You are on page 1of 49

Asset pricing

Prof. Lutz Hendricks

November 17, 2010

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 1 / 49


Issues

1 What determines the rates of return / prices of various assets?


2 How can risk be measured and priced?

We use the Lucas fruit tree model.


The implications are far more general than the simple model.

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 2 / 49


The Lucas Fruit Tree Model

We study the model introduced by Lucas (1978).


Agents:
A single representative household.
Preferences:

max E0 ∑ β t u ( ct ) (1)
t =0

E0 is the expectation as of time t = 0.

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 3 / 49


The Model
Technology

This is an endowment economy.


There are K identical fruit trees.
Each tree yields dt units of consumption goods in period t.
dt is random and the same for all trees.
Trees cannot be produced.
Fruits cannot be stored.

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 4 / 49


The Model
Technology

The aggregate resource constraint:

ct = Kdt (2)

Assume that d is a …nite Markov chain with transition matrix


π (d 0 , d ).
An important feature: All uncertainty is aggregate.
There are no opportunities for households to insure each other.
This is why we can work with a representative household.

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 5 / 49


The Model
Markets

There are markets for fruits and for trees.


There is also a one period bond, issued by households (in zero net
supply).
Its purpose is to determine a risk-free interest rate.

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 6 / 49


Household problem

The household starts out with bonds (b0 ) and shares (k0 ).
At each date, he chooses ct , bt +1 , kt +1 .
The budget constraint is

pt kt +1 + bt +1 = Rt bt + (pt + dt ) kt ct (3)

Notation:
p : the price of trees. Suppressing dependence on the state.
R : the real interest rate on bonds.
the price of bonds is normalized to 1 (how?).

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 7 / 49


Household problem

V (k, b, d ) = max u (c ) + βEV k 0 , b 0 , d 0 (4)


subject to
Rb + (p + d ) k c + pk 0 b0 = 0 (5)

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 8 / 49


Household problem

First-order conditions:

c : u 0 (c ) = λ
k 0 : λp = EVk (k 0 , b 0 , d 0 )
b 0 : λ = EVb k 0 , b 0 , d 0

Envelope:

Vk = λ (p + d )
Vb = λR

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 9 / 49


Household problem
Euler equations

u 0 (ct ) = β Et u 0 (ct +1 ) Rt +1
pt +1 + dt +1
= β Et u 0 ( c t + 1 )
pt

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 10 / 49


Household problem
Solution

A solution consists of state contingent plans fc (d t ) , k (d t ) , b (d t )g


for all histories d t .
These satisfy:
2 Euler equations
1 budget constraint.
b0 and k0 given.
Transversality: limt !∞ E0 βt u 0 (ct ) [bt + pt kt ] = 0.

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 11 / 49


Market clearing

For every history we need:


Bonds:
bt = 0

Trees:
kt = Kt

Goods:
ct = Kt dt

There is no trade in equilibrium!

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 12 / 49


Competitive Equilibrium

A CE consists of:
1 an allocation: fc (d t ) , b (d t ) , k (d t )g.
2 a price system: fp (d t ) , R (d t )g
These satisfy:
1 household: 2 Euler equations and 1 budget constraint.
2 3 market clearing conditions.

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 13 / 49


Recursive Competitive Equilibrium

Objects:
Solution to the household problem: V (k, b, d ) and c (k, b, d ),
k 0 = κ (k, b, d ), b 0 = B (k, b, d ).
Price functions: p (d ) , R (d ).
Equilibrium conditions:
Household: 4
Market clearing: 2
No need for consistency: law of motion of the aggregate state is
exogenous.

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 14 / 49


Consumption smoothing
The Euler equation implies (for any asset):
βu 0 (ct +1 )
Et Rt +1 =1 (6)
u 0 ( ct )

De…ne: Marginal rate of substitution:


MRSt +1 = β u 0 (ct +1 )/u 0 (ct ) (7)

MRSt +1 is inversely related to consumption growth.


1 σ
With u (c ) = c1 σ :
u 0 (c ) = c σ
(8)
σ
MRSt +1 = β (ct +1 /ct ) (9)

With constant R, the household chooses constant consumption


growth.
L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 15 / 49
Consumption smoothing
The coe¢ cient of relative risk aversion (σ) determines how much
MRS ‡uctuates with c.
High σ implies that the household chooses smooth consumption.
Illustration for the deterministic case:
ct+1/ct
Low σ

High σ

Rt+1
L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 16 / 49
Consumption smoothing

With high σ, marginal utility changes a lot when c changes.


