4 January 2007
Available online 23 April 2007

Abstract

Domestic sector energy use is increasing in the UK and currently accounts for 30% of total use. Policies of liberalised energy markets
have allowed greater consumer choice but have not sought to reduce carbon emissions. Overall sales of energy efficiency products are
rising, but UK housing stock standards are poor and do not facilitate improved efficiency and further, the sales of such products are
influenced by their price, thus the higher capital costs of products such as boilers and solar systems make them initially unattractive to
consumers. Previous market-based research into the adoption of energy efficiency products has often focused on single factors, for
example demographics. This has limited the ability of policy makers to make informed decisions that address a broader range of factors,
such as individuals’ cognitive abilities, values and attitudes, as well as external factors such as social networks, marketing, and products
and services. This paper provides a wider critique of the theoretical base related to consumer behaviour, product attributes and socio-
environmental theories that relate to energy use. The aim of the paper is to draw together theories relevant to energy use in order to aid
policy making in the broader context and to develop the discussion around integrated theories of consumer behaviour.
r 2007 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Energy efficiency; Adoption of innovations; Consumer choice

1. The case for carbon reduction and energy efficiency it has been generated from renewable sources. Legislation
has also facilitated consumer investment in domestic-scale
During the period 1990–2004, energy use in the domestic energy generation systems (solar thermal or photovoltaic
sector increased by 18% to account for just over 30% of systems for example) as utilities are required to buy any
the UK final energy consumption. Domestic energy is used excess energy generated (DTI, 2001). Consequential effects
for space heating (58%), water heating (24%), and lighting of the ease to switch suppliers, foe example, the UK
and appliances (18%). The source of the energy used is ‘28-day rule’, has meant that utilities have been unable to
predominantly from carbon fuels, such as gas, or electricity offer customers a package of energy services, for example,
generated in large-scale power stations (DTI, 2004). installing energy saving measures and charging consumers
European governments have been implementing policies based on the savings that they made as a result, however,
that encourage the adoption of energy efficiency in the legislative changes in 2003 in the UK have since enabled
home through incentives and regulation. In addition, this (DTI, 2005).
consumers have been able to exercise choice in the energy In 2002, the government in the Netherlands, which had
market due to liberalisation of the electricity and gas the highest level of consumer demand for green power in
markets, allowing them to choose more easily from whom Europe at the time, sought to further the adoption of green
they receive their supply of energy, and also whether or not energy products and their use by developing a virtuous
circle whereby funding to stimulate the market increases
Corresponding author. Tel.: +441525237569. demand for products, the demand leads to a reduction in
E-mail address: a.j.faiers.s02@cranfield.ac.uk (A. Faiers). costs, and as a consequence, reduced costs stimulate
1
Current address: 4, Pinkle Hill Road, Heath and Reach, Bedfordshire, further investment in the products, which leads to greater
England LU7 0AG, UK. demand. As a consequence of this, there was a total

0301-4215/$ - see front matter r 2007 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2007.01.003
ARTICLE IN PRESS
4382 A. Faiers et al. / Energy Policy 35 (2007) 4381–4390

increase of 675,000 customers for green energy between 2. Understanding environmentally sensitive behaviour in
1995 and 2002, with premiums for green electricity falling order to aid policy decisions
to in some cases either zero premium or even green
electricity cheaper than electricity generated by conven- Factors understood to determine demand for energy
tional fossil fuel-based processes (Bird et al., 2002). efficiency measures typically include the cost of installation
An overview of the market for heating systems in the UK and the simple pay back period, i.e. the period before a
shows that the uptake of measures that increase the return on the original investment is accrued. Market
efficiency of energy use has been increasing. In August research shows that consumers are generally only willing
2004, the UK market for energy efficiency products was to install measures providing the return on investment is
worth £5783 million, which was made up of thermal relatively rapid (Faiers and Neame, 2006). However, simple
insulation products, high efficiency central heating systems payback periods vary significantly and do not generally
driven by SEDBUK ‘A’ rated boilers, and double glazing account for future changes to the cost of energy, future tax
and conservatories. Over the 5 years to 2009, it is expected implications on energy, or other changes affecting currency
that while growth in double glazing products and central values. Examples show that the successful adoption of
heating will remain stable, the growth for insulation green energy occurs when the availability of the products is
products will be strong, based on the legislative require- high, they are aggressively marketed, and competitive with
ments for improved insulation of newbuild property other energy products, as is the case in the Netherlands and
(Mintel, 2005). Sweden. Pricing remains a critical issue, although retail
However, legislation is not always an appropriate driver competition has stimulated the market to an extent.
for improvements as the choice to improve energy However, marketing activity has been slow to develop
efficiency performance is dependant on the householder. awareness and education (as reviewed by Salmela and
For example, it is estimated that 90% of homes have some Varho, 2006), which is considered to be one of the critical
insulation fitted, but not to the level of insulation that factors in adoption (Bird et al., 2002).
would be required for a newbuild property under the Previous investigations that were seeking to profile
Part L building regulations 2006, which require 200 mm of potential eco-consumers have based their methodology
loft insulation to be fitted (Mintel, 2005). Despite current on demographic data. However, the results of these
low capital costs and rapid simple pay-back, it is estimated research projects are often either inconclusive or incon-
that in 2003 only 6.4 million households in the UK had sistent with each other. For example, in separate projects
cavity wall insulation out of a potential market of 17.8 investigating the impact of education levels, Straughan and
million households with cavity walls. Whilst loft insulation Roberts (1999), Vlosky et al. (1999), and Pedersen (2000)
has penetrated the market, with estimates of 74% of all all concluded that individuals with ‘higher’ education are
households having loft insulation in 2003, the level of more likely to exhibit environmentally positive buying
insulation varies significantly with 85% of households behaviour. However, later evidence from Peattie (2001),
having less than half the recommended amount of and Laroche et al. (2001) found that consumers of
insulation fitted (Mintel, 2005). ecologically compatible products tended to be less edu-
Despite the example of the Netherlands and the other cated. Straughan and Roberts (1999) also concluded that
factors affecting energy consumption such as the liberal- characteristics of age, gender and income, which may in
isation of the market, higher taxation on fossil fuel earlier research have been found to have some correlation
generation, and voluntary targets for the industry, green to stated ‘green’ consumption, on further analysis are
power generation on the whole remains low and the unlikely to actually influence positive eco-behaviour.
virtuous circle desired, for example by the Netherlands, has Historically, it may be that research utilised demo-
failed to develop past an initial stimulation of the market graphic data because it was accessible. Morris (2004), for
(van Rooijen and van Wees, 2006). Despite incentives and example, found that although the research methodologies
policy measures, domestic level renewable energy systems of a range of micro-sociological studies of participation
currently available, such as domestic solar hot water and purport to assess the cognitive processes involved, they
photovoltaic systems have not penetrated the market actually utilise data regarding physical factors such as
sufficiently so as to become significant and be reported in available resources, age, and income. Hence, this supposes
annual market reports such as Mintel (2005). In conclu- that if specific demographic factors do not differentiate
sion, whilst legislation seeks to promote the use of energy consumer behaviour, then other factors must prevail. This
efficiency products, the rate at which they are being presumption makes certain theories and approaches less
adopted is not making a significant impact on the reduction robust and in need of review, for example, those general-
of carbon emissions needed to meet current targets through isations based on demographics by Rogers (1995) and is
the Kyoto Protocol. This suggests that while some house- supported through Jackson’s comprehensive review of
holders are proactive in adopting energy efficiency consumer behaviour in the context of sustainable develop-
measures, a key research question remains as to under- ment (Jackson, 2004).
standing what factors are preventing others from making Models have been developed over time to explore a
similar decisions. range of issues relevant to how individuals act in relation to
ARTICLE IN PRESS
A. Faiers et al. / Energy Policy 35 (2007) 4381–4390 4383

