You are on page 1of 38

DIIS WORKING PAPER

DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

WORKING PAPER

Power and Change:


Locating Institutional Change Theories
in a Power Context
Lily Salloum Lindegaard
DIIS Working Paper 2013:20

1
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

LILY SALLOUM LINDEGAARD


Research Assistant
lili@diis.dk

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
Many thanks to the other members of the CCRI programme for their insights and constructive
comments to the working paper.

Thank you to the members of the Centre for Climate Change Study in Central Vietnam, who
were an invaluable help during the research process. In addition, a special thanks to the officials
of Quang Binh Province and Hue Province for taking the time to participate in the research and
contributing their knowledge and experience.

ABOUT THE CCRI PROGRAMME


“Climate Change and Rural Institutions” (CCRI) is a collaborative research programme which
explores the role of meso-level institutions in climate change adaptation. The programme is coordi-
nated by DIIS in collaboration with partners in Nepal, Uganda, Vietnam and Zambia.

For more information, please see www.diis.dk/ccri.

DIIS Working Papers make available DIIS researchers’


and DIIS project partners’ work in progress towards
proper publishing. They may include important
documentation which is not necessarily published
elsewhere. DIIS Working Papers are published under
the responsibility of the author alone. DIIS Working
Papers should not be quoted without the express
permission of the author

DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20


© The author and DIIS, Copenhagen 2013
Danish Institute for International Studies, DIIS
Østbanegade 117, DK-2100 Copenhagen, Denmark
Ph: +45 32 69 87 87
Fax: +45 32 69 87 00
E-mail: diis@diis.dk
Web: www.diis.dk
Cover Design: Carsten Schiøler
Layout: Ellen-Marie Bentsen
Printed in Denmark by Vesterkopi AS
ISBN: 978-87-7605-635-3 (print)
ISBN: 978-87-7605-636-0 (pdf )
Price: DKK 25.00 (VAT included)
DIIS publications can be downloaded
free of charge from www.diis.dk

2
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

CONTENTS

Abstract4

1 Introduction: The ’Why’ of Institutional Change 5

2 Institutions and Change in Literature 6


2.1 Critical v. Mainstream Institutionalism 6
2.2 The New Institutionalisms 7
2.3 Fundamental Differences in Institutionalisms 9
2.4 Impacts of Innovation 11

3 Conceptualizing Institutions, Change and Power 14


3.1 Conceptualizing Institutions 14
3.2 Conceptualizing Institutional Change 14
3.3 Concepts of Power in the Context of Institutions 17

4 Locating Institutional Change Theories in a Power Context 21


4.1 Path Dependency 21
4.2 Gradual Institutional Change 23
4.3 Institutional Bricolage  24

5 Incorporating Power Concepts into Institutional Change Analyses 26


5.1 Operationalizing a Power-Based Analytical Framework 26
5.2 Applying these Relationships in Analysis 27
5.3 CCRI as a Power Analysis Case 29

6 Institutional and Innovation Theories in Power Analyses 33


6.1 Theories of Institutions and Institutional Change 33
6.2 Innovation Theories 34
6.3 Contributions of a Power Analysis 34

Works Cited 35

3
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

ABSTRACT

This working paper aims to better understand the drivers of institutional change. To do
this, it locates diverse institutional change theories, specifically path dependency, gradu-
al institutional change and institutional bricolage, in a power context and reflects on the
power-related aspects of each theory. It then develops a novel approach of a power analysis
of institutional change, which allows for the combined use of institutional change theories
despite their diverse theoretical underpinnings and thus offers a thorough, highly complex
consideration of institutional change.

