You are on page 1of 7

Espen Gaarder Haug

THE COLLECTOR:

Know Your
Weapon Part 2
BSD trader ‘Soldier’ last time I told you
about delta and gamma Greeks. Today I’ll
and lar strike and maturity, stochastic volatility,
jumps, and more. For instance a sudden
enlighten you on Vega, theta, and probability S = Asset price.
increase in the Black-Scholes implied volatility
Greeks. X = Strike price. for an out-of-the-money strike does not neces-
New Trader Sir, I already know Vega. r = Risk-free interest rate. sary imply that investors expect higher volatili-
BSD trader Soldier, if you want to speculate ty. The increase can just as well be due to an
b = Cost-of-carry rate of holding the
on an increase in implied volatility what type option “arbitrageur” expecting higher volatili-
underlying security. ty of volatility.
of options offer the most bang for the bucks?
T = Time to expiration in years.
New Trader At-the-money options with long Vega local maximum
time to maturity. σ = Volatility of the relative price change
of the underlying asset price. When trying to profit from moves in implied
BSD trader Soldier, you are possibly wrong on volatility it is useful to know where the option
strikes and time! Now start with 20 push-ups N(x) = The cumulative normal distribution has the maximum Vega value for a given time to
while I start to tell you about Vega. function. maturity. For a given strike price Vega attains its
New Trader Yes Sir! maximum when the asset price is

2 Vega Greeks S = Xe(−b+σ


2
/2)T
.

1 Refreshing notation on the BSM 2.1 Vega At this asset price we also have in-the-money
formula 1
Vega, also known as kappa, is the option’s sen- risk neutral probability symmetry (which I
Let me at this time shortly refresh your memory sitivity to a small change in the implied volatili- come back to later). Moreover, at this asset price
of the Black-Scholes-Merton (BSM) formula ty. Vega is equal for put and call options. the generalized Black-Scholes-Merton (BSM) for-
mula simplifies to
c = Se(b−r)T N(d1 ) − Xe−rT N(d2 ) ∂c ∂p √ √
Vega = = = Se(b−r)T n(d1 ) T > 0 Xe−rT
p = Xe−rT N(−d2 ) − Se(b−r)T N(−d1 ), ∂σ ∂σ c = Se(b−r)T N(σ T) − ,
2
Xe−rT √
Implied volatility is often considered the mar- p= − Se(b−r)T N(−σ T).
where 2
ket’s best estimate of expected volatility for the
duration of the option. It can also be interpret- Similarly, the strike that maximizes Vega given
ln(S/X) + (b + σ 2 /2)T
d1 = √ , ed as a basket of adjustments to the BSM formu- the asset price is
σ T la, for factors that the formula doesn’t take into
√ 2
d2 = d1 − σ T, account; demand and supply for that particu- X = Se(b+σ /2)T
.
Thanks to Jørgen Haug for useful comments on this paper.

50 Wilmott magazine
Vega global maximum Figure 1 shows the graph of Vega with respect X
Vega(S, X, T, r, b, σ ) = bT
Some years back a BSD trader called me late one to the asset price and time. The intuition Se
behind the Vega-top (Vega-mountain) is that the  
evening, close to freaking out. He had shorted (SebT )2
effect of discounting at some point in time Vega S, , T, r, b, σ .
long term options, which he hedged by going X
long short term options. To his surprise the long dominates volatility (Vega): the lower the inter-
term options’ Vega increased as time went buy. est rate, the lower the effect of discounting, and As for the gamma symmetry, see Haug (2003),
After looking at my 3D Vega chart I confirmed the higher the relative effect of volatility on the this symmetry is independent of the options
that this was indeed the expected behavior. For option price. As the risk-free rate goes to zero being calls or puts—-at least in theory.
options with long term to maturity the maxi- the time for the global maximum goes to infin-
mum Vega is not necessarily increasing with ity, that is we will have no global maximum
longer time to maturity, as many traders believe. when the risk-free rate is zero. Figure 2 is the 2.3 Vega-gamma relationship
Indeed, Vega has a global maximum at time same as figure 1 but with zero interest rate. The Following is a simple and useful relationship
effect of Vega being a decreasing function of between Vega and gamma, described by Taleb
1 time to maturity typically kicks in only for
TV̄ = , (1997) among others:
2r options with very long times to maturity—
unless the interest rate is very high. It is not, Vega = σ S2 T.
and asset price
however, uncommon for caps & floors traders
2
−b+σ 2 /2 to use the Black-76 formula to compute Vegas
SV̄ = Xe(−b+σ /2)T V̄
= Xe 2r . 2.4 Vega from delta
for options with 10 to 15 years to expiration
(caplets). Given that we know the delta, what is the Vega?
At this global maximum, Vega itself, described
by Alexander (Sasha) Adamchuk2 is equal to the Vega and delta are related by a simple formula
following simple expression 2.2 Vega symmetry described by Wystrup (2002):

