You are on page 1of 24

Effect of Brand Loyalty on Advertising and Trade Promotions: A Game Theoretic Analysis

with Empirical Evidence


Author(s): Deepak Agrawal
Source: Marketing Science, Vol. 15, No. 1 (1996), pp. 86-108
Published by: INFORMS
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/184185 .
Accessed: 04/04/2011 12:31

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at .
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless
you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you
may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.

Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at .
http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=informs. .

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed
page of such transmission.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

INFORMS is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Marketing Science.

http://www.jstor.org
Effect of Brand Loyalty on Advertising and
Trade Promotions: A Game Theoretic
Analysis with Empirical Evidence

Deepak Agrawal
Purdue University

cies for the two manufacturers. The analysis indicates that, if


Abstract one brand is sufficiently stronger than the other and if adver-
In this paper we examine the issue of balancing media adver-
tising is cost effective, then the stronger brand loyalty requires
tising (pull strategy) and trade promotions (push strategy) for
less advertising than weaker brand loyalty, but a larger loyal
manufacturers of consumer packaged goods utilizing a three-
segment requires more advertising than a smaller loyal seg-
stage game theoretic analysis and test model's implications
ment. Moreover, stronger brand loyalty requires more trade
with scanner panel data.
promotion spending under these conditions. The analysis also
We develop a model of two competing manufacturers who
indicates that the retailer promotes the stronger loyalty brand
distribute their brand to consumers through a common re-
more often but provides a smaller price discount for it com-
tailer. In the model the manufacturers directly advertise their
pared to the weaker loyalty brand.
brand to consumers and also provide trade deals to the re-
These analytical results can be understood better if we view
tailer. Each manufacturer's brand has a loyal segment of con-
advertising as a "defensive" strategy used to build brand loy-
sumers who buy their favorite brand unless the competing
alty which helps in retaining the loyal consumers, and price
brand is offered at a much lower price by the retailer. The
promotions as an "offensive" strategy used to attract the loyal
number of loyal consumers is different for the two brands and
consumers away from the rival brand. For example, the result
so is the strength of their loyalty to their favorite brand. The
that the stronger brand invests less in advertising than the
loyal consumers of the brand with stronger loyalty require a
weaker brand can be explained as follows. The stronger loy-
larger price differential in favor of the rival brand before they
will switch away from their favorite brand. alty brand does not find use of advertising attractive because
The manufacturers first decide advertising spending level, it faces little threat from the weaker brand due to its suffi-
and then the wholesale price of their respective brands. The ciently stronger loyalty. Instead it spends more on promotions
two manufacturers do not observe each other's decisions (provided advertising is cost effective) to attract away the
while making these decisions, however they do take into ac- weaker brand's loyal consumers. The weaker brand, on the
count how the other firm is likely to react as a function of their other hand, finds it optimal to defend its loyal franchise by
own decisions. Advertising directly affects the strength of loy- spending more on advertising, as promotions do not help
alty a consumer has for the favorite brand. If the favorite brand much due to the difficulty in attracting away the stronger
advertises, the loyalty strength increases but if the rival brand brand's loyal consumers. In this sense, the stronger brand
advertises, it decreases. The marginal effect of own versus plays "offensive" by using more trade promotions, and the
competing brand advertising is different in magnitude. weaker brand plays "defensive" by emphasizing advertising.
The two manufacturers provide trade deals to the retailer We also conduct an empirical analysis of the model's prop-
by discounting the brand from a regular wholesale price. The ositions using scanner panel data on seven frequently pur-
trade discounts are partially passed on to the consumers by chased nondurable product categories. In a sample of 38 na-
the retailer who sets the retail prices of the two brands after tional brands from the seven categories we find that weaker
observing the wholesale prices. The retail shelf price discounts loyalty brands spend more on advertising; brands with larger
make the promoted brand more attractive to the consumers loyal segment spend more on advertising; and the retailer pro-
due to the reduced price differential between their favorite motes stronger loyalty brands more often but provides a
brand and the promoted brand, thus affecting their switching smaller price discount on average for them compared to
behavior. weaker loyalty brands. These findings are consistent with the
The model and its analysis shed light on the role of brand model.
loyalty in the optimal advertising and trade promotion poli- (Advertising;BrandLoyalty;GameTheory;PromotionalMix)

0732-2399/96/1501 /0086$01.25
MARKETINGSCIENCE/Vol. 15, No. 1, 1996 Copyright ? 1996, Institute for Operations Research
pp. 86h108 and the Management Sciences
EFFECT OF BRAND LOYALTY ON ADVERTISING AND TRADE PROMOTIONS:
A GAME THEORETIC ANALYSIS WITH EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE

1. Introduction to the brand.1 In our model one brand enjoys strong


There has been a recent revival of interest, among both loyalty among its loyal customers (named as stronger
practitioners and academics, in the issue of advertising brand), whereas the rival brand enjoys relatively less
versus trade promotions (see Low and Mohr 1992; Nes- loyalty among its loyal customers (named as weaker
lin et al. 1994a;Neslin et al. 1994b). Consumer packaged brand). Each manufacturer is assumed to decide adver-
goods manufacturers are taking a hard look at their pro- tising level and wholesale price for its brand, taking into
motional mix, particularly trade promotional spending. account possible actions of the competing brand man-
One estimate is that 33% of the trade promotion dollars ufacturer; and the retailer sets retail prices after observ-
is used up in the administrative aspects of trade pro- ing the wholesale prices of the two brands.
motions (a major part of which goes toward the time The analysis points to the differing roles of the
spent by salesforce in settling retailer claims), another strength and size of brand loyalty in the promotional
33% goes directly toward retailer's revenue, and only mix. It indicates that stronger brand loyalty requires less
the remaining 33% ultimately reaches the consumer in advertising than weaker brand loyalty but a larger loyal
the form of a shelf price reduction (Ernst and Young segment requires more advertising than a smaller loyal
Report 1993). These estimates corroborate the concerns segment. Thus it indicates that the weaker brand would
of manufacturers that trade promotional spending is spend more advertising dollars, and the brand with
not getting the desired results, and there is a need to get larger loyal segment size would spend more on adver-
out of the vicious circle of heavy trade dealing in favor tising. Also, the weaker brand would promote to the
of more effective activities, particularly advertising trade more often than the stronger brand.
which helps build brand equity. However, it appears In addition we find that trade promotional spending
that some amount of trade dealing inevitably will be is dependent on cost effectiveness of advertising. If ad-
desirable because trade deals are used not only to in- vertising is cost effective, then the weaker brand would
duce shelf price reductions but also to secure shelf spend fewer trade promotional dollars than the stronger
space, wider distribution, and retailer cooperation (Nar- brand. And if advertising is costly, then the weaker
asimhan 1990). So the real issue facing manufacturers brand would spend more trade promotional dollars
is to achieve a balance between trade dealing and ad- than the stronger brand. At the retail level, however, we
vertising. find that the retailer would promote the stronger brand
In this paper we address this issue by developing a more often but provide a smaller price discount on av-
three-stage game theoretic model of two competing erage for it than the weaker brand. We provide intuition
manufacturers selling their respective brands through for these findings and relate them to previous findings
a common retailer. Our approach is to study adver- in the literature.
tising and trade promotions simultaneously in a com- These analytical results can be understood better if
petitive setting. This is consistent with the Neslin et we view advertising as a "defensive" strategy used to
al. (1994a, p. 405) call for research addressing both build brand loyalty which helps in retaining the loyal
advertising and promotions together and not sepa- customers, and price promotions as an "offensive"
rately. Our primary objective is to understand the role strategy used to attract the customers away from the
of brand loyalty in the optimal promotional mix for rival brand. For example, one result is that the stronger
manufacturers. The game theoretic approach here is brand invests less in advertising than the weaker brand.
not intended to explain observed phenomena but is The intuition behind this result is that the stronger
intended to understand and prescribe optimal pro- brand does not find use of advertising attractive because
motional policy.
In the paper we distinguish between the strength and
' In the theoretical model strength of brand loyalty is defined as the
size of brand loyalty. Strength of brand loyalty is con-
price differential needed before the consumer will switch away to the
ceptualized as the intensity of customer loyalty toward less favored brand (Pessemier 1959). It is noteworthy here that brand
the brand, whereas size of brand loyalty is conceptual- loyalty strength was operationalized differently in the empirical anal-
ized as the proportion of consumers in the market loyal ysis.

MARKETING SCIENCE/Vol. 15, No. 1, 1996 87


AGRAWAL
BrandLoyaltyon Advertisingand TradePromotions

it already enjoys sufficiently stronger loyalty and there- ered to have more immediate and short-term effects on
fore faces little threat from the weaker brand. Instead it purchase behavior (Rossiter and Percy 1987). And there
finds it optimal to spend more on promotions (when is evidence that advertising effects follow a hierarchical
advertising is cost effective) in order to attract away the process (AIDA model, Strong 1925), whereas sales pro-
weaker brand's customers. The weaker brand, on the motion effects do not (reference price theory, Helson
other hand, finds it optimal to defend its loyal franchise 1964; prospect theory, Kahneman and Tversky 1979).
by spending more on advertising, as the promotions do Given these differences and the fact that both advertis-
not help much because it is difficult to attract away the ing and price promotions commonly are used in the
stronger brand's loyal customers. In this sense, the promotional mix of a brand, it becomes important to
stronger brand plays "offensive" by using more trade model them differently yet simultaneously in a single
promotions, and the weaker brand plays "defensive" framework so that their opposing effects can be studied.
by emphasizing advertising. On the analytical side, Raju et al. (1990) examined two
We also conduct an empirical analysis of the model's competing manufacturers' pricing policies as a function
propositions using scannerpanel data on seven frequently of brand loyalty. They define a stronger and a weaker
purchased nondurable product categories. In a sample of brand in terms of strength of brand loyalty and examine
38 national brands from the seven categories,we find that how the degree of brand loyalty determines the optimal
weaker loyalty brands spend more on advertising;brands frequency and depth of price promotions. Their analysis
with larger loyal segment spend more on advertising;and indicates that the weaker brand promotes more often
the retailer promotes stronger loyalty brands more often than the stronger brand (this is shown to hold empiri-
but provides a smaller price discount on average for them cally as well) and offers smaller price discount when it
compared to weaker loyalty brands. These findings are is sufficiently weaker, but offers greater discount when
consistent with the model, thereby indicating support for it is only moderately weaker, than the stronger brand.
it. We next provide a brief review of the relevant literature We build on this framework by incorporating manufac-
and point out main contributionsof this researchover pre- turer advertising and retailer pricing decisions in ad-
vious research. dition to manufacturer pricing, thereby allowing us to
study advertising and trade promotion tradeoffs and
retail promotion activities.
2. Literature Review Other research which examines pricing policies of
Advertising and trade promotions differ significantly in competing manufacturers includes Narasimhan (1988),
several respects, including their effect on consumers' Rao (1991), and Lal (1990a, b). Narasimhan defines
purchase behavior, time frame within which effects take brand power in terms of proportion of customers loyal
place, and the processes by which the effects take place. to the brand and predicts that the average price will be
For example, in the context of frequently purchased higher and the frequency of promotion lower for the
goods, the main effects of advertising are considered to stronger brand. Rao examines competition between a
be brand positioning, category expansion, brand rein- national brand and a private label and shows that only
forcement (repeat purchase), and brand switching the national brand promotes to attract the private label
(Deighton et al. 1990), whereas the main effects of sales customers (if they are sufficient in number). The private
promotions are considered to be brand switching, pur- label does not promote because its promotions only in-
chase acceleration, stockpiling, and repeat purchase crease the frequency of promotions by the national
(Blattberg and Neslin 1990). Advertising is commonly brand. Lal addresses the issue of why retail promotions
believed to positively affect brand loyalty, whereas pro- occur and argues that national brand manufacturers al-
motions may either have a negative effect or not have ternate promotions in order to keep the private label
any effect (Neslin and Shoemaker 1989, Davis et al. brand from encroaching upon their market share.
1992). Advertising is considered to have long-lasting ef- One interesting finding in this paper is that at the man-
fects with possible delayed response and slow decay ufacturerlevel weaker loyalty brand promotes more often
(Little 1979). Promotions, on the other hand, are consid- than the stronger loyalty brand (consistent with Rajuet al.