environmentally sensitive buying. These include for exam- Table 1


ple, the buying process (Peattie, 1992), attitude formation Overview of relevant theories and models
(Schiffman and Kanuk, 1997), and recently, Bagozzis’ Consumer choice Post-Keynesian Theory
model of consumer action (reviewed by Jackson, 2004) and Behaviour Economic Theory
an attempt to explain causal links between values and Hierarchy of Needs
behaviour, by Thøgersen and Olander (2002). Needs, values and attitudes Personality Theory
A wide range of models and theories has recently been Control Theory
subject to a very thorough review by Jackson (2004) who Self-Discrepancy Theory
adequately demonstrates that beyond cognitive assessment Pro-social Behaviour
and rational choice there are emotional influences and Perceived Consumer Effectiveness
Collective Action Dilemma
societal and cultural issues that impinge on consumer Willingness to Pay
buying and individual’s behavioural choices. The review by Value Belief Norm Theory
Jackson concludes with a discussion of integrative theories,
Learning Cognitive consistency
which draw together internal and external factors. The Balance Theory
added value of integrated theories should be that alter- Consistency Theory
native causal factors can be assessed, such as the impact of Cognitive Dissonance Theory
emotions or the environment in the buying process, for Relational Discrepancy Theory
example, previously only considered as a cognitive process. Social learning Social Exchange Theory
Integrating theories may also further explain the impact of Behaviour Economic Theory
alternative influences on the rate at which individuals Behaviour Perspective Model
behave in respect of the buying process. Buying process Rational Choice
However, Jackson shows that integrative theories can Theory of Reasoned Action
become cumbersome. An example is Bagozzis’ Model of Theory of Planned Behaviour
Consumer Action, which is relatively inaccessible to a Hierarchy of Effects
Innovation Decision Theory
wider audience and cannot easily aid policy decisions
despite the breadth of issues that it covers. To understand Categorisation of consumers Behavioural Economic Theory
future energy use, with the intention of delivering achiev- Diffusion Theory
able acceptable emissions of carbon, it will be necessary to Product attributes and Attribute Theory (Diffusion
understand all the external and internal influences around categorisation Theory)
energy use; the technologies or processes, the adopters of
such processes and the environment in which they reside.
Hence, policy makers will be able to implement sound needs. Procedural rationality asserts that consumers have
policy and practitioners will be able to deliver lasting rules that allow them to make decisions. These rules are
solutions. based on non-compensatory procedures, which need not
take into account all elements, but just those important to
3. Towards a theory of efficient energy use by household the individual. If the criteria meet those of the individual,
consumers then their needs are satisfied and they proceed with the
purchase.
This section seeks to focus on the critical internal and Considering the reasons behind the consumption choice,
external factors that influence consumer choice in respect Behavioural Economic Theory (BET, as reviewed by
of energy use, using discussion from the wide range Diclemente and Hantula, 2003) posits that core reasons
of Consumer Behaviour Theories. Using this approach, it exist as to why ‘goods’ will be purchased by an individual;
is hoped to generate discussion in relation to a focussed for maintenance, to accumulate, for pleasure, and for
theory of efficient energy use that utilises existing accomplishment. In this respect, ‘maintenance’ goods
Consumer Behaviour Theory where appropriate. As an would be core goods to cover basic needs whereas
aid to this overview, Table 1 provides a graphical theory ‘accumulation’ goods would be standard items but of
map. better quality, ‘pleasure’ goods would be luxury items, and
the ‘accomplishment’ goods would be innovative items that
3.1. Consumer choice set the consumer out as a leader. This categorisation of
motivations corresponds closely with the concept of ‘needs’
Consumer theories have provided a range of insights into versus ‘wants. Individual needs will differ between needing
principles that direct or influence consumer choice. For ‘core’ goods, necessary for everyday living, and ‘peripheral’
example, Lavoie (2004) writes on post-Keynesian Con- goods, which are luxuries and based on ‘want’, compatible
sumer Theory and how it may have potential synergies with with the Hierarchy of Needs (Brugha, 1998). According to
consumer research and economic psychology. Consumers post-Keynesian Theory (as reviewed by Lavoie, 2004),
appear to utilise principles that occur in a priority order, on consumers needs are satiable, separable, sub-ordinate to
which they make proceduralised choices relative to their each other, and can ‘grow’; in other words, once a level of
ARTICLE IN PRESS
4384 A. Faiers et al. / Energy Policy 35 (2007) 4381–4390