X For options with different strikes we have the √


Vega(SV̄ , TV̄ ) = √ . Vega = Se(b−r)T Tn [N −1 (e(r−b)T | |)],
2 reπ following Vega symmetry

X = 100, r = 0%, b = 0%, σ = 12%,

X = 100, r = 15%, b = 0%, σ = 12%,


0.45 1.80
0.40 1.60
0.35 1.40
0.30 1.20
0.25 h 1.00 h
0.20 0.80
0.15 0.60
0.10 5775 0.40 5775
0.05 4620 0.20 4620
0.00 3465 0.00 3465
250

250

2310
225

2310
225
200

200
175

Days to maturity
175

1155 Days to maturity


150

150

1155
125

125
100

100
75

0
75

0
50

50

Asset price
25

25

Asset price
0

Figure 1. Vega Figure 2. Vega


^

Wilmott magazine 51
ESPEN GAARDER HAUG

where N −1 (·) is the inverted cumulative normal X = 100, r = 5%, b = 0%, σ = 60%,
distribution, n() is the normal density function,
and is the delta of a call or put option. Using 0.45
the Vega-gamma relationship we can rewrite this 0.40
relationship to express gamma as a function of 0.35
the delta
0.30

e(b−r)T n[N −1 (e(r−b)T | |)] 0.25


= √ . 0.20
Sσ T
0.15
Relationships, such as the above ones, between 0.10
delta and other option sensitivities are particu- 0.05
lar useful in the FX options markets, where one
300 0.00
often consider a particular delta rather than
246 −0.05
strike.

365
192

323
2.5 VegaP

281
138

239
198
The traditional text book Vega gives the dollar Asset price 84

156
114
change in option price for a percentage point 30 Days to maturity

72
change in volatility. When comparing the Vega

30
risk of options on different assets it makes more
sense to look at percentage changes in volatili- Figure 3. Vega Leverage
ty. This metric can be constructed simply by
σ
multiplying the standard Vega with 10 , which σ with DgammaDvol, see Haug (2003), Vomma is in
gives what is known as VegaP (percentage VegaLeverage call = Vega ≥ 0,
call my view one of the most important Greeks.
change in option price for a ten percent change σ DvegaDvol is given by
VegaLeverage put = Vega ≥ 0.
in volatility): put
 