4
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

1. INTRODUCTION:THE ‘WHY’ OF the analysis can reflect upon how these theo-
INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE ries can fit together and may be able to supple-
ment each other.
Theories have developed over time to bet- In identifying this shared context, deter-
ter understand how institutions change; they mining a point of comparison and analytical
often provide detailed accounts of the actors, access to institutional change theories was nec-
methods and processes through which change essary. A context with an existing, robust body
occurs. However, due to their focus on ‘how’ of literature and analytical tools was seen as
change occurs, they often omit a thorough preferable in order to better support this analy-
treatment of another question integral to un- sis. These considerations led to the selection of
derstanding institutional change: ‘Why does power as a common analytical context; power
institutional change occur?’ is included in all of these theories as having
Institutional change theories touch on this a role in change. In addition, I would suggest
‘why’ to varying degrees. Mahoney and Thelen that certain aspects of power in institutional
(2010) reflect on several drivers of institutional change, though touched on by some of the
change in their work on gradual institutional theories, are not thoroughly analysed in previ-
change, including those related to resource ac- ous institutional change literature. This choice
cumulation, shifts in the balance of power and thus also offers an opportunity to further de-
issues of compliance; however, their primary velop institutional change literature, which
focus on the ‘how’ of institutional change per- will support later analyses of power in institu-
sists. Other accounts of institutional change, tions and institutional change.
for instance Douglas’ (1986) and Cleaver’s Specifically, this discussion of institutional
(2012) presentations of institutional bricolage, change theory aims to support the theoretical
also consider this question, albeit more implic- underpinnings of the Climate Change and
itly through their discussion of power in insti- Rural Institutions project (for more infor-
tutional change. In still other accounts of insti- mation see www.diis.dk/ccri). Following the
tutional change, these two questions of ‘how’ focus of this project, it will reflect specifically
and ‘why’ become entangled, for example in on how institutional change theories relate to
Mahoney’s (2000) account of critical junctures issues of climate change adaptation (CCA)
in path dependency. and change within meso-level, or mid-level,
In contrast, this paper singles out the ques- government institutions. To embark on this
tion of ‘why.’ It seeks to better understand the analysis, the paper will first offer, in Chap-
drivers of institutional change, thereby sup- ter 2, a brief introduction to selected litera-
plementing existing literature on institutional ture regarding institutions and change. The
change and enhancing the analytical usefulness concepts to be used in the paper will then be
of institutional change theories. It will do this discussed in Chapter 3, which will present
by selecting different theories of institutional conceptualisations of institutions and institu-
change, namely path dependency, gradual in- tional change as well as conceptualisations of
stitutional change and institutional bricolage, power. Chapter 4 will then locate institution-
and considering them in a shared analytical al change theories in a bower context, offering
context. This strategy allows the analysis to ef- a basis for Chapter 5’s discussion of institu-
fectively shift between the various theories and tional and innovation theories in power anal-
creates room for comparison. In addition, by yses. Chapter 6 will ultimately offer conclu-
locating them in a shared conceptual location, sions and reflections.

5
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

2 INSTITUTIONS AND CHANGE ignable, unambiguous nature of institutions in


IN LITERATURE this view, evident in Mainstream Institution-
alism’s identification of certain ‘design prin-
There is extensive literature on both institu- ciples’ for optimal institutional functioning.
tions and change. This chapter seeks to present This is also evident in development coopera-
some of the main concepts from literature on tion. A Danida review of methods for evalu-
these topics to contextualise the paper’s sub- ating capacity development, entitled Between
sequent discussions. Regarding institutions, Naivety and Cynicism, discusses the failures of
it will present the dichotomy between Criti- donors’ Mainstream Institutionalist approach
cal versus Mainstream Institutionalism and to capacity building: “Donors have tried to
subsequently give a brief overview of the three deal with seemingly obvious capacity prob-
New Institutionalisms: Historical, Sociological lems in specific organisations by supporting
and Rational Choice Institutionalism. It will changes in their structures, staff training, the
then discuss and contrast these approaches be- introduction of new procedures, and supply-
fore moving on to a discussion of institutional ing equipment and technical assistance (TA).
change literature, which will include a discus- Often this has not had much impact” (Boesen
sion of innovation literature. and Therkildsen 2004: 1). The authors refer to
these Mainstream Institutionalism-based ap-
2.1 Critical v. Mainstream proaches as ‘mechanical blueprint approaches’
Institutionalism (Boesen and Therkildsen 2004: 1) and point
Cleaver’s (2012) Critical and Mainstream In- out the naivety of simplistic conceptions of
stitutionalisms offer simple, yet conceptually institutions and institutional change. Gen-
useful, accounts of institutions. She presents erally, Mainstream Institutionalism also sees
these two broad schools of institutional thought institutions as regulating behaviour for the
in the context of natural resource management common good through both rules and norms,
in both developing and developed countries, thereby supporting individuals’ strategic deci-
though the two distinct perspectives on insti- sion-making.
tutions are applicable in many other contexts In contrast, Critical Institutionalism offers
as well. They are distinguished by their dichot- a more complex account of the production
omy between rational, functional and design- and function of institutions. It emphasises
able institutions and more organic or ‘messy’ “the complexity of institutions entwined in
institutions, informed by social, cultural and everyday social life, their historical transfor-
historical contexts. mation and the interplay between the tradi-
The first of these (rational, functional and tional and the modern, formal and informal
designable institutions) is represented by arrangements” (Cleaver 2012: 8-9). This view
Mainstream Institutionalism. Cleaver asserts incorporates an awareness of the intricacies of
that Mainstream Institutionalism “is privi- social arrangements and identities as well as
leged in policy, partly because it offers a bridge unequal power relations. Its complexities often
between neo-liberal economic ideas and the deter policymakers as they offer no clear pre-
desirability of decentralised local management scriptions and, because of the consideration of
and ‘ownership’” (Cleaver 2012: 8). Looking social arrangements and power relations, could
outside of natural resource management as easily become politicised (Cleaver 2012).
well, a preference for Mainstream Institution- In comparing the two, Cleaver notes that
alism by policymakers is likely given the des- Critical Institutionalist approaches differ from