consumption has been reached, the individual as the if they realise that they are part of a collective effort to
consumer is no longer satisfied and moves onto another achieve a certain goal. (Peattie, 2001; Roberts, 1996). This
‘need’. This puts some categories subordinate to others, also requires the individual to trust that others will do their
based on the principle of irreducibility. In practical terms, part in achieving an overall goal, including politicians and
it follows that individuals will allocate how much of their other stakeholders in the environment (Lee and Holden,
budget they are willing to spend within categories using 1999). The impact of ignoring this factor for marketing
their own judgement. As choices are related to income, would be that consumers avoid the social or societal
consumers move through the hierarchy of needs and have messages marketed with a product if they felt that their
the capacity and resources to innovate and desire new actions were isolated and would have no effect; the concept
‘needs’. known as the ‘collective action dilemma’ (Prakash, 2002).
Past research on factors that influence ‘willingness to
3.2. Needs, values and attitudes influencing choice pay’ has shown that attitudes are excellent predictors of
environmentally friendly behaviour (Laroche et al., 2001).
‘Needs’ and ‘wants’ will to some extent be influenced by This may be enhanced if manufacturers provide evidence
an individual’s values and attitudes. Values are beliefs that that their products or services support environmental
an individual holds and which will guide their behaviour; claims, demonstrable through such schemes as accredita-
for example self respect, or the maintenance of good tion to standards (Vlosky et al., 1999) but there may still be
health. Personality theories posit that the ‘self’ contains limiting factors, such as premiums set too high (Salmela
guides and standards that cause individuals to ‘self and Varho, 2006). A critical issue remains that consumers
regulate’. The guides to this self regulation are generally do not always purchase products despite their stated
accepted to be taught when the individual is still young, intentions to do so: for example, 20% of consumers state
and depending on the style of nurturing can either be a a willingness to pay between 10% and 20% more for green
promotional self regulation, whereby consequences are power products, yet actual adoption is less than 1%
based on nurture and aspiration, or a preventive self (Truffer et al., 2001). Policy makers should therefore
regulation, whereby consequences are based on safety, consider the discrepancies that can exist between indivi-
duty, and obligation. Either way, the consequences of this duals stated and actual behaviour as referred to in the main
self regulation, as predicted by ‘Control Theory’ and ‘Self- body of this paper. Therefore, when seeking to validate
discrepancy Theory’ are emotional, motivational, or policy, aspects that can lead to contradictions should be
behavioural (Robins and Boldero, 2003). mitigated. For example, if constituents state that they
It has been suggested that demographics may provide would buy an affordable measure, the policy maker should
subtle indicators of a person’s values. For example, determine the definition of ‘affordable’.
Salmela and Varho (2006) also support the findings of Stern develops the role of the social environmental with
other research where it was suggested that ‘green’ the Value–Belief–Norm (VBN) Theory. Stern et al. (1999)
consumers were found within particular professions, such used the basis of norm activation theories, i.e. personal and
as social and healthcare sectors. However, these concepts moral norms, to develop a VBN Theory, which begins to
show only indicators towards a person’s values and may explain public support for environmentalism. Norm
not provide the causal link to them. activation follows when an individual has become aware
Attitude is the way that an individual views, or behaves of potential consequences that may arise from an action.
towards an object, often in an evaluative way (Moore, Through the ascription of responsibility for those con-
2001). ‘Social–psychological antecedents’, or more gener- sequences, individuals will alter their behaviour, thus
ally ‘attitudes’ have been identified as a key determinant of activating their personal norms. Adding to this, moral
environmentally conscious behaviour over demographics norm activation theory posits that when an individual has
(Stern, 2000); attitudes such as environmental concern, accepted the beliefs of a particular movement, generally on
political orientation, and in particular ‘perceived consumer altruistic principles, they accept responsibility that their
effectiveness’ (PCE) have been proven to be causal links to own actions may affect those beliefs and modify their
behaviour (Roberts, 1996; Lee and Holden, 1999). There is behaviour. As a development, VBN theorises that indivi-
also support for Batsons’ Model of Pro-social Behaviour to duals accept the values of a movement, and that their
further understanding of these factors (Lee and Holden, actions could improve the situation regarding those values
1999). Consumers can be influenced by their ethics and that may be under threat. Thus, their behaviour has been
beliefs, for example if they are motivated by ‘moral’ or ‘normed’ through their beliefs based on the values of the
‘material’ ethics. Where consumers are motivated on movement. As with all social theories, there is the risk of
‘moral’ grounds, they move away from material consumer- free-riding, where individuals benefit from the actions of
ism as moral issues conflict with material gain (Lavoie, others, however, this can be overcome when there is a belief
2004). in the viability of group actions and individuals cannot
PCE is based on the concept that individuals who are distinguish their efforts from those of others. Stern et al.
confident that their individual actions will lead to positive (1999) found that non-activist support for environmental
consequences for the environment will be motivated to act improvements was based on the three dimensions of
ARTICLE IN PRESS
A. Faiers et al. / Energy Policy 35 (2007) 4381–4390 4385

