You are on page 1of 12

Geoforum 43 (2012) 573–584

Contents lists available at SciVerse ScienceDirect

Geoforum
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/geoforum

Contests and struggle: Cotton farmers and COTTCO in Rushinga district,


Zimbabwe, 1999–2006
Godwin Masuka
Department of Resource Management and Geography, The University of Melbourne, 3010 Victoria, Australia

a r t i c l e i n f o a b s t r a c t

Article history: The paper examines the relations between farmers and The Cotton Company of Zimbabwe (COTTCO) in
Received 19 November 2009 Rushinga district of Zimbabwe. Based on interviews with farmers and secondary data, it examines the
Received in revised form 9 October 2011 practice of side marketing of contracted seed cotton. While a large body of literature has discussed the
Available online 2 December 2011
social and economic effects of contract farming on farmers, there are less critical studies on side market-
ing of crops by farmers in unstable economic and political environment such as Zimbabwe. The paper
Keywords: demonstrates that farmers taking advantage of the macroeconomic environment in Zimbabwe violated
Zimbabwe
contracts by selling seed cotton to other buyers. In the process, farmers renegotiated the meaning of
Economic crisis
Contract farming
the contract and appealed to market rationality embedded in the neo-liberal ideology. For these farmers,
COTTCO side marketing was part of a survival strategy, albeit in imperfect markets and a difficult economic envi-
Farmers ronment. Nonetheless, side marketing of seed cotton strained relations between farmers and COTTCO.
Side marketing The paper shows the tensions in contracts that require regulation by the state and the neo-liberal ideol-
ogy that promote free markets and argue against strong regulation.
Ó 2011 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

1. Introduction district took advantage of competition among seed cotton buyers


to side market, thereby disadvantaging COTTCO to whom they
Research on contract farming suggests that the outcomes are were contracted. Cotton production is the main source of liveli-
complex and contested (Dorward et al., 1998; Eaton and Shepherd, hood for farmers in Rushinga district, therefore their recourse to
2001; Glover and Kusterer, 1990; Little and Watts, 1994; Raynolds, side marketing was a tactical strategy to survive in the harsh mac-
2000). The literature states many problems associated with roeconomic and political environment. I argue that in deregulated
contract farming ranging from biased contracts against farmers, markets as in Zimbabwe which also experienced macroeconomic
cheating by companies on producer prices, failure to supply farm- instability and a collapse of inputs markets, there are trade-offs be-
ers with inputs and extension advice and cheating (Clapp, 1994; tween short-term profits (by farmers and opportunistic buyers)
Kirsten and Sartorius, 2002; Little and Watts, 1994). For compa- and long-term investment in financing crop production. By exam-
nies, side marketing of crops by farmers is one of the major prob- ining how side marketing works within the broad framework of
lems experienced in contract farming (Dorward et al., 1998). Side the political economy of African agriculture and contract farming
marketing occurs when a farmer sell his/her produce to a different in particular; the paper contributes to the literature on smallholder
buyer than the one which provided inputs. Side marketing is pre- agriculture, neo-liberalisation and the role of private companies in
valent in liberalised agricultural markets particularly where there agriculture. As argued in this paper, there are tensions and con-
is high competition for crops among buyers (Coulter et al., 1999; tradictions between contracts that require state regulation and
Poulton et al., 1998). In deregulated markets, farmers have an the neo-liberal ideology that is against regulation of markets or
incentive to side market crops to buyers offering higher prices strong government interference. Arguably, there are discrepancies
(Dorward et al., 1998). between neo-liberal theory and practice, primarily because of neo-
The paper examines how market-regulated contracts were liberal theory’s failure to recognise that markets are socially
negotiated by farmers and companies in Rushinga district. It high- embedded (Polanyi, 1944) and influenced by social, political and
lights the contextual factors that influenced contract farming and economic factors within which individual agents operate. In the
impacted on the relations between farmers and The Cotton context of Zimbabwe, neo-liberalism and contract farming was
Company of Zimbabwe (COTTCO). I argue that farmers in Rushinga being negotiated and adjusted to work in specific geographic, eco-
nomic and political environments described in this paper. In this
E-mail address: godwinmasuka@yahoo.com sense, I examine how neo-liberalism and contract farming was

0016-7185/$ - see front matter Ó 2011 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.geoforum.2011.11.001
574 G. Masuka / Geoforum 43 (2012) 573–584

negotiated instead of merely being dictated in Zimbabwe’s in Rushinga district, contracted farmers did not access all inputs,
deregulated cotton sector. It could be argued that this development particularly fertilisers; neither was COTTCO guaranteed seed cot-
occurred in a peculiar operating environment and could not hap- ton from farmers. Furthermore, not all farmers overcome input
pen elsewhere where capitalist systems were strongly rooted or imperfections. In particular, farmers outside contracts can be dis-
in stable economic and political environments. advantaged when companies buy inputs in bulk, thereby causing
The paper is divided into six sections. Section 2 discusses con- shortages on the open markets. In contrast, contracting companies
tract farming and neo-liberal reforms in order to set the context could benefit from economies of scale by purchasing inputs in bulk
for the discussion that follows. Section 3 focuses on the political from manufacturers (Da Silva, 2005).
economy of Zimbabwe and the cotton sector. Such a discussion is
important because contracts exist in imperfect markets and are 2.1. Contract farming in Africa: an overview
influenced by political and economic factors in specific geographic
settings (Morrison et al., 2006). Section 4 outlines the research The institution of contract farming dates back to Ancient Greece
methods used in this paper. Section 5 discusses contract farming (Eaton and Shepherd, 2001, p. 1). Over time contract farming be-
(the input credit scheme) in Rushinga. It focuses specifically on came a central institution in agricultural production in Western
side marketing of seed cotton. It discusses the tensions between Europe, North America and Japan (Watts, 1994). In Africa, contract
farmers and COTTCO and exposes the contradictions in market- farming started in the colonial period. It involved production of
regulated contracts. Section 6 concludes the paper and draws non-traditional crops such as fruits and vegetables (Little and Watts,
implications of this discussion. 1994). However, by the 1990s, contract farming expanded to in-
clude the production of cotton, coffee, maize, tobacco, sorghum
and cashew nuts (Dorward et al., 1998; Kindness and Gordon, 2001).
2. Neo-liberalism and contract farming The growth of contract farming in Africa occurred hand in hand
with the World Bank’s neo-liberal economic reforms which began
Contract farming is an agreement between farmers and a pro- in the early 1980s (Morrison et al., 2006; World Bank, 1994). In
cessing and/or marketing company for the production and supply particular, the reforms promoted market-oriented and export-ori-
of agricultural products (Eaton and Shepherd, 2001, p. 2). Most ented growth in place of state-led and inward-looking policies
contracts stipulate production and/or marketing conditions; how- (Bates, 1981; Gore, 2000; World Bank, 1981, 1989). In agriculture,
ever, in some contracts companies simply provide inputs to farm- the main objective was to abolish state marketing boards and to
ers and pay market prices for the crop at the selling stage minus liberalise input and output markets in order to promote efficiency
the costs of inputs provided (Little and Watts, 1994). In this case, and competition. In addition, reforms would end governments’
companies use the farmers’ expected crop harvest as collateral policy biases against farmers (e.g. through low producer prices
for credit repayment (Dorward et al., 1998; Mather, 1999). Con- and taxes), which allegedly contributed to a decline in food pro-
tracts in Zimbabwe’s cotton sector follow the latter. duction in Africa in the late 1970s (Bates, 1981).
In the past decades, agro-companies in both the developing and The assumption was that under liberalisation the state with-
developed countries increasingly used contract farming in agricul- draws from input and output markets and it would be replaced
tural production (Little and Watts, 1994; Minot, 1986; Murray, by the private sector which then enters into mutually beneficial
2001). This is associated with the industrialisation and globalisa- contracts with farmers (Townsend, 1999; World Bank, 1981). The
tion of agriculture, particularly in the agro-food sector (Friedland private sector would provide farmers with inputs hence bridge
et al., 1991; Whatmore, 2002). Further, competition for supplies the input supply gap left by the withdrawal of state marketing
forced companies to adopt vertical integration strategies and con- boards from input markets (Gibbon, 1992; World Bank, 1981). Fur-
tract farming in agricultural production in order to secure raw thermore, contract farming would promote export-led growth and
materials at the source (at farm gate) (Minot, 1986; Kirsten and generate foreign currency for struggling developing countries (Del-
Sartorius, 2002). The agro-industrial restructuring heralded a gado, 1995; Jaffee and Morton, 1995; World Bank, 1981). In theory,
‘new political economy of agriculture’ in which traditional systems contract farming had positive externalities in the form of rural
of ‘farming’ were integrated into the world economy through development by creating employment, increasing farmers’ income,
contract farming, vertical integration and distribution networks promoting infrastructural development and developing markets in
controlled by transnational companies (Friedland et al., 1991, pp. local areas (Glover and Kusterer, 1990; Key and Runsten, 1999;
3–4; McMichael, 1994). Although the impact varied geographically World Bank, 1981). This neo-liberal objective blended well with
and was contested, these strategies increased the power of compa- some developing government’s ‘populist rhetoric’ of targeting the
nies over producers (Mather, 1999). For example, through contract poor and promoting rural development in the face of limited state
farming companies have better control over product quality, prod- resources (Watts, 1990).
uct price and timely passage of information to producers (Minot, Despite the enthusiasm by neo-liberal proponents regarding the
1986). In theory, contract farming enables companies to control positive outcomes of reforms and contract farming in particular,
or influence production decisions at the farm without incurring there was increasing evidence that in many cases the reforms did
the costs of buying land or hiring labour (Grosh, 1994; Key and not deliver the expected outcomes (Gibbon, 1992; Ponte, 2001).
Runsten, 1999; Mather, 1999). In several agricultural sectors, the entry of the private sector was
The main advantage of contract farming is that it allows small- low, particularly in the input market (Dorward et al., 1998;
holder farmers access to credit and inputs (Grosh, 1994; Minot, Shepherd and Farolfi, 1999). As a result, smallholder farmers
1986; Webber and Wang, 2005). As a result, farmers overcome in- experienced input supply problems (Crawford et al., 2003; Ponte,
put market imperfections and credit constraints due to a lack of 2001). This somewhat supports the argument of those critical of
collateral required by commercial banks (Delgado, 1999; Kirsten the neo-liberal reforms that they failed to address the structural
and Sartorius, 2002). Furthermore, contract farming guarantees problems that impeded and militated against agricultural develop-
farmers market access for their produce (Key and Runsten, 1999; ment and smallholder production (Gibbon, 1992). The problems
Minot, 1986). In principle, contract farming allows farmers and faced by farmers included undeveloped input and output markets,
agribusinesses to share the risk in case of crop failure (Glover, poor infrastructure, underfunding in research and extension
1984). However as this paper demonstrates, the practice of con- services, weak or no contract enforcement measures which in-
tract farming is somewhat different from the theory. For example creased the risks and costs of doing business for the private sector
G. Masuka / Geoforum 43 (2012) 573–584 575