88 MARKETINGSCIENCE/Vol. 15, No. 1, 1996


AGRAWAL
BrandLoyaltyon Advertisingand TradePromotions

1990), and at the retail level, the retailer promotes the can be induced to switch away if there is sufficient price
weaker brand less often than the stronger brand (consis- differential between the favorite brand and the less pre-
tent with Rao 1991). Rajuet al. consider only manufactur- ferred brand. In other words, both brands are in each
ers, whereas Rao considers retail price competition be- consumer's consideration set, with one brand being the
tween a national brand and a private label. Thus our find- favorite. We define the extent of favoriteness by the
ing helps to reconcile the results of Raju et al. and Rao. price differential needed before the consumer will
Neslin et al. (1994b) model a monopolist manufac- switch away to the less favored brand (Pessemier 1959).
turer's optimal promotional mix policy as a dynamic We assume that it takes a larger price differential to
econometric model. They examine promotional mix make a consumer who prefers brand s to switch to
policy as a function of retailer carrying costs, retail pass brand w than what it takes a consumer who prefers
through, consumers' response to advertising, and con- brand w to switch to brand s. This implies that brand s
sumers' response to retail price promotions. Their sim- commands stronger preference among its loyal consum-
ulations demonstrate a tradeoff effect between advertis- ers compared to what brand w commands among its
ing and trade promotions consistent with our finding loyal consumers. Let the loyalty among loyal consumers
(when advertising is cost effective). Also, they find that to brand s be Is,,and the loyalty among loyal consumers
as retail pass through increases (either in terms of fre- to brand w be lw, such that Is, > Iw,.
quency or depth), frequency of trade promotions de- The number of loyal consumers to each brand may dif-
creases, depth of trade discounts increases, total expen- fer such that a brand may have a very few but strongly
ditures on promotions increase, and advertising expen- loyal consumers, many but only mildly loyal, or any other
ditures decrease for the monopolist. We also find this combination. Without loss of generality we normalize the
in our analysis for the stronger brand, which enjoys total number of consumers to equal one and assume that
higher retail pass through in terms of frequency. Se- a proportion ms of consumers prefer brand s and propor-
thuraman and Tellis (1991) also develop a monopoly tion mwprefer brand w, where ms + mw= 1. We further
model to investigate the impact of the ratio of price to assume that a consumer loyal to brand s has a reservation
advertising elasticity on the tradeoff between advertis- price r for brand s and a lower reservation price (r - Is)
ing and trade promotions. We add to this literature by for brand w, whereas a consumer loyal to brand w has a
incorporating competition in the analysis. reservation price r for brand w and a lower reservation
In summary, the main contributions of this research price (r - iw) for brand s. Each consumer is assumed to
over previous research are in studying advertising and buy a brand and buy one unit of the chosen brand such
trade promotions simultaneously in a competitive setting, that surplus is maximized. Thus the demand function at
in developing an integrated analytic framework to ex- the retail level for brand i (where i = s, w; i * j) can be
amine the tradeoffs between the two, in incorporatingthe written as (see Figure 1):
role of the retailer,and in empirically investigating the role
of brand loyalty in promotional policies using scanner [1 if pi < pj - Ij,

panel data from several product categories. In the next Di(pi,pj) = jmiif pi - li c pj c pi + Ij,
section, we describe the model in detail and present anal-
tO if pj < pi - Ii.
ysis of manufacturer advertising and price promotional
policies and of retail pricing. Then we present details of The manufacturers are assumed to advertise their
empirical investigation, and finally summarize the discus- brands directly to the consumers. They simultaneously
sion and conclude with directions for further research.

Figure1 Consumer
DemandFunction
3. Model Consumers Consumerw
In our model, there are two national brands s and w wouldn'tbuy s wouldn'tbuy w
offered through a common retailer to a group of con-
sumers. Each consumer is loyal to a brand, but he/she PS-IS PI PJ+ IW _ PW

MARKETING SCIENCE/VOL 15, No. 1, 1996 89


AGRAWAL
BrandLoyaltyon Advertisingand TradePromotions

decide advertising levels (i.e., without knowing the ad- for their respective brands to the retailer. As part of
vertising level for the rival brand) a, and a,,, for their their promotional mix, manufacturers offer trade
respective brands such that own advertising positively deals to the retailer with the intention of reducing the
affects and competing brand's advertising adversely af- selling price of the brand making it more attractive to
fects the strength of brand loyalty. Furthermore the ef- loyal and nonloyal consumers alike. The trade pro-
fect of own advertising is assumed to differ from that motional spending is defined as the total discount
of competing brand's advertising through a parameter, given to retailers over all purchases; where discount
y. A high y means that the effect of own advertising is is the difference between the regular price (i.e., the
higher than competitor's advertising, whereas a low y highest wholesale price) and the actual wholesale
means that the effect of competitor advertising is higher price in equilibrium. After observing the wholesale
than that of own advertising. In other words, a high y prices, the retailer is assumed to set retail prices p, and
means advertising works more on brand's own loyal p, for the two brands, respectively, so as to maximize
customers than on potential brand switchers (similar to expected profits. The marginal costs of production
the idea that advertising affects loyals differently than and distribution for the two manufacturers, and the
switchers as in Tellis 1988 and Deighton et al. 1994).2 marginal cost of retailing are assumed to be zero.
Finally, to incorporate diminishing returns to advertis- In this three-stage model the manufacturers are as-
ing, we assume that advertising effects have a square sumed to decide advertising levels first for their re-
root formulation and that advertising costs are linear, spective brands without knowing the advertising
i.e., it costs aa, and aa?.,to advertise for manufacturers level for the rival brand. Next they are assumed to
s and w, respectively, where a captures the cost effect- decide the wholesale prices for their respective
iveness of advertising. A small a implies advertising is brands without knowing the wholesale price of the
relatively cost effective, and a large a implies advertis- rival brand but knowing the advertising levels of both
ing is relatively costly. This parameter captures market- brands. These assumptions imply that (1) in any
wide advertising effectiveness and is assumed to be the given planning horizon advertising decision precedes
same for both brands. It reflects the notion that in some pricing decision, (2) pricing is changeable more easily
markets advertising may be relatively cost effective in than advertising, and (3) once advertising is under-
reaching target consumers, such as when target audi- taken it becomes a sunk investment. Lastly, the re-
ence is geographically concentrated, or when a cam- tailer is assumed to decide the retail prices for the
paign has higher effectiveness because of the nature of brands it offers to consumers after observing the
the clientele. These assumptions translate into the fol- wholesale prices of the two brands. There is support
lowing asymmetric effects formulation for the post- for this stagewise decision making in the literature
advertising loyalties: (Quelch and Farris 1983, Shapiro 1987).
Now we solve this three-stage game for the equilib-
rium advertising and pricing strategies beginning with
Is = + yFas- (1 - y)aF,
ISO the third stage retail pricing strategy.
Retail Pricing Strategy
IW= lu.o + -y a5 - (1 - -y)a,
The retailer's profit function is:
where 0 < y < 1 captures the effectiveness of own ad-
vertising. (P if Ps < Pw -
s-W) I,
After deciding advertising levels, the manufactur- ms(ps - ws) + mw(pzv - wW)
ers simultaneously declarewholesale prices wsand ww
if Ps1 is pw c Ps + Iw,

(PW- wu,) if PZw


< PS - is.
2 Many of the results in this paper are based on y > 0.5, which implies
own advertising is more effective than competitor advertising in af- The retailer would maximize profits by charging the
fecting brand loyalty. highest price that the consumers will pay. Intuitively,

90 MARKETINGSCIENCE/VOL.15, No. 1, 1996


AGRAWAL
BrandLoyaltyon Advertisingand TradePromotions

there are three possibilities for the retailer as indicated PROOF. See Appendix.
by the retail demand function: (1) if the stronger brand This result suggests that at the retail level, we would
is sufficiently cheaper than the weaker brand, promote expect to see more frequent promotions but lower dis-
the stronger brand and sell it to both consumer seg- counts on the stronger brand. This finding is consistent
ments; (2) if the weaker brand is sufficiently cheaper with Rao (1991), whose model corresponds to a retailer
than the stronger brand, promote the weaker brand and setting the price of its own private label and retail price
sell it to both consumer segments; and (3) if the two of the competing national brand. He finds that the
brands are not sufficiently different in wholesale prices weaker brand is promoted less often than the stronger
then do not promote either brand, and sell each to its brand. This result is interesting also because at the man-
loyal segment. Consistent with these possibilities, we ufacturer level, it is reversed. We describe manufacturer
obtain the following retail pricing strategy in equilib- results next.
rium:
Manufacturer Pricing Strategy
PROPOSITION1. The optimal pricing strategy of the re- We solve for the second-stage manufacturer pricing
tailer is to chargep, = r - 1w- E,pw = r if ww > w, + (1 / equilibrium treating advertising spending in the first
mW,)lw;chargeps = r, pu' = r if w, (1/ms)l C< ww s Ws stage of the game as a sunk investment. The post-
+ ( /m)1,)l1,; and charge, ps = r, pw = r - - e if w > ww advertising profit function for manufacturer i (i = s, w;
+ (//ms)i. I # j) is:
PROOF. See Appendix. [wi if wj > w, +(1 /mj)1j,
To understand this equilibrium note that the retailer
ni = jmiwi if wi- (1/rmi)n w? c< WI.+ (1/m)nJ),
can always sell a brand to its loyal segment at regular
price. It promotes a brand only if the margin obtained to if wi > wi + (1/mi)Ii.
on selling the promoted brand to all of the market is
It can be shown that a mixed strategy equilibrium in
higher than selling it only to the loyal segment at regular
prices exists for the above game when l. m2 r and Is
c
price. The equilibrium indicates that the retailer pro-
2 mj(r - lW)/(1 + msmw)(see Raju et al. 1990). We in-
motes a brand if its wholesale price is sufficiently lower
terpret the mixed strategy equilibrium as a promotional
and that he/she promotes only one brand at a time, if
equilibrium in which the reservation price r is the reg-
at all. Moreover, when the retailer promotes a brand,
ular price and a promotional price is any price below r.
he/she does not buy the nonpromoted brand from the
We obtain the following results:
manufacturer.

1.1. Thepricediscountofferedby the retailer


COROLLARY
PROPOSITION2. The weakerbrandmanufacturer
pro-
motes more often but providessmaller discount on average
on the weakerbrandis largerthan thatofferedon the stronger
than the strongerbrandmanufacturer.
brand.

PROOF. See Appendix.