environmental citizenship, consumer behaviour and policy only employ a fraction of their knowledge at any one time;
support, and in these three, personal pro-environmental in other words, they appear to utilise a ‘working knowl-
norms were the common factor. In testing this theory, the edge’. Generally, an individual will seek to reduce
causal links in VBN were the best theoretical account for dissonance, so this working knowledge is more likely to
these three dimensions. be consistent with their current values and attitudes. This
may provide an insight into why individuals change their
3.3. Learning, dissonance and cognitive complexity behaviour over time as they review their ‘working knowl-
influencing choice edge’ and adopt revised values and attitudes. Self-reporting
mechanisms can be used to measure attitude to a given
Developing an understanding of an issue, product or product as behaviour includes verbal responses to pro-
service is dependant on learning and behaviour will be ducts. However, it is not always possible to demonstrate a
shaped by values and knowledge (Kaiser et al., 1999). Of consistent relationship between attitudes and behaviour, as
particular relevance to consumer behaviour is the concept there are environmental factors that may influence
that individuals with either more knowledge or concern behaviour; for example social norms and expectations
about particular environmental issues state a willingness to (Robins and Boldero, 2003). Also of consequence are
pay higher prices for alternative products (Rowlands et al., ‘habits’, where individuals may be aware of the need or a
2002; Prakash, 2002). In a general behavioural context, as desire to change their behaviour, but because of their past
opposed to consumption behaviour, Correia et al. (2005) behavioural patterns, or ‘habits’ they cannot make the
and Ellen (1994) both highlight examples of where the actual change required to update their behaviour; a
existence of higher levels of knowledge was an important phenomenon identified by Salmela and Varho (2006).
predictor of pro-social and pro-environmental behaviour. Cognitive consistency theories such as Balance Theory,
Individuals will need to analyse products and services in Consistency Theory, and Cognitive Dissonance Theory
order to learn about them. Analysis of a product will highlight individuals’ need for consistency. Where indivi-
require evaluation of both the content and the structure of duals experience inconsistency, this creates a state of
a product. Content in this context is defined as being a dissonance, which in turn drives a desire to return to
mental evaluation born from knowledge of and beliefs consistency. Hence, dissonance can also be a mechanism
about that product, whereas ‘structure’ defines how the that underlies resistance to change. Dissonance occurs at
individual cognitively places the product in relationship to the individual level, and directly affects the decision to
other products, goods or services. Therefore, an individual adopt ‘goods’, emphasising the need to investigate beha-
will seemingly categorise a product thereby easing their viours at the micro level (Jermias, 2001). Another example
decision to accept or reject it. This process works by of a Cognitive Consistency Theory, Relational Discrepancy
limiting available input from the environment, by organis- Theory, suggests that discrepancies represent different
ing and moderating information, to a level that the qualitative psychological situations and lead to differing
individual can still make an informed decision (Zinkhan outcomes, thus the consequential feelings that individuals
and Braunsberger, 2004). How elaborately an individual experience may result in behaviour other than that
may evaluate a product is a function of his or her ‘cognitive originally intended by that individual. For example,
complexity’; the greater the degree of complexity, the discrepancies that occur when the individual is acting
higher the utilisation of product information and market- against their ‘ideal’ standard will cause a ‘dejection’-related
ing messages on the decision to accept or reject a product. outcome, and discrepancies that occur against a more
Using a repertory grid to analyse cognitive complexity in definite standard, by which the individual believes they
relation to consumer behaviour, Zinkhan and Braunsber- ‘ought’ to behave, will create an ‘agitation’-based outcome
ger (2004) found that although individuals may have a (Robins and Boldero, 2003). To avoid dissonance occur-
complex understanding of one product, they may have a ring in the first place, individuals usually favour informa-
more ‘simple’ understanding of another, hence cognitive tion that confirms their beliefs and so will seek that
complexity is a ‘context specific’ phenomenon. In seeking information out. Alternatively, they may ignore or
to understand the basis of complexity, the research found hypercritically scrutinise feedback that disagrees with their
support for the concept that where individuals had had point of view. Hence, individuals have a ‘confirmatory’
more experience, and had been exposed to more stimuli bias, which will impact on marketing activities that seek to
regarding the products, they had developed superior persuade or influence behaviour, as people who agree with
evaluative criteria and problem solving skills. This in turn the values of the concept will be more open to an awareness
enabled them to make decisions independently of the campaign.
experience of others, to transfer their knowledge to others Individuals have been shown to adopt various strategies
and be more open to training in respect of the products. In for reducing dissonance when it occurs and the extent to
other words, a virtuous circle had developed in that the which these are followed is dependant on the ‘choice’ and
more they knew, the more they wanted to know. ‘commitment’ of the individual. For example, individuals
The result of learning is that individuals accumulate an may follow a course of action but experience dissonance.
immense resource of knowledge over time, but they will Hence, they attempt to persuade themselves that having
ARTICLE IN PRESS
4386 A. Faiers et al. / Energy Policy 35 (2007) 4381–4390