6
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

those of Mainstream Institutionalism because 1996: 6). Within this, historical Institution-
“their starting point is often a broad focus on alists often focus on formal aspects of institu-
the interactions between the natural and social tions as well as the asymmetric power relations
worlds rather than a narrower concern with they propagate. This has led them to an im-
predicting and improving the outcomes of par- plicit focus on power as well as an account of
ticular institutional processes” (Cleaver 2012: institutions as ‘path dependent,’ or prone to
13). This is one of several fundamental differ- continue in an established trajectory. Change
ences between Critical Institutionalism and occurs sporadically when these trajectories are
Mainstream Institutionalism and is extremely punctuated by points of sudden, substantial
relevant in relation to applying these concepts change leading to a new trajectory, referred to
in situations of climate change. Due to the un- as ‘critical junctures’ (Hall and Taylor 1996).
certainties and ambiguities of climate change Criticisms of Historical Institutionalism focus
contexts, as well as their intrinsic blending of on its tendency to view institutions in an
the natural, social, political, etc., Critical Insti- overly ‘sticky,’ deterministic manner, there-
tutionalism approaches are likely to be much by downplaying the role of actors and agency
more analytically capable and successful. (Bell 2011).
Many of these differences are also evident Sociological Institutionalism considers in-
between the three New Institutionalisms, fur- stitutions in the context of more informal, cul-
ther discussed below. tural practices. It argues that culture, not just
efficiency, shapes institutions and considers in-
2.2 The New Institutionalisms stitutional forms and practices in light of “the
Historical Institutionalism, Sociological Insti- symbol systems, cognitive scripts, and moral
tutionalism and Rational Choice Institution- templates that provide the ‘frames of meaning’
alism are collectively referred to as the ‘New guiding human action” (Hall and Taylor 1996:
Institutionalisms’ and have been highly in- 14). This provides a broader account of insti-
fluential in institutional discourse for the last tutions than that of a political science perspec-
several decades (Hall and Taylor 1996). These tive. It also presents an interesting account of
New Institutionalisms are characterised by an the way institutions shape individual action by
“emphasis on legitimacy, the embeddedness of ascribing institutions not only the power to set
organizational fields, and the centrality of classi- rules, but also the power to define what peo-
fication, routines, scripts, and schema” (Green- ple perceive as possible within a given context
wood and Hinings 1996: 1023) and are there- (Hall and Taylor 1996). This contributes to a
by distinguished from the old institutionalism’s very stable account of institutions, which has
consideration of influence, coalitions and com- led to a critique of Sociological Institutional-
petition of values and power (Greenwood and ism as lacking an explanation of endogenous
Hinings 1996). Below are brief accounts of the change (Mahoney and Thelen 2010).
three New Institutionalisms, which describe Rational Choice Institutionalism grew out
their main characteristics and critiques and of political science and considers institutions
their treatment of institutional change. as “coordinating mechanisms that sustain par-
Historical institutionalists largely define ticular equilibria” (Hall and Taylor 1996, Ma-
institutions as “the formal or informal proce- honey and Thelen 2010: 6). It proceeds from
dures, routines, norms and conventions em- an economic consideration of organisational
bedded in the organizational structure of the dynamics, considering things like rent-seeking
polity or political economy” (Hall and Taylor and transaction costs in institutional genesis