∂2c ∂2p d1 d2
σ (b−r)T √ The Vega elasticity is highest for out-of-the- DvegaDvol = = = Vega ≤≥ 0.
VegaP = Se n(d1 ) T ≥ 0. money options. If you believe in an increase in ∂σ 2 ∂σ 2 σ
10
implied volatility you will therefore get maxi-
mum bang for your bucks by buying out-of-the- For practical purposes, where one “typically”
VegaP attains its local and global maximum at wants to look at Vomma for the change of one
the same asset price and time as for Vega. Some money options. Several traders I have met will
typically tell you to buy at-the-money options percentage point in the volatility, one should
options systems use traditional text book Vega, divide vomma by 10000.
while others use VegaP. when they want to speculate on higher implied
volatility, to maximize Vega. There are several In case of DvegaPDvol we have
When comparing Vegas for options with
advantages to buying out-of-the-money options  
different maturities (calendar spreads) it d1 d2
makes more sense to look at some kind of in such a scenario. One is the higher Vega-lever- DvegaPDvol = VegaP ≤≥ 0.
age. Another advantage is that you often also get σ
weighted Vega, or alternatively Vega bucket-
ing, 3 because short term implied volatilities a positive DvegaDvol (and also DgammaDvol), a Options far out-of-the money have the highest
are typically more volatile than long term measure we will have a closer look at below. The Vomma. More precisely given the strike price,
implied volatilities. Several options systems drawbacks of deep-out-of-the-money options is Vomma is positive outside the interval
implement some type of Vega weighting or faster time decay (in percent of premium), and
Vega bucketing (see Haug (1993) and Taleb typically lower liquidity. Figure 3 illustrates the 2 2

Vega leverage of a put option. (SL = Xe(−b−σ /2)T


, SU = Xe(−b+σ /2)T
).
(1997) for more details).
Given the asset price the Vomma is positive out-
2.6 Vega leverage, Vega elasticity 2.7 DvegaDvol, Vomma side the interval (relevant only before conduct-
The percentage change in option value with DvegaDvol, also known as Vega convexity, Vomma ing the trade)
respect to percentage point change in volatility (see (Webb 1999)), or Volga, is the sensitivity of 2 2
is given by Vega to changes in implied volatility. Together (XL = Se(b−σ /2)T
, XU = Se(b+σ /2)T
).

52 Wilmott magazine
If you are long options you typically want to have taken into account in the Black-Scholes formula. age point change in volatility to a one day change
as high positive DvegaDvol as possible. If short A DvegaDvol trader does not necessary need to in time, one should divide the DVegaDtime by
options, you typically want negative DvegaDvol. identify the exact reason for the implied volatili- 36500, or 25200 if you look at trading days only.
Positive DvegaDvol tells you that you will earn ty to change. If you think the implied volatility Figure 5 illustrates DVegaDtime. Figure 6 shows
more for every percentage point increase in will be volatile in the short term you should typ- DvegaDtime for wider range of parameters and a
volatility, and if implied volatility is falling you ically try to find options with high DvegaDvol. lower implied volatility, as expected from Figure 1
will lose less and less—-that is, you have positive Figure 4 shows the graph of DvegaDvol for we can here see that DvegaDtime actually can be
Vega convexity. changes in asset price and time to maturity. positive.
While DgammaDvol is most relevant for the
volatility of the actual volatility of the underly- 2.8 DvegaDtime
ing asset, DvegaDvol is more relevant for the DvegaDtime is the change in Vega with respect
3 Theta Greeks
volatility of the implied volatility. Although the to changes in time. Since we typically are looking 3.1 Theta
volatility of implied volatility and the volatility at decreasing time to maturity we express this as
of actual volatility will typically have high corre- Theta is the option’s sensitivity to a small
minus the partial derivative
lation, this is not always the case. DgammaDvol change in time to maturity. As time to maturity
is relevant for traditional dynamic delta hedging ∂Vega decreases, it is normal to express theta as minus
under stochastic volatility. DvegaDvol trading DvegaDtime = − the partial derivative with respect to time.
∂T
has little to do with traditional dynamic delta 
bd1 1 + d1 d2
hedging. DvegaDvol trading is a bet on changes = Vega r − b + √ − Call
σ T 2T
on the price (changes in implied vol) for uncer- ∂c Se(b−r)T n(d1 )σ
tainty in: supply and demand, stochastic actual ≤≥ 0 call = − =− √
∂T 2 T
volatility (remember this is correlated to implied
volatility), jumps and any other model risk: fac- For practical purposes, where one “typically” − (b − r)Se(b−r)T N(d1 )
tors that affect the option price, but that are not wants to express the sensitivity for a one percent- − rXe −rT N(d2 ) ≤≥ 0.