The household then keeps c smooth.

ct+1

High σ
Low σ

ct

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 17 / 49


Asset pricing implications

We will now derive the famous Lucas asset pricing equation.


De…ne: Rate of return on trees: RtS+1 = (pt +1 + dt +1 ) /pt .
Directly from the 2 Euler equations:

βu 0 (ct +1 ) βu 0 (ct +1 ) S
Et Rt +1 = Et Rt +1 =1
u 0 ( ct ) u 0 ( ct )

Or n o
E fMRSt +1 Rt +1 g = E MRSt +1 RtS+1 = 1 (10)

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 18 / 49


When does an asset pay a high expected return?

Re-write asset pricing equation using

Cov (x, y ) = E (x y ) E (x ) E (y )

as

1 = E fMRS g E fR g + Cov (MRS, R )


1 Cov (MRS, R )
E (R ) = (11)
E (MRS )

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 19 / 49


When do assets pay high returns?

1 Cov (MRS, R )
E (R ) = (12)
E (MRS )

High returns require low Cov (MRS, R ).


With CRRA utility: high MRS means low consumption growth.
Therefore: Assets pay high returns if their returns are positively
correlated with consumption growth.

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 20 / 49


When do assets pay high returns?
Intuition

Imagine there are good times (high c) and bad times (low c).
There are 2 assets: A pays dividends in good times, B pays in bad
times.
The value of the dividend is u 0 (c ).
Assets that pay in good times are not valuable: u 0 (c ) is low.
Assets that pay in bad times provide insurance - they are valuable
(have low expected returns).

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 21 / 49


Risk (premia)
The "risk free" assets has expected return
1
E (Rf ) = (13)
E (MRS )

A "risky" asset has expected return


1 Cov (MRS, R )
E (R ) = (14)
E (MRS )

The risk premium is


Cov (MRS, R )
E (R ) E (Rf ) = (15)
E (MRS )

This de…nes what risk means: covariance with consumption


growth.
Note that risk can be negative (insurance).
L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 22 / 49
The Equity Premium Puzzle

Mehra and Prescott (1985): Asset return data pose a puzzle for the
theory.
The equity premium is "high" (6-7% p.a.)
The cov of c growth and Rs is low.
The reason: Consumption is very smooth.

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 23 / 49


The Equity Premium Puzzle

Kocherlakota (1996)

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 24 / 49


The Equity Premium Puzzle

A back-of-the envelope calculation with CRRA utility:

Cov β [ct +1 /ct ] σ , Rs


EP = n o (16)
σ
E β [ct +1 /ct ]

Take log utility: σ = 1.


Cov (MRS, Rs ) ' 0.0022.
E (MRS ) ' 1.
EP ' 0.2%.
Replicating the observed equity premium requires very high risk
aversion (σ = 40).

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 25 / 49


The Equity Premium Puzzle
How severe is the puzzle?

Investors forego very large returns.

Mehra & Prescott (2003)

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 26 / 49


The Equity Premium Puzzle
Long holding periods

Over 20 year holding periods: stocks dominate bonds.

Mehra & Prescott (2003)

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 27 / 49


The Equity Premium Puzzle
Why do we care?

The EP puzzle shows that we do not understand


1 what households view as "risky"
2 why households place a high value on smooth consumption
This has implications for:
1 The welfare costs of business cycles
They are very low in standard models.
2 Stock price volatility.
Standard models fail to explain it (see below).

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 28 / 49


The Equity Premium Puzzle
How to resolve the puzzle

Proposed explanations include:


[ct γct 1 ]1 σ
1 Habit formation: u (ct , ct 1) = 1 σ .
Implies high risk aversion when ct is close to ct 1.
2 Heterogeneous agents
Implicit in the standard model: all idiosyncratic risk is perfectly insured.
3 Borrowing constraints
The young should hold stocks (long horizon), but cannot.
The old receive mostly capital income and …nd stocks risky.
4 Taxes / regulations (McGrattan & Prescott 2001)
The runup in stock prices since the 1960s stems from lower dividend
taxes & laws permitting institutional investors to hold equity.