7
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

and reproduction. Rational Choice Institu- centives are aligned with social objectives,
tionalism emphasises actors’ rational, strategic monetary and fiscal policies are grounded
behaviour to fulfil their preferences and thus in solid macroeconomic institutions, idi-
explains the creation of certain institutional osyncratic risks are appropriately mediat-
structures in terms of their benefit to pertinent ed through social insurance, and citizens
actors (Hall and Taylor 1996). When explain- have recourse to civil liberties and political
ing institutional change, however, Rational representation. Poor countries are those
Choice Institutionalism struggles due to its where these arrangements are absent or ill-
fundamental understanding of institutions as formed. (Rodrik 2004: 1)
sustaining an equilibrium. Therefore, it gener-
ally relies on exogenous bases for change (Ma- Clearly, institutions and the conceptualisations
honey and Thelen 2010). of institutions are highly influential. Within
Rational Choice Institutionalism is ex- international development generally, institu-
tremely influential in current international de- tions have come into the spotlight and have
velopment practice; many of the same reasons been tasked with supporting and enabling de-
for which policymakers prefer mainstream in- velopment; within the growing movement to
stitutionalism, particularly the rational, strate- address climate change, institutional develop-
gic nature of institutions, also make a Rational ment has the possibility of becoming just as
Choice Institutionalist approach desirable as it influential. The subsequent focus on getting
presents institutions as simple to understand institutions right, however, is not enough. It
and adjust. As Rational Choice Institutional- fails to take into account the complexity of in-
ism has gained ground, it has brought with it stitutional intervention and institutions’ role
complementary approaches, notably that of in societies. Because of the power and cultur-
New Institutional Economics, which incorpo- al aspects of institutions revealed in the other
rates institutions into agency-based theories of institutionalisms, intervening in institutional
markets. Instead of decisions being solely de- arrangements is much more challenging than
termined by actors’ rationality, under New In- Mainstream Institutionalist and Rational
stitutional Economics they are also affected by Choice Institutionalist perspectives acknowl-
the underlying institutional context (Hubbard edge. These perspectives also fail to consider
1997). Within development, this influence has the intricate, interconnected relationship of
led to a focus on establishing institutions con- institutions and society, which renders institu-
ducive to desired development outcomes, or as tional engineering difficult at best. However,
it has come to be called, ‘getting institutions these perspectives continue to be common,
right’ (Rodrik 2004). Dani Rodrik’s work has especially among policymakers. It is therefore
been foundational in this line of thought, and necessary to get conceptualisations of institu-
he notes: tions right. Without a thorough understand-
ing of institutions conceptually and the mean-
There is now widespread agreement among ing of these conceptions in practice, coherent,
economists studying economic growth institutionally-based development will inevita-
that institutional quality holds the key to bly be ‘absent or ill-formed.’
prevailing patterns of prosperity around The presentation of these selected concepts
the world. Rich countries are those where is thus of utmost importance for such devel-
investors feel secure about their property opment strategies. While the institutionalisms
rights, the rule of law prevails, private in- above represent only a few main concepts

8
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

within a diverse, extensive body of institution- 1996: 15). Critical Institutionalism, on the
al literature,1 they offer an introductory point other hand, presents a more integrated account
to understanding the meaning and dynamics of the relation between actors and institutional
of this literature. The next section will more structures.
deeply explore the differences between these These accounts offer a clear indication that
institutionalisms to better grasp the implica- considering structure and agency should not
tions of their conceptual distinctions. be an ‘either/or’ situation. Instead, all of these
institutionalisms fall on a continuum between
2.3 Fundamental Differences in structure and agency, perhaps emphasising one
Institutionalisms over the other, but clearly informed by both.
There are three fundamental differences be- Indeed, this view is supported by sociologist
tween the institutionalisms that inform most Norman Long, who contends that, “the con-
of the variances in their accounts of institu- stitution of social structures, which have both
tions. These are the role of structure and agen- a constraining and enabling effect on social
cy, the consideration of formal and informal behaviour, cannot be comprehended without
institutions and the role of power. These three allowing for human agency” (Long and Long
aspects are discussed in turn below. 1992: 24). This paper thus rejects an opposi-
tion between agency and structure, but sees
2.3.1 Structure and Agency them as mutually informing; as Cleaver notes,
The debate regarding the role of structure and “neither the exercise of agency nor societal
agency has permeated social science and is a structures determine outcomes – they are rath-
key factor shaping the divergences in under- er shaped in the interaction between the two”
standings of institutions. Is it the structures (Cleaver 2012: 122; original emphasis). This
of the institutions themselves or the agency of becomes significant in subsequent discussions
the actors within the institutions that deter- of power and institutional change; integrat-
mine their functions and development? Each ing structure and agency shapes understand-
of the Institutionalisms above offers a slightly ings of both sources of power and the manner
different answer. Rational Choice Institution- in which power drives institutional change,
alism, for instance, places a greater emphasis which are further discussed in Chapter 4.
on actors’ choices, with institutional structures
offering a context of rules and regulation that 2.3.2 Formal and Informal Institutions
frames actors’ strategic options. Conversely, in Another key difference is the treatment of in-
Sociological Institutionalism, “institutions do formal and formal institutions in institutional
not simply affect the strategic calculations of schools of thought. Generally, Rational Choice
individuals…but also their most basic pref- Institutionalism and Mainstream Institution-
erences and very identity” (Hall and Taylor alism tend to focus on formal institutions,2
which is especially clear in Mainstream Insti-
tutionalism’s conception of designable insti-

1 For instance, within natural resource management alone, a


single, influential institutional debate is that of negotiated ac-
cess, which is very much about power, agency and institutions 2 Though there are, of course, exceptions. For instance
(e.g. Sarah Berry, Sally Falk Moore, Jesse Ribot, Pauline Peters, Elinor Ostrom’s work represents an example of a New In-
Christian Lund, etc.). Other fields have similarly specialised stitutional Economics mode of thought can also accommo-
institutional discourses. date informal institutions.