followed that course of action, the rejected alternative was associate certain aspects or emotions with a product.
less attractive, and that the chosen alternative was not as Conditioning is carried out over time through media
unattractive as they originally perceived. Similarly, the advertising, where desirable features are always linked to
individual may exaggerate the attractiveness of the chosen a certain product or service, for example, happiness and
alternative and the unattractiveness of the rejected alter- laughter being linked to certain food products suggesting
native (Jermias, 2001). that the consumer will experience similar emotions or
outcomes if they consume the product. According to the
3.4. Social learning Behaviour Perspective Model, consumer choice will be
influenced by various stimuli, such as hedonic reinforce-
As an alternative approach to reducing dissonance, ment as with the example above, informational reinforce-
individuals may seek advice from a social network in order ment, where ‘information’ will suffice to persuade a
to improve their own judgment or to increase their consumer to act in a certain way, and through ‘aversive’
justification for a decision, in other words, learn from the stimuli, which persuade a consumer to act to avoid a
social network. Hence, they will utilise that advice to fill negative outcome (Diclemente and Hantula, 2003).
gaps in their own knowledge or assess the value of Wider cultural and societal influences will also influence
alternative options for a decision. When presented with behaviour (Dunphy and Herbig, 1995). A collective society
advice, the recipient could choose to ignore it, accept it in will look more readily for solutions to global issues
part with modification, or accept it unconditionally. This compared with an individualistic society. (Pedersen, 2000;
raises the question as to whether there are two cycles of the Parthasarathy et al., 1995) Collective societies have greater
innovation decision process, where first, information has to social interaction and disseminate messages faster. However,
be adopted, and second, the product itself. Yaniv (2004) individualistic societies, such as in the UK, tend towards
identified factors that will affect whether or not attitudes more materialistic values (Lynn and Gelb, 1996), which is
can be changed through advice. The key influences are relevant to this study when considering the inclination of an
knowledge of the field in which the decision is made, and individual to buy a personal, domestic power generation
also the relative ‘distance’ between the opinions of the system. In respect of the product, Peattie (1992) and Rogers
individual seeking advice and the advisor. Hence, those (1995) are consistent in their findings that while products
with less knowledge are more likely to take advice, and must be compatible with the cultural environment in which
where advice is consistent with the individuals’ own the adopter resides; factors such as the economic climate,
opinion, it is regarded. However, there are no guarantees security of employment, political stability and climate,
that the advice will be right, or are there clear justifications religious beliefs, weather and season should also be
for ever accepting knowledge from others. considered. In an earlier work, Lai (1991) argues that these
Individuals can therefore engineer their social network to should be considered as situational factors in the adoption
fit with their own values and attitudes. Reducing dis- process. Cultural compatibility has been proven to affect
sonance in relationships may suggest that individuals will product and service choice in the buying and adoption
gravitate towards others that have a closer opinion to their process (Pedersen, 2000) for example; Heimburger et al.
own. Heider’s Balance Theory, dated 1946, suggests that (2002) recognised that a key cause of failure to adopt
individuals will develop positive attitudes towards those emergency contraception was the role of cultural influences
with whom they have had previous association, which is such as family norms and religious beliefs.
important in that it introduces the element of ‘trust’ in a
relationship. Social Exchange Theory suggests that indivi- 3.5. The buying process
duals choose whom they have a relationship with based on
demographic characteristics, personality attributes and The buying process (Peattie, 1992), has been widely
their attitudes. These relationships have a strong degree documented and follows the process of rational choice,
of commensurability, in that individuals are more likely to whereby the evaluation of alternatives is based on an
engage with one another if their attributes are common, evaluation of costs against benefits. This is a cognitive
even if they are diametrically opposed (Corbitt et al., 2003). process influenced by varying perspectives, such as available
For example, if both people believe in the existence of information, quality or value. Rational Choice is compatible
‘climate change’, they are more likely to engage with each with the innovation decision process (Rogers, 1995) which
other, even if they are at polar ends of the debate regarding suggests that individuals recognise a need for a product,
its potential consequences, than if one of the parties had generate an awareness of the product based on its attributes
no view on or belief in its existence as an issue. Hence, if and then decide to either consume or reject the product. If
one does not share some qualities, aspirations or obliga- the product is consumed, its use may be later discontinued,
tions with another, they will not connect (Robins and and similarly, if it is rejected, can be later adopted. However,
Boldero, 2003). rational choice does not incorporate the fact that individuals
Behavioural Economics Theories identify the existence also utilise their emotional perspective and may choose to
of ‘classical conditioning’, where consumers have been either ally or distance themselves to goods or services they
conditioned through media to act in a certain way, or like or dislike (Hansen, 2005).
ARTICLE IN PRESS
A. Faiers et al. / Energy Policy 35 (2007) 4381–4390 4387

The Theory of Reasoned Action (TRA), and Planned The Hierarchy of Effects model differs from the
Behaviour (TPB) are established theories reviewed by innovation-decision process in that the ‘knowledge’ and
many researchers (for example Jackson, 2004; Kalafatis ‘awareness’ stages are reversed, due to the different focus
et al., 1999; Kaiser et al., 1999). TRA and TPB attempt to that the processes have. In the innovation-decision model,
place the buying decision process within a context of ‘knowledge’ refers to the adopter and how they become
rational decision-making based on perceptions, values and knowledgeable about their needs or wants, and ‘awareness’
attitudes by explaining the control that the individual has refers to the heightened awareness of an innovation as they
over the buying decision. The theory suggests that the level learn about it. In the hierarchy of effects, the focus on the
of ‘intention’ shown by an individual is the best predictor adopter comes at the decision stage, as the awareness stage
of behaviour. ‘Intention’ is influenced by internal and refers to when the potential buyer first becomes aware of
external control constructs, and is seen as a function of the the products, and then develops knowledge about it
individual’s attitude toward behaviour and any subjective subsequently.
norms. Hence, ‘intention’ is a cognitive representation of The ‘innovation decision’ process has been used speci-
an individual’s behavioural tendency. Kidwell and Jewell fically to design or test projects that are being implemented.
(2003) developed this understanding of intention by Hubbard and Mulvey (2003) and Heimburger et al. (2002)
establishing that an antecedent relationship exists between used the process to evaluate the implementation of a
internal and external control influences, with external diffusion project, and found that the adoption rate was
control as an antecedent and internal control as the more positively related to the level of knowledge potential
proximate determinant of behavioural intent. Consistent adopters demonstrated, and despite some adopters reject-
with the criticisms of rational choice however, more recent ing the innovation due to its attributes, they remained open
studies have agreed that TRA does not account for minded to later adoption. Morris et al. (2000) mapped the
affective or emotional behaviour. Fitzmaurice (2005) decision process that farmers took to adopt a government
argues that the buying decision involves hedonic and self- funded grant scheme. From their findings, the authors were
expressive involvement. The findings of an experiment to able to identify where weaknesses lay with the marketing
judge the mediating effect of self-congruity found that approach the government agency took; focusing primarily
‘eagerness’ was a mediating factor on intention. In other on the knowledge and persuasion stages but not facilitating
words, the more ‘eager’ a person was to carry out a the later stages of ‘decision, implementation and confirma-
behaviour, the greater the intention to perform that tion’. Other research has found that the awareness stage in
behaviour. This raises the theoretical question as to the the process is the optimal point at which to gain a full
order in which consumers follow the buying process; does understanding of all the product attributes and thus
affective reasoning precede cognition? Fitzmaurice (2005) overcome any post-purchase dissonance (Rogers, 1995).
argues through empirical results that attitudes do not Kaplan (1999) takes this further by stating that the early
impact on ‘eagerness’, thereby implying that affective need for ‘knowledge’ is critical, as it a pre-cursor to
reasoning is a separate component of the process. adoption interest.
The Hierarchy of Effects model focuses on the motiva-
tion for buying using the rational choice model but begins 3.6. Categorisation of consumers
to incorporate affective or emotional influences. An
individual progresses along a ‘think-feel-do’ path, where BET suggests four categories of consumer based on
they think about the purchase, develop a feeling about environmental and cognitive parameters. Consumers can
purchasing it, based on their liking, preferences and how be influenced in their moods or desires through commu-
convinced they have become, and finally either purchase or nication techniques and will respond, in part, according to
do not. The attitude formation process (Schiffman and their level of ‘education’ in respect of the product in
Kanuk, 1997) correlates with the hierarchy of effects by question. The four categories are ‘initiators’, ‘early’ and
suggesting that attitudes are formed on the basis of how the ‘later’ imitators, and finally, ‘last’ adopters, as outlined in
individual has gained knowledge on the product (thought), Table 2 below. Within the categories, the consumers would
then evaluated the product utilising both cognitive and demonstrate their type of behaviour along a high-low
affective (feeling) reasoning and finally formed an attitude
(do). Whilst many authors have considered the merits of Table 2
the ‘feel-think-do’ model and assume that behaviour is An overview of the behavioural perspective model (after Diclemente and
always dependant on awareness (Meyer, 2001), it might Hantula, 2003)
not always apply to actual buying behaviour. Parthasar-
Antecedent influences Dominant type of Category of adopter
athy et al. (1995) argues that later adopters, the ‘laggards’
behaviour
in particular, are more motivated by the social influences
around them, encouraging them to ‘do’ first, then ‘think’ Moods Accomplishment Initiator
and finally ‘feel’. In effect, this means that the final set of Ability to pay Pleasure Early imitator
Deprivation Accumulation Later imitator
adopters will be less influenced by their own judgement,
Learning Maintenance Last adopter
than by that of their peer groups or the society they live in.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
4388 A. Faiers et al. / Energy Policy 35 (2007) 4381–4390