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 29 / 49


Beta

Now we derive the famous "beta" measure of risk.


Suppose asset m (the market) is perfectly correlated with marginal
utility:
u 0 (ct +1 ) = γ Rm,t +1 (17)

The market’s expected return is

Cov (MRS, Rm )
E Rm R= (18)
E (MRS )

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 30 / 49


Beta

Now we relate the covariance term to marginal utility:

u 0 ( ct + 1 ) Cov (u 0 (ct +1 ) , Rm,t +


Cov (MRS, Rm ) = Cov , Rm,t +1 = (1
u 0 ( ct ) u 0 ( ct )
E (u 0 (ct +1 ))
E (MRS ) = (2
u 0 ( ct )

Therefore:
Cov (u 0 (ct +1 ) , Rm,t +1 ) γ Var (Rm,t +1 )
E (Rm ) R= = (21)
E u 0 ( ct + 1 ) E u 0 ( ct + 1 )

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 31 / 49


Beta

For any asset i:

Cov (u 0 (ct +1 ) , Ri ) γ Cov (Rm , Ri )


E Ri R= 0
= (22)
E u ( ct + 1 ) E u 0 ( ct + 1 )

Take the ratio for assets i and m:

E Ri R = βi [E Rm R ]
Cov (Rm , Ri )
βi =
Var (Rm )

This is the famous CAPM asset pricing equation.

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 32 / 49


Beta

The risk premium for asset i depends on:


it’s beta (essentially the correlation with the market)
the market price of risk: E Rm R.
A stock’s beta can be estimated from data on past returns of the
stock (Ri ) and the market (using a broad stock index).
Betas are used to
Measure the risk of an asset.
Calculate the required rate of return for investment projects.
Evaluation of mutual fund managers.

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 33 / 49


Securities market line
In equilibrium, all asset returns line up on the SML.

Perold (2004)
L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 34 / 49
Securities market line: Evidence
Stocks with higher βs have higher expected returns, but not enough.

Fama (2004)
L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 35 / 49
Solving for the asset price
We show that the asset price equals the present discounted value of
dividends.
Start from the Euler equation:
pt +1 + dt +1
u 0 ( c t ) = β Et u 0 ( ct + 1 ) (23)
pt

Solve for the price:


β u 0 ( ct + 1 )
pt = Et (pt +1 + dt +1 ) (24)
u 0 ( ct )

Replace pt +1 with (24) shifted to t + 1:

β u 0 ( ct + 1 )
pt = Et dt +1 +
u 0 ( ct )
β u 0 ( ct + 1 ) β u 0 ( ct + 2 )
Et E t + 1 (pt +2 + dt +2 ) (25)
u 0 ( ct ) u 0 ( ct + 1 )
L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 36 / 49
Solving for the asset price
The law of iterated expectations:

Et fEt +1 (x )g = Et (x ) (26)

Eliminate the Et +1 :
( )
β u 0 ( ct + 1 ) β 2 u 0 ( ct + 2 )
pt = E t dt +1 +E t (pt +2 + dt +2 ) (27)
u 0 ( ct ) u 0 ( ct )

Iterate forward for T periods:


( )
T
β j u 0 ( ct + j )
pt = E t ∑ dt +j (28)
j =1 u 0 ( ct )
( )
β T + 1 u 0 ( ct + T + 1 )
+E t (pt +T +1 + dt +T +1 ) (29)
u 0 ( ct + T )

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 37 / 49


Solving for the asset price

Impose that the last term vanishes in the limit:


( )

β j u 0 ( ct + j )
pt = E t ∑ dt +j (30)
j =1 u 0 ( ct )

There is no good reason for this assumption!


The asset price equals the discounted present value of dividends.
The stochastic discount factor is the marginal rate of substitution.

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 38 / 49


Example: Log Utility

In the Lucas model, assume: u (c ) = ln(c ). K = 1.