PROOF. See Appendix.
This manufacturer level finding is consistent with the
This result follows from the retail price equilibrium
above. The retailer offers a larger discount 1I on the manufacturer pricing equilibrium in Raju et al. (1990);
weaker brand compared to lw on the stronger brand. and the retail level findings (Corollaries 1.1 and 1.2) are
Note that because the regular price is the same (=r) for consistent with retail pricing model of Rao (1991). A
both brands, this result holds for percentage discounts reason for this reversal of findings at the manufacturer
as well. In other words, the retailer offers a higher per- and retail level is essentially that the retailer cares about
centage price discount on the weaker brand than the category profit, whereas manufacturers care about their
stronger brand. respective brand profit. The retailer realizes that the
stronger brand does not have to be promoted as steeply
COROLLARY1.2. The retailer promotes the stronger as the weaker brand because it commands a price pre-
brandmorefrequentlythan the weakerbrand. mium with consumers. Thus promoting the stronger

MARKETINGSCIENCE/Vol. 15, No. 1, 1996 91


AGRAWAL
BrandLoyaltyon Advertisingand TradePromotions

brand more steeply would only erode retailer's profit (1) the ratio of total retail spending over total trade pro-
margin on stronger brand and forego profits it makes motional spending on the brand during the year; (2) the
on the weaker brand. ratio of price discount in retail promotion over price
However, at the manufacturer level, the brands are in discount in trade promotion for the brand in a particular
a market share game. The stronger brand increases its promotion; and (3) the ratio of frequency of retail pro-
profits only by attracting weaker brand's customers. motions over frequency of trade promotions in a year.
Therefore it keeps trying to induce the retailer to pro- It turns out that the ratio of expected retail spending
mote its brand more steeply by offering steeper trade over expected trade promotional spending on the brand
deals. Moreover, the stronger brand, in order to be pro- is higher for the stronger brand consistent with Bucklin
moted at the retail level, not only has to overcome the (1988), Curhan and Kopp (1986), Blattberg and Neslin
loyalty of the weaker brand but also has to provide at- (1990), and Tellis and Zufryden (1994). More interest-
tractive enough margin to the retailer to entice the re- ingly, however, it turns out that retail pass through is
tailer into promoting the brand. This aggressive strategy higher for the stronger brand in terms of frequency but
on part of the stronger brand necessitates higher trade lower in terms of size of discount.
discounts on average compared to the weaker brand, This result is interesting because it shows that the two
which is only trying to keep its loyal customers from measures of pass through can go in different directions,
switching to the stronger brand. and that the retailer may follow this strategy to suc-
But the frequency with which the stronger brand pro- cessfully maximize its profits and yet appease both the
vides a trade discount is lower than the weaker brand stronger and weaker brand manufacturers with respect
because to induce the retailer to discount stronger brand to compliance with the terms of the trade deals.3
to attract weaker brand's loyal customers, the stronger COROLLARY 2.2. As the size of its loyal segment in-
brand has to offer a lower price on all its sales to the creases,the weakerbrandmanufacturerpromotesmoreoften
retailer, including those that ultimately result from its and providesa largerdiscount on average, but the stronger
own loyal customers. Therefore, it provides trade dis- brandpromotesless oftenand providesa smallerdiscounton
counts relatively less often. The retailer, on the other average.
hand, enjoys a higher margin on the stronger brand
PROOF. See Appendix.
even after promotion (the stronger brand is discounted
This result is interesting because it indicates that the
by 4, compared to a discount of 1 on the weaker brand);
two brands follow different strategies as the size of their
therefore the retailer promotes the stronger brand more
own loyal segment changes. Unlike the stronger brand
often.
the weaker brand manufacturer prefers to rely more on
Thus adding a retailer to the model provides new im-
promotions as its own loyal segment size increases. The
plications and also helps in understanding the differ-
intuition behind this result is that consumers are only
ences in the results of Raju et al. and Rao. Another in-
weakly loyal to brand w, and as more consumers be-
teresting implication from the above results is with re-
come loyal to the weaker brand it uses promotions to
spect to retail pass through, stated formally next.
keep them from switching to the rival brand. The
COROLLARY 2.1. Comparedto the weaker brand, the stronger brand, on the other hand, does not need
strongerbrandenjoys higher retail pass throughin termsof promotions to keep the strongly loyal consumers from
frequencybut lowerpass throughin termsof size of discount. switching.
PROOF. See Appendix. PROPOSITION 3. The stronger brand manufacturer
Conceptually retail pass thorough (RPT, for short) is spendsmoretradepromotionaldollarsthan the weakerbrand
defined as the fraction of trade deal that is passed on to
the consumers in the form of a retail promotion (Che-
3In practice, however, manufacturers may favor frequency aspect of
valier and Curhan 1976). Because there are two dimen- pass through as a monitoring device because it is easier to observe and
sions to a retail promotion, the size and frequency of is more comparable across retailers than size of discount pass through.
discount, there are at least three ways to look at RPT: This issue needs to be researched further.

92 MARKETINGSCIENCE/Vol. 15, No. 1, 1996


AGRAWAL
BrandLoyaltyon Advertisingand TradePromotions

manufacturer, if advertising is cost effective, specifically Iwi - aai ifwj> wi+ (1/m1)1
when a* < a < a**; and spends less tradepromotionaldol-
miw, - aa,
lars than the weakerbrand manufacturer,if advertising is
costly, specificallywhen a > a**. if wi - (1/m.)l C wj C w. + (1/m )1,

-aa, if wi > w + (1/mi)li,


PROOF. See Appendix.
The intuition behind this result is that if advertising where a captures the cost effectiveness of advertising such
is cost effective, the weaker brand is able to defend its that a lower a implies more cost-effectiveadvertising, and
loyal franchise by spending on advertising, and the advertising affects initial loyalties such that (for i = s, w;
stronger brand has to spend more trade promotion dol- i * j), li = li, + yva7 - (1 - y)Fa1. We obtain the following
lars to attract the rival's loyal consumers. But if adver- Nash equilibrium:
tising is costly, then the weaker brand is not able to
defend its franchise very well, and the stronger brand PROPOSITION 4. 'Whenthe stronger brand is suffi-
does not have to spend more trade promotion dollars ciently stronger, specificallywhen l, 2 1b0;l( -,- mu,r; and
to attract the rival's loyal consumers. when own advertisinghas greatereffecton own loyalties (y
> 2), the optimal advertising levels are such that: a* = 0;
COROLLARY3.1. As the size of its loyal segment in- - ((m2,r - Iwo) )/y)2 when a c a*; and a* = 0; a*U
creases, the weakerbrandmanufacturerspends moredollars = ((lv - lzvo)/y)2 when a > a*, wherea* = mz,,r(1 + m?,
on promotions,but the stronger brandspends fewer dollars - m,)y2/(mzi,r - lu,o)2;and 1*,= l (lzLo,
ISOr, a, m,L,);and
on promotions. /so = msr(1 + mw)/(l + mwms) + (1 - )/(m ,r -Iz,,)
if m2(1 + mZ)/(1 + mSmZV) ? m2,; and
PROOF. See Appendix.
This result is consistent with Corollary 2.2, as ex-
I (1 - ) M2r(1 + mw)
pected.

3.2. As the relativeeffectivenessof own ad-


COROLLARY ?m,~ if1 mz(1mS) O

2(1 +m,,)
vertising, y, in affecting loyalty strength increases, both
brandsspend less on promotions.

PROOF. See Appendix. PROOF. See Appendix.


This result indicates that promotions become less at- This equilibrium suggests that if the stronger brand
tractive for the manufacturers as advertising becomes is sufficiently stronger than the weaker brand, then the
more effective in reinforcing brand loyalty among loyal stronger brand would not invest in advertising for the
consumers. purpose of building loyalty4 because it already enjoys
sufficiently stronger loyalty. The weaker brand, on the
COROLLARY 3.3. As loyaltystrengthof the weakerbrand
other hand, invests in advertising to build loyalty be-
increases,both brandsspend less on promotions.
cause it pays to invest in advertising to defend its loyal
PROOF. See Appendix.
franchise from switching to the stronger brand. More-
Consistent with Corollary 3.2, this result indicates over, if advertising is highly cost effective (a c a*),
that both brands decrease promotional spending as then the weaker brand spends more on advertising
(= ((mwr - I,/ )2) compared to when advertising is
their ability to keep loyal consumers increases.
Next we examine manufacturer advertising equilib- not so cost effective.
rium.
4Note that advertising levels (aS,a,,) represent advertising used for
Manufacturer Advertising Strategy building brand loyalty; these levels are over and above the minimum
The preadvertising profits for manufacturer i (i = s, w; amount of advertising the two manufacturers may undertake to main-
I f j) are: tain their brand in consumers' consideration set.

MARKETING SCIENCE/VOl. 15, No. 1, 1996 93


AGRAWAL
BrandLoyaltyon Advertisingand TradePromotions

COROLLARY 4.1. As the size of own loyal segment in- fective; the stronger brand would not invest in adver-
creases, the advertisingspendingalso increases. tising for the purpose of building loyalty because it al-
ready enjoys sufficiently higher loyalty. It also would
PROOF. See Appendix.
not spend any money on promotions because the threat
This result indicates that as more consumers become
from weaker brand promotions is minimal. The weaker
loyal to a brand, the brand invests more in advertising.
brand, on the other hand, would invest in advertising
This is consistent with the loyalty reinforcing role of
to build loyalty because advertising is cost effective and
advertising in the model.
it pays to invest in advertising to defend its loyal fran-
COROLLARY 4.2. As the relativeeffectivenessof own ad- chise from switching to the stronger brand. Also, the
vertising, y, in affecting loyalty strength increases, the ad- two brands would not spend any money on promotions
vertising spendingdecreases. because advertising is very cost effective in keeping the
loyal consumers. Thus in this situation the weaker
PROOF. See Appendix.
brand would worry about defending its loyal franchise,
Corollaries 3.2 and 4.2 provide an interesting result
and the stronger brand would be content with its loyal
on the effect of y on promotional spending (i.e., adver-
franchise.
tising and trade promotional spending) by the two
RESULT2. When the stronger brand is sufficiently
brands. Note that as y increases, the advertising by a
stronger, specifically when i,o and l,o satisfy conditions
brand plays a more defensive role as it reinforces own
as in Proposition 4, and when advertising is cost effec-
brand loyalty. Thus both brands are better able to keep
tive, specifically when a* < a < a**, the stronger brand
their loyal customers and hence find it less attractive to
does not advertise (a* = 0); the weaker brand advertises
spend on promotional activities. This reasoning is also
(a* = ((lw - lzo)/y)2); both brands promote and the
consistent with Corollary 3.3, which says that trade pro-
weaker brand spends less trade promotional dollars
motional spending would decrease for both brands as
than the stronger brand in equilibrium.
the two brands develop their own strong loyal fran-
PROOF. See Appendix.
chises. One reason for these results put together may be
RESULT3. When the stronger brand is sufficiently
that as both brands develop their own strong loyal fran-
stronger, specifically when Is, and lwo satisfy conditions
chises, perhaps the competitive backlash is reduced,
as in Proposition 4, and when advertising is costly, spe-
which in turn reduces the need for promotional
cifically when a > a**, the stronger brand does not ad-
spending.
vertise (a* = 0); the weaker brand advertises (a*
Finally we substitute the manufacturer pricing equi-
= - Iwo)/ y)2); both brands promote and the weaker
librium into the advertising equilibrium to get the over-
brand spends more trade promotional dollars than the
all manufacturer equilibrium as a function of exogenous
stronger brand in equilibrium.
initial brand loyalties.
PROOF. See Appendix.
Overall Manufacturer Equilibrium We first note that these results apply to a situation
We obtain the following results on overall manufacturer where the two brands sufficiently differ with respect to
equilibrium: strength of brand loyalty. In other situations, such as
RESULT 1. When the stronger brand is sufficiently when both brands command strong loyalties, both
stronger, specifically when lSOand lwosatisfy conditions brands do not advertise or promote in equilibrium (re-
as in Proposition 4, and when advertising is very cost fer to Lemma 2 in the appendix). Still other cases, such
effective, specifically when a c a*, the stronger brand as when both brands have weak loyalties or when loy-
does not advertise (a* = 0); the weaker brand advertises alties are not sufficiently different, we leave for future
(a* = ((m 2r - lwo)/y)2); and both brands do not pro- research.
mote in equilibrium. The results indicate that given sufficient difference in
PROOF. See Appendix. loyalty strength, the weaker brand would spend rela-
The intuition behind this result is that if the stronger tively more on advertising than the stronger brand.
brand is sufficiently stronger and advertising is cost ef- Intuitively, the stronger brand does not invest in