(Dorward et al., 2005; Kydd and Dorward, 2001; Sugden, 2009). From 2000, the government seized white-owned farms and em-
Critics argue that the abolition of state marketing boards which oc- barked on a land redistribution programme to benefit landless
curred under liberalisation without putting in place alternative black people (Government of Zimbabwe, 2001). Although the
measures or institutions to enable farmers to access inputs and objectives were noble, the land redistribution process was accom-
to enforce common quality standards was counterproductive panied by violence which disrupted commercial agricultural pro-
(Mather and Greenberg, 2003; Van Donge, 2002). duction (McGregor, 2002; Richardson, 2007; Willems, 2004),
There is debate in the literature on the outcome of neo-liberal including commercial cotton production by white farmers (see
reforms and in particular the benefits of contract farming on farm- Fig. 1).1 For example, in the early 1990s over 155 white farmers pro-
ers (Clapp, 1994; Kirsten and Sartorius, 2002; World Bank, 1994). duced cotton (accounting for about 10%), but by 2003, only 12 farm-
For some farmers, contract farming allows them access to produc- ers were left (accounting for less that 1% of national cotton
tion inputs and markets. Yet for others, contract farming leads to production) (Keeley and Scoones, 2003).
exploitation (Clapp, 1988). The critical literature argues that con- In the process of land redistribution, the government overruled
tracts are sites of struggle, conflicting interpretations, manipula- Supreme Court decisions against land seizure, arguing that the law
tion and dishonesty (Grossman, 1998, p. 7). More importantly, was an obstacle to historical and social justice (Helluma and
contract farming is influenced by local institutional and historical Derman, 2004). Consequently the international community,
factors, the political and economic environment as well as by geo- western think tanks and the International Financial Institutions
graphic settings within which farmers and companies operate condemned the land distribution and criticised the government’s
(Jackson and Cheater, 1994, p. 141; Morrison et al., 2006). This pa- failure to protect private property rights (IMF, 2005; Moyo and
per contributes to these debates by highlighting contextual factors Yeros, 2007). Western countries went onto impose sanctions on
that influenced contract farming and the relations between farm- Zimbabwe’s ruling elite and the country was isolated internation-
ers and COTTCO in Rushinga district. ally. Despite this, several African countries supported the land
redistribution programme (Moyo and Yeros, 2007).
These economic policies and political developments coupled
3. Zimbabwe: Recent political economy and the agricultural with intermittent droughts in 2001 and 2002 had a severe impact
sector on the economy. For example, Zimbabwe’s economic growth de-
clined from 1% in 1999 to 5% in 2000, to 10% in 2001 and to
Zimbabwe adopted neo-liberal economic reforms in 1991 after 15% in 2003 (Muir-Leresche and Sikume, 2006). Overall between
a decade of state-led economic policies (Skalnes, 1995). The aim of 1999 and 2003, Zimbabwe registered a cumulative economic de-
the Economic Structural Adjustment Program (ESAP) was to re- cline in real GDP of 28.4% (Ministry of Finance, 2005). Annual infla-
dress economic decline, increase productivity and competitiveness tion increased from 50% in 2000 to 200% in early 2003, before
of the economy (Government of Zimbabwe, 1991; Mlambo, 1997). shooting up to over 11 million per cent by August 2008 (Central
The government aimed to liberalise the agricultural sector in order Statistical Office, 2000–2008). Furthermore, corruption and rent
to create competitive and efficient multi-channel marketing sys- seeking activities drained resources from the already struggling
tem that allowed farmers to sell their products to whomever they economy (Bracking, 2009; Mumvuma et al., 2006).
wish (Oni, 1997). As the economy contracted, Zimbabwe experienced severe
Liberalisation of Zimbabwe’s cotton sector occurred as part of shortages of foreign currency2 and could not import enough agricul-
these neo-liberal economic reforms. The government sequenced tural inputs and raw materials,3 resulting in declining agricultural
reforms in the cotton sector to smoothen the transition to a liber- production and food shortages (National Economic Consultative
alised market (Larsen, 2002). This began in 1991 when the govern- Forum, 2006; Sachikonye, 2002). As agricultural production declined
ment granted the state-owned Cotton Marketing Board (CMB) so too did the value of exports. For example, from 1998 to 2004, the
managerial autonomy to run on a commercial basis. In 1994, the value of agricultural exports fell from US$ 805 million to US$ 384
government stripped the CMB of its statutory monopoly in pur- million (a decline of over 40%) (IMF 2005; The Reserve Bank of
chasing, ginning, marketing, and export of cotton lint. As a result, Zimbabwe, 2007). Meanwhile, cotton lint exports which in 1998
private traders could participate at various stages of the cotton had generated US$ 150 million, declined to US$ 53 million in 2002
chain. In the following season (1995/1996), three companies before rising to US$ 122 million in 2004 (The Reserve Bank of
namely Cargill, Cotpro and Boka Auctions entered the cotton sec- Zimbabwe, 2007). This paper examines contract farming in the
tor. However, COTTCO continued to dominate the purchasing, mar- context of this unstable environment.
keting, ginning and export of cotton (Goreux, 2003). This was
mainly because at liberalisation COTTCO inherited a developed
infrastructure from the Cotton Marketing Board (CMB). Further, 4. Research methods and background to Rushinga district
none of the new companies could match its input credit scheme
(Poulton et al., 2004). It was not until the new millennium that I conducted research for this paper in Rushinga district, in the
more players entered the sector. By 2006, over twenty companies north east of Zimbabwe, over a period of 12 months, commencing
and individual business people operated in the cotton sector, in February 2006 and continuing until May 2007. In 2002, Rushin-
mainly at the purchasing stage of seed cotton. ga district had a total population of 67,187 of whom 31,996 were
Zimbabwe experienced an economic crisis from the late 1990s
1
following a series of questionable economic policies and controver- Critics argue that the land redistribution was marred by corruption and nepotism
sial political decisions (Brett, 2005). These included paying the and did not benefit a majority of landless people (Makadho, 2006; Sachikonye, 2003);
however, others argue that the land redistribution was successful and benefited the
nearly 60,000 war veterans unbudgeted gratuities of ZW $50,000
landless people (Scoones et al., 2010).
in 1997. This costed the treasury over ZW$ 4 billion (about US$ 2
This led to the growth of a parallel market for foreign currency. For example, from
2,150,537 at the official exchange rate) (Moore, 2003). Again in mid 2006 to August 2007, the official exchange rate was ZW$1: US$ 250, but on the
1997, the government’s decision to intervene in a civil war in the parallel market the exchange rate was about US$1: ZW$ 1500–2000 (in November
2006). By April 2007, the parallel market rate had increased to US$1: ZW$ 200,000–
Democratic Republic of Congo costed over US$ 200 million (Moore,
250,000. The Reserve Bank of Zimbabwe allegedly participated in the parallel market
2003). Further, policy reversals on taxation and the imposition of and this fuelled exchange rates (Makochekanwa, 2007).
price controls in 1998 following the food riots affected the viability 3
Zimbabwe required US$ 2.5 million annually to import sulphur and ammonia for
of businesses and eroded investor confidence (Brett, 2005). fertiliser production (Utete, 2003).
576 G. Masuka / Geoforum 43 (2012) 573–584

Fig. 1. Seed cotton production trends in Zimbabwe (1990–2006). Source: The Agricultural Sector of Zimbabwe, Statistical Bulletin, 2000; Crop Forecasting Committee
Estimates (various years).