9
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

tutions (Cleaver 2012). In contrast, the other acknowledgement of power correlates here
institutionalisms include more of a focus on with the focus on informal institutions, while
informal institutions, with Sociological and Mainstream Institutionalism’s technocratic
Critical Institutionalism most strongly focus- focus on formal institutions precludes an en-
ing on informal institutions (Hall and Taylor gagement with implicit power dynamics. This
1996). These differences also have important is in line with certain development literature
implications. By including or disregarding in- that suggests de-politicisation (and concurrent
formal institutions, the meaning and role of discounting of power) is an inherent goal and
formal institutions also change. For instance, result of technocratic approaches (Ferguson
by disregarding the role of informal norms in 1994, Li 2007). This paper would point out,
preventing littering, one attributes a height- however, that there is no correlation between
ened role and meaning to the formal fines es- an awareness of power and a focus on agen-
tablished to deter littering. In addition, certain cy, which may seem likely given agency’s focus
sources of, impacts on and strategies of power on strategic action. Thus, Mainstream Insti-
are also either included or disregarded. For ex- tutionalism intentionally overlooks the subtle
ample, if the role of informal social networks pervasiveness of power in social processes and
in a disaster-affected community are disregard- norms, considering instead the formal and ex-
ed, formal humanitarian agencies and institu- plicit, while Critical Institutionalism’s dynam-
tions are accorded both much more power and ic, ‘messy’ approach to institutions fosters an
responsibility, which leads to a myriad of sub- awareness of and engagement with these subtle
sequent consequences. If social networks do aspects of power.
play a role in disaster relief, for instance, this Differing views on power are also evident
disregard could lead to inefficient relief efforts in the New Institutionalisms, though not with
and tragic outcomes. the same clarity as in the dichotomy between
Critical and Mainstream Institutionalism. Sim-
2.3.3 Role of Power ilarly to Mainstream Institutionalism, Rational
Probably the most important difference in the Choice Institutionalism’s emphasis on formal
institutionalisms in the context of this paper institutions and individual agency largely steer
is their differing conceptualizations and rec- it away from acknowledging wider dynamics
ognition of the role of power. The various in- of power. However, it leaves some space for
stitutionalisms diverge sharply on this point. dynamics of power in institutions’ impact on
Power drives the dichotomy between Critical actors’ preferences. Conversely, historical insti-
Institutionalism and Mainstream Institution- tutionalists engage more explicitly with power
alism, being explicitly acknowledged by Criti- dynamics. Hall and Taylor (1996) write that a
cal Institutionalism and largely overlooked by “notable feature of historical institutionalism is
Mainstream Institutionalism. This is illustrated the prominent role that power and asymmet-
in Cleaver’s description of the factors shaping rical relations of power play in such analyses”
human behaviour in the two, with those for (Hall and Taylor 1996: 9). Social institution-
Critical Institutionalism consisting of “social alism also considers power, though implicit-
structures and power dynamics, relationships, ly through its considerations of, for instance,
norms, [and] individual creativity,” while those cultural authority. These diverging views on
for Mainstream Institutionalism consist of “in- power should be kept in mind as factors that
formation, incentives, rules, sanctions and re- inform differences in theories of institutional
peated interactions” (Cleaver 2012: 16). The change.

