You are on page 1of 23

Draft: December 17, 2002

CREATING WEALTH AND COMPETITIVENESS IN MINING


by John E. Tilton1

The ability of companies and countries to mine copper and other mineral commodities competitively and in the process to generate new wealth depends on their mineral endowment. Chile, for example, produces and exports copper because it is well endowed with high-quality, low-cost deposits. This production creates wealth that benefits mining companies and their stockholders, the government, local communities, as well as copper consumers around the world. The widespread perception that mineral endowment must largely determine competitiveness, or what economists call comparative advantage, must be true at any particularly moment. Countries with abundant reserves must be competitive. This follows from the definition of reservesthe quantity of a mineral commodity found in discovered deposits that are profitable to exploit under current conditions. As a result, it is a tautology and not particularly interesting. The important question is what causes reserves to change over time, producing in the process new wealth and shifts in competitiveness?

William J. Coulter Professor of Mineral Economics at the Colorado School of Mines and at the time some of the research for this article was conducted, Visiting Scholar at the Centro de Mineria of the Pontificia Universidad Catolica in Chile. I am grateful to Rio Tinto plc for kindly providing access to its Mine Information System. This paper is an updated and expanded version of Tilton (2000) and Tilton (2001b). It was prepared for the CRU World Copper Conference: Costs and CapitalImproving Performance in the Copper Industry, held March 19-21, 2002, in Santiago, Chile.

Draft: December 17, 2002

Three possible answers come readily to mind. First, as mining occurs and the best (lowest cost) deposits are depleted, mineral commodity prices may rise, permitting the profitable exploitation of the next best set of deposits. Second, the discovery of previously unknown deposits may augment reserves. Third, innovation and new technology may create reserves by allowing previously known but uneconomic deposits to be exploited profitably. The prevailing or traditional view of competitiveness and wealth creation focuses on the first two possible explanations and for the most part ignores the third. What we can call the alternative view, on the other hand, focuses on the third explanation, and claims it is as important or more important than the first two, especially over the longer term. We know that the first explanation at least in recent years is of little relevance, because real production costs and prices for copper as well as many other mineral commodities have fallen, not risen. While exploration and the discovery of previously unknown deposits are important, are they as important as the innovation and new technologies that permit the profitable mining of previously known but uneconomic resources? Studies that several colleagues and I have conducted over the past few years on the causes and consequences of labor productivity growth in the copper mining industries of the United States and Chile spotlight the importance of innovation and new technology.2 They provide considerable support for the alternative view of competitiveness and wealth in mining.

See Tilton and Landsberg (1999), Aydin and Tilton (2000), Tilton (2000), Garcia and others (2000), Tilton (2001a), Tilton (2001b), and Garcia and others (2001).

Draft: December 17, 2002

For many closely associated with the mining industry, as well as for a few observers outside the industry,3 the importance of innovation and new technology has long been recognized. For the most part, however, government officials and the general public consider mining to be a mature industry with relatively stagnant technology. In the world, as they see it, countries that discover new deposits to replace those being depleted maintain their competitiveness. Countries that fail to do so lose their competitiveness and the wealth flowing from mining. Important and quite different policy implications flow from the traditional and alternative views for both mining companies and mineral producing countries. The implications of the traditional view are considered next, then the evidence from the United States and Chile regarding innovation and new technology, and finally the implications of the alternative view.

The Traditional View

According to the traditional view, the overriding determinant of competitiveness and wealth creation in mining is the geological legacy a country enjoys along with the exploration efforts undertaken to uncover that legacy. This view is intuitively quite appealing, and over time has accumulated quite a large following. It also has a number of important implications. First, it suggests that other determinants of competitiveness and wealth creation are insignificant compared to geologic endowment. The generation and diffusion of new technology along with other innovations, in particular, are of little or no importance.
3

See, for examples, Adelman (1970) and Trocki (1990).