In equilibrium: ct = dt .
β u 0 (c t +1 ) β dt
MRSt +1 = u 0 (c t )
= d t +1 .
The asset pricing equation becomes
( )

βj dt
pt = Et ∑ dt +j
dt +j
j =1
β
= dt
1 β

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 39 / 49


Example: Periodic dividends

In the Lucas model, assume:


Utility is u (c ) = c 1 σ /(1 σ).
dt alternates between d H and d L .
Asset pricing equation:

∑ βj dt /dt +j
σ
pt = dt +j (31)
= dtσ ∑ βj dt1+jσ

On good days, pt is pulled up by low u 0 (c 0 ), but is pushed down by


low dt +1 .

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 40 / 49


The Excess Volatility Puzzle

Consider a stock with dividend process dt .


Its price is given by
( )

β j u 0 ( ct + j )
pt = E t ∑ u 0 ( ct )
dt +j (32)
j =1

In the data:
Dividends are very smooth (a goal of company policy).
Stock prices are much more volatile than dividends.
But in the theory: stock prices should be the average of future
dividends and thus smoother than dividends.
This is the ‡ip-side of the Equity Premium Puzzle.

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 41 / 49


Bubbles

Recall how the asset pricing formula is derived:


We iterate forward on the asset pricing Euler equation

β u 0 ( ct + 1 )
pt = Et (pt +1 + dt +1 ) (33)
u 0 ( ct )

We assume that the pt +1 term vanishes in the limit.


What if it does not vanish?
Then any (current) asset price can satisfy the asset pricing equation.
The deviation between pt and the fundamental price from (33) is
called a bubble.
It is purely a self-ful…lling expectation.

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 42 / 49


Bubbles: Example

Consider an asset that pays no dividends.


Its fundamental price is 0.
β u 0 (c t +1 )
Assume that the MRS is constant at u 0 (c 1 )
= 1.
The the asset pricing equation is

pt = Et pt +1 (34)

One price process that satis…es this: p doubles with probability 1/2
and drops to 0 otherwise.
This satsi…es (34) for any pt .
Bubbles are a possible explanation for asset price volatility.
Note that the bubble does not o¤er any excess return opportunities.

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 43 / 49


State contingent claims

Some assets pay out only in particular states of the world


e.g. insurance contracts
Standard asset pricing formulas apply to those assets.
It just adds notation...

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 44 / 49


State contingent claims

We start from the Lucas fruit tree model.


In addition to stocks and bonds, households can purchase assets that
pay out in exactly one state of the world.
Notation:
quantity purchased of asset that pays out in state d 0 : y 0 (d 0 ).
price of that asset: q (d 0 jd ).

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 45 / 49


Household

states: all assets held, k, b, and all y (d ).


choices: b 0 , k 0 , y (d 0 ).
Dynamic Program:

V (k, b, y (1) , ..., y (N ) , d ) = max u (c ) (35)


0 0 0 0
d0
+ βEV k , b , y (1) , ..., y (N ) ,(36)

subject to

Rb + (p + d ) k + y (d ) = c + b 0 + pk 0 + ∑ q d 0 jd y0 d0 (37)
d0

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 46 / 49


First-order conditions for state contingent claims

u 0 (c ) q d 0 jd = β Pr d 0 jd Vy (d 0 ) k 0 , b 0 , y 0 (1) , ..., y 0 (N ) , d 0 (38)

Envelope:

Vy (d ) (., d ) = u 0 (c ) (39)
Vy (d ) ., d̂ = 0, d̂ 6= d (40)

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 47 / 49


Euler equation

u 0 (c ) q d 0 jd = β Pr d 0 jd u 0 c 0 (41)

In more standard form:


βu 0 (c 0 ) 1
1 = Pr d 0 jd (42)
u (c ) q (d 0 jd )
0

where the rate of return on the state contingent claim is 1/q.

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 48 / 49


Reading

Romer, Advanced Macroeconomics, ch. 7.5


Ljunqvist & Sargent, ch. 7.
Mehra, Rajnish; Edward C. Prescott (1985). "The Equity Premium:
A Puzzle." Journal of Monetary Economics 15(2): 145-61.
Mehra, Rajnish; Edward C. Prescott (2003). "The equity premium in
retrospect." NBER working paper #9525.
Kocherlakota, Narayana R. (1996). "The Equity Premium: It’s Still a
Puzzle." Journal of Economic Literature 34(March): 42-71.

L. Hendricks () Asset pricing November 17, 2010 49 / 49

You might also like