94 MARKETING SCIENCE/VOl. 15, No. 1, 1996


AGRAWAL
BrandLoyaltyon Advertisingand TradePromotions

Figure2A AdvertisingExpenditures

Size of loyal segment Ad spending


Adsenig
a w
Small
Large .~~~~~~~~~~ 'ge aI

Strong a aS w Sm
> aS
Strengthof
Loyalty l A A __ oy lty
Weak
Weak a
aS
as Weaker
> ~~~~~~~~~~~~~
Stronger
w w

Ad spending al

as

> Loyalty
Weaker Stronger Strength

advertising to build loyalty because it already enjoys not price promote for the push effect. If advertising is
sufficiently stronger loyalty to begin with. The weaker only moderately cost effective (a* < a < a**), the
brand, on the other hand, invests in advertising to build weaker brand is moderately able to defend its loyal
loyalty so that it is better able to defend its loyal fran- franchise by spending on advertising and the stronger
chise. In contrast to relative advertising spending, the brand needs to outspend the rival on trade promotions
relative trade promotional spending is affected by the to attract the rival's loyal consumers. And if advertising
cost effectiveness of advertising. The results suggest is costly (a > a**), then the weaker brand is not able to
that manufacturers would price promote only if adver- defend its franchise very well, and therefore, the
tising is not very cost effective, i.e., if they believe that stronger brand does not need to outspend the rival on
consumer pull is sufficient for their category, they will trade promotions to attract the rival's loyal consumers.

Figure2B TradePromotionalExpendituresWhenAdvertisingIs Cost Effective

Size of loyal segment Promotional


Large Small Spending
s MEP~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
Strong MEPs MEP MEPX 1
Lav%o ~~~~~~~MEPS
Strengthof | VLv v
Loyalty 1
Weak MEP > MEP
PW
~ Loyalty
Weaker Stronger Stength

MARKETING SCIENCE/VOL 15, No. 1, 1996 95


AGRAWAL
BrandLoyaltyon Advertisingand TradePromotions

Figure2C TradePromotionalExpendituresWhenAdvertisingIs Costly

Size of loyal segment Promotional


Large Small Spending

Strong MEPs < MEPs5 MIEPW

srn~~~~~~~~~
X
Strength of A
Loyalty MEPW
EWeakP
Weak
MEPw >w MEPS
I I > Loyalty
Weaker Stronger Strength

These results are summarized graphically in Figures 2 brand, thus the average retail price discount is indepen-
(a), (b), and (c). dent of the segment size. Given this we do not derive
The results can be further illustrated with the help of the comparative statics results of retail promotions as a
an example. Consider two real but disguised brands X function of segment size. We empirically examine four
and Y in a food category. Brand X is a strong national of these results. The empirical analysis is presented
brand (loyalty estimate = 0.66) competing with a next.
weaker national brand Y (loyalty estimate = 0.52). The
model suggests that since the loyalty to X is already very
strong, it only needs to do minimal advertising to main- 4. Empirical Analysis
tain its brand in consumers' consideration set. Brand Y, In this section we attempt an empirical analysis of the
on the other hand, needs to invest in advertising to build model by examining data, to see if the patterns in data
brand loyalty; otherwise, it may lose its loyal consumers are consistent with the model's implications. To the ex-
to X. Indeed, the market share adjusted advertising tent the data patterns are consistent, it increases our
spending for brand X is almost half that of brand Y. In confidence in the underlying assumptions and structure
addition if advertising is costly (such as when there are of the model.
no significant economies of scale of advertising; perhaps
Hypotheses Development
because consumers are spread all over the market), X
An ideal method for examining model's propositions
needs to spend fewer dollars on promotions also, be-
would be to identify pairs of strong and weak loyalty
cause given costly advertising Y is not able to increase
brands which compete with each other and compare
its loyalty strength much, and with fewer trade pro-
their promotional activities. In reality, however, several
motional dollars X is able to attract Y's loyal customers.
brands compete with one another, making it difficult to
Indeed, the trade promotional spending of X is less than
unambiguously identify two brands which compete
30% of spending of Y. If advertising is cost effective
with only each other. Therefore we develop an across
(such as when customers are geographically concen-
category framework in which we obtain brand loyalty
trated and easy to reach), the model suggests that X
estimates for brands in several product categories and
would need to spend relatively more trade promotional
relate these estimates to measures of their promotional
dollars to make the rival's loyal customers switch.
activities using regression analysis.5 Furthermore, since
The main results from the theoretical analysis relating
strength of brand loyalty and size of loyal segment to
advertising and pricing policies are summarized in Fig- 'We use the terms manufacturer advertising/ promotions and brand
ure 3. Note that the retailer provides a discount of ls on advertising / promotions interchangeably in this section even though
the weaker brand and a discount of l,7,on the stronger the same manufacturer may offer multiple brands in a category.

96 MARKETING SCIENCE/VOl. 15, No. 1, 1996


AGRAWAL
BrandLoyaltyon Advertisingand TradePromotions

Figure3 MainTheoreticalResults

Manufacturer Trade Promotion Average Price Discount Frequency of Promotions


Advertising Expenditures
Expenditures
Manufacturer Retailer Manufacturer Retailer
Strength of Brand as < aw MEPs>MEPw if x*<anx** ADS > ADw RADS < RADw MPS< MPw RPS> RPw
Loyalty (Proposition4) MEPs<MEPw if >(Xa** (Proposition 2) (Corollary 1.1) (Proposition2) (Corollary 1.2)
(main effects) (Proposition 3)
Size of Loyal (,aI/n,)> ? (dMEPI/dm,)< 0 (dAD /dd)< 0 (dMP / dm)< 0
Segment (da&/Idm.)> | (dMEPI/d w,)>0 (ADA./do )> - (dMFP/dm)>O -

(comparative statics) (Corollary4.1) (Corollary 3.1) (Corollary 2.2)_ (Corollary2.2)

Notation:
aj : Manufactureradvertisingexpenditures for brandi (i=s,w)
MEPi : Trade promotionexpenditures for brandi (i=s,w)
ADi : Average price discount offered by manufacturerof brandi (i=s,w)
RADi : Average price discount offered by retailerfor brandi (i=s,w)
MPi : Frequency of trade promotions for brandi (i=s,w)
RPj : Frequencyof retail promotions for brandi (i=s,w)
mi : Size of loyal segment of brandi (i=s,w)
a : Cost effectiveness parameterof advertising(a higher a implies costlier advertising)

not all data are accessible to us (for example, wholesale H3. The averageprice discount at the retail level is neg-
prices and corresponding retail prices), we focus on atively relatedto the strengthof brandloyalty.
only those propositions for which we are either able to
H4. Thefrequencyof price promotionsat the retail level
obtain data or construct proxy measures. Thus we do
is positively relatedto the strength of brandloyalty.
not test hypotheses concerning trade promotion expen-
ditures. Construct Measurement

Manufacturer Advertising BrandLoyalty(LOYALTYi,SIZEi). In the theoretical


Results 1-3 imply that the weaker brand manufacturer model, the strength of brand loyalty is defined as the
spends more advertising dollars than the stronger relative price differential needed to switch given that
brand, and Corollary 4.1 implies that advertising spend- the two competing brands have same regular price. In
ing is higher for the larger loyal segment size, thus in- reality, however, it is difficult to estimate such a price
dicating following expected patterns in the data: differential because, first, unambiguously identifying a
competing pair of brands in a category with several
H1. Themanufactureradvertisingspendingis negatively competing brands is not possible, and second, brands
relatedto the strength of brandloyalty. have different regular prices. Even if such price differ-
H2. The manufactureradvertisingspending is positively entials were available, how to relate them to measures
relatedto the size of loyal segment. of brand advertising and promotional activities is not
clear. Therefore we focus our efforts on developing an
Retail Promotions interval scaled estimate of brand loyalty which reflects
Corollaries 1.1 and 1.2 imply the following patterns relative strength of loyalty among consumers in the
in the data: market and which could be related to the interval scaled

MARKETINGSCIENCE/VOL 15, No. 1, 1996 97


AGRAWAL
BrandLoyaltyon Advertisingand TradePromotions

estimates of brand advertising and promotional activi- the similarities of our brand loyalty measure with these
ties. approaches later in this section (after Equation 5).
In the literature brand loyalty has been measured in We next describe the method for estimating strength
several different ways. Raj (1982) defines highly loyal of brand loyalty (LOYALTYi) and size of brand loyal
customers as those who devote more than 50% of their segment (SIZEi)using scanner panel data which contain
product class purchases to the brand. Krishnamurthi purchase histories of several households over several
and Raj (1991) use the proportion of times each brand weeks.
is bought on all preceding purchase occasions, updating We estimate the following logit model:
it as each purchase occurs, as a measure of brand loy-
h-exp(uZ)i
alty. These share of purchase driven measures do not it
exp ( uhj)(1)
capture the effect of marketing mix. For example, a
brand may have high share of purchases just because it uh= ai + y propen, + , fkXk,I where (2)
is heavily price promoted. Guadagni and Little (1983) k

use an exponential smoothing formulation for brand h purchases


Pith the probability that household
loyalty which incorporates the effect of past purchases brand i at purchase occasion t,
(including past marketing mix activity) on the current the utility to household h of purchasing
i=
purchases. Fader and Lattin (1993) develop an alterna- brand i at purchase occasion t,
tive measure assuming choice probabilities are distrib-
propeni = a measure of household h's propensity to-
uted according to a Dirichlet distribution which also in- ward brand i based on purchase behavior
corporates the effect of past purchases. Allenby and before time t,
Rossi (1991), on the other hand, define brand loyalty as t = the level of marketing mix variable k for
the residual of the predicted probability of choice from brand i at purchase occasion t, and
the choice indicator averaged over all occasions. This a i, y, fk = model parameters.
measure filters out the effect of past marketing mix ac-
tivities in computing brand loyalty. All these measures Households are heterogeneous in their propensity to
capture the heterogeneity across households in propen- purchase different brands. To capture this heterogeneity
sity to purchase different brands quite well, and treat in preferences across households we use the measure
this heterogeneity as a direct measure of brand loyalty. propenh (Srinivasan and Kibarian 1989). To compute
Chintagunta et al. (1991) and Gonul and Srinivasan this measure, we first estimate (using maximum likeli-
(1993) conceptually distinguish between household het- hood estimation procedure) the above logit model with-
erogeneity and intrinsic brand preference. These au- out the propenh term on first half of the data, which we
thors use the intercept term in the brand utility model call calibration period data. Next we use the estimated
as a measure of intrinsic brand preference and use semi- parameters to compute predicted probability of choice,
parametric methods for estimation. qt over the calibration period. The heterogeneity mea-
It can easily be shown that the intercept term in the sure is then computed as:
utility model is perfectly able to capture the rank order
propenh = 6 propenh
information in the relative price differentials needed to
make a consumer switch away from one brand to the
+ (1i- tq)(y i_-q_i) where (3)
other. In other words, the relative price differentials (the
definition of brand loyalty used in this paper) and the I 1 if i chosen at t -1,
intercept values have a perfect rank order correlation.
=0 otherwise.
Therefore we develop a measure of brand loyalty here
along the lines of Chintagunta et al. (1991) and Gonul Here Yi propenh =0, and 0 < 6 < 1 is a smoothing
and Srinivasan (1993) which is based on the intercept parameter, usually in the range of 0.70 to 0.85. The
term in the brand utility model and which also incor- propenh measure was initialized as 0.0 for all brands.
porates heterogeneity across households. We discuss Note that propenhincreases if the brand is chosen on