Draft: December 17, 2002

There are two, quite different rationales for this position. The first contends that the technology of mining is mature and stagnant, and that the few changes that do take place do not greatly affected costs. The second recognizes that advances in technology occur, but argues they diffuse quickly around the world providing particular mines, companies, and countries with few opportunities to acquire a cost advantage over other producers. The first of these explanations flies in the face of considerable empirical evidence, and yet in many circles is still widely accepted. Second, the traditional view sees competitiveness and wealth creation in mining as largely a transitory gift of nature. Companies and countries with the best deposits are the most competitive and generate the most wealth. Once their deposits are exhausted, however, competitiveness will shift to those companies and countries with the next best set of deposits. New discoveries can also from time to time cause a change in the distribution of reserves. Third, there is little managers and workers can do to sustain or improve the competitiveness of any particular mine. A mine can produce only so long as it has reserves. Once these are gone, it will close. To remain competitive over the longer run, companies must replace their depleting reserves by new discoveries or by acquiring new deposits in other ways. Fourth, the ability of governments to promote the competitiveness of their mining industries is similarly limited. While policies that encourage domestic exploration may delay the inevitable, the depletion of the best deposits and the exploitation of the best exploration sites will eventually encourage mining companies to search abroad for new reserves. Through taxation and other means, governments can acquire some of the wealth

Draft: December 17, 2002

created from their domestic mineral resources and invest it, thereby ensuring that future generations too benefit from the countrys mineral wealth even after it is gone. What they cannot do is prevent the depletion of their mineral deposits and the loss of competitiveness that follows.

The United States Throughout much of the 20th century the United States mined more copper than any other country. By the late 1970s and early 1980s, however, its industry was in trouble. Between 1970 and 1985, output declined by nearly a third, and its share of Western world production fell from 30 to 17 percent. Employment dropped by 70 percent. Cash costs declined but not enough to keep pace with the drop in market price. As a result, very few mines were earning a profit, and many were not even covering their variable or cash costs. U.S. copper producers petitioned the government for protection from imports in 1978 and 1984, claiming their survival was at stake. On both occasions, their request was denied. The media as well lamented the industrys fortunes. Business Week in the mid1980s ran a cover story declaring the death of mining in the United States. Amoco Minerals, Arco/Anaconda, Cities Service, Louisiana Land and Exploration, and other companies left the industry. They sold their mines to other companies, spun them off as independent companies, or simply shut them down. Of the 24 significant copper mines operating in the United States in 1975, six had closed by 1990 and another five had sharply cut back production.

Draft: December 17, 2002

Yet the industry did survive, staging one of the most spectacular turnarounds in modern industrial history. By 1995 output was 72 percent above its 1985 level, and even 21 percent above its 1970 level. Western world market share recovered to 23 percent. Imports were down, and profits up as costs continued to fall while prices recovered.

Innovation, Mineral Endowment, and Competitiveness Many factors contributed to the recovery of the U.S. copper mining industry, including a decline in real wages, an increase in by-product revenues, a rise in copper prices, and the depreciation of the dollar. Among these, however, a dramatic improvement in labor productivity was more equal than others. As Figure 1 shows, labor productivity more than doubled between 1980 and 1986. So where two workers were needed in 1980, one would do six years later. Labor productivity continued to rise after 1986, though at a more modest pace, and by 2001 was three times its 1980 level. Part of this surge in labor productivity can be attributed to an increase in the amount of capital, energy, and other factors available per worker. During the 1980s, for example, Bingham Canyon undertook a $400 million modernization program that helped the mine quadrupled its labor productivity. Even more important, however, was the introduction of new technologies and other innovations. One particularly important development was the increasing use of the solvent extraction electrowinning (SX-EW) process, which greatly reduced both the operating and capital costs of producing copper. A better understanding of rock mechanics allowed new mine plans that reduced stripping ratios and so diminished the amount of waste generated per ton of ore. Innovative agreements with labor increased the flexibility in