males and 35,191 were females (Central Statistical Office, 2004). by farmers and how they bargained with buyers. I also witnessed
Land tenure is of the communal type in which the state owns all how farmers were misled by false ‘price promotions’ advertised
land and users have usufruct rights (Tshuma, 1997). The average at the entrances of company depots. For example, several farmers
farm size in communal areas is between 3 and 5 ha. Farmers in realised that the price advertised by COTTCO and other buyers
Rushinga have an average of 5 ha. were false when the transactions were complete (at the payment
Rushinga district lies in agro ecological region four4 and receives stage) and could not reverse them. In other cases, alert farmers left
an annual rainfall of 450–600 mm. The district experiences mid sea- their seed cotton bales or packets a few metres away and inquired
son droughts, and is suitable mainly for drought resistant crops. The about the price offered by different buyers. These insights could
colonial government introduced cotton production in Rushinga dis- only be gained by observing the behaviour of farmers during the
trict in the mid 1960s as party of its rural strategy to promote pro- transaction process.
duction of cotton in rural areas (Nyambara, 2000). In Rushinga, I used purposive sampling and snowball approaches to identify
cotton was the main cash crop with about 90% of households pro- farmers. In purposive sampling, the researcher selects people that
ducing cotton. As elsewhere in Africa,5 cotton was the main source provide relevant information about the specific phenomenon under
of income and therefore central to the livelihoods of the people of investigation (Mason, 2002; Robson, 2002). Following this ap-
Rushinga district. Further, there were limited economic activities proach, I used the list of names of the group leaders and secretaries
and employment opportunities outside agriculture, which accounts provided by the local staff at Chomutukutu Ward to indentify partic-
for 91% of the work force (Central Statistical Office, 2004). ipants. In turn, the group chairperson and secretaries provided the
I used participant observation and in-depth formal interviews names of their group members, from which I selected participants.
with farmers, officials from COTTCO, the government extension In total, 35 farmers participated in the interviews. Farmers lived
departments and local elected leaders. I also used secondary in the villages of Rupate, Chari, Hoko, Mandendera, and Chip-
sources including reports by COTTCO, the government, academic amuriwo. The villages are within a radius of 10 km from Chom-
literature and newspapers which published stories related to the utukutu business centre. Famers interviewed belonged to eight
topic. groups. Eight were women, and their age ranged from early twen-
In interviews, I asked farmers’ opinions on contract farming and ties to mid fifties, with an average age being 38 years. The average
side marketing. I wanted to know if the prevailing economic envi- age for men was 45 years. All of them were married and lived in
ronment and competition for seed cotton had influenced farmers’ the villages. Farmers’ production history was diverse. Older farm-
decisions to side market. My interviews with officials from COTTCO ers (above 55 years) had a long history of cotton production, some
focused on side marketing and strategies the company was adopt- stretching as far back as the late 1970s. By contrast, three farmers
ing to reduce losses from side marketing. By asking these ques- below the ages of 25 had spent a year to two in contracts. On aver-
tions, I wanted to understand the historical and contextual age, they produced 2 or 3 bales in the previous three to four sea-
factors that mediated and impacted on contract farming in geo- sons. Most of the farmers interviewed had more than 5 years
graphic environments like Rushinga and Zimbabwe in general. experience in cotton production and at least 2 years in contracts.
Participant observation involved me visiting and observing the Data collection was iterative. I used information from the initial
buying and selling of seed cotton at COTTCO depots at Rushinga interviews to frame questions in later interviews. I wrote notes as
and Chomutukutu business centres. Participant observation is use- farmers refused to have their views tape-recorded or names pub-
ful when the primary aim is to find out what is going on (in a social lished for fear of political backlashes. All interview information
event) when the event is repeated frequently (Robson, 2002, p. was transcribed, and later manually coded. During cording, I
315). By observing farmers repeatedly while they sold seed cotton, indentified conceptual categories. I used a thematic approach to
I gained insights on the actual processes of marketing as ‘practiced’ analyse data.

4
5. COTTCO and contract farming in Rushinga district
Zimbabwe has five agro-ecological regions based on rainfall patterns, soil fertility
and agricultural potential. The region’s suitability for crop production decreases from
region one to five. The Cotton Company of Zimbabwe (COTTCO), formerly the Cot-
5
See, Minot and Daniels, 2002; Mosley, 2005; Oxfam International, 2002. ton Marketing Board (CMB) was established through the Cotton
G. Masuka / Geoforum 43 (2012) 573–584 577

Marketing and Control Act (Chapter 106) in 1969 (Blackie, 1983). It Table 1
had statutory monopoly in purchasing, ginning, marketing, and ex- Number of contracted farmers and COTTCO’s market share in Zimbabwe. Source:
Cotton Company of Zimbabwe, Annual Reports (1993–2006).
port of cotton lint. The government commercialised the CMB in
1992, and later privatised in September 1997 (Ministry of Agricul- Year/season Farmers contracted Percentage market share
ture, 1998). of purchased seed cotton

COTTCO participated at all stages of the cotton chain. At the 1992/1993 28,000 100
production stage, it contracted farmers to produce seed cotton 1993/1994 42,000 94
1994/1995 71,636 80
through its input credit scheme. It operated the largest input credit 1995/1996 86,426 81
scheme in Zimbabwe’s cotton sector (Table 1).6 The CMB (now 1996/1997 75,511 70
COTTCO) established the scheme in 1992 with the financial backing 1997/1998 48,000 74
of the Government of Zimbabwe and the World Bank7 following a 1998/1999 53,868 67
1999/2000 76,500 79
drought that reduced cotton production by 60% (Goreux, 2003).
2000/2001 66,100 71
The scheme aimed to ‘‘spearhead a revival of small and communal 2001/2002 80,000 71
sector cotton production at a time when the situation appeared 2002/2003 70,000 68
hopeless for most. . . growers’’ (Cotton Marketing Board, 1992/ 2003/2004 –a 58
1993, p. 5). Therefore at inception, the input scheme was largely 2004/2005 –a 40
2005/2006 50,000 50
developmental; however, with the privatisation of COTTCO in 1997
a
the scheme was commercialised. Under the input scheme, the CMB Figures for these years are missing.
and later COTTCO supplied farmers with inputs such as fertilisers,
seeds and agro-chemicals to farmers on credit and deduct the costs
of the inputs provided at the selling stage (plus a small interest fee, their seed cotton. It also expelled farmers who cheated by putting
which is usually below commercial rates). foreign products in packets (for example, stones or water) to in-
In Rushinga district like elsewhere in Zimbabwe, COTTCO oper- crease the weight of seed cotton. COTTCO could track farmers
ated two main types of input schemes: the ordinary and the gold using grower’s numbers and national identity numbers attached
class. To qualify for COTTCO’s ordinary scheme, farmers produced on each seed cotton pack. In theory, COTTCO could follow the legal
800 kg, had at least 2 ha of land and other assets (such as cattle, channel and have farmers who break contracts prosecuted. How-
goats or carts). To qualify for the gold class, farmers produced ever, in practice this was difficult largely because there were no
6,000 kg or 25 bales.8 Farmers in the latter group constituted the clear legal rules governing the operation of contract farming. Fur-
‘elite club’ and were considered low risk farmers (Larsen, 2002). ther, this was uneconomic because litigation costs were high and
COTTCO signed individual contracts with these farmers, and some- time consuming for the small loans given to farmers.10 As a result,
times provided cash loans in order to build mutual trust and increase COTTCO used group pressure and self-regulatory mechanisms such
loyalty (Gordon and Goodland, 2000). In Rushing district, COTTCO as excluding farmers from future contracts to force farmers to repay
contracted an average of 2300 farmers from 2002 to 2006. loans.11
The ordinary scheme was the largest, involving over 90% of It appears the contract was biased in favour of COTTCO. For
COTTCO’s contracted farmers in Zimbabwe and over 99% in Rush- example, the contract did not state the penalties that COTTCO
inga district.9 Farmers in this scheme were organised into self- would incur if the company failed or decided not to honour the
selecting groups of 10–30 people. Each group was headed by an contract by not supplying inputs to farmers, or purchase seed cot-
elected chairperson and a secretary. In theory, self selecting groups ton, yet it punished farmers if they side marketed. In theory, COTT-
were more likely to be effective compared to groups formed with CO could manipulate this silence in its favour. The observation that
outside influence from donors or companies (Stringfellow et al., contracts are biased against farmers is widely acknowledged in the
1997). Farmers signed asset declaration forms, stating the assets literature (Clapp, 1988; Mather, 1999; Raynolds, 2000; Singh,
they owned (such as cattle, goats, wheelbarrows and ox drawn 2002). According to Watts (1994), most contracts whether written
carts). A reputable witness like the Village Headman or an elected or verbal favour companies. In interviews, farmers were critical of
Councillor verified assets declared by the farmers. These assets, to- COTTCO’s decision to demand all seed cotton even though the
gether with the expected crop harvest were used as collateral company had not supplied them with all inputs particularly from
against the loan of inputs (Dorward et al., 1998). By signing con- 2003 to 2006. Some farmers argued that they were not bound by
tracts, farmers agreed to sell seed cotton to COTTCO and group mem- the contract and were free to sell their seed cotton to buyers. By
bers were jointly and severally liable for loan defaults. In theory, this so doing, they exercised market freedom. Arguably, farmers’
not only reduced administrative costs for COTTCO, but also increased unwillingness to comply with COTTCO’s demands contributed to
social pressure from group members to repay loans. COTTCO also the breakdown of relations between the two parties.
employ Loans and Extension Officers (LEOs) in all cotton growing re-
gions of Zimbabwe. LEOs provided extension advice and were the
point of contact between COTTCO and farmers. They also monitored 5.1. Loan repayment and side marketing of seed cotton
farmers to reduce side marketing.
At the time of selling, COTTCO deducted the costs of inputs sup- At the national level, COTTCO recorded high loan recovery rates,
plied. It accepted repayment of inputs only in the form of seed cot- averaging 90% from 1992 to 1999, and 95–98% from 2000 to
ton. COTTCO blacklisted or expelled farmers who side marketed 2006.12 In Rushinga district, COTTCO had loan recovery rates averag-
ing between 98% and 99% from 2002 to 2006.13 Over 95% of the
6
farmers interviewed in 2006 had repaid their loans (by the end of
Cargill which began operating an input credit scheme in 2002/2003 had about
18,000 contracted farmers. Others contract between 100 and 5000 farmers, Interview
10
with cotton company officials, May 2006. On average, 30–40% of farmers received Interview with Head of Crop and Inputs Procurement COTTCO, Harare, 25/09/
inputs from companies and they accounted for about 60% of national cotton 2006.
11
production. In Slovakia, the lack of public institutions to enforce contracts forced sugar
7
The government and the World Bank provided ZW$ 36.5 million and US $5.7 contracting to use private enforcement mechanisms (Gow et al., 2000).
12
million respectively. Communication with Head of Inputs, COTTCO, Harare, 24/10/2006, see Gordon
8
A standard bale weighs between 200 and 250 kg. and Goodland (2000).
9 13
Interview with an informant, Rushinga district, 15/03/2006. Interview with a senior officer, COTTCO, Rushinga Centre, 11/03/2006.
578 G. Masuka / Geoforum 43 (2012) 573–584