X = 100, r = 5%, b = 0%, σ = 20%, X = 100, r = 5%, b = 0%, σ = 50%,

0.016 0

0.014
−0.0005
0.012

0.01
−0.001
0.008

0.006 319 326


−0.0015
0.004 256 271

192 215
0.002 −0.002 Days to maturity
Days to maturity
128 160
0
−0.002 64 −0.0025 105
341
148

315
140

289
133

263
125

50
118

0
236
210
110

184
103

158
131
95
88

105
79
80
73

53
65

26
0
58
50

Asset price Asset price ^


Figure 4. DvegaDvol Figure 5. DvegaDtime

Wilmott magazine 53
ESPEN GAARDER HAUG

X = 100, r = 12%, b = 0%, σ = 12% Theta-Gamma relationship


There is a simple relationship between drift-less
gamma and drift-less theta

−2θ
= .
S2 σ 2
0.0001

0
4 Rho Greeks
−0.0001 4.1 Rho
Rho is the option’s sensitivity to a small change
−0.0002
5313 in the risk-free interest rate.

−0.0003 4350
Call
3388
−0.0004 Days to maturity
2425 ∂c
ρcall = = TXe −rT N(d2 ) > 0,
∂r
−0.0005 1463
in the case the option is on a future or forward
244
225
206
188

500
169
150
131
113
94

(that is b always will stay 0) the rho is given by


75
56
38
19
0

Asset price
∂c
ρcall = = −Tc < 0.
Figure 6. DvegaDtime (Vanna) ∂r

Put
Put for both puts and calls,
X ∂p
∂p Se(b−r)T n(d1 )σ θ (S, X, T, 0, 0, σ ) = ρput = = −TXe −rT N(−d2 ) < 0
put = − =− √ S ∂r
∂T 2 T  
S2
+ (b − r)Se(b−r)T N(−d1 ) × θ S, , T, 0, 0, σ .
X in the case the option is on a future or forward
+ rXe −rT N(−d2 ) ≤≥ 0 (that is b always will stay 0) the rho is given by
Theta-Vega relationship
Drift-less theta There is a simple relationship between Vega and ∂c
ρput = = −Tp < 0.
In practice it is often also of interest to know the drift-less theta ∂r
drift-less theta, θ , which measures time decay
Vega × σ
without taking into account the drift of the θ =− . 4.2 Cost of Carry
underlying or discounting. In other words the 2T
drift-less theta isolates the effect time-decay has This is the option’s sensitivity to a marginal
on uncertainty, assuming unchanged volatility. change in the cost of carry rate.
Bleed-offset volatility
The uncertainty or volatilities effect on the A more practical relationship between theta Cost of Carry Call
option consist of time and volatility. In that case and Vega is what is known as bleed-offset vol. It
we have measures how much the volatility must ∂c
increase to offset the theta-bleed/time decay. = TSe (b−r)T N(d1 ) > 0.
Sn(d1 )σ ∂b
θcall = θput =θ =− √ ≤0 Bleed-offset vol can be found simply by dividing
2 T
the 1-day theta by Vega, Vega . In the case of posi-
tive theta you can actually have negative offset Cost of Carry Put
3.2 Theta symmetry
vol. Deep in-the-money European options can
In the case of drift-less theta for options with dif- have positive Theta, in this case the offset-vol ∂p
= −TSe (b−r)T N(−d1 ) < 0.
ferent strikes we have the following symmetry, will be negative. ∂b