Draft: December 17, 2002

work rules and manning assignments. Better ore handling systems, larger trucks and shovels, bigger drills, in-pit mobile crushers with conveyor belts, more cost-effective explosives, and the computerization of truck schedules and real time process controls in mills are examples of other new technologies and innovations that the U.S. industry introduced in its revival efforts. Relying on the traditional view of competitiveness and wealth creation in mining, we would expect to find behind the revival of the U.S. copper mining industry an improvement in the mineral endowment being exploitedeither from raising the cutoff grade at existing mines or from shifting production from high cost to low cost mines. One looks in vain, however, for much evidence of either. Trends in copper head grades do show a rise in the early 1980sfrom 0.59 percent in 1980 to 0.68 percent in 1984as presumably some mines with poorer deposits closed and other mines turned to higher-grade ores to reduce their costs during this particularly difficult period. However, the rise in head grades was short lived, and over the entire 1971-1993 period that Tilton and Landsberg (1999, Fig. 4.5) examine grades drop considerably, from 0.78 percent to 0.60 percent. We also know that shifts in mine location did not play a dominant role. The new mines brought on stream during the 1975-1990 period, including Flambeau and Cyprus Tohono, contributed very little to the countrys total output, under five percent. So the revival of the U.S. industry came about because existing mines recovered their competitiveness. In particular, Bagdad, Chino, Morenci, Ray, and Tyrone more than doubled their output, while Bingham Canyon increased its production by 50 percent.

Draft: December 17, 2002

These substantial increases raise the possibility that the revival of the U.S. industry was largely the result of productivity improvements and cost reductions flowing from a shift in output away from poor high-cost deposits to the good deposits at these mines. However, when we measure how much of the rise in labor productivity for the industry as a whole was the result of shifts in output from low to high productivity mines and how much was the result of individual mines increasing their productivity, we find that the shift in mine location accounted for only a quarter of the rise in industry productivity (Aydin and Tilton, 2000). This means that three-quarters of the total increase came about as a result of improvements in labor productivity at individual mines, where mineral endowments presumably changed little. These findings suggest that changes in mineral endowment were of secondary importance compared to innovative activity in the recovery of the U.S. industry.

Technology Diffusion and Competitiveness Our research on the U.S. copper mining industry challenges the traditional view of competitiveness and wealth creation in yet another way. Earlier we noted that proponents of the traditional view claim that innovation and new technology have little or no influence on competitiveness because new technology in the global economy diffuses rapidly around the world. For example, it is argued, there is little or no difference in the time at which a new and more efficient shovel or explosive is available to mines in the United States, Chile, Zambia, or elsewhere. So a cost advantage based on new technology either will not arise at all or will be extremely short lived.

Draft: December 17, 2002

This conclusion, however, is based on two implicit assumptions. The first is that a new process or technique is the result of but one innovation. The second is that the effects on all producers are neutral in the sense the impact on costs is the same. As the solvent extraction electrowinning (SX-EW) process illustrates, neither of these assumptions may hold. Ranchers Exploration and Development Company undertook the first commercial production of copper using the SX-EW process in 1968 at its Bluebird Mine in Arizona. Since that time literally hundreds of innovations have improved the processenhancing the quality of the copper produced, reducing costs, increasing the range of treatable copper bearing minerals, and extending the weather and other conditions for successful operation. Moreover, these developments will certainly continue into the future. This means that companies and countries that stay at the forefront of these efforts can indefinitely enjoy a cost advantage over their rivals thanks to technology. In addition, the SX-EW process reduces the costs of some producers much more than others. Specifically, it favors: Companies and countries that historically have been important copper producers, as these producers over the years have accumulated substantial waste piles of oxide copper minerals. The SX-EW process is particularly suited to recover the copper from such low-grade ores. Companies and countries where stringent environmental regulations are enforced. The sulfur emission recovered from smelting copper provides a low cost source for the diluted sulfuric acid used in leaching step of SX-EW processing.

Draft: December 17, 2002

Companies and countries possessing copper deposits in arid regions. The leaching step of the SX-EW process is difficult to control where precipitation is heavy.

Companies and countries with substantial copper reserves that contain few byproducts of value. So far the SX-EW process has not been able to recover economically gold, silver, molybdenum, and other valuable by-products often found in copper ores.

These conditions exist particularly in the United States and Chile. This explains why these two countries account for such a large share of the worlds total SX-EW copper production, and why in turn the SX-EW process accounts for such a large share of their total copper output. The SX-EW process is a particularly dramatic example of the impact on competitiveness and wealth creation that innovation and new technology can have. At the other end of the spectrum, there are thousand of small innovations that can improve the performance of individual mines. As every mine is unique, it has its own innovative opportunities. Although small innovations may individually have little influence on competitiveness and wealth creation, when aggregated they can be of great importance. While some of these opportunities extend over several or even many mines, many are useful only for a given mine with its unique situation. These innovations do not diffuse rapidly around the world.