continuum according to the level of antecedent influences, In addition, consumption on the basis of an incentive can
such as their ‘moods’, their ‘ability to pay’, levels of lead to discontinued use of the product if the individual
‘deprivation’, and the level of their ‘learning’ in respect of becomes disillusioned with it, and withdrawal of the
the product or service. incentive may lead to reduced levels of consumption
BET suggests a categorisation which is in some way (Cabraal et al., 1998; Rogers, 1995). ‘Compatibility’
compatible with the categorisation of individuals that describes how the product fits with the individual’s values,
follow the innovation-decision process as generalised by attitudes and behaviour. Attributes also include how visible
Diffusion Theory (Rogers, 1995). This theory categorises the innovation is (‘observability’), or how accessible it is for
adopters into five types, based on the time at which they individuals to use on a trial basis (‘trialability’). ‘Complex-
adopt an innovation relative to its launch. From empirical ity’ is considered to be a restrictive factor in adoption, and
evidence, the theory has identified relevant factors such as describes how difficult it is to understand either the
personality, values and attitudes, which affect this time innovation, or its principles (Vollink et al., 2002; Kai-ming
difference in adoption. Adopter categories change from Au and Enderwick, 1999; Rogers, 1995).
highly innovative to least innovative as the diffusion It has been demonstrated that consumers assess attri-
sequence unfolds. Adopters are categorised into (a) butes in a stepwise process, commencing with relative
innovators (2.5% of adopters), (b) early adopters (12.5% advantage, then compatibility and complexity. These three
of adopters), (c) early majority (35% of adopters), (d) late attributes have been shown to hold the most influence over
majority (35% of adopters) and (e) laggards (15% of the purchase choice (Rogers 2001; Dunphy and Herbig,
adopters). The theory suggests that the distribution of these 1995; Mohr, 2001; Martinez et al., 1998). Rejection of the
categories is normally distributed with the first 50% of innovation can occur at any time in the process and
consumers being in the first three adopter categories. attributes cannot compensate for each other. A product
BET allows categorisation based on dominant motiva- that demonstrates good relative advantage does not
tions for purchase. As seen in Table 2 below, an ‘initiator’ necessarily enhance the trust that adopters have in it,
will have the resources and mindset to purchase products for although it may influence their perceptions of quality and
accomplishment, whereas someone buying for ‘maintenance’ how they would use it (Vollink et al., 2002). In the case of
issues may be less innovative because they have priorities how customers have assessed ‘green’ electricity, it would
that are not driven by need for accomplishment or pleasure. seem that consumers do not always trust ‘green power’
products to be necessarily ‘green’, in part because they are
3.7. Product attributes and categorisation not knowledgeable about the power networks and infra-
structure (Salmela and Varho, 2006).
Expanding on the categorisation of products and goods Pujari et al. (2003) propose that only two levels of
in BET, Diffusion Theory models consumer expectations attributes exist, namely ‘core’ attributes and ‘auxiliary’
of products and services against product attributes, attributes. Whereas ‘core’ attributes provide the basic level
suggesting that these expectations influence the willingness of benefits that consumers require, ‘auxiliary’ attributes
to buy. Instead of goods categorised against the motivation help to define that product against another. The impact of
for purchase as above, products are categorised against five this categorisation suggests that the success of a ‘green’
predominant attributes; relative advantage, compatibility, product will depend on whether the product has environ-
observability, trialability, and complexity (Rogers, 1995). mental considerations fully incorporated within it as core
The ‘relative advantage’ describes the marginal advan- attributes, rather than as an auxiliary benefit added later.
tage an innovation has over existing products. The critical As seen in BET, where an individual has fewer disposable
aspect of relative advantage is how potential adopters resources available they will be influenced by the degree of
perceive its advantage, rather than how it actually performs uncertainty or risk arising from a product or service. Hence,
(Smizgin and Bourne, 1999; Aggarwal et al., 1998), for risk appears to be a restrictive attribute that it will lessen the
example, the enhanced status that ownership of a product likelihood of purchase (Aggarwal et al., 1998; Smizgin and
brings (Martinez et al., 1998; Rogers, 1995). Bhate and Bourne, 1999; d. Ruyter et al., 2001). Consumers will
Lawler (1997) suggest that it is factors of convenience and perceive risk based on either issues of performance or time,
price that are most significant. Firms can improve the or on perceptions and attitudes formed from personal or
perceived relative advantage by decreasing any disadvan- vicarious experience. Levels of risk may alter depending on
tage and have been shown to increase the rate of adoption the resources available to the individual; for example an
by offering incentives (Velayudhan, 2003; Prakash, 2002). adopter with adequate financial resources will view any
Incentives can take many forms, either monetary or non- capital risk more favourably than an adopter with poor
monetary, but are not without risk to the firm (Prakash, financial resources (Martinez et al., 1998).
2002). For example, as Velayudhan (2003) discovered
through research, featuring grants as part of the promo- 3.8. Towards a model for understanding behaviour
tional package focuses attention on the high cost of the
innovation and away from some other advantageous In conclusion, the buying decision, or the decision to
features that might have persuaded a potential consumer. behave in a certain way towards energy use is informed by
ARTICLE IN PRESS
A. Faiers et al. / Energy Policy 35 (2007) 4381–4390 4389