98 MARKETING SCIENCE/VOl. 15, No. 1, 1996


AGRAWAL
BrandLoyaltyon Advertisingand TradePromotions

previous occasion and decreases if it is not. If the brand brand over the households in its loyal segment reflect-
is not chosen on previous occasion then yh _I = 0, which ing the strength of loyalty among its loyal consumers:
will have a negative effect on propenh. And if the brand
>hm
is chosen on previous occasion then y- = 1, which will LOYALTYi
= , where (5)
Nh
have a positive effect on propenZh, as desired. The
propenh estimates were found not to be significantly LOYALTYi= estimated brand loyalty6 for brand i,
sensitive to different values of 6, therefore we use a Nh =number of households in the segment loyal to
value of 0.75 in all our estimations. Finally, the brand i.
propenh vector for household h on the last purchase oc- The size of loyal segment, SIZE,, is computed as the
casion T in the calibration period is used as a measure percentage of households that belong to the loyal seg-
of household heterogeneity as it represents the most sta- ment of brand i.
ble vector in the calibration period of household pro- We note that our brand loyalty measure is similar to
pensities towards different brands. the two approaches available in the literature. One ap-
Next, we estimate the logit model in Equation (1) proach is to use a measure of household heterogeneity
with the marketing mix variables X"'s and the similar to propenh measure to capture brand loyalty
propenh term on the second half of data, which we call (Allenby and Rossi 1991, Fader and Lattin 1993, and
estimation period data, using maximum likelihood es- Guadagni and Little 1983), and the other approach is to
timation procedure. This provides us with the estimates use the intercept term in the utility model in Equation
of model parameters a's, ', and, 's. Next we estimate (2) to capture the intrinsic brand preference (Chinta-
the household level predicted probability of choice of gunta et al. 1991, Gonul and Srinivasan 1993). The dif-
each brand on each occasion at equal marketing mix ference in our method is that instead of using only the
activity on the estimation period data using the follow- intercept term or the household heterogeneity, we com-
ing model: bine the effects of both to capture brand loyalty and use
a computationally easier estimation procedure com-
mht
- where (4) pared to the semiparametric procedures. Also, our
=j exp(&,+ 5y IPP
propen h )
method guarantees a loyalty and segment size estimate
i= predicted probability of choice of brand i for for each brand in the category unlike semi-parametric
household h at purchase occasion t keeping the mar- methods. We need these estimates for each brand to test
keting mix activity constant across brands. the hypotheses.
This step (Equation 4) in effect gives the brand spe-
ManufacturerAdvertisingExpenditures(EXPENADV.).
cific preference (relative to other brands in the category)
We note that our interest is in examining the effect of
for each household when all brands have equal mar-
exogenously specified initial brand loyalties on manu-
keting mix support, akin to a measure of intercept term
facturer advertising and retail price promotion policies.
(incorporating household heterogeneity) in the utility
Accordingly, we use advertising data from a period
function.
subsequent to the time period of scanner panel data to
Next, we classify each household into a loyal segment
account for this direction of causality.7 The data on
based on the predicted probability vector on the last
purchase occasion T in the estimation period, Mh, for
that household. We assume that the household is loyal 6A simple share of purchases measure has a correlation of 0.51 (p
to that brand which has the highest predicted probabil- = 0.0003) with LOYALTY,,indicating that as intended LOYALTYiis
ity of choice (i.e., h E segment1 s.t. mih > mh- Vi * j). not simply capturing share of purchases.
We use the last purchase occasion here because it rep- 7Note that as with advertising, the causality in the empirical data may
resents the most stable probability vector given the pur- work in reverse with price promotions also, i.e., price promotions may
affect brand loyalty rather than brand loyalty affecting price promo-
chase history of the household. Lastly, we compute the
tions. Thus to test the model it would also be desirable to ensure loy-
interval scaled loyalty measure for each brand by av- alty estimates precede price promotion estimates in time. The inability
eraging the predicted probabilities of choice of the to do this is a limitation of our empirical analysis.

MARKETING SCIENCE/Vol. 15, No. 1, 1996 99


AGRAWAL
BrandLoyaltyon Advertisingand TradePromotions

brand advertising were obtained from Arbitron's ad- Table 1 Descriptionof Data
vertising dollar summary published yearly. This pub-
Category # Purchases# Brands # Households#Stores #Weeks
lication reports dollar advertising expenditures in nine
media for most national brands. The measure of adver- OrangeJuice* 2958 6 115
tising expenditures is computed as the brand advertis- Crackers* 3159 6 252 15 104
ing expenditure expressed as a percentage of the total Coffee* 4946 4 398 6 108
advertising expenditures for all brands analyzed in the Laundry
Detergent* 2275 7 300 13 52
category.
Catsup* 4502 4 333 5 161
AveragePrice Discount Offeredby the Retailer(PRICED- PeanutButter* 8465 6 404 5 161
ISi). We operationalize this construct by the percentage Dishwashing
reduction in the average price when the brand goes on Liquid* 5356 13 256 5 161
promotion (i.e., feature and/or display), where price
FromI.R.I.,Inc.
reduction is the difference between the estimated reg- ** FromA.C.Nielsen, Inc.
ular price and the posted price. The regular price is es-
timated by the average price when the brand was not
featured or displayed. To examine the data patterns implied by H1 - H4, we
Frequencyof RetailPromotions(FREQPROMi). We op- begin by noting that the theoretical analysis assumes a
erationalize the frequency of retailer promotions by the sequential decision making process in which retail pro-
frequency of price cuts observed in the scanner panel, motion frequency and average price discount decisions
defined as the number of occasions on which the esti- are dependent on manufacturer advertising expendi-
mated regular price exceeds the actual price posted in tures decided earlier on in the first stage. To incorporate
the store, expressed as a percentage of the total number this dependence among decisions in the model, we in-
of occasions on which the brand could have been avail- clude EXPENADVi as an explanatory variable in retail
able. This proxy measure captures the relativefrequency promotion equations. We estimated the following three
of retailer promotions across brands. linear statistical models to derive the data patterns:

Data Description EXPENADVi = a0 + ajLOYALTYj


We estimated brand loyalties, loyal segment sizes, retail + a2SIZEj+ (6)
E ajDj+ (,
promotion frequencies, retail average price discounts,
and brand advertising expenditures for seven product
PRICEDISi = jo + j3LOYALTYi
categories: orange juice, crackers, coffee, laundry deter-
gent, catsup, peanut butter, and dishwashing liquid. A + j32EXPENADVi+ ,lfjDj + 2, (7)
brief description of the datasets is provided in Table 1.
There are 46 brands in these seven categories, of FREQPROMi= yo + yjLOYALTYj
which eight are private labels. We include the private
labels in the estimation of brand loyalties and segment + y2EXPENADV-+ E 71D1+ i, (8)
sizes, but exclude them in further analysis because theo-
retical analysis concerns brands which may promote to where subscript i (i = 1 to 38) refers to a national brand
the trade. Private labels do not promote to the trade as and D1s(j = 1 to 7) are the 0-1 category specific dummy
they are owned by the trade itself. This implies a sample variables included to capture any category specific dif-
size of 38 national brands for examining the data pat- ferences on variables not included in the above equa-
terns. We present the estimates of the various measures tions.
in Table 2 for all the brands in the seven categories. Note It is hypothesized that a1 < 0 (H1), a2 > 0 (H2), 81
that all measures within a category are defined in rela- < 0 (H3), and yi > 0 (H4).
tive terms rather than absolute terms thus making We estimated the above three equations using Joint
across category comparisons possible. Generalized Least Squares (SUR) estimator which

100 MARKETING SCIENCE/VOl. 15, No. 1, 1996


AGRAWAL
BrandLoyaltyon Advertisingand TradePromotions

Table2 MeasurementEstimateson Seven ProductCategories

Category Brand Loyalty Size EXPENADV PRICEDIS FREQPROM

OrangeJuice 1 0.6077 0.1910 0.1544 0.1379 0.1105


2 0.4373 0.4494 0.4859 0.1254 0.1579
3 0.4828 0.2584 0.2917 0.1705 0.1870
4* 0.4897 0.0112 0.0852 0.0352
5* 0.3424 0.0377 0.1700 0.3110
6 0.4774 0.0562 0.0436 0.1381 0.1024
Crackers 7* 0.5039 0.1382 0.0244 0.0603
8* 0.5693 0.4431 0.0396 0.0615
9 0.5698 0.0203 0.1685 0.2403 0.3237
10 0.5763 0.0610 0.1774 0.0702 0.3212
11 0.7204 0.0285 0.2957 0.1682 0.3051
12 0.6012 0.3089 0.3548 0.1345 0.3103
Coffee 13 0.4439 0.0244 0.0251 0.1753 0.6929
14 0.6071 0.2774 0.4948 0.1587 0.6821
15 0.5712 0.5488 0.4730 0.0164 0.6543
16 0.6140 0.1494 0.0070 0.0991 0.6435
Laundry 17 0.5668 0.3808 0.4188 0.1222 0.6561
Detergent 18 0.5263 0.1967 0.1204 0.0875 0.6617
19 0.5544 0.1715 0.0868 0.1190 0.5683
20 0.4633 0.1130 0.1195 0.1022 0.6496
21 0.5482 0.0502 0.0455 0.0656 0.5389
22 0.5633 0.0586 0.1517 0.0938 0.4399
23 0.5566 0.0293 0.0572 0.0649 0.3360
Catsup 24 0.0000 0.0000 0.3561 0.4320 0.2820
25 0.8022 0.9153 0.4307 0.0189 0.5019
26 0.5633 0.0780 0.1983 0.0577 0.4870
27* 0.7046 0.0068 0.0126 0.4919
PeanutButter 28 0.6594 0.3137 0.3742 0.0214 0.5764
29 0.6097 0.3217 0.2111 0.0405 0.5602
30 0.4072 0.0054 0.1571 0.0197 0.5180
31 0.5246 0.0563 0.2212 0.0872 0.5180
32 0.2979 0.0027 0.0299 0.0545 0.5764
33* 0.6631 0.2949 0.0943 0.6286
Dishwashing 34 0.5303 0.0241 0.0413 0.0785 0.5640
Liquid 35 0.4635 0.1124 0.1107 0.0602 0.4634
36 0.4182 0.0120 0.0250 0.0011 0.4410
37 0.5160 0.0161 0.1306 0.0677 0.4484
38 0.0000 0.0000 0.0670 0.0894 0.0882
39 0.3935 0.0723 0.0900 0.1532 0.5093
40 0.0000 0.0000 0.0167 0.0102 0.0882
41 0.3091 0.0040 0.0255 0.0106 0.3056
42 0.5573 0.2731 0.1498 0.0398 0.5851
43 0.4989 0.2289 0.2595 0.0279 0.5528
44 0.5293 0.2169 0.0720 0.0591 0.5540
45* 0.5722 0.0361 0.2456 0.3540
46* 0.7041 0.0040 0.0013 0.1441

Privatelabel brand.
***** Datanot available.