Table 2 As a result, members who failed to repay loans faced immense so-
Number of farmers contracted by COTTCO in Rushinga district. Source: COTTCO, cial pressure and this sometimes resulted in tensions and the
Rushinga depot, 2006.
breakdown of social relationships. The people of Rushinga district
Year 2002/2003 2003/2004 2004/2005 2005/2006 belong to a collectivist culture and farmers had a high regard for
Total farmers 3000 3000 1600 1685 social capital existing among group members. This helped them
to organise and cooperate in various areas (through arranging
work parties to weed or harvest cotton, they assisted each other
in the event of sickness or when a natural disaster occurs).
Table 3
COTTCO’s seed cotton intake and amount side marketed in Rushinga district (2004–
In addition, social pressure occurred because the majority of
2007). Source: COTTCO, Rushinga depot, 2006. members of the input groups were from the same villages and
lived within a radius of two kilometres. Some were related through
Year 2003/ 2004/ 2005/ 2006/
2004 2005 2006 2007
kinship ties, lineages, marriages or shared the same totems. For
example, in one group, two members were brothers and another
Intake (tonnes) 7512 2506 4511 4209
two were father and son. Therefore the possibility of breaking up
Side marketed (tonnes) 751 1882 1895 2152
Expected intake 8263 4388 6406 6361 valued social relations added pressure on farmers to avoid default.
(tonnes) The vice chairmen of an input group summed up this concern by
% Side marketed 9.08 42.89 29.58 33.83 saying that, ‘‘It is better to remain without any money after paying
your loan’’. It could be argued that while participation in the input
credit scheme had benefits, it placed farmers under immense pres-
sure to repay loans for the good of others in the group. Indeed, in
September 2006) but several of them still went onto side market sur-
these collectivist cultures group interests or objectives are priori-
plus seed cotton. The section below discusses the reasons for loan
tised over individual interests. COTTCO recognised the importance
repayment before turning to side marketing of seed cotton.
of culture, social relationships and kinship ties among farmers and
It appears economic and social reasons motivated farmers to re-
relied on these to force farmers to repay loans.16
pay loans. Economic reasons included the possibility of losing as-
The foregoing shows that a combination of economic and social
sets, blacklisting and exclusion from the input credit scheme. An
pressures increased loan repayments. For example, loan recovery
input group chairperson explained that farmers knew that if they
averaged above 95%; however, not all farmers sold ‘all cotton to
did not repay loans, COTTCO could confiscate their assets. Another
COTTCO’ as stipulated in the contract.17 Instead over half of farmers
farmer agreed when he said, ‘‘being in an input group places farm-
sold enough seed cotton to repay what they owe COTTCO and sold or
ers under significant pressure to work hard since they are aware
side marketed surplus seed cotton to other buyers who offered high-
that they have a debt that needs to be repaid at the end of the
er prices. In Rushinga, side marketing (of surplus seed cotton) cut
season’’.
across gender, age and socioeconomic classes. For example, a 40-
Apart from losing assets, farmers were also aware that in the
year farmer who produced six bales of seed cotton in 2006 sold four
case of default on a loan repayment COTTCO could exclude them
bales to COTTCO (in early June at ZW$ 60,000/kg), one to Cargill (at
from the input credit scheme. Access to inputs was the main rea-
ZW$ 65,000/kg) and another bale to Alliance ginneries (at ZW$
son for farmers to join contract farming. For example, over 90%
72,000/kg). Another farmer sold three bales to COTTCO in mid July
of farmers admitted that they could not afford to buy all inputs
2006 at ZW$ 95,000/kg and one and half bales to Alliance ginneries
on cash on the open market at the start of the season. They had nei-
at ZW$ 120,000/kg. Yet another farmer produced six bales and sold
ther cash nor access to credit with which to buy inputs.14 However,
two to COTTCO (at ZW$ 100,000/kg), two bales each to Alliance gin-
the unstable macroeconomic environment resulted in severe short-
neries (at ZW$ 145,000/kg) and Grafax (at ZW$ 140,000/kg) respec-
ages and the escalation of prices of inputs. This resulted in distor-
tively. Several farmers interviewed sold seed cotton to different
tions in the input market as unscrupulous traders took advantage
buyers depending on the price offered.
of the shortages to sell inputs on the parallel market where prices
Table 3 shows COTTCO’s total intake of seed cotton in Rushinga
were much higher.15 Some farmers recognised these constraints
district. It shows that in the 2003/2004 season, 9% of contracted
and preferred to participate in contracts as companies had a better
cotton was side marketed but this increased drastically to over
chance of sourcing inputs. A farmer in Mandendera village summed
40% in the 2004/2005 season (COTTCO Rushinga depot, 2006). Side
up this concern when he said, ‘‘it is better to be in an input group be-
marketing was not limited to Rushinga, but occured in other parts
cause these companies know where to get inputs’’. For these farmers,
of Zimbabwe. COTTCO estimated that in 2001 about 30% of seed
the long term benefits of participating in COTTCO’s input credit
cotton it was due under contract was side marketed (COTTCO,
scheme outweighed the costs. However, in the short term and in
2002). In 2002 over 30,000 tons of seed cotton out of a total pro-
the context of the prevailing economic environment farmers’ selling
duction of 195,670 tons (about 15%) was side marketed (COTTCO,
decision were influenced by prices offered by different seed buyers.
2001/2002). It is likely that side marketing increased in the past
Another related factor that explains farmers’ behaviour to repay
couple of years, as a result of the proliferation of new buyers
loan was social pressure. As earlier indicated, COTTCO advances in-
who capitalised on the economic crisis.
puts to self-selecting farmers organised in groups. Members were
A majority of farmers side marketed seed cotton to get higher
individually and jointly liable for loan repayments. This means that
prices. In the period under review (1999–2006), there was in-
the whole group was punished when a member defaulted and
creased competition among buyers for a limited supply of seed cot-
could not receive inputs until the outstanding loans were paid.
ton both in Rushinga and in Zimbabwe generally.18 In Rushinga
district, up until 2001 COTTCO and Cargill dominated the buying
14
This applies to other smallholder farmers in Africa (Dorward et al., 2004; Ponte,
2001).
15 16
In mid 2006, a 50 kg bag of fertiliser was priced between ZW$ 2.5 million and Interview with a senior official, COTTCO, Harare, 25/09/2006.
17
ZW$3 million in retail shops, while the government regulated retail price was ZW$ Interview with an Officer, Rushinga, June 2006.
18
252,000. The price of government-subsidised petrol was ZW$ 350–400 per litre, but For example, from 1993 to 2000, national cotton production averaged 248,000
on the parallel market it costed nearly ZW$ 5000 per litre (The Sunday Mail, 12/02/ tonnes and was purchased by eight buyers, but in 2006 production fell to 198,000
2006). Corruption was rife and politicians allegedly bought inputs from state-run tonnes and was purchased by over 20 buyers (supplying ginneries with a capacity of
institutions and sold them at the parallel market at exorbitant prices (Zumbika, 2006). 519,000 tonnes per annum).
G. Masuka / Geoforum 43 (2012) 573–584 579

Fig. 2. Comparison of seed cotton price in Chomutukutu ward in 2006 season. Source: Field notes/interview with buyers, 2006.