10
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

2.4 Impacts of Innovation practices were praised as innovators and early


Another influential discourse to be acknowl- adopters, while those who did not were cast as
edged in discussions of change is that of inno- laggards inevitably doomed to leave farming.
vation. While there is not yet an established This application of Roger’s concept of innova-
body of scholarly literature on climate change tion diffusion has been criticised as misleading
innovation, innovation has long been present and detrimental (Röling 2006) as it disregards
in development discourses, for instance those structural limitations and other considerations
surrounding agricultural practices. As climate that may affect or predetermine a farmer’s de-
change affects some of the same develop- cision. An example of such limitations can be
ment-oriented institutions as those involved in seen in Cleaver’s description of irrigation prac-
agriculture, looking at innovation discourses tices in Tanzania, particularly in relation to a
in agricultural development can offer insights certain water user association. This association
into the impact of these discourses in a climate was dominated by locally powerful individu-
change setting. als who monopolised decision-making power
Innovation literature has historically been regarding the irrigation scheme for the area’s
dominated by three interlocking narratives: irrigation farmers. Less powerful women and
that of the diffusion of innovations, the agri- smallholders felt that they could not affect
cultural treadmill and the transfer of technolo- change and innovation in their own irrigation
gy (also called the linear model). Though these scheme, hindered by social dynamics of power
theories have their origins in economics and which were formalised in the water user associ-
agricultural development, they have become ation (Cleaver 2012). In addition, the diffusion
highly influential in extremely diverse share of of innovation concept problematically assumes
industries, fields and schools of thought. The that the proposed innovation is advantageous
‘diffusion of innovations’ propagated by Ever- for and should be adopted by all. Some farm-
ett Rogers (1962) considers groups of farmers ers, however, might intentionally choose to
according to how quickly they adopt an inno- forgo an innovation because it is irrelevant for
vation. In Rogers’ account, the distribution of their needs. These farmers may opt for other,
these groups followed a bell curve, with very possibly also innovative, methods or technol-
few being innovators, slightly more being early ogies, but may still be deemed ‘laggards’ be-
adopters, roughly a third being the early ma- cause of their reticence in adopting the accept-
jority, another third being the late majority ed or ‘conventional’ innovation. Ironically, this
and the remainder being laggards. Since its could easily undermine the emergence of new
development, this concept of the spread of in- innovations and ultimately also hinders a thor-
novation has become widely accepted and ap- ough understanding of the conditions which
plied in everything from advertising to health foster innovations and change.
care (Horsky and Simon 1983, Khoumbati Another influential aspect of the diffusion
et al. 2006). It represents a classic example of of innovations concept is the agricultural tread-
rational choice assumptions, with its focus on mill put forward by Cochrane (1958). This
actors’ strategic decision-making to maximise adds to the diffusion of innovation concept
their benefits. and describes a situation where some farmers
Within agricultural development, this con- adopt an innovation which provides them with
cept of the diffusion of innovations has been windfall profits. Slowly, more and more farm-
extremely prominent. Those who quickly ers adopt this innovation until it is only the
adopted new agricultural technologies and sick, elderly and inept who have not adopted

11
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

it. These groups, now using outdated produc- will diffuse or not. These failures in the mod-
tion methods, cannot compete and drop out els’ performance are further worsened by the
of the market. Their resources, e.g. land, are damaging effects they can have when actually
absorbed by the remaining farmers, leading to successful (see Röling 2006 and FAO 2005).
‘scale enlargement’ (Cochrane 1958). In this These innovation concepts have other pos-
concept the diffusion of innovation is driven sible pitfalls that should be noted. One of these
by market forces. is an underlying idea of innovative change as
The third of these interlocking narratives ‘discontinuous processes’ (Anderson 2008:
is the transfer of technology model, or linear 55), or cut off from existing power dynamics
model. It is based on a simplistic, linear in- and institutional processes. This conception
novation pipeline that progresses from funda- of innovation effectively renders causal study
mental research, through applied and adaptive of institutional change processes useless as the
research, subject matter specialists, extension notion of discontinuity removes any possibili-
and contract farmers, ultimately ending with ty of identifying connections or relationships
‘follower farmers’ (Röling 2006). This model between innovations and wider institutional
considers science and research as the sources of processes. It is thus not useful for this analysis
innovation, extension as the delivery mecha- and in general offers a limiting perspective. An-
nism and end users as the recipients of external other possible pitfall is the sharp, unflattering
innovation. In this way, it and its predecessors contrast that is often drawn between innova-
promulgate closed innovations, characterized tion and previous practices. Anderson (2008)
by control of the development of innovations. notes a “…tendency to portray the historical
Röling describes how these three concepts heritage, including know-how, values, norms,
of innovations and their diffusion came to- and principles, as some sort of straight-jacket
gether to dominate international agricultural or networks as lock-in mechanisms that have
development practices: to be overcome. Launching a new course or pi-
oneering is portrayed to be an urgent necessity
Diffusion of innovations was a research for a vigorous economy and a modern public
tradition based on empirical studies that sector” (Andersen 2008: 55). Innovation be-
looked at what had happened in the past. comes equated with future growth and success
But the macro benefits of the treadmill, through highly normative suppositions, and
as perceived by economists, transformed becomes a goal in itself. Kimberly and Evan-
the research tradition into a policy model isko (1981) acknowledge this long-standing
for what is desirable in future. This model trend, describing the attitude as: “Innovation
emphasises technology transfer (technology is good and more innovation is better” (Kim-
supply push) and free markets as recipes for berly and Evanisko 1981: 710). In a study of
agricultural development. (Röling 2006: organizational innovation of hospitals, they
4; original emphasis) also find that it is not clear that the quality
of innovation is considered when an innova-
These interlocked concepts of innovation and tion is adopted. Innovations can thus become
diffusion have been propagated by the Wash- an untried silver bullet, a tendency of which
ington consensus and adhered to by the WTO. analyses should be wary. In climate change re-
This is despite repeated failures of the model in alities, adaptation innovations offer precarious
agricultural development and the impossibility choices as they present a risk which must be
of predicting whether a technology innovation weighed against the alternative risks of failing