MARKETING SCIENCE/VOl. 15, NO. 1, 1996 101


AGRAWAL
BrandLoyaltyon Advertisingand TradePromotions

resulted in more efficient (but qualitatively identical) Table3 EstimationResults


estimates compared to OLS and 2SLS estimators, as this variable
Dependent
estimator takes into account the correlations in error variables
Independent EXPENADV PRICEDIS FREOPROM
terms across the equations. We checked for multicolli-
nearity and model misspecification problems by esti- 0.107C2 0.135a2 0.231a2
CONSTANT* (1.963) (4.112) (4.957)
mating various specifications including SIZE, and the
-0.1 83' - 0.1 98a 0.477al
LOYALTYi*SIZEi interaction terms in all three equa- LOYALTY (1.422) (2.82) (4.768)
tions but found no difference in qualitative results. 0.607a1
SIZE (5.364)
-0.05 0.049
EXPENADV (0.591) (0.397)
5. Empirical Results 0.084 0.120a2 _0.343a2
The results of the SUR estimation presented in Table 3 Dl** (1.348) (2.973) (5.969)
indicate that the equations fit the data reasonably well, 0.191a2 0.153a2 -0.222a2
with the system weighted R2 being 0.743. D2 (2.869) (3.627) (3.696)
With respect to advertising expenditures, the data 0.093 0.101 b2 0.158b2
support the patterns hypothesized in H1 and H2. The D3 (1.4575) (2.451) (2.702)
0.048 0.073b2 0.055
stronger brands spend less on advertising (p < 0.10),
D4 (0.907) (2.198) (1.157)
and brands with larger loyal segments spend more on 0.104 0.141a2 -0.04
advertising (p < 0.0001). D5 (1.456) (3.037) (0.609)
With respect to retail promotions, the data support 0.098c2 0.109 0.071
the patterns postulated in H3 and H4. The retailer pro- D6 (1.712) (0.514) (1.358)
vides higher price discount on average for the weaker SYSTEMWTDR2 0.743
n 38
loyalty brands (p < 0.01) and promotes the weaker loy-
alty brands less often as compared to stronger brands tvalues in parentheseswith each estimate.
(p < 0.0001). We note that this particular empirical re- * The Divariablescapturecategoryspecific effects.
al significantat 0.01 level using one-tailedtest.
sult supports the analytical finding of the retail pricing
a2
model in Rao (1991). significantat 0.01 level using two-tailedtest.
bl significantat 0.05 levelusingone-tailed test.
We also estimated the three equation system with the b2 test.
at 0.05 levelusingtwo-tailed
significant
advertising expenditure variable adjusted for market cl significantat 0.10 level using one-tailedtest.
share points. In other words, we divided the EXPEN- c2
significantat 0.10 level using two-tailedtest.
ADV by the market share (in %) to take into account Note:Alldirectionalhypothesesare tested using a one-tailedtest.
the possibility that a large share brand may spend more
just because of its greater size. The market share
measure was computed as a share of purchases in the 6. Conclusions and Future Research
panel. The results with respect to H1(p < 0.01), The theoretical analysis presented here provides implica-
H3(p < 0.05), and H4(p < 0.05) did not change. But be- tions for the optimal advertising and price promotion
cause the correlation between SIZE and market share is policies for competing manufacturers selling through a
high (=0.91, p < 0.01), the pattern hypothesized in H2(p common retailer.For example, the analysis indicates that
> 0.35) was significant only at the 0.35 level. if the stronger loyalty brand is sufficiently stronger than
Overall the data seem to be consistent with the pat- the weaker loyalty brand and if advertising is cost effec-
terns implied by the model. This is by no means a con- tive, then stronger brand loyalty requires less advertising
clusive test of model's validity; however, we believe than weaker brand loyalty, but a larger loyal segment re-
that good regression fits combined with strong signifi- quires more advertising than a smaller loyal segment.
cance of the results is encouraging. We also believe that Moreover,strongerbrand loyalty requiresmore trade pro-
the testing methodology presented here is useful and motion spending under these conditions. In addition, the
that efforts should continue to further test the theory. retailer should promote the stronger loyalty brand more

102 MARKETING SCIENCE/Vol. 15, No. 1, 1996


AGRAWAL
BrandLoyaltyon Advertisingand TradePromotions

often but provide a smaller price discount for it compared coincide with the objectives of the manufacturers. In
to the weaker loyalty brand. The empirical analysis, based future, extensions of the model to incorporate these
on scanner panel data on seven product categories, pro- features would be desirable. Another limitation is the
vides encouraging evidence for the model. However, there linear additive form used for the effect of advertising
are several caveats associated with these analyses in ad- on brand loyalty. Although it helps to keep the model
dition to their strengths. tractable, this functional form does not capture the
The results with respect to brand loyalty strength may possible advertising threshold effects. Lastly the as-
at first seem counter-intuitive. For example, recently the sumption that the size of loyal segment remains un-
consumer packaged goods company, Proctor and Gam- changed after advertising takes place is a limitation. In
ble, announced a strategy to move away from trade reality, advertising may induce changes in the size of
dealing in favor of advertising. P&G is widely regarded loyal franchise.
as a strong national brand manufacturer. One way to In addition to advertising and trade dealing,
interpret P&G's actions in the model's context would be manufacturers also use consumer promotions in the
that P&G is trying to build brand loyalty so that it be- promotional mix to attract customers such as cents-
comes unquestionably a stronger brand. Once the off coupons, sampling, and contests. It will be desir-
brands are sufficiently stronger, P&G wouldn't need to able to consider consumer promotions also in the
invest further in advertising. In a way, the model im- model.
plies that P&G's brands are not "sufficiently" stronger In the empirical investigation, the most limiting fac-
in loyalty strength yet. tor is the unavailability of trade promotions data,
The model and its analysis in this paper has the ad- which precluded us from investigating propositions
vantage of parsimony. It integrates the advertising and regarding trade promotion spending. Also the defi-
pricing decisions in a very parsimonious way through nition of strength of brand loyalty does not exactly
the construct of brand loyalty in a three-stage formula- match in the theoretical and empirical analysis. More-
tion. It incorporates main effects of advertising- over, in the theoretical model we analyze a suffi-
namely, brand reinforcement-and of promotions- ciently stronger brand competing with a weaker
namely, brand switching and repeat purchase in a com- brand; however, it is difficult to identify empirically
petitive setting in the context of established product cat- if the stronger brand is indeed sufficiently stronger
egories. The model also considers the role of the retailer, than the weaker brand. This is a limitation of our em-
thus capable of providing implications for retail pass pirical analysis. Another limitation is the assumption
through. The analyses highlight the distinction between that each consumer is loyal to some brand as each
the strength and size of brand loyalty, which is appeal- household is classified as a loyal household (to some
ing theoretically and also useful practically. For exam- brand). In reality a consumer may not be loyal to any
ple, marketers may benefit directly from knowing the one brand but may regularly switch among a subset
composition of their category franchise; specifically, of brands. Inclusion of a switching segment in the
how many loyal customers there are for each brand, and analysis will enrich the framework.
how loyal they are to each brand. In summary we develop a parsimonious analytic
The main caveats associated with the model relate to framework to examine the tradeoffs between advertis-
the absence of (1) dynamic effects of advertising and ing and trade promotion strategies. Extensions of this
promotions; (2) of repeated interactions among the framework to incorporate dynamic and repeated inter-
manufacturers, retailers, and consumers; and (3) retail action effects and retail competition should prove fruit-
competition. Retail competition, for example, plays a ful in enhancing our understanding of the promotional
significant role in the retailer pricing strategy as the re- mix. In addition we develop a methodology for esti-
tailers continuously monitor competitors' pricing and mating the size and intensity dimensions of brand loy-
promotional activities for designing their own strate- alty using readily available scanner panel data. Further
gies. Moreover, retailer's primary objectives, to maxi- work on refining this methodology should also prove
mize store traffic and shelf turnover, do not necessarily fruitful because these estimates (of size and intensity of

MARKETING SCIENCE/Vol. 15, No. 1, 1996 103


AGRAWAL
BrandLoyaltyon Advertisingand TradePromotions

brand loyalty) are of direct and significant relevance in


optimal brand strategy.8
s.t. p",< p -1I, (A5)

? C p7V C r, Oc p5 C-- r. (A6)


Appendix
Since this is symmetric in lv, 1, to Action 1, the retailer will pick pS
PROOF OF PROPOSITION 1. The retailer's profit function is: =rand pUI= r - - E, and earn profits
15 of I = [r - 15 - E - w].

mi(ps-ws)+ ( if p < p-1, Now, the retailer will follow Action 1 only if fl > fl, fl1. Now,
PS
rl > [lr if
rlr ms(ps
- Ws) + mW(pU1,
-
W70) if p5
-
Is C:- p7V CpS + IlV,/
(r - - e - w5) > r - mvwv - mSwS,
(Pw -ww) if p7,, < pS-Is
1
or if, w7, > ws +-IW, (A7)
Given the reservation prices, (r, r - IS) for the customer loyal to
brand s, and (r - I,. r) for the customer loyal to brand w, for brands
and,flr > rlr if (r - lw- e - w5)
s and w, respectively, the retailer does not charge a price above r.
There are three possible actions for the retailer: > (r - 1, - E - w5), or if, ww > w5 + (lw - Is).
Action 1: Sell only brand s to the whole market.
Action 2: Sell each brand to their own loyal segments. Since mwlu,> (17?.- IS),therefore condition (A7) is sufficient. Thus,
Action 3: Sell only brand w to the whole market. when W7., > Ws + m7V17V, retailer follows action 1. By symmetry, when
Retailer's optimization problem under Action 1 is: wI > w7, + m5sl,retailer follows Action 3. And for all intermediate
prices, wI - mI" c W7Vc wI + mWl17Vretailer follows Action 2.
max = (ps - Ws) The pricing strategy of the retailer is therefore:

chargep, = r - 17V- C; p7V = r if W7v> wI + (1/mW)lW


s.t. Ps < pw -w, (Al)
chargep, = r; pw= r if w5- (1/m5)1 C W7V C wI + (1/mW)lW
O -p-7V - r, Oc ps C r. (A2)
charge p5 = r; p7V = r - 1- e if wS > wW+ (1 /m5)lI. L
/lips > 0, retailer will choose the maximum p. that satisfies
Since lO1H1r
PROOF OF COROLLARY1.1. This result directly follows from the
constraints (Al) and (A2). Also, since flr is independent of Pw,retailer
retail price equilibrium above. The weaker brand has to offer a larger
can pick any Pwthat satisfies (Al) and (A2). Therefore, the retailer will
discount Is in order to attract the stronger brand loyal consumers,
pick pw= r and ps = pw - l7 - e r--l0v - , where eis an infinitesimal
whereas the stronger brand has to offer 17V to attract weaker brand loyal
number. The profits will be flr = [r - 17- e - wS.
consumers, where 1I > lw in equilibrium (shown later in Proposition
Retailer's optimization problem under Action 2 is:
4). 0
max flr = mS(ps - Ws) + mw(pw - ww) PROOF OF COROLLARY1.2. Retailer promotes the stronger brand
with a probability, Prob.[ww > ws + (1/mW)17V], and promotes the
s.t. WA) weaker brand with probability, Prob.[ws > ww + (1 /ms)Isj. As shown
PS -IS pw PS+1w,
in Raju et al. (1990), the asymmetry in loyalties (lw c m2%r and 15 2 ms(r
0 ' pwc r, 0 p5 C r. (A4) - lIj)/(1 + msmj)) ensures that the probability with which the weaker
brand is able to attract stronger brand's loyal consumers is zero, i.e.,
Condition (A3) represents all possible pairs of prices (ps, pw) for
Prob.[ws > W71, + (1 /mS)1J] = 0. Thus at the retail level, weaker brand's
which each brand retains its loyal customer. The retailer can maximize
promotion frequency is lower than that of the stronger brand. As
profits by charging the highest price for each brand, because 19H/2
shown later the asymmetry in post-advertising loyalties is preserved
ps > 0 and OHr/Opw > 0. The optimal prices, therefore, are ps = r and
in equilibrium. O
pw = r. Retailer will earn profits of H-2 = r - msws- MWwU PROOFOF PROPOSITION2. The mixed strategy pricing equilibrium
Retailer's optimization problem under Action 3 is:
for 0 c lw c m%2 r and 15 2 ms(r lW)/(1 + mSmW) - available from Raju
et al. (1990) is:

8 author thanks Rajiv Lal, V. Srinivasan, James Lattin, Scott Neslin 0 if 0 _ w5 < msr,
(area editor), and two anonymous reviewers for several useful sug-
mW(msmwr + l1V) . mw
gestions and Faruk Gul, Richard Staelin, Allen Weiss, Brian Gibbs,
+ Iw)2 if mr
(mwWs ? w, r--
Daniel Putler, and Peter Reiss for helping to improve this paper. The
f *(Ws) = O if fr - c-ws < r,
author also wishes to acknowledge James Lattin, Randolph Bucklin,
Peter Fader, A. C. Neilsen Inc., and Information Resources Inc. for mSm7vr + l17 if w, =

making the scanner datasets available, and the Marketing Science In-
stitute for financial support. 10 if w>r.

104 MARKETING SCIENCE/VOl. 15, No. 1, 1996


AGRAWAL
BrandLoyaltyon Advertisingand TradePromotions

-'7V MEPW = m% r-l, + - mlog).


p0 if O c W7,, < m,r + m, 7V MV, M7,,,r- 17,,

if m,r+ - cw7,_ <r,


- 1- We plot the trade promotion expenditures as a function of 17., for
g*(w7,,) MSZV w)
=,2 w various values of M7n0in Figure 4.
IZV
m7J,m7,,r 17
The plot shows that at 17V = mVr, MEP.= MEP,,= 0; for 17 < 17.
O if
W7V>irf <Wm,r, MEP, > MEP,,; at 17. = 171MEI. = MEP,; and for 0 l,7

where f*, g* represent probability distribution functions of wholesale < w, MEP, < MEP7.

prices for brands s and w, respectively. For 0 ? l7. - m2r and Isv 2ll, the equilibrium advertising levels
Probability of a promotion by manufacturer i, (MP), is the cumu- (derived in the proof of Proposition 4) suggest that 4,.will be > lu
lative probability of charging a price below r. The equilibrium pricing provided advertising is cost effective; specifically, when a* < a < a**
strategy implies: where a* solves OEHU'[l, = mWr]/017 = 0, and a** solves OEFw[l.,
= l]w/Ol,, = 0; and, 1,, will be < Iu,when a > a**. Therefore, MEP,

MP,=
ZV 7V
MP7,, = > MEPW when a* < a < a** (advertising is cost effective); and MEP,
m7vr - Izv)
m7,(m7,,r < MEPl,,when a > a** (advertising is costly). O
If 17 c m7,r,then mW,r- lw < r, therefore, MP,, > MPs. As shown PROOF OF COROLLARY 3.1. The two derivatives,

later (proof of Proposition 4), the post-advertising loyalties satisfy 17V


OMEPs 212 _ w
m 2 r. +7V
c5
W__ _ log m, +
The average trade discount offered by manufacturer i, (AD), is reg- 9mw m7Vr\m7V U

ular price minus average price when on promotion, i.e., AD, = r


and
- fti<r wif(wl/w; < r)dw,, implying

OMEP7v 21w 21lVm7vr- 1,lr- mr2vr2 r m 7,,rl- lu,


(m3U,r2 +
- .12- 1,,m5m7,,r + l,,)m7r log s 7 3- + 2+ -log
(mIm7vr
U)
OmW mw m%(m,,r- Ij) mz, \ msmz,.r
ADS= m70(m72r
-4IW)
are both 2 0 for lw m 2r. O
PROOF OF COROLLARIES 3.2 AND 3.3. The two derivatives
lr - ) (m r - W.+mSmwr log( ' 1))

AD.,, = mW(mWr- lw) MEP,


1 - 2u, +1 + 17V
logM
mw mi, MV
Using numerical enumeration, it can be shown that ADs > AD7,,
when 17Vc Wr. 0 and
PROOF OF COROLLARY 2.1. In equilibrium, the weaker brand pro-
aMEPw (m%2r - lW)
motes to the trade more often but the retailer promotes the stronger
'91w m 2,(mwr -1,,)
brand to consumers more often, implying that retail pass through in
terms of frequency is lower for the weaker brand. Similarly, the
stronger brand provides a larger price discount on average to the trade
but the retailer offers a larger price discount on the weaker brand, Figure4 TradePromotionalExpenditures
implying that retail pass through in terms of depth of discount is lower
for the stronger brand.
0.9
PROOF OF COROLLARY 2.2. The first-order derivatives,
0.8U
aMP, 17V ad MPW, mwlwr(2-
aMW,. m7vr DmiV mv(mw,r- 0.7

are both positive when 17, c mZ2 r. Similarly, it can be shown that 0.6

0. 5
OAD,
< 0 and >ADw- 0. D
am,i aMDV 0.4 <
PROOF OF PROPOSITION 3. The expected promotional expenditure 0.3
MEP, for brand i is Li (r - wj)f(wj)dw,: 0.2 -
(mwr+ lw)(m2,r - 17,) 0.1 s
MEPV- zin -.P

0o
- M2 r + lW) 1 + 0 I- OL cc
c
(M7,,r m(imnwr 1)7 o 6 6 6 6 6 6 6 6
MW, M7vr mw

MARKETINGSCIENCE/Vol. 15, No. 1, 1996 105


AGRAWAL
BrandLoyaltyon Advertisingand TradePromotions

are both c 0 for lV, m' r. Since I,V= 1,, + ya1,,- (1 - y)a,, therefore,
c and
OMEP,/ &y < 0; OMEP,O /&y < 0; OMEPI/ Ml,T,, < 0; and OMEP,V/ aOl710
<0. EL
01.-X
= (l-
1 m)fmr(1+ mV) -1ITOV + 7,r
(1 + M,m) W if (,SMs___+ M
,
<7 <i2
m70'
PROOFOF PROPOSITION 4. We first show that given a* = 0 and a 2 <

< a*, it is optimal for firm w to have a* = ((m%,r - 17,,0)/Y)2. Next we


show that given a* = ((m%2r- l700)/y)2and a - a*, it is optimal for Expected profits to firm w now are:
firm s to have a = 0.
Let a* = 0. The initial loyalties are asymmetric (i.e., la,. mz2r and c
V
Er7"(a=V(a'l=' , = )) = m,,r - aa,
is, 2 Is,); the stronger brand enjoys sufficiently stronger loyalty such
that the retailer promotes only the stronger brand). If post advertising
which are lower than what the firm earns at au,.
loyalties are also asymmetric then firm w solves the following problem
If a7, is increased even further, the regime continues to remain asym-
to choose a,v:
metric and expected profits to firm w continue to decrease. Therefore,
max EHl'1(a*= 0, a71,) given a* = 0, it is optimal for firm w to have a* = ((m%2 r - 1",O)/Y)2
provided a ? a*.
Now let a* = ((m%2r _l,,")/y)2 and a - a*. The loyalties are asym-
s.t. Il7, = 17?O0+ Ya7 mWr, (A9) metric. If firm s advertises, the loyalties continue to remain asymmet-
ric. Firm s solves:

IS= I,, - (1- y) A;2 m(r - (A10) max Efls(as, a*)


1 + mSm1,,
MM7
a,

From Lemma 1 (proved below), OEH?7/O1l1.> 0. Therefore firm w


chooses aw such that 17vis at its maximum and constraints (A9) and lvt)
st. I 17VI+ Y(m,r-
-
(1 - Y)v?a m2r, (A1)
(A10) are satisfied. a* = ((m2r - lw")/Y)2 is the optimal level at which
constraint (A9) is binding and constraint (A10) is satisfied because
a
m 2r(l + mJU (l -
Y) M2
/S = +~ 4-(1
I't,+
?St1 y - )(m7wr
Y) 17) 21+
m*(r-IW
msmzv
A 2
IS 2: + (m,r
l
- 17t(1)
0 i7(1+rM:S) y (
From Lemma 1, OEHs/Olu, > 0. Therefore firm s will choose as such
The expected profits to firm w are:
that 1,,is at its maximum and constraints (All) and (A12) are satisfied.
a = 0 is the optimal level at which constraint (All) is binding and
EHlw= =0O, a7t= =m1,r-aa1*. constraint (A12) is satisfied because Is, to. The expected profits to
firm s are:
If a7Vis chosen at a level beyond a*, the post advertising loyalties
now fall in the pure strategy regime wherem2r < 17,,< 1. From Lemma EHs(aa = 0, a*, = (m,r l)2) =mSr-aa, = mr.
2 (also proved below), under pure strategy, expected profits to firm w
are: If a, is increased beyond a*, i.e., if as > 0, the post advertising
loyalties continue to remain asymmetric and the expected profits
EHw(a* = 0, >a) = m7vr-aa7V,
a,v EflW(as,a*) = mr - aa, are lower than what the firm earns at a*.
which are lower than what the firm earns at a*l,. Therefore, given aT* ((mT2r-
= /Y)2 and a _ a*, it is optimal for
1ot)

If aw is increased further, 15 continues to decrease and 14,continues firm s to have a* = 0. Hence, a* = 0; a*, = ((m2,r - Ir)/y)2 is a Nash
to increase. At aZV = ((IS( - mwr)/( 1 - ))2, the competition moves equilibrium when l (- mzvrtl'; i1S0/ and a 2 a*.
from pure strategy to asymmetric regime where the weaker brand is Now, we show that for a > a*; a* = 0 and a* = ((I* - 17.,.>)/Y)2.
now asymmetrically stronger. The loyalties now are: When the cost effectiveness of advertising is such that a > a*, firm
w wishes to increase its loyalty only upto l/*, because beyond l* the
expected profits decrease. The level l* can be computed by solving
l = Is, + Y7a- (1 - y)f a= 1s0+ 0 - (1 - y) (h. - mM%Vr) r
aEnI[17,, = *Ia,I/Ol,= O.
Therefore, for a > a*, the optimal advertising levels are:a* = 0 and
' a*,= ((MZ1 - 17,, /y)2; where
'IV=17Wo + Ya7 -(1-) = IV + - m7,r)
ly
M,,,r(l + 9El17[V = Wrl2,
Asymmetry conditions < m 2r and 174 15 ms(r -1s)(1 + m,mw,) are
a* = 2 M7,-ml,,)y solves [ =0;
satisfied for ISO 150 where
and l* = I*(1l,,o,1,,,,r, a) solves &En1vilw = l*vllV = 0. ?I
-
Ms r(l + mw) (l y) (m2 fMs2(
. + M71) m2
M PROOFOF LEMMA 1. To show: aEUsI/Dali > 0 and aETw/Oalw > 0.
mS( (1 + m'M') (1y Umr-l1V,)if m M(1+mm70,)
The expected profits of manufacturer i are given by:

106 MARKETING SCIENCE/VOL 15, No. 1, 1996


AGRAWAL
BrandLoyaltyon Advertisingand TradePromotions

the two brands to respective loyal segments at price r), and earn ex-
EHl =jI (wi - aaj)g(wj)f(wj)dwjdw, pected profits, net of advertising, equal to:
EHll = m,r - aa,; Ell" = m,0r - aa,,. O
+ f (mw - aaj)g(wj)f(wj)dwjdwj PROOF OF COROLLARIES 4.1 AND 4.2. In equilibrium, the optimal
advertising levels are a* = 0; a* = ((mX2r - 10W)/ ))2. The first deriva-
+f f
tives Oaa/&mzv> 0 and Na*/&Yy< 0 for brand w. Since the optimal
(-aaj)g(wj)f(wj)dwjdw.
advertising is a direct function of own segment size and y, the deriv-
atives will have the same signs for brand s. O
For loyalties satisfying 15 2 m,(mz,r - 21,,,/m?,,) and 1, < m2 r, the ex- PROOF OF RESULT 1. The condition a ? a* implies that the equi-
pected profits are:
librium advertising levels area* = 0 anda*, = ((mX2r - l0,)/y)2. At
these levels l, = m%2rwhich implies that the equilibrium promo-
(m%r2 + 172,+ m,,7vr(l - 3m7,))(m,r - aa)
Ens 2
mIVr(mvr - 1w)
tional frequencies (MP*, MPI*) are both zero. Similarly, the pro-
motional spending levels (MEP*, MEP*) are also both zero. El
EL =m(mmwr
+ I,, +m%Wr(m7,r- 214,,) PROOF OF RESULT 2. The condition a > a* ensures that the optimal
m.V mVr(mVr - 1V,) post-advertising loyalty 1X*,, is below m72r. Similarly, the condition a
<a** ensures that loyalty 1*is above i:. Thus when a* < a < a**,
mrmwr
+ m log ( m the equilibrium advertising levels areas = 0 anda* = ((I* - l",,)/ y)2.
At these levels, the equilibrium promotional frequencies are both non-
w + -
m7,,1,vr(m - )+mv
zero, and trade promotional expenditures are such that MEP*
- aa4lv mzlt,r(12 - 3m,,) + m > MEP*t(see Figure 4). El
PROOF OF RESULT 3. The condition a > a** ensures that the optimal
The derivatives with respect to 1t, are: post-advertising loyalty I* is below i: and equilibrium advertising lev-
els are a* = 0 and a* - ((jxt _ ) / y)2. At these levels, the equilibrium
EH'_ (m,r - aa,)(m%r2 - 3m73r2 + m72r2 + 2m,v1,vr - 12,)
promotional frequencies are both nonzero, and trade promotional ex-
m2r(m,Vr - 17V)2
penditures are such that MEP* < MEP* (see Figure 4). El
The second term in the numerator is always positive (for mw,< 1);
therefore the derivative is positive if m,r > aa,, i.e., when the expected
References
Allenby, G. M. and P. E. Rossi (1991), "Quality Perceptions and Asym-
profits net of advertising are positive, a condition required to hold in
metric Switching Between Brands," MarketingScience, 10, 185-
equilibrium.
204.
9EIIv (m,m.,,r + j )(m 2 r2 + m2%4j,,r+ m2,,,l,r - 2m,r2 - 12) Blattberg, R. C. and S. A. Neslin (1990), SalesPromotion:Concepts,Meth-
0l1W m
2,mr(m,vr -JU)2 ods, and Strategies,Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall, Inc.
Bucklin, R. (1988), "Pass Through of Manufacturer Trade Promotions
m 3 r2 - 2m2l Ir + 12
by Grocery Retailers," Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation, Grad-
-
mr(m,r uate School of Business, Stanford University, CA.
Chevalier, R. and R. C. Curhan (1976), "Retail Promotions as a Func-
(1 - m)\ l( mm,vrA
tion of Trade Promotions: A Descriptive Analysis," Sloan Man-
V mV m - I J
m,r
agementReview, 18, 19-32.
Chintagunta, P. K., D. C. Jain, and N. J. Vilcassim (1991), "Investigat-
m
2r(mU,r
- 17V)2 1 ing Heterogeneity in Brand Preferences in Logit Models for
Panel Data," Journalof MarketingResearch,28, 417-428.
The first, second, and third terms are positive, whereas the fourth Curhan, R. C. and R. J. Kopp (1986), "Factors Influencing Grocery
term is negative. The numerator of the difference between first and Retailers' Support of Trade Promotions," Report No. 86-104
fourth term is positive when m,,,r> aau,,i.e., when the expected profits (July), Marketing Science Institute, Cambridge, MA.
net of advertising are positive, a condition required to hold in equilib- Davis, S., J. J. Inman, and L. McAlister (1992), "Promotion has a Neg-
rium. Thus, for all lw c M2 r, 9EHs/oil,, > 0, and oEI-UI/417,V> 0. C] ative Effect on Brand Evaluations-or Does It? Additional Dis-
PROOF OF LEMMA 2. To show, under pure strategy, where 1, > lw confirming Evidence," Journalof Marketing Research,29, 143-
> mU,r,the expected profits are: 148.
Deighton, J., C. M. Henderson, and S. A. Neslin (1994), "The Effects
EFIS = mr - aa,; EnT" = m,,r - aa7,.
of Advertising on Brand Switching and Repeat Purchasing,"
This proof proceeds as in Appendix A in Raju et al. (1990). If there Journalof MarketingResearch,31, 28-43.
is an equilibrium in pure strategies, it must be that both firms charge Ernst and Young Report (1993), "Do Trade Promotions Really
r and that (w, = r; w,, = r) is a Nash equilibrium. At these prices (w, Work?," a talk presented by Steve Laughlin at KrannertSchool
= r, w7, = r), the two firms sell to the retailer at r (who in turn sells of Management, Purdue University.

MARKETINGSCIENCE/Vol. 15, No. 1, 1996 107


AGRAWAL
BrandLoyaltyon Advertisingand TradePromotions

Fader, P. S. and J. M. Lattin (1993), "Accounting for Heterogeneity S. G. Powell, and L. G. Schneider (1994b), "The Effects of Re-
and Nonstationarity in a Cross Sectional Model of Consumer tailer and Consumer Response on Optimal Manufacturer Ad-
Behavior," MarketingScience, 12, 304-317. vertising and Trade Promotion Strategies," Working Paper,
Gonul, F. and K. Srinivasan (1993), "Modeling Multiple Sources of Amos Tuck School of Business, Dartmouth College.
Heterogeneity in Multinomial Logit Models: Methodological Pessemier, E. A. (1959), "A New Way to Determine Buying Deci-
and Managerial Issues," MarketingScience, 12, 213-229. sions," Journalof Marketing,24, 41-46.
Guadagni, P. M. and J.D. C. Little (1983), "A Logit Model of Brand Quelch, J. A. and P. W. Farris (1983), Casesin Advertisingand Promotion
Choice Calibrated on Scanner Data," MarketingScience,2, 202- Management,Plano, Texas: Business Publications, Inc.
238. Raj,S. P. (1982), "The Effects of Advertising on High and Low Loyalty
Helson, H. (1964), AdaptationLevel Theory, New York: Harper and Consumer Segments," Journalof ConsumerResearch,9, 77-89.
Row, Inc. Raju, J. S., V. Srinivasan, and R. Lal (1990), "The Effects of Brand
Kahneman, D. and A. Tversky (1979), "Prospect Theory: An Analysis Loyalty on Competitive Price Promotional Strategies," Manage-
of Decision Making Under Risk," Econometrica,47, 263-291. ment Science,36, 276-304.
Krishnamurthi, L. and S. P. Raj (1985), "The Effect of Advertising on Rao, R. C. (1991), "Pricing and Promotions in Asymmetric Duopo-
Consumer Price Sensitivity," Journalof MarketingResearch,22, lies," MarketingScience, 10, 131-144.
119-129. Rossiter, J. R. and L. Percy (1987), Advertisingand PromotionManage-
(1991), "An Empirical Analysis of the Relationship Between ment, New York: McGraw Hill, Inc.
Brand Loyalty and Consumer Price Elasticity," MarketingSci- Sethuraman, R. and G. J. Tellis (1991), "An Analysis of the Trade Off
ence, 10, 172-183. Between Advertising and Price Discounting," Journalof Mar-
Lal, R. (1990a), "Manufacturer Trade Deals and Retail Price Promo- keting Research,28, 160-174.
tions," Journalof MarketingResearch,27, 428 444. Shapiro, C. (1987), "Theories of Oligopoly Behavior," Discussion Pa-
(1990b), "Price Promotions: Limiting Competitive Encroach- per No. 126, Woodrow Wilson School, Princeton University,
ment," MarketingScience,9, 247-262. Princeton, New Jersey.
Little, J. D. C. (1979), "Aggregate Advertising Models: The State of the Srinivasan, V. and T. Kibarian (1989), "Purchase Event Feedback: Fact
Art," OperationsResearch,27, 629-667. or Fiction," Unpublished paper, Graduate School of Business,
Low, G. S. and J. J. Mohr (1992), "The Advertising-Sales Promotion Stanford University (February).
Trade-Off:Theory and Practice," Report No. 92-127, Marketing Strong, E. K. (1925), ThePsychologyof Selling, New York:McGraw-Hill,
Science Institute, Cambridge, MA. Inc.
Narasimhan, C. (1988), "Competitive Promotional Strategies," Journal Tellis Gerard J. (1988), "Advertising Exposure, Loyalty, and Brand
of Business, 61, 427-449. Purchase: A Two-Stage Model of Choice," Journalof Marketing
(1990), "Managerial Perspectives on Trade and Consumer Pro- Research,25, 134-144.
motions," MarketingLetters,1, 239-251. and F. S. Zufryden (1995), Tackling The Retailer Decision Maze:
Neslin, S. A. and R. Shoemaker (1989), "An Alternative Explanation Which Brands to Discount, How Much, When, and Why?,"
for Lower Repeat Rates After Promotional Purchases," Journal MarketingScience,14, 271-299.
of MarketingResearch,26, 205-213. Walters, R. G. (1989), "An Empirical Investigation into Retailer Re-
et al. (1994a), "A Research Agenda for Making Scanner Data sponse to Manufacturer Trade Promotions," Journalof Retailing,
More Useful to Managers," MarketingLetters,5(4), 395-412. 65, 253-272.

Tlhispaperwas receivedSeptember14, 1993, and has beenwith the author223 days for 4 revisions;processedby Scott Neslin, Area Editor.

108 MARKETINGSCIENCE/VOl. 15, No. 1, 1996

You might also like