of seed cotton claiming over 80% of the market share. By 2006 there example, the bonus payment in December allowed farmers to have
were six other players in the market including, Insing, Grafax, COT- a cash injection during the festive season.21
TRADE, Olam, FSI Agricom and Alliance ginneries competing for seed These benefits notwithstanding, the unstable economic envi-
cotton purchases. Consequently, COTTCO’s market share for seed ronment from 2000 characterised by hyperinflation, escalation
cotton purchases declined to nearly 45%.19 As competition intensi- of prices, shortages of cash and basic food commodities wiped
fied in 2006, none of the eight companies operating in Rushinga dis- all the benefits that once accrued to farmers under COTTCO’s
trict graded cotton at the point of purchase.20 As the ‘scramble’ for staggered payment system. As one farmer noted, ‘‘by the time
cotton increased buyers paid a flat price for all seed cotton irrespec- we get price adjustments and bonus payments the money would
tive of quality. Consequently, farmers could sell regardless of quality, be valueless and cannot buy anything. . .may be just sweets for
and were less concerned with grading than before. As one farmer children’’. In this sense, farmers had good reasons to demand full
noted ‘‘even if I do not grade my crop companies will still buy it’’. payment at the time of selling. COTTCO insisted that it was
In this sense, competition benefited farmers by cutting labour costs uneconomic to pay farmers full prices at the time of selling be-
in grading at farm gate. However, these practices impacted on seed fore assessing the movements of international lint prices, as this
cotton quality standards (Larsen, 2001; Jimat Development Consul- could result in losses.22 This was a rational business decision in
tants, 2005). the interests of COTTCO’s shareholders. However, this decision
Fig. 2 shows prices offered by the major buyers in Chomutukutu meant that farmers could bore the risks and losses of declines in
Ward in the 2006 selling season. It shows significant price differ- international lint prices. In an inflationary environment like Zimba-
ences between buyers; as a result, farmers had an incentive to side bwe (inflation reached over 11 million per cent in 2008), farmers
market. For example, by the end of August 2006, COTTCO paid ZW$ prioritised higher and full prices on the spot, hence their decision
105,000/kg compared to ZW$ 155,000/kg and ZW$ 180,000/kg to side market.
paid by Alliance and Insing respectively. In the opinion of these It could be argued that under the prevailing circumstances
farmers, new buyers like Insing had a competitive edge over COTT- COTTCO’s inability to meet farmers’ expectations resulted in them
CO. Market rationality dictated that farmers would sell their pro- selling seed cotton to other buyers who offered higher and full pay-
duce to the highest bidder. This was the case among many ment at the time of selling.23 Farmers’ behaviour in exercising mar-
farmers. As one farmer and chairperson of an input credit group ket freedom and COTTCO’s insistence that farmers follow the terms
asked me rhetorically, ‘‘if it were you, would you sell all your seed of the contract exposes the tensions inherent in contract farming in
cotton to COTTCO when there are higher prices elsewhere’’? An- deregulated markets. As Little and Watts (1994, p. 221) observes
other farmer concurred when he said, ‘‘COTTCO ngaikwidze mitengo, ‘‘. . .it is when farmers begin to behave as free market actors, selling
isu chatinoda imari kwete company’’ (COTTCO should increase its their produce to the highest bidder, that the contract farming
prices, what we want is more money not the company). Clearly, schemes are jeopardized’’. Through side marketing farmers were
farmers’ concerns at the time were to maximise profit and to be attempting to renegotiate the contract by appealing to market prin-
able to support their families, because cotton was their main ciples embedded in the neo-liberal theory.
source of livelihood. Undoubtedly, the entry of more buyers since liberalisation pro-
COTTCO’s payment system may also have contributed to the in- vided farmers with selling options. In contrast prior to and imme-
crease in side marketing among contracted farmers. Traditionally, diately after liberalisation, COTTCO had a monopoly and dictated
COTTCO had three forms of payment. It paid farmers an interim
price (at the time of selling); a bonus payment (in December of
each year) and gave farmers back-pay or price adjustments at
the end of the season (usually in August and September). As a re-
sult, farmers who sold their seed cotton at the beginning of the sea- 21
See Hanyani-Mlambo et al., 2002.
son benefited from price increases that occurred as the season 22
Interview with a senior official at COTTCO, 26/09/2006.
progressed. Prior to the economic crisis in 2000, COTTCO’s pay- 23
Most of the new buyers did not finance cotton production through contract
ment system was competitive and attractive to most farmers. For schemes. They capitalised on the deregulated market system and lack of regulation to
free ride on other companies’ investments. As a result, they could offer farmers higher
prices. According to Poulton and Hanyani-Mlambo (2008, p. 56) ‘‘other things being
equal, a firm that does not provide pre-harvest support [operate inputs credit
19
Interview with a senior official, COTTCO, Rushinga depot, May 2006. schemes] to cotton producers can pay a 21% higher average seed cotton price than a
20
Personal observations, Rushinga, June, 2006. company that does’’.
580 G. Masuka / Geoforum 43 (2012) 573–584

the market terms for farmers.24 For example in 1999, a depot man- It could be argued from an agribusiness perspective that side
ager at COTTCO responded to farmers’ demand for higher prices and marketing threatened the commercial sustainability of contract
threats to boycott the selling season by saying, ‘‘we are not worried farming and companies’ willingness to provide inputs to farmers.
even if they keep their produce for a year. They cannot take it any- Companies contract farmers to secure the supply of raw materials
where. In the end they will still bring it here.’’ The manager went at the source, if this is no longer guaranteed because of side mar-
onto say, ‘‘if I am a peanut butter processing company it is not my keting, in theory companies could stop investing in cotton produc-
business to see whether the person who makes containers also tion. In the absence of an alternative scheme, farmers would go
makes profit, that is our business culture in the company.’’25 This without inputs resulting in a decline in production. In theory, side
not only showed the arrogance and disregard for farmers’ welfare marketing is not in the long term interests of farmers. However, as
by the manager, but demonstrated the skewed power relations be- this paper showed in real markets the desire to maximise returns
tween COTTCO and farmers. influenced farmers’ decisions. The section below discusses COTT-
Without alternative input or output markets, farmers were price CO’s responses to side marketing. It considers COTTCO’s three
takers. However, in the period under review farmers had alternative strategies namely; the threat to withdraw from contract farming,
market outputs. They circumvented the contract principally reducing the number of contracted farmers and lobbying the gov-
through side marketing. In this sense, side marketing was a form ernment to re-regulate the sector.
of ‘tactical resistance’ (Watts, 1990, p. 158) to the terms of the con-
tract through which farmers sought to circumvent a system they
considered exploitative (Bassett, 2001; Scott, 1990). If contracts 5.2. Strategies of addressing side marketing
were exploitative, why did farmers enter into these contracts? Ear-
lier I noted that farmers’ need to access inputs (often caused by thin In 2003, COTTCO and FSI Agricom threatened to withdraw its in-
input markets), forced them to enter into unfavourable contracts put credit scheme unless the government took stern measures
with companies. According to Clapp (1994, p. 91) ‘‘it is in the imme- against buyers who promoted side marketing of contracted seed
diate interests of the weak [farmers] to maintain the ideology [con- cotton (COTTCO Annual Report, 2004).26 The company’s managing
tract] that subordinates them, for it also lends them sustenance’’. director said at the time ‘‘as a private company guided by stakeholder
Farmers also used social and kinship networks to their benefit. interests, COTTCO cannot continue with the role of national benefac-
Above I noted that even though these are market-regulated con- tor, with competitors coming to reap where they did not sow’’ (The
tracts, COTTCO relied on kinship and social networks to enforce Financial Gazette, 17/09/2003). COTTCO’s threat was received with
loan repayment. On their part, farmers used kinship ties to circum- divided opinion. On the one hand, industry analysts and farmers
vent the required production history set by COTTCO for new farm- feared that this could reduce cotton production critical because
ers to join contracts. For example, a chairman of an input credit COTTCO contracted over half of cotton farmers in Zimbabwe (see Ta-
group who produced an average of 15 bales each year had in the ble 1).27 On the other hand, the vice President of the Zimbabwe Farm-
past three seasons (2002–2005) sold two bales of seed cotton to ers Union was critical and arguing that if the two companies found
COTTCO under his son’s name in order to help him to build a pro- the cotton industry unprofitable, they could withdraw. COTTCO’s
duction history. The farmer ‘weaned off’ his son after he qualified withdrawal seemed unlikely because since privatisation in 1997 it
for contracts. In future, the son could possibly help others to do has declared huge profits despite the increase in side marketing.
the same. Although this was not allowed by COTTCO, several farm- For example, in 1998 COTTCO recorded a net profit of ZW$791 mil-
ers confirmed the practice. In this regard farmers relied on social lion, well above its forecast of about ZW$246 million (COTTCO An-
capital in order to meet and/or circumvent requirements of a mar- nual Report, 1998/1999). While in 2002, COTTCO’s net profit was
ket regulated contract. ZW$2.3 billion, nearly a 116% increase from the previous year (COTT-
The paper contends that contracts do not exist in idealised mar- CO Annual Report, 2001/2002). In 2003, profit after tax was ZW$13
ket setting, but in imperfect markets like Rushinga district. There- billon, before increasing to ZW$103 billion and ZW$172 billion in
fore the paper underscores the need to understand contextual 2004 and 2005 respectively (COTTCO Annual Reports, 1998–2006).
factors in different geographical settings that influence contract As COTTCO and FSI Agricom threatened to withdraw their input
farming and shape the behaviour of farmers. In the context of Zim- schemes, Grafax (an Asian-based company) announced a ZW$2 bil-
babwe’s economic environment, farmers disagreed with the con- lion input credit scheme earmarked for newly resettled cotton
tract and attempted to negotiate the meaning of the contract. farmers.28 This somewhat proved that the sector was still attractive
The implications of these practices are far reaching. Firstly, it to investors, although this was partly because of the distortions that
shows that in a liberalised market environment where COTTCO existed in the economy (Poulton and Hanyani-Mlambo, 2008). In the
has no exclusive rights to seed cotton, it had to innovate and be end, COTTCO did not withdraw the contract scheme; instead, it first
competitive to farmers. Secondly, it shows the challenges of oper- suspended its input scheme and then later reduced the number of
ating contracts in an unstable economic environment. Thirdly, it contracted farmers and focused on what it called ‘loyal’ and highly
demonstrates the inherent contractions in the neo-liberal ideology productive farmers (The Cotton Company of Zimbabwe, 2006). These
that on one hand promote free markets and argue against regula- were mostly the better-off farmers who produced over 1000 kg of
tion but on the other hand require state regulation to function cotton and own assets (Larsen, 2006). For example, Table 2 shows
properly, especially to deal with opportunistic traders and those that COTTCO reduced the number of contracted farmers in Rushinga
free riding on other company’s investments. Therefore, in unregu- district from 3000 in the 2002/2003 season to 1600 in the 2004/2005
lated agricultural markets there could trade-offs between short season and 1685 farmers in the 2005/2006 season (COTTCO,
term benefits and long term interests. Rushinga depot, 2006).29 This way COTTCO could reduce the losses