10

Draft: December 17, 2002

Labor Productivity, Costs, and Mine Survival The collapse and revival of the U.S. copper mining industry over the 1970-1995 period raises yet another intriguing issue: Why did some mines manage to survive and even to expand their output over this period, while others shut down? Table 1 separates the 24 significant copper mines operating in the United States in 1975 into three groups. The 10 expanding mines managed not only to survive but to increase their output over the following 15 difficult years. The three contracting mines survived as significant producers, but suffered a loss in output. The 11 non-surviving mines either stopped production completely or cut back to the point where they were no longer significant producers. Economic theory and common sense leads us to expect the expanding mines to have the lowest cash costs and the highest labor productivity at the start of the period, and just the opposite to hold for the non-surviving mines. Table 2 provides some support for these expectations, though there are anomalies. The non-surviving mines, for example, have lower cash costs in 1975 and higher labor productivity than the contracting mines. Even more surprising, simple econometric models indicate that the ability of mines to reduce their cash costs and to increase their labor productivity after 1975 is actually more important in explaining survival than their starting position in 1975 (Tilton, 2001a). This again suggests that innovative activity played an important role in the recovery of the U.S. copper industry. Why were certain mines more successful than others in fostering productivity growth and in reducing cash costs? While a host of factors were likely involved, Table 2 indicates that the expanding mines produced more and held substantially larger reserves

11

Draft: December 17, 2002

than the contracting and non-surviving mines at the beginning of the period. Large mines with many employees possess more human capital for innovative efforts. Given the greater number of jobs at risk, they may also be more concerned about survival. Similarly, mines with many years of reserves are likely to have greater incentives to invest in new facilities embodying the latest technology since the expected returns can be realized over a longer time horizon. Chile To what extent can we generalize the finding that innovative activity is as important or more than mineral endowment in the creation of wealth and competitiveness in mining? There are good reasons to suspect the U.S. situation may be an anomaly. While the country is a major producer, the development of most new copper mines has in recent years largely taken place abroad, particularly in Chile. One would expect exploration and the development of new deposits to play a much more important role in competitiveness and wealth creation in the latter countries. Our research on Chile was largely motivated by the desire to see if copper mining in that county enjoyed a similar jump in labor productivity during the 1980s as in the United States. And if so, to what extent innovative activity as opposed to the development of new mines drove the increase. As Figure 2 shows, labor productivity increased in Chile during the 1980s, but at a modest pace.4 Chile did experience a jump in productivity similar to that in the United

It is important to note that labor productivity is measured differently in Figures 1 and 2. In Figure 1, labor productivity is the copper contained in U.S. mine output per thousand hours of work by copper company employees. In Figure 2, for the reasons indicated in footnote 5, labor productivity is the copper contained in Chilean mine output per copper company employee. So the levels of productivity shown in the two curves should not be directly compared. As the hours worked per copper company employee in Chile fell during

12

Draft: December 17, 2002

States, but only in the 1990s, a decade after the jump in the United States.5 The 1990s was the decade during which many new mines came on stream in Chile, suggesting that better deposits rather than innovative activity were largely behind the surge in labor productivity in that country. Previously, the state mining company Codelco contributed the lions share of the countrys copper output. In 1990, for example, its mines accounted for three-quarters of all the copper mined in Chile. Over the decade that followed, this figure fell to nearly one-third as Escondida, Candelaria, Cerro Colorado, Zaldivar, El Albra, Collahuasi, and other new mines came on stream, developed for the most part by private multinational mining corporations. Our research indicates that the shift in mine output, particular toward new mines, accounts for about two-thirds of the jump in labor productivity during the 1990s (Garcia and others 2001). This still leaves a surprisingly large portion of the jumpnearly a thirdattributable to increases in labor productivity at old mines. Chiquicamata, Salvador, El Teniente, and AndinaCodelcos traditional minesincreased labor productivity by 37, 70, 70, and 84 percent respectively between 1990 and 1997. A host of different innovative efforts largely created these impressive improvements.