12
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

to adapt. For a rural farmer with no other live- Egelyng 2007). Rather than focusing on pro-
lihood strategies or safety nets, an unsuccessful ducing technological innovations, or doing dif-
innovation can be disastrous. ferent things, the objective thus becomes doing
Despite these pitfalls, such innovation lit- things differently, or supporting change in inno-
erature still flourishes in many fields, and as vation systems (PHILA 2005). In addition, in
climate change literature begins to emerge, an innovation systems approach, innovation is
the imprint of innovation is already evident. an interactive process involving many different
In the 2010 World Development Report, for actors and sources of knowledge (Friis-Hansen
instance, an entire chapter is devoted to ‘Accel- and Egelyng 2007).
erating Innovation and Technology Diffusion’ Another focus of new innovation concepts
(World Bank 2010: 287) in the face of climate is learning. Douthwaite’s (2002) “learning
change. With phrases such as, “breakthrough selection” model, for instance, also suggests
innovations,” “energy revolution” and “cli- a complex, multi-agent system, but focuses
mate-smart alternatives” (World Bank 2010: specifically on multi-actor learning and inno-
287), it reflects the overly-simplistic approach- vation selection. Another learning-focused in-
es evident in Boesen and Therkildsen’s (2004) novation concept is that put forth by Pretty (in
naivety concept and characteristic of policy- Uphoff 2002), which looks at the social pro-
makers’ preference for rapid, straightforward cesses supporting sustainable innovation. Pret-
results. It is only after this heady optimism that ty presents sustainable agriculture as a learning
the report goes on to note that “reaping the process, not a technology package or specific
benefits of technological changes will require model.
significant changes in human and organisa- These newer innovation concepts thus in-
tional behavior, as well as a host of innovative corporate diverse actors and sources of knowl-
supporting policies to reduce human vulner- edge and focus more on the endogenous occur-
ability and manage natural resources” (World rence of innovation than exogenous production
Bank 2010: 288). The report itself thus illus- and diffusion. They consequently diverge from
trates divides within institutional thinking, the closed innovation tendencies of the earlier
with more simplistic mainstream perspectives innovation concepts, instead illustrating open
uneasily coexisting with critical perspectives of innovation, where internal and external influ-
more complex realities. This is especially prob- ences are combined in developing innovations.
lematic in relation to climate change, where The divide between these two generations of
simplistic, linear innovation assumptions are innovation and diffusion concepts also reflects
foundationally incompatible with the variabil- some of the same divides as those of institu-
ity and uncertainty that characterizes changing tional theory. The older generation reflects the
climates. economic, technocratic simplicity of Main-
While the diffusion of innovation concepts stream and Rational Choice Institutionalism,
clearly remain influential, their weaknesses where models and straightforward policy pre-
have led to the dominance of other concepts scriptions dominate. In contrast, the newer
of innovation since the 1990s. Instead of fo- generation presents a more complex account of
cusing on linear pipelines, one new perspective the inputs to and processes of innovation and
instead emphasizes innovation systems, or the diffusion more in line with the foundational
“wide range of different actors and organiza- perceptions of Critical Institutionalism.
tions…required to stimulate widespread local Concepts of innovations and institutions
technological development” (Friis-Hansen and are thus closely linked in both theory and prac-

13
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

tice. In practice particularly, they become fur- The definition used for the purposes of
ther integrated as they are implemented jointly this paper, according to the discussions of the
through development projects and programs, previous chapter, must then take into account
a reality also evident in CCA, for instance in power, agency, structure and both formal and
the 2010 World Development Report. Due informal institutions. At the same time, it
to innovation’s inherent focus on change, the must be narrow enough to remain analytically
impacts and pitfalls of concepts of innovation useful. The following definition balances these
and diffusion also become tied to concepts of needs:
institutional change. As the different innova-
tion concepts have varying implications re- The formal and informal norms, rules and
garding the role of power in change, the paper organizations which structure a society
will return to them later in Chapter 5’s incor- and which are established, reproduced and
porations of power. altered through contestation and reasser-
tion by societal structures and actors.