26
See, The Herald, 28/03/2003; The Financial Gazette, 17/09/2003.
24 27
Despite this, producer prices prior to liberalisation and immediately after (when Makamure et al., 2001; The Herald, 20/09/2006.
28
there were a few competitors) were higher than in the period after 2001 (when Interview with officials from Grafax, 20 July 2006, see also The Herald, 21/08/
competition increased). Poulton and Hanyani-Mlambo (2008, pp. 46–47) attribute 2003.
29
this to increased operational costs during the economic crisis (after 2001), the Similarly, FSI Agricom scaled down its contracts, citing problems with side
distortions in the economy and company’s unwillingness to pass the benefits of the marketing. Other companies like Cholima and Farmers’ World withdrew from the
depreciation of the exchange rate to farmers. cotton sector in 2003 allegedly because of side marketing (The Financial Gazette, 17/
25
COTTCO depot manger cited in The Sunday Mail, 02/05/1999. 09/2003).
G. Masuka / Geoforum 43 (2012) 573–584 581

associated with side marketing and perhaps also be able to fulfil its 2006, the Minister of agriculture Dr. Made expressed similar senti-
obligation to supply inputs in a difficult economic environment.30 ments when he said, ‘‘we do not want a situation whereby COTTCO
It appears this approach was not very successful as the suppos- gives inputs to farmers and other players come into buy the
edly ‘loyal farmers’ engaged in side marketing (see Table 3).31 The cotton.’’36
problem was therefore not about trust or loyalty of farmers but Despite these recommendations and initiatives by industry
about COTTCO’s perceived lack of competitiveness in an unregulated bodies and stakeholders, the government did not implement legis-
market environment. As argued above, this occurred because most of lation in the cotton sector. However, in 2006 and 2007 the Ministry
the new buyers were free riding on other companies which financed of Agriculture new requirements for buyers to be awarded export
cotton production.32 permits. In early 2006, the Ministry of Agriculture noted that, ‘‘only
COTTCO also appealed to the government to introduce reforms those who supported cotton farmers by giving seed and inputs will
in the cotton sector in order to establish what it called a ‘‘level be issued with export permits.’’37 Further, all companies were re-
playing field’’.33 For example, in 2003 COTTCO took the unprece- quired to sell 30% of their lint to the domestic market. Thus, in the
dented step to present a draft reform proposal for the cotton sector absence of legislation the Ministry of Agriculture could use these
to the Ministry of Agriculture (COTTCO Annual Reports, 2003, 2005). requirements to exert influence on buyers (Poulton and Hanyani-
In 2006, COTTCO reported that ‘‘the company is actively involved in Mlambo, 2008, p. 28).
the setting up of a regulatory framework that would ensure enforce- There could be several reasons why this was the case. First,
ment of quality standards and promote the growth of the cotton there were disagreements between companies in the cotton sector
industry’’ (COTTCO Annual Report, 2006, p. 15). However, COTTCO regarding the proposed reforms. On the one hand, companies
advised its shareholders that ‘‘while we remain hopeful [about which financed cotton production and suffered most from side
new legislation] it is evident that this will be a lengthy process marketing supported legislation. On the other hand, mostly new
due mostly to lack of industry consensus, particularly among some players which benefited from the unregulated environment ap-
players who appear to insist on reaping where they did not sow, thus peared somewhat resistant to the reforms. In interviews officials
encouraging side marketing of the crop’’ (COTTCO Annual Report, from the new buyers agued that big companies (COTTCO and Carg-
2006, p. 15). ill) wanted legislation to restrict competition in the sector and en-
It is important to note that since liberalisation in 1994 Zimba- act entry barriers for new players. In particular they were critical of
bwe had no regulatory framework on contract farming or the cot- the proposal that all buyers should ‘respect the sanctity of the con-
ton sector in general. Without the state to enforce contracts or tract’ arguing that this could restrict farmers’ freedom to sell to
industry standards, players cooperated informally through the Na- whomever they wish. Further, they claimed that the National Cot-
tional Cotton Council. The National Cotton Council was established ton Council (NCC) was dominated by COTTCO; as a result, the pro-
in 1994 for stakeholders to meet regularly to discuss issues affect- posal that the NCC should recommend a buyer for licensing to the
ing the cotton sector. It had no legal powers to enforce resolutions Ministry of Agriculture before they could participate would in-
agreed by its members. Consequently, members agreed among crease COTTCO’s dominance and disadvantage new buyers.38
themselves to uphold industry standards on uniform grading and To compound this, there were differences within the state, with
quality (Larsen, 2001; Poulton et al., 2004); however as players in- some key actors publicly in favour of reforms while others ap-
creased in the sector informal cooperation became ineffective peared reluctant. For example, the then Deputy Minister strongly
(Poulton et al., 2004). As competition increased buyers paid less advocated for reforms yet there were allegations that some politi-
attention to grading procedures and quality standards. As a result, cians had shareholdings in the new companies accused of promot-
there was increasing concern among stakeholders that Zimbabwe ing side marketing disregarding industry standards on quality and
would losing its international market share as a supplier of high grading hence their reluctance to support the proposed reforms.39
quality lint along with the premium prices it received (Larsen, More importantly, in the context of the history and geographi-
2001; Robinson and Ndlela, 1994).34 cal space described in this paper, re-regulation of the sector could
It was in this context that in 2004 industry stakeholders includ- have appeared like the state was siding with and promoting the
ing COTTCO, Cargill and the National Cotton Council drafted regu- interests of cotton companies and disregarding the concerns of
lations for the cotton sector and presented them to the Ministry of farmers. Such a position could have been unpalatable to some pol-
Agriculture (Poulton and Hanyani-Mlambo, 2008). The Presidential iticians from cotton growing regions like Rushinga. For example in
Land Review Committee made similar arguments for the establish- 2007, the Member of Parliament for Rushinga district was critical
ment of an industrial body that would among other things, monitor of cotton buyers and encouraged farmers to stop cotton production
and enforce common standards (Jimat Development Consultants, if buyers refused to increase prices.40 I argue that the divisions
2005; Utete, 2003). Similarly, in 2005 the then deputy Minister among players in the cotton sector together with government’s inac-
of agriculture (who was a former managing director and a large tion possibly because some politicians benefited from the status quo
shareholder in COTTCO) argued that the government introduce may explain why legislation was not enacted.
policies that stop buyers or ginners from operating unless they The paper examined the relations between farmers and COTT-
put in place an input and cotton production finance scheme.35 In CO. In particular, it showed the tensions between contracts that re-
quire regulation and the neo-liberal ideology that argues against
30
However, in the 2006/2007 season, COTTCO increased the number of contracted regulation of markets. It could be argued that in deregulated agri-
farmers following and agreement with the National Cotton Council, The Ministry of cultural markets as in Zimbabwe which also experienced macro-
Agriculture and The Ministry Industry and International trade that issuance of export economic instability and the collapse of inputs markets, there
permits would be proportional to the support provided by a company towards crop
production (Poulton and Hanyani-Mlambo, 2008).
31
Interviews with COTTCO officials and farmers in Rushinga district.
32 36
See Poulton and Hanyani-Mlambo, 2008. Dr. Made cited in The Herald, 25/08/206.
33 37
Interview with Head of Inputs and Crop Procurement of COTTCO, Harare, 25/09/ Internal document prepared by the Markets and Trade section, Ministry of
2006. Agriculture, 2006.
34 38
The deterioration of quality standards affected other liberalised markets in Interview with the operations managers of two new companies, 26/09/2006.
39
commodities like cotton, cocoa and coffee (Gibbon, 1999; Losch, 2002; Shepherd and Interview with an industry informant, 23/09/2006. In 2006, high ranking
Farolfi, 1999; Tollens and Gilbert, 2003). government officials officiated at the new company’s events despite the accusation
35
Speech by Mr. S. Nguni at the official opening of the Zimbabwe Cotton Campaign that they were disregarding industry standards.
40
stakeholders meeting, Harare, 20–21 September, 2005. See The Herald, 26/04/2007.
582 G. Masuka / Geoforum 43 (2012) 573–584