54 Wilmott magazine
5 Probability Greeks call occurs when the options are at-the-money for- Divide by 100 to get the associated measure for
ward, X = SbT . However, for a cash-or-nothing option percentage point volatility changes.
In this section we will look at risk-neutral proba- (see Reiner and Rubinstein (1991b), Haug (1997)) we
bilities in relation to the BSM formula. Keep in will also have value-symmetry for puts and calls at 5.3 DzetaDtime
mind that such risk adjusted probabilities could the risk-neutral probability strike. Moreover, at the The in-the-money-risk-neutral probability’s sensi-
be very different from real world probabilities.4 probability-neutral straddle we will also have Vega- tivity to moving closer to maturity is given by
symmetry as well as zero Vomma.  
5.1 In-the-money probability ∂ζc b d1
− = n(d2 ) √ − ≤≥ 0,
In the (Black and Scholes 1973, Merton 1973) Strikes from probability ∂T σ T 2T
model, the risk neutral probability for a call
Another interesting formula returns the strike of an and for a put
option finishing in-the-money is  
option, given the risk-neutral probability pi of end-
∂ζp b d1
ζc = N(d2 ) > 0, ing up in-the-money. The strike of a call is given by − = −n(d2 ) √ − ≤≥ 0
∂T σ T 2T

and for a put option Xc = S exp[−N −1 (pi )σ T + (b − σ 2 /2)T], Divide by 365 to get the sensitivity for a one day
move.
ζp = N(−d2 ) > 0. where N −1 (x) is the inverse cumulative normal
distribution. The strike for a put is given by 5.4 Risk neutral probability density
This is the risk neutral probability of ending up
in-the-money at maturity. It is not identical to the √ BSM second partial derivatives with respect to
Xp = S exp[N −1 (pi )σ T + (b − σ 2 /2)T].
real world probability of ending up in-the-money. the strike price yield the risk neutral probability
The real probability we simply cannot extract density of the underlying asset, see Breeden and
from options prices alone. A related sensitivity is
5.2 DzetaDvol Litzenberger (1978) (this is also known as the
the strike-delta, which is the partial derivatives of Zeta’s sensitivity to change in the implied volatil- strike gamma)
the option formula with respect to the strike ity is given by
  ∂2c ∂2p n(d2 )e−rT
price ∂ζc ∂ζp d1 RND = 2
= 2
= √ ≥0
= = −n(d2 ) ≤≥ 0 ∂X ∂X Xσ T
∂c ∂σ ∂σ σ
= −e−rT N(d2 ) > 0, Figure 7 illustrates the risk neutral probability
∂X and for a put density with respect to variable time and asset
∂p   price. With the same volatility for any asset price
= e−rT N(−d2 ) > 0 ∂ζp ∂ζp d1
∂X = = n(d2 ) ≤≥ 0 this is naturally the log-normal distribution of
∂σ ∂σ σ the asset price, as evident from the graph.
This can be interpreted as the discounted risk-
neutral-probability of ending up in-the-money
(assuming you take the absolute value of the call X = 100, r = 5%, b = 0%, σ = 20%,
0.045
strike-delta).
0.04
Probability mirror strikes
0.035
For a put and a call to have the same risk-neutral-
probability of finishing in-the-money, we can 0.03
find the probability symmetric strikes
0.025
S2 2 S2 (2b−σ 2 )T
Xp = e(2b−σ )T , Xc = e , 321 0.02
Xc Xp
259 0.015
where Xp is the put strike, and Xc is the call strike.
This naturally reduces to N[d2 (Xc )] = N[d2 (Xp )] . A 196 0.01
Days to maturity
special case is Xc = Xp , a probability mirror strad- 134 0.005
dle (probability-neutral straddle). We have this at
72 0
2
Xc = Xp = Se(b−σ /2)T
0

.
15
30
45
60

10
75
90
105
120
135
150
165
180
195

At this point the risk-neutral probability of ending


up in-the-money is 0.5 for both the put and the call. Asset price
^
Standard puts and calls will not have the same
value at this point. The same value for a put and a Figure 7. Risk-Neutral-Density