a wide range of internal and external factors. This paper Dunphy, S., Herbig, P.A., 1995. Acceptance of innovations: the customer
has sought to draw together the key issues from Consumer is the key!. The Journal of High Technology Management Research 6
Behaviour Theories with a view to a model of behaviour (2), 193–209.
Ellen, P.S., 1994. Do we know what we need to know? Objective and
being developed in further research that can be used to subjective knowledge effects on pro-ecological behaviours. Journal of
inform the policy decision process. Business Research 30, 43–52.
The scope of this paper has not included a discussion in Faiers, A., Neame, C., 2006. Consumer attitudes towards domestic solar
relation to the ‘rebound’ effect, where technological power systems. Energy Policy 34, 1797–1806.
efficiencies are cancelled out by higher levels of use due Fitzmaurice, J., 2005. Incorporating consumers’ motivations into the
theory of reasoned action. Psychology and Marketing 22 (11),
to savings made. However, this is a critical consequence on 911–929.
the use of energy following adoption of energy measures Hansen, T., 2005. Perspectives on consumer decision making: an
and should be considered in full. integrated approach. Journal of Consumer Behaviour 4 (6), 420–437.
In advance of a model being developed that can identify Heimburger, A., Acevedo-Garcia, D., Schiavon, R., Langer, A., Mejia,
causal relationships between the three central factors of the G., Corona, G., del Castillo, E., Ellertson, C., 2002. Emergency
contraception in Mexico City: knowledge, attitudes, and practices
adoption decision, i.e. the product, the individual and the among providers and potential clients after a 3 year introduction
environment in which they are placed, policy makers effort. Contraception 66, 321–329.
should be more aware that carbon reduction targets will Hubbard, S.M., Mulvey, K.P., 2003. TIPs evaluation project retrospective
rely on individuals using energy efficiently and those study: wave 1 and 2. Evaluation and Program Planning 26 (1), 57–67.
individuals operate in a social context and the influence Jackson, T., 2004. Motivating sustainable consumption: a review of
evidence on consumer behaviour and behavioural change. A report to
of cultural, social and emotional influences cannot be the Sustainable Development Research Network. Sustainable Devel-
underestimated. To that end, it would appear that the issue opment Research Network. Accessed online at /www.Defra.gov.ukS
of learning and awareness, coupled with accessibility to on 12/01/05.
simple technologies would be a central factor to formulat- Jermias, J., 2001. Cognitive dissonance an resistance to change: the
ing effective policy. influence of commitment confirmation and feedback on judgment
usefulness of accounting systems. Accounting, Organisations and
Thanks are extended to the valuable comments made by Society 26, 141–160.
the anonymous reviewers during the publication of this Kai-ming Au, A., Enderwick, P., 1999. A cognitive model on attitude
material. towards technology adoption. Journal of Managerial Psychology 15
(4), 266–282.
Kaiser, F.G., Wolfing, S., Fuhrer, U., 1999. Environmental attitude and
References ecological behaviour. Journal of Environmental Psychology 19, 1–19.
Kalafatis, S.P., Pollard, M., East, R., Tsogas, M.H., 1999. Green
Aggarwal, P., Cha, T., Wilemon, D., 1998. Barriers to the adoption of marketing and Azjens theory of planned behaviour: a cross-market
really-new products and the role of surrogate buyers. Journal of examination. Journal of Consumer Marketing 16 (5), 441–460.
Consumer Marketing 5 (4), 358–371. Kaplan, A.W., 1999. From passive to active about solar electricity:
Bhate, S., Lawler, K., 1997. Environmentally friendly products; factors innovation decision process and photovoltaic interest generation.
that influence thier adoption. Technovation 17 (8), 457–465. Technovation 19, 467–481.
Bird, L., Wustenhagen, R., Aabakken, J., 2002. A review of international Kidwell, B., Jewell, R.D., 2003. An examination of perceived behavioural
green power markets: recent experience, trends, and market drivers. control: internal and external influences on intention. Psychology and
Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 6, 513–536. Marketing 20 (7), 625–642.
Brugha, C.M., 1998. The structure of development decision making. Lai, A.W., 1991. Consumption situation and the product knowledge in the
Theory and Methodology 104, 77–92. adoption of a new product. European Journal of Marketing 25 (10),
Cabraal, A., Cosgrove-Davies, Schaeffer, L., 1998. Accelerating sustain- 55–67.
able photovoltaic market development. Progress in Photovoltaics: Laroche, M., Bergeron, J., Barbaro-Ferleo, G., 2001. Targeting customers
Research and Applications 6, 297–306. who are willing to pay more for environmentally friendly products.
Corbitt, B.J., Thanasankit, T., Yi, H., 2003. Trust and e-commerce: a Journal of Consumer Marketing 18 (6), 503–520.
study of consumer perceptions. Electronic Commerce Research and Lavoie, M., 2004. Post Keynesian consumer theory: potential synergies
Applications 2, 203–215. with consumer research and economic psychology. Journal of
Correia, C.J., Benson, T.A., Carey, K.B., 2005. Decreased substance use Economic Psychology 25, 639–649.
following increases in alternative behaviours: a preliminary investiga- Lee, J.A., Holden, S.J.S., 1999. Understanding the determinants of
tion. Addictive Behaviours 30, 19–27. environmentally conscious behaviour. Psychology and Marketing 16
DiClemente, D.F., Hantula, D.A., 2003. Applied behavioural econo- (5), 373–392.
mics and consumer choice. Journal of Economic Psychology 24, Lynn, M., Gelb, B., 1996. Identifying innovative national markets for
589–602. technical consumer goods. International Marketing Review 13 (6),
d. Ruyter, K., Wetzels, M., Kleijnen, M., 2001. Customer adoption of 43–57.
e-service: an experimental study. International Journal of Service Martinez, E., Polo, Y., Flavian, C., 1998. The acceptance and diffusion of
Industry Management 12 (2), 184–207. new consumer durables: differences between first and last adopters.
DTI, 2001. The Blue Book: Energy Report 2001 Available online at Journal of Consumer Marketing 15 (4), 323–342.
/www.dti.gov.uk/thebluebookS. Accessed 23 May 2005. Meyer, A., 2001. What’s in it for the customers? Successfully marketing
DTI, 2004. Digest of UK Energy Statistics 2004. Available online at green clothes. Business Strategy and the Environment 10, 317–330.
/www.dti.gov.uk/energy/S. Accessed 23 May 2005. Mintel, 2005. Residential Energy Efficiency (Industrial Report)
DTI, 2005. Consumer protection in energy supply: the role of the 28 Day UK August 2004. Available online at /http://reports.mintel.comS.
Rule Ofgem submission to the Energy Services Working Group Accessed 3 June 2005.
July 2003 Available online at: /http://www.dti.gov.uk/energy/ Mohr, J., 2001. Marketing of High-Technology Products and Innovations.
environment/energy_efficiency/ofgem28day.pdfS Accessed 3 June 2005. Prentice-Hall, New Jersey, USA.
ARTICLE IN PRESS
4390 A. Faiers et al. / Energy Policy 35 (2007) 4381–4390