were trade-offs between short-term profits and long-term invest- anonymous reviewers for useful comments on earlier drafts of this
ment in the sector. While it is clear that side marketing, non obser- paper. I take responsibility for any shortcomings.
vance of grading procedures and quality standards are not in the
long term interests of the cotton sector, it is important to contex-
tualise and understand the behaviour of farmers and companies. References
They operated in imperfect markets and specific geographic setting
Bassett, T.J., 2001. The Peasant Cotton Revolution in West Africa: Côte d’Ivoire,
outlined above. In these real market setting, farmers and buyers 1880–1995. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
faced severe challenges. It appears they both responded to the Bates, R.H., 1981. Markets and States in Tropical Africa: The Political Basis of
challenges in rational ways and market principles informed this Agricultural Policies. University of California Press, Los Angeles.
Blackie, M.J., 1983. Case Study: The Zimbabwe Cotton Marketing Board. Department
behaviour. Because the two had conflicting objectives, tensions oc-
of Land Management, Working Paper 2/83. The University of Zimbabwe.
curred in the relationship. Bracking, S., 2009. Political economies of corruption beyond liberalism: an
interpretive view of Zimbabwe. Singapore Journal of Tropical Geography 30,
31–51.
Brett, E.A., 2005. From corporatism to liberalization in Zimbabwe: economic policy
6. Conclusion regimes and political crisis, 1980–97. International Political Science Review 26
(91), 91–106.
Central Statistical Office, 2004. Zimbabwe Census 2002: Provincial Profile:
The paper examined the relations between farmers and COTTCO
Mashonaland Central. Central Census Office, Harare, Zimbabwe.
largely mediated by contract farming in Rushinga district of Zim- Clapp, R.A., 1988. Representing reciprocity, reproducing domination – ideology and
babwe. It particularly focused on side marketing of seed cotton. the labor process in Latin-American contract farming. Journal of Peasant Studies
16 (1), 5–39.
In so doing, the paper highlighted important aspects of the political
Clapp, R.A., 1994. The moral economy of the contract. In: Little, P.D., Watts, M.J.
economy of African agriculture in the era of liberalisation. More (Eds.), Living Under Contract: Contract Farming and Agrarian Transformation in
importantly, the paper examined the conflict between contracts Sub-Saharan Africa. The University of Wisconsin Press, Madison, pp. 78–94.
that demand regulation by the state or monopolies and the neo- Cotton Marketing Board, Annual Reports.
Coulter, J., Goodland, A., Tallontire, A., Stringfellow, R., 1999. Marrying Farmer Co-
liberal ideologies that promote competitive markets and oppose operation and Contract Farming for Agricultural Service Provision in Sub-
state interference or strong regulation. For example in Zimbabwe, Saharan Africa. Overseas Development Institute, Natural Resources Perspectives
most of the new buyers did not finance cotton production and par- No. 48.
Crawford, E., Kelly, V., Jayne, T.S., Howard, J., 2003. Input use and market
ticipated only at the buying and marketing stages. As a result, they development in sub-Saharan Africa: an overview. Food Policy 28 (4), 277–292.
were free riding on companies that financed cotton production Da Silva, C.A.B., 2005. The Growing Role of Contract Farming in Agri-food Systems
through contract schemes. This caused conflict between companies Development: Drivers, Theory and Practice. Agricultural Management,
Marketing and Finance. FAO, Rome.
that finance cotton production through contract farming and those Delgado, C., 1995. Agricultural diversification and export promotion in sub-Saharan
that did not, as the former lost seed cotton due to them because of Africa. Food Policy 20 (3), 225–243.
increased side marketing by contracted farmers. In some sense Delgado, C., 1999. Sources of growth in smallholder agriculture in sub-Saharan
Africa: the role of vertical integration of smallholder farmers with processors
therefore, in deregulated agricultural markets there were/are
and marketers of high value added items. Agrekon 38, 165–189.
trade-offs between short-term profits and long-term investments. Dorward, A., Poulton, C., Kydd, J. (Eds.), 1998. Smallholder Cash Crop Production
The contractual relationship between COTTCO and farmers was under Market Liberalisation: A New Institutional Economics Perspective. CAB
International, New York.
distinctive in cotton production and in the rural economy of Rush-
Dorward, A., Kydd, J., Morrison, J., Urey, I., 2004. A policy agenda for pro-poor
inga district. However, this paper argued that side marketing of agricultural growth. World Development 32 (1), 73–89.
seed cotton strained the relations between these two parties. On Dorward, A., Kydd, J., Poulton, C., 2005. Beyond liberalisation: ‘‘development
the one hand, farmers exercised freedom and applied market prin- coordination’’ policies for African smallholder agriculture. IDS Bulletin 36 (2),
80–85.
ciples embedded in the neo-liberal ideology when they sold seed Eaton, C., Shepherd, A.W., 2001. Contract Farming: Partnerships for Growth: Food
cotton to whoever they wish after they paid loans owed to COTT- and Agricultural Organisation. FAO Agricultural Services Bulletin 145, Rome.
CO. In addition, farmers sought to maximise their returns as cotton Friedland, W.H., Busch, L., Buttel, F.H., Rudy, A.P. (Eds.), 1991. Towards a New
Political Economy of Agriculture. Westview Press, Boulder.
production was their main source of income. On the other hand, Gibbon, P., 1992. A failed agenda? African agriculture under structural adjustment
COTTCO also wanting to increase shareholder value and profits with special reference to Kenya and Ghana. Journal of Peasant Studies 20 (1),
wanted farmers to supply all seed cotton as stated in the contract. 50–96.
Gibbon, P., 1999. Free competition without sustainable development? Tanzanian
The disagreements between the two parties over the meaning of cotton sector liberalisation, 1994/95 to 1997/98. The Journal of Development
side marketing strained relations. The contest between farmers Studies 36 (1), 128–150.
and COTTCO tell a story about the difficulties of operating contract Glover, D.J., 1984. Contract farming and smallholder outgrower schemes in less-
developed countries. World Development 12 (11–12), 1143–1157.
farming in the period under review. In particular, it shows that the
Glover, D.J., Kusterer, K.C., 1990. Small Farmers, Big Business: Contract Farming and
outcome from contract farming was not determined by or merely Rural Development. Macmillan, Hampshire.
based on the written contractual agreement entered into by the Gordon, A., Goodland, A., 2000. Production credit for African small-holders:
conditions for private provision. Savings and Development 1 (XXIV), 55–84.
two parties; rather it was influenced by other actors/agents oper-
Gore, C., 2000. The rise and fall of the Washington consensus as a paradigm for
ating in the market, by the state and by local, national and interna- developing countries. World Development 28 (5), 789–804.
tional factors. As these agents competed to maximise their returns, Goreux, L., 2003. Reforming the Cotton Sector in Sub-Saharan Africa. Africa Region
they both sought to renegotiate the meaning of contracts with Working Paper Series 62. World Bank, Washington, DC.
Government of Zimbabwe, 1991. Zimbabwe: A Framework for Economic Reform
varying levels of success. In this regard, neo-liberalism was not (1991–1995), Harare, Zimbabwe.
merely dictated or imposed; rather, it was being negotiated and Government of Zimbabwe, 2001. Zimbabwe’s Land Reform Programme.. Ministry of
changed to suit locally specific trajectories in Rushinga district Lands, Agriculture and Rural Resettlement, Harare, Zimbabwe.
Gow, H.R., Streeter, D.H., Swinnen, J.F.M., 2000. How private contract enforcement
and to work in the prevailing economic and political environment. mechanisms can succeed where public institutions fail: the case of Juhocukor a.
s. Agricultural Economics 23 (3), 253–265.
Grosh, B., 1994. Contract farming in Africa: an application of the new institutional
economics. Journal of African Economies 3 (2), 231–261.
Acknowledgements
Grossman, L.S., 1998. The political ecology of bananas: contract farming, peasants,
and agrarian change in the eastern Caribbean. University of North Carolina
I am grateful to the Department of Resource Management and Press, Chapel Hill.
Geography, University of Melbourne for financial support. I thank Hanyani-Mlambo, B., Larsen, M.N., Poulton, C., 2002. An Overview of the Cotton
Sub-Sector in Zimbabwe. Imperial College, University of London. <http://www.
cotton farmers in Rushinga district for being generous with their imperial.ac.uk/agriculturalsciences/research/sections/aebm/projects/cotton_
time and knowledge. I also thank Enocent Msindo and the downloads/sysovzim.pdf> (accessed 22.12.04).
G. Masuka / Geoforum 43 (2012) 573–584 583