the 1970-1997 period from over 2000 to under 1500, the labor productivity figures shown in Figure 2 for Chile would have to be reduced by 33 to 50 percent to reflect output per copper company employee. 5 The increasing tendency in recent years for copper producers in Chile to outsource to third parties many economic activities raises the possibility that the growth in labor productivity shown in Figure 2 is overestimated. To assess this possibility we corrected the productivity figures shown in the figure for four known shortcomingsthe growing use of outsourcing and contract employees, the decline in the average number of hours mining company employees work per year, changes in the quantities of byproducts produced, and changes in the extent to which ore is processed domestically. The results show that the readily available measure of output per company employee closely tracks the corrected figures (Garcia and others 2000). While the errors introduced by outsourcing are significant, they are for the most part cancelled out by the decline over time in the average number of hours that company employees work annually. Errors arising from the other two sources examined are small by comparison. Thus, the almost four-fold increase in labor productivity in the copper mining industry in Chile over the 1978-1997 period is real, and not just an artifact of outsourcing or the way productivity is measured.

13

Draft: December 17, 2002

Moreover, when we examine labor growth over a longer periodfrom 1978 to 1997we find innovative activities at the level of individual mines to be even more important. Their contribution to the rise in labor productivity was 45 percent, compared to 55 percent for the shift in output from low to high productivity mines. We had expected the development of new mines to account for all or almost all of the growth in labor productivity in Chile, and so were surprised by these figures. They indicate that innovation and new technology as well as the discovery and development of new deposits have played an important role in enhancing Chiles competitiveness in the world copper industry. Without innovation, many of Chiles older mines would no longer be producing, Codelco would not be the worlds largest copper producer, and copper exports from Chile would be a third or so below their current levels.

The Alternative View According to the traditional view, a countrys geologic legacy and exploration determine its ability to compete and create wealth in mining. Aside from finding and developing new high quality deposits, there is little government, management, and workers can do to reduce the relative costs of their mining activities or to extend the working lives of their operating mines. The pressing policy questions that emerge from this view are: How long will our mineral endowment last? How should wealth (or what are commonly called rents) created by mining be divided among workers, companies and their shareholders, the state as a whole, and other interested parties?

14

Draft: December 17, 2002

How much of the wealth or rents should the state invest in other forms of capital, to ensure that future generations continue to benefit from the countrys geologic legacy after the mines are shut?

These questions lead inevitably to concerns over sustainability, intergenerational equity, and the intricacies of green accounting. On the other hand, if the traditional view is wrong or incomplete, if innovation and new technology are important sources of competitiveness and wealth creation in mining as suggested by the alternative view, the set of important policy issues changes. The whole process becomes much more internally driven. There is still wealth created and rents to be captured, but they are not predetermined gifts of nature, fixed in size, that producersfirms and countriescan effortlessly gather up. They are instead created by the mining companies that succeed in the global competition to reduce production costs. Mining becomes much more of a high tech industry than generally recognized, where managers and workers are not helpless bystanders watching external forces unravel their predetermined fate. Instead, they are crucial players who through their innovative efforts influence their own destinies. While every mine eventually runs out of reserves, innovation and new technology may extend the path to extinction by decades. The role of government shifts from ensuring that society as a whole gets its fair share of the wealth created by mining and that it is used in a manner that achieves intergenerational equity, to creating an economic climate conducive to the innovative activities of firms and individuals. In short, public policy focuses more on how to increase the benefits flowing from mining, and less on how best to divide them.

15

Draft: December 17, 2002

Now, human ingenuity can keep the real costs and therefore prices of copper and other mineral commodities falling indefinitely. This in turn reduces concerns about sustainability and intergenerational equity. The copper industry in the United States provides considerable support for the alternative view of the sources of competitiveness and wealth in mining. During its dramatic turnaround in the 1980s, it greatly reduced its production costs, not by discovering new and better deposits, but by a variety of innovative activities that substantially reduced costs and more than doubled labor productivity. In Chile, we find, as we expected, that the discovery and development of new mines contributed greatly to that countrys rising labor productivity, particularly during the 1990s. More surprisingly, we find that innovation and new technology also played an important role in sustaining that Chiles competitiveness and in contributing to the wealth created by the industry. While the stunning revival of the copper mining industry in the United States during the 1980s may be exceptional, the experience of the successful copper mining firms in that country and Chile is not all that unusual. New technologies have radically affected competitiveness and wealth creation in the gold, nickel, and other metal industries. Around the world, mining companies are continually searching for new technologies and other innovations to reduce costs. The discovery and development of new deposits is only one of many possible ways of enhancing competitiveness and wealth creation by reducing costs, and often not the most important. This, as we have seen, greatly alters the policy agenda for mining.