Wilmott magazine 55
ESPEN GAARDER HAUG

5.5 From in-the-money probability by Reiner and Rubinstein (1991a). Alternatively, risk adjusted probabilities, discounted at the risk less
to density the probability of ever getting in the money interest rate—hence the common name “risk-neutral”
before maturity can be calculated in a very sim- probabilities, which is somewhat of a misnomer.
Given the in-the-money risk-neutral probability, ple way in a binomial tree, using Brownian 5. This analytical probability was first published by Reiner and
pi , the risk neutral probability density is given by bridge probabilities. Rubinstein (1991a) in the context of barrier hit probability.

e−rT n[N −1 (pi )]


RND = √ , End of Part 2 ■ BLACK, F. (1976): “The Pricing of Commodity Contracts,”
Xσ T
BSD trader “Sergeant, that is all for now. You Journal of Financial Economics, 3, 167–179.
where n() is the normal density function. ■ BLACK, F., AND M. SCHOLES (1973): “The Pricing of
now know the basic operation of the Black-
Scholes weapon.” Options and Corporate Liabilities,” Journal of Political
5.6 Probability of ever getting in- New Trader “Did I hear you right? ‘Sergeant’?”
Economy, 81, 637–654.
the-money ■ BREEDEN, D. T., AND R. H. LITZENBERGER (1978): “Price of
BSD trader “Yes. Now that you know the State-Contigent Claimes Implicit in Option Prices,” Journal
For in-the-money options the probability of ever basics of the Black-Scholes weapon, I have of Business, 51, 621–651.
getting in-the-money (hitting the strike) before decided to promoted you. ■ HAUG, E. G. (1993): “Opportunities and Perils of Using
maturity naturally equals unity, since we are Option Sensitivities,” Journal of Financial Engineering,
New Trader Thank you Sir, for teaching me
already in-the-money. The risk neutral probabili- 2(3), 253–269.
all your tricks.
ty for a out-of-the-money call ever getting in the ■ _____ (1997): The Complete Guide To Option Pricing
money is BSD trader Here’s a three million loss limit. Formulas. McGraw-Hill, New York.
Time for you to start trading. ■ _____ (2003): “Know Your Weapon, Part 1,” Wimott

pc = (X/S)µ+λ N(−z) + (X/S)µ−λ N(−z + 2λσ T). New Trader Only three million? Magazine, May.
■ MERTON, R. C. (1973): “Theory of Rational Option
Similarly, the risk neutral probability for an out- Pricing,” Bell Journal of Economics and Management
FOOTNOTES & REFERENCES Science, 4, 141–183.
of-the-money put ever getting in the money (hit-
ting the strike) before maturity is ■ REINER, E., AND M. RUBINSTEIN (1991a): “Breaking Down
the Barriers,” Risk Magazine, 4(8).
√ 1. While the other sensitivities have names that correspond
pp = (X/S)µ+λ N(z) + (X/S)µ−λ N(z − 2λσ T), ■ _____ (1991b): “Unscrambling the Binary Code,” Risk
to Greek letters Vega is the name of a star. Magazine, 4(9).
2. Described by Adamchuck on the Wilmott forum ■ TALEB, N. (1997): Dynamic Hedging. Wiley.
where www.wilmott.com on February 6, 2002.
■ WEBB, A. (1999): “The Sensitivity of Vega,” Derivatives
ln(X/S) √ b − σ 2 /2 3. Vega bucketing simply refers to dividing the Vega risk
Strategy, http://www.derivativesstrategy.com/maga-
z= √ + λσ T, µ= , into time buckets.
σ T σ2 zine/archive/1999/1199fea1.asp, November, 16–19.
 4. Risk-neutral probabilities are simply real world proba-
■ WYSTRUP, U. (2002): “Vanilla Options,” in the book
2r bilities that have been adjusted for risk. It is therefore
λ = µ2 + 2 . not necessary to adjust for risk also in the discount fac-
Foreign Exchange Risk by Hakala J. and Wystrup U.,
σ Risk Books.
tor for cash-flows. This makes it valid to compute mar-
This is equal to the barrier hit probability used
ket prices as simple expectations of cash flows, with the
for computing the value of a rebate, developed

56 Wilmott magazine

You might also like