Helluma, A., Derman, B., 2004. Land reform and human rights in contemporary Murray, W.E., 2001. The second wave of globalisation and agrarian change in the
Zimbabwe: balancing individual and social justice through an integrated pacific Islands. Journal of Rural Studies 17, 19–38.
human rights framework. World Development 32 (10), 1785–1805. National Economic Consultative Forum, 2006. NECF/ZCFU Agricultural Planning
International Monetary Fund, 2005. Zimbabwe: Selected Issues and Statistical Conference, Harare International Conference Centre: National Economic
Appendix, Report No. 05/359. International Monetary Fund, Washington, DC. Consultative Forum (10–11 May 2006).
Jackson, J.C., Cheater, A.P., 1994. Contract farming in Zimbabwe: case studies of Nyambara, P.S., 2000. Colonial policy and peasant cotton agriculture in Southern
sugar, tea, and cotton. In: Little, P.D., Watts, M.J. (Eds.), Living Under Contract: Rhodesia, 1904–1953. The International Journal of African Historical Studies 33
Contract Farming and Agrarian Transformation in Sub-Saharan Africa. The (1), 81–111.
University of Wisconsin Press, Madison. Oni, S.A., 1997. The Impact of ESAP on the Communal Areas of Zimbabwe.
Jaffee, S., Morton, J., 1995. Marketing Africa’s High Value Foods: Comparative Department of Agricultural Economics, Harare.
Experiences of an Emergent Private Sector. Hull Publishing Company, Dubuque. Oxfam International, 2002. Cultivating Poverty: The Impact of US Cotton Subsidies
Jimat Development Consultants, 2005. STABEX Cotton Sector Study, Final Report. on Africa. Oxfam Briefing Paper 30. Oxfam International.
Jimat Development Consultants, Harare. Polanyi, K., 1944. The Great Transformation. Beacon Press, Boston.
Keeley, J., Scoones, I., 2003. Seeds in a globalised world: agricultural biotechnology Ponte, S., 2001. Policy reforms, market failures and inputs use in African
in Zimbabwe. IDS Working Paper 189. Institute of Development Studies, Sussex. smallholder agriculture. The European Journal of Development Research 13
Key, N., Runsten, D., 1999. Contract farming, smallholders, and rural development in (1), 1–29.
Latin America: the organization of agroprocessing firms and the scale of Poulton, C., Hanyani-Mlambo, B., 2008. The Cotton Sector of Zimbabwe. World Bank
outgrower production. World Development 27 (2), 381–401. Working Papers. World Bank.
Kindness, H., Gordon, A., 2001. Agricultural Marketing in Developing Countries: The Poulton, C., Dorward, A., Kydd, J., 1998. The revival of smallholder cash crops in
Role of NGOs and CBOs. Policy Series 13. Natural Resources Institute, Chatham, Africa: public and private roles in the provision of finance. Journal of
UK. International Development 10 (1), 85–103.
Kirsten, J., Sartorius, K., 2002. Linking agribusiness and small-scale farmers in Poulton, C., Gibbon, P., Hanyani-Mlambo, B., Kydd, J., Maro, W.E., Larsen, M.N., et al.,
developing countries: is there a new role for contract farming? Development 2004. Competition and coordination in liberalized African cotton market
Southern Africa 19 (4), 503–529. systems. World Development 32 (3), 519–536.
Kydd, J., Dorward, A., 2001. The Washington consensus on poor country agriculture: Raynolds, L.T., 2000. Negotiating contract farming in the Dominican Republic.
analysis, prescription and institutional gaps. Development Policy Review 19 (4), Human Organization 59 (4), 441–451.
467–478. Richardson, C.J., 2007. How much does drought matter? Linking rainfall and GDP
Larsen, M.N., 2001. Zimbabwean Cotton Sector Liberalisation: A Case of Successful growth in Zimbabwe. African Affairs 106 (424), 463–478.
Private Coordination? CDR Working Papers 01.1. Centre for Development Robson, C., 2002. Real World Research. Blackwell Publishers, Oxford.
Studies, Copenhagen. Robinson, P., Ndlela, D., 1994. Cotton Industry Study. ZimConsult, Harare.
Larsen, M.N., 2002. Is oligopoly a condition of successful privatization? The case of Sachikonye, L., 2002. Whither Zimbabwe? Crisis & democratisation. Review of
cotton in Zimbabwe. Journal of Agrarian Change 2 (2), 185–205. African Political Economy 91, 13–20.
Larsen, M.N., 2006. Market coordination and social differentiation: a comparison of Sachikonye, L.M., 2003. The Situation of Commercial Farm Workers after Land
cotton-producing households in Tanzania and Zimbabwe. Journal Agrarian Reform in Zimbabwe. Farm Community Trust of Zimbabwe, Harare.
Change 6 (1), 102–131. Scott, J.C., 1990. Domination and the Arts of Resistance: Hidden Transcripts. Yale
Little, P.D., Watts, M.J. (Eds.), 1994. Living Under Contract: Contract Farming and University Press, New Haven, CT.
Agrarian Transformation in Sub-Saharan Africa. University of Wisconsin Press, Scoones, I., Marongwe, N., Mavedzenge, B., Mahenehene, J., Murimbarimba, F.,
Madison. Sukume, M., 2010. Zimbabwe’s Land Reform: Myths & Realities. Weaver Press,
Losch, B., 2002. Global restructuring and liberalisation: cote d ’voire at the end of Harare.
the international cocoa market? Journal of Agrarian Change 2 (2), 206–227. Shepherd, A.W., Farolfi, S., 1999. Export Crop Liberalisation in Africa: A Review.
Makadho, J., 2006. Land redistribution experiences in Zimbabwe 1998–2004. In: Agricultural Services, Bulletin No. 135. FAO, Rome.
Rukuni, M., Tawonezvi, P., Eicher, C., Munyuki-Hungwe, M., Matondi, P. (Eds.), Singh, S., 2002. Multi-national corporations and agricultural development: a study
Zimbabwe’s Agricultural Revolution Revisited. University of Zimbabwe of contract farming in the Indian Punjab. Journal of International Development
Publications, Harare, pp. 165–188. 14 (2), 181–194.
Makamure, J., Jowa, J., Muzura, H., 2001. Liberalisation of Agricultural Markets. Final Skalnes, T., 1995. Politics of Economic Reform in Zimbabwe: Continuity and Change
Report: SAPRI, Harare. in Development. St. Martin’s Press, New York.
Makochekanwa, A., 2007. Zimbabwe’s Black Market for Foreign Exchange: Stringfellow, R., Coulter, J., Lucey, T., Mackone, C., Husain, I., 1997. Improving Access
Department of Economics, University of Pretoria, Working Paper Series: of Smallholders to Agricultural Services in Sub-Saharan Africa: Farmer
2007–13. Cooperation and Role of the Donor Community: Natural Resources Institute,
Mason, J., 2002. Qualitative Researching. SAGE publications, London. No. 20.
Mather, C., 1999. Agro-commodity chains, market power and territory: re- Sugden, F., 2009. Neo-liberalism, markets and class structures on the Nepali
regulating, South African citrus exports in the 1990s. Geoforum 30, 61–70. lowlands: the political economy of agrarian change. Geoforum 40, 634–644.
Mather, C., Greenberg, S., 2003. Market liberalisation in post-apartheid South Africa: The Cotton Company of Zimbabwe (various) Annual Reports. The Cotton Company
the restructuring of citrus exports after ‘deregulation’. Journal of Southern of Zimbabwe, Harare.
African Studies 29 (2), 393–412. The Financial Gazette.
McGregor, J., 2002. The politics of disruption: war veterans and the local state in The Herald.
Zimbabwe. African Affairs 101, 9–34. The Reserve Bank of Zimbabwe, 2007. Monetary Policy Statement. The Reserve Bank
McMichael, P. (Ed.), 1994. The Global Restructuring of Agro-Food Systems. Cornell of Zimbabwe, Harare, 1 October 2007.
University Press, London. The Sunday Mail.
Ministry of Agriculture, 1998. Policy Statement for the 1998/9 Agricultural Tollens, E.F., Gilbert, C.L., 2003. Does market liberalisation jeopardise export
Marketing Year. Ministry of Agriculture, Harare. quality? Cameroonian cocoa, 1988–2000. Journal of African Economies 12 (3),
Ministry of Finance, 2005. Budget Statement. Government Printer, Harare. 303–342.
Minot, N.W., 1986. Contract Farming and its Effect on Small Farmers in Less Townsend, R.F., 1999. Agricultural Incentives in Sub-Saharan Africa: Policy
Developed Countries. Department of Agricultural Economics, Working Paper 31, Challenges. World Bank, Washington, DC.
Michigan State University, Michigan. Tshuma, L., 1997. A Matter of (In)justice: Law, State and the Agrarian Question in
Minot, N., Daniels, L., 2002. Impact of Global Cotton Markets on Rural Poverty in Zimbabwe. Sapes Books, Harare.
Benin. World Bank, Washington, DC. Utete, C.M.B., 2003. Report of the Presidential Land Review Committee, Special
Mlambo, A.S., 1997. The Economic Structural Adjustment Programme: The Case of Studies, vol. 11. Government Printers, Harare.
Zimbabwe, 1990–1995. University of Zimbabwe Publications, Harare. Van Donge, J.K., 2002. Disordering the market: the liberalisation of burley tobacco
Moore, J.L., 2003. Zimbabwe’s Fight to the Finish: The Catalyst of the Free Market. in Malawi in the 1990s. Journal of Southern African Studies 28 (1), 89–115.
Keegan Paul, London. Watts, M.J., 1990. Peasant under contract: agro-food complexes in the third world.
Morrison, P., Murray, W., Dimbag, N., 2006. Promoting indigenous entrepreneurship In: Bernstein, H., Crow, B., Mackintosh, M., Martin, C. (Eds.), The Food Question:
through small-scale contract farming: the poultry sector in Sarawak, Malaysia. Profits Versus People. Earthscan Publications Ltd. London.
Singapore Journal of Tropical Geography 27 (2), 191–206. Watts, M.J., 1994. Life under contract: contract farming, agrarian restructuring, and
Mosley, W.G., 2005. Global cotton and local environmental management: the flexible accumulation. In: Little, P.D., Watts, M.J. (Eds.), Living Under Contract:
political ecology of rich and poor small-holder farmers in southern Mali. The Contract Farming and Agrarian Transformation in Sub-Saharan Africa. The
Geographical Journal 171 (1), 36–55. University of Wisconsin Press, Madison.
Moyo, S., Yeros, P., 2007. The radicalised state: Zimbabwe’s interrupted revolution. Webber, M., Wang, M.Y.L., 2005. Markets in the Chinese countryside: the case of
Review of African Political Economy 111, 103–121. ‘‘rich Wang’s village’’. Geoforum 36, 720–734.
Muir-Leresche, K., Sikume, C., 2006. Agricultural policies in a global environment. Whatmore, S., 2002. From farming to agribusiness: global agri-food networks. In:
In: Rukuni, M., Tawonezvi, P., Eicher, C., Munyuki-Hungwe, M., Matombi, P. Johnston, B.F., Taylor, P.J., Watts, M.J. (Eds.), Geographies of Global Change:
(Eds.), Zimbabwe’s Agricultural Revolution Revisited. University of Zimbabwe Remapping the World. Blackwell Publishers, Malden.
Publications, Harare, pp. 505–523. Willems, W., 2004. Peasant demonstrators, violent invaders: representations of land
Mumvuma, T., Mujajati, C., Mufute, B., 2006. Understanding economic reforms: the in the Zimbabwean press. World Development 32 (10), 1767–1783.
case of Zimbabwe. In: Mensor, J., (Ed.), Understanding Economic Reforms in World Bank, 1981. Accelerated Development in Sub-Saharan Africa: An Agenda for
Africa: A Tale of Seven Nations. Palgrave. Action. World Bank, Washington, DC.
584 G. Masuka / Geoforum 43 (2012) 573–584

World Bank, 1989. Sub-Saharan Africa: From Crisis to Sustainable Growth: A Long- Zumbika, N., 2006. Agricultural finance. In: Rukuni, M., Eicher, C., Tawonezvi, P.,
term Perspective Study. World Bank, Washington, DC. Munyuki-Hungwe, M., Matondi, P. (Eds.), Zimbabwe’s Agricultural Revolution
World Bank, 1994. Adjustment in Africa: Reforms, Results, and the Road Ahead. Revisited. University of Zimbabwe Publications, Harare, pp. 339–354.
Oxford University Press, New York.

You might also like