16

Draft: December 17, 2002

References Adelman, M. A. 1970. Economics of exploration for petroleum and other minerals, Geoexploration 8, pp. 131-150. Aydin, H., and J. E. Tilton. 2000. Mineral endowment, labor productivity, and comparative advantage in mining, Resource and Energy Economics 22, pp. 281293. Crowson, P. 2001. Mining and public policy: an alternative view: a comment, Natural Resources Forum 25, pp. 67-69. Garcia, P., P. F. Knights, and J. E. Tilton. 2000. Measuring Labor Productivity in Mining, Minerals and Energy 15, pp. 31-39. Garcia, P., P. F. Knights, and J. E. Tilton. 2001. Labor productivity and comparative advantage in mining: the copper industry in Chile, Resources Policy 27, pp. 97105. Tilton, J. E. 2000. Mining and public policy: an alternative view, Natural Resources Forum 24, pp. 49-52. Tilton, J. E. 2001a. Labor productivity, costs, and mine survival during a recession, Resources Policy 27, pp. 107-117. Tilton, J. E. 2001b. Mining and public policy: an alternative view: reply, Natural Resources Forum 25, pp. 71-72 Tilton, J. E., and H. H. Landsberg. 1999. Innovation, productivity growth, and the survival of the U.S. copper industry, in R. D. Simpson (ed.) Productivity in Natural Resource Industries: Improvement through Innovation (Washington, DC: Resources for the Future). Trocki, L. K. 1990. The role of exploration in iron and copper supply, Resources and Energy 12, pp. 321-338.

17

Draft: December 17, 2002

Figure 1. Labor Productivity in the U.S. Copper Industry, 1975-2001 (Tons of copper contained in mine output per thousand man-hours by copper company employees)

90

75

60

45

30

15

Source: U.S. Geological Survey; U.S. Mine Safety and Health Administration.

18

Draft: December 17, 2002

Figure 2. Labor Productivity in the Chilean Copper Industry, 1970 -2001 (Tons of copper contained in mine output per copper company employee)

140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0

Note: Figures for 1998-2001 are estimates. Source: Comisin Chilena del Cobre, Servicio Nacional de Geologa y Minera, and Consejo Minero.

19

Draft: December 17, 2002

Table 1. Output and Labor Productivity for 24 U.S. Copper Mines, 1975 and 1990a Outputb _________________________ 1975 1990 Growth Productivityc _______________________ 1975 1990f Growthf

Mines Expanding Minesd Bagdad Chino Morenci Ray Tyrone Bingham Canyon Pinto Valley San Manuel Cyprus Miami Sierrita Contracting Minesd Butte Missione White Pine

20 53 125 49 75 247 66 109 45 132 91 106 71 19 27 44 31 13 24 16 33 20 31 20 75 1542

136 145 324 112 155 371 88 142 57 137 90 79 51 4 2 3 2 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 98 1995

590 172 158 129 106 50 34 30 28 4 -2 -26 -29 -80 -93 -94 -94 -96 -99 -100 -100 -100 -100 -100 30 29

20 60 53 44 51 31 59 22 42 35 43 28 13 45 34 18 35 44 38 32 42 30 16 39
g

102 91 95 68 95 153 77 36 52 57 123 62 24 44 14 15 30 35 49 22 29 21 14 45


g

414 51 78 55 87 394 31 63 24 61 184 122 82 -1 -59 -18 -14 -20 30 -32 -31 -31 -12 16
g

Non-Surviving Minesd,f Silver Bell Mineral Park Superior Yerlinton Bisbee Esperanza Continental Ajo Battle Mountain Ruth McGill Sacaton All Other Minesh Total Industryh