Moore, D.R., 2001. Visual perception theories and communicating Schiffman, G.L., Kanuk, L.L., 1997. Consumer Behaviour, sixth ed.
construction industry concepts. Work Study 50 (2), 58–62. Prentice-Hall International (UK) Limited, London.
Morris, C., 2004. Networks of agri-environmental policy implementation: Smizgin, I.T.D., Bourne, H., 1999. Electronic cash: a qualitative
a case study of England’s Countryside Stewardship Scheme. Land Use assessment of its adoption. International Journal of Bank Marketing
Policy 21, 177–191. 17 (4), 192–202.
Morris, J., Mills, J., Crawford, I.M., 2000. Promoting farmer uptake of Straughan, R.D., Roberts, J.A., 1999. Environmental segmentation
agri-environment schemes: the Countryside Stewardship Arable alternatives: a look at green consumer behaviour in the new
Options Scheme. Land Use Policy 17, 241–254. millennium. Journal of Consumer Marketing 16 (6), 558–575.
Parthasarathy, M., Rittenburg, T.L., Dwayne Ball, A., 1995. A re- Stern, P.C., 2000. Toward a coherent theory of environmentally significant
evaluation of the innovation-decision process: the implications for behaviour. Journal of Social Issues 56 (3), 407–424.
product management. Journal of Product and Brand Management 4 Stern, P.C., Dietz, T., Abel, T., Guagnano, G.G., Kalof, L., 1999. A
(4), 35–47. value–belief–norm theory of support for social movements: the case
Peattie, K., 1992. Green Marketing. M&E Business Handbooks. Long- for environmentalism. Human Ecology Review 6 (2), 81–97.
man Publishing, London, UK. Thøgersen, J., Olander, F., 2002. Human values and the emergence of a
Peattie, K., 2001. Golden goose or wild goose? The hunt for the green sustainable consumption pattern: a panel study. Journal of Economic
consumer. Business Strategy and the Environment 10, 187–199. Psychology 23, 605–630.
Pedersen, L.H., 2000. The dynamics of green consumption: a matter of Truffer, B., Markard, J., Wustenhagen, R., 2001. Eco-labelling of
visibility? Journal of Environmental Policy and Planning 2, 193–210. electricity—strategies and trade-offs in the definition of environmental
Prakash, A., 2002. Green marketing, public policy and managerial standards. Energy Policy 29, 885–897.
strategies. Business Strategy and the Environment 11, 285–297. van Rooijen, S.N.M., van Wees, M.T., 2006. Green electricity policies in
Pujari, D., Wright, G., Peattie, K., 2003. Green and competitive influences the Netherlands: an analysis of policy decisions. Energy Policy 34 (1),
on environmental new product development performance. Journal of 60–71.
Business Research 56, 657–671. Velayudhan, S.K., 2003. Dissemination of solar photovoltaics: a study on
Roberts, J.A., 1996. Green consumers in the 1990s: profile and the government programme to promote solar lantern in India. Energy
implications for advertising. Journal of Business Research 36, 217–231. Policy 31 (14), 1509–1518.
Robins, G., Boldero, J., 2003. Relational discrepancy theory: the Vlosky, R.P., Ozanne, L.K., Fontenot, R.J., 1999. A conceptual model of
implications of self-discrepancy for dyadic relationships and for the US Consumer willingness to pay for environmentally certified wood
emergence of social structure. Personality and Social Psychology products. Journal of Consumer Marketing 16 (2), 122–136.
Review 7 (1), 56–74. Vollink, T., Meertens, R., Midden, C.J.H., 2002. Innovating diffusion of
Rogers, E.M., 1995. Diffusion of Innovations, fourth ed. Free Press, innovations theory: innovation characteristics and the intention of
New York. utility companies to adopt energy conservation interventions. Journal
Rogers, E.M., 2001. Diffusion of preventive innovations. Addictive of Environmental Psychology 22, 333–344.
Behaviours 27, 989–993. Yaniv, I., 2004. Receiving other peoples advice: influence and benefit.
Rowlands, I.H., Parker, P., Scott, D., 2002. Consumer perceptions of Organisational Behaviour and Human Decision Processes 93, 1–13.
‘green power’. Journal of Consumer Marketing 19 (2), 112–129. Zinkhan, G.M., Braunsberger, K., 2004. The complexity of consumers’
Salmela, S., Varho, V., 2006. Consumers in the green electricity market in cognitive structures and its relevance to consumer behaviour. Journal
Finland. Energy Policy 24 (18), 3669–3683. of Business Research 57, 575–582.

You might also like