20

Draft: December 17, 2002

Notes: All U.S. copper mines whose 1975 output equaled or exceeded 10,000 tons or more of contained copper equivalent in concentrates are included in this table with the exception of Twin Buttes. Although Twin Buttes 1975 output was 13,800 tons of contained copper, it was excluded because its 1975 production was abnormally low, causing its productivity for that year to be unusually low as well. b Output is measured in thousands of tons of copper equivalent contained in concentrate production. Output growth is the percent change in output between 1975 and 1990. c Productivity is measured in tons of copper equivalent contained in concentrate produced per thousand manhours of labor input. Productivity growth is the percent change in productivity between 1975 and 1990. d Expanding mines survived the recession in the copper market during the 197590 period and even managed to increase their output. Contracting mines survived the recession but suffered a decline in output. Non-surviving mines ceased to be significant producers in the sense that their output fell below 4,000 tons of copper equivalent. e The Mission mine also includes the Pima mine. f Labor productivity reported for non-surviving mines for 1990 is actually for their last normal year of operation: 1975 for Ruth McGill and Bisbee, 1976 for Battle Mountain, 1977 for Yerington, 1980 for Mineral Park, 1981 for Silver Bell, Superior, Esperanza, and Continental, and 1983 for Ajo and Sacaton. g Productivity data for All Other Mines are not available. h Output for All Other Mines is the contained copper in concentrate production, and does not include the copper equivalent of byproduct output. Productivity for All Other Mines is measured in tons of copper contained in concentrate per thousand manhours of labor input, and does not take into account the copper equivalence of byproduct output. Total Industry Output includes the copper equivalency of byproducts for all mines except those included under All Other Mines. Sources: Brook Hunt and Associates; Rio Tinto Mine Information System; U.S. Mine Safety and Health Administration.
a

21

Draft: December 17, 2002

Table 2. Average Output, Labor Productivity, and Cost Performance for Expanding, Contracting, and Non-Surviving U.S. Copper Mines, 1975-1990a Performance Expanding Mines Contracting Mines Non-Survivorsd __________________________________________________________________________ Output Growth 81 -18 -96 1975-90 (percent) .......................................................................... 1975 Productivity (tons/1000 hours) 36 24 28

Productivity Growthd 125 124 -19 1975-90 (percent) .......................................................................... 1975 Cash Costsb (cents per pound) Cash Costs Growthb,d 1975-90 (percent) 1975 Breakeven Costsc (cents per pound) 154 -42 116 165 -19 146 160 23 116

Breakeven Costs Growthc,d -29 -26 -6 1975-90 (percent) .......................................................................... 1975 Average Outputa (thousands of tons) 1975 Average Reserves (millions of tons) 1975 Average Reserve Life (years)e 92 558 47 89 126 10 25 34 9

22

Draft: December 17, 2002

Notes: See Table 1 for an explanation of how output and productivity are measured. This table also defines expanding, contracting, and non-surviving mines, and identifies the mines in each of these groups. b Cash costs are in real (1997) U.S. cents per pound. As noted in the text, they cover all the expenses of mining and processing through to the refined metal stage minus capital costs (specifically, depreciation, amortization, and interest on external debt). Cash costs typically include expenditures for labor, materials, energy, and contract services of third parties. c Breakeven costs are also in real (1997) U.S. cents per pound. They are actually adjusted breakeven costs, which are cash costs minus any revenues received for coproducts and byproducts, minus the difference, if any, between a mines reported revenues per pound of copper and the world copper price. d Data for 1990 reported for labor productivity, cash costs, and breakeven costs for non-surviving mines are actually for their last normal year of operation: 1975 for Ruth McGill and Bisbee, 1976 for Battle Mountain, 1977 for Yerington, 1980 for Mineral Park, 1981 for Silver Bell, Superior, Esperanza, and Continental, and 1983 for Ajo and Sacaton. e Reserve life for each mine is calculated by dividing the product of its reserves and the grade of its reserves by its 1975 output. Sources: Output and productivity data: Table 1 and the sources cited there. Cash costs, adjusted breakeven costs, reserves, and grade of reserves: Rio Tinto Mine Information System.
a

23

You might also like