3 CONCEPTUALIZING This definition offers an excellent starting


INSTITUTIONS, CHANGE AND point, providing space for both institutional
POWER establishment and change as well as influence
from structures and actors. It paints a diverse
This chapter presents the main concepts of in- picture of the many different aspects of institu-
stitutions and institutional change to be dis- tions that will be important for this analysis. It
cussed in the paper. It then discusses the role should, however, be noted that no single sen-
of power in these concepts generally to prepare tence can adequately describe the diversity of
for the more detailed integration of power into institutional realities. For instance, while the
institutional change theories in the following definition divides out formal and informal,
chapter. such a clear divide does not always exist. The
purview of informal and formal can overlap
3.1 Conceptualizing Institutions and their relationship with each other often
Developing coherent concepts of institutions changes over time. In this sense, the definition
and institutional change is essential. Concep- should be considered as a starting point to in-
tions of institutions, for instance, determine form the discussions below.
both the properties of institutions as well as
possibilities for institutional change. As Ma- 3.2 Conceptualizing Institutional
honey and Thelen (2010: 4) note, a “focus on Change
persistence of institutions makes it natural for The following sub-section presents the con-
approaches to explain continuity rather than cepts of institutional change to be presented
change”. They go on to say: “If institutions in the paper, namely path dependency, gradual
are changed not just in response to exogenous institutional change and institutional brico-
shocks or shifts, then their basic properties lage.
must be defined in ways that provide some dy-
namic element that permits such change” (Ma- 3.2.1 Path Dependency
honey and Thelen 2010: 7). Path dependency, rather than describing how
institutions change, focuses on why they re-
main the same. In a path-dependent perspec-

14
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

tive, institutions are seen as ‘sticky,’ or difficult argument that past events influence future
to change, which leads them to continue in a events” (2000: 510). In contrast to this, Ma-
set path or trajectory. When changes do occur, honey focuses on certain defining features of
they are attributed to critical junctures where path dependency, for instance how a sequence
major shocks disrupt the status quo, causing of path-dependent events are started and the
a new trajectory to be established. In path de- methods by which they are reproduced. This
pendency, institutional change is thus a polar- represents a more strict conception of path
ized pattern of continuity punctuated by dras- dependency, where particular characteristics
tic change. must be present for a trajectory to be consid-
Theories of path dependency focus on ered path-dependent. It is important to dis-
continuity in a certain trajectory, and a cor- tinguish between these two accounts as their
responding body of literature within path differences have analytical ramifications; this
dependency has developed to explain this paper will adhere to the first, more general
tendency. There are several different causes conception of path dependency.
to which a path dependency can be attrib-
uted. Campbell (2010) provides an overview 3.2.2 Gradual Institutional Change
of the causes as explained in different disci- In contrast to path dependency, others attrib-
plines. Four reasons from a political science ute institutional change to more continuous,
perspective include: (1) political institutions subtle processes. Lund (2006) and Moore
have large start-up costs; (2) politicians de- (1978), for example, identify institutional
liberately make institutions they establish change as stemming from processes of ‘regular-
difficult to change; (3) actors accumulate ization’ and ‘situational adjustment.’ Regular-
knowledge of a set of institutional processes ization allows for processes and organisations
and are reluctant to change to an unknown to become durable parts of social reality, while
system; and (4) the beneficiaries of an existing situational adjustment occurs when actors cre-
institutional arrangement support its contin- ate or resolve ambiguous situations by “reinter-
uation. Other causes include those put forth preting or redefining rules and relationships”
by sociologists, that the institutionalization (Lund 2006: 699).
of certain perspectives and practices limits Others consider these continuous changes
what decision-makers consider as possible in other ways. Mahoney and Thelen (2010)
or appropriate, and by comparative political consider gradual transformation the result of
economists, that the interlocked nature of in- the constant negotiations of power and rules.
stitutions makes it difficult to change a single Negotiations of power are characterised by a
institution (Campbell 2010). These aspects of dichotomy of dominance and pragmatism
institutions and institutional actors contrib- as institutional actors assert their interests in
ute to the ‘sticky’ nature of institutions. order to gain dominance, but must often com-
There are both more rigid and more relaxed promise in a pragmatic manner. These negoti-
accounts of path dependency. Sehring (2009), ations and subsequent changes are grounded
for instance, offers a relaxed view of path de- in their conception of institutions as “distribu-
pendency, stating that it should not be seen as tional instruments laden with power implica-
historical determinism, but instead represents tions” (Mahoney and Thelen 2010: 8; original
the reproduction of successful strategies. Ma- emphasis). They are characterised by an inter-
honey (2000) describes this view as “a broad play between actors and structure and formal
conceptualization that essentially entails the and informal, as actors attempt to impact the

15
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

institutional structures through both formal Does the institution in question afford actors
and informal means. opportunities for exercising discretion in in-
Mahoney and Thelen (2010) delineate terpretation or enforcement?” (Mahoney and
four specific types of change and four specif- Thelen 2010: 18). The resulting breakdown in-
ic change agents, who drive change. The types dicates the importance of the political context
of change are displacement, layering, drift and institutional characteristics in determining
and conversion. Displacement occurs when both the kind of change and change agent:
existing rules and norms are removed and re-

Seeks to Preserve Institution Follows Rules of Institution


Insurrectionaries No No
Symbionts Yes No
Subversives No Yes
Opportunists Yes/No Yes/No
Source: Mahoney and Thelen 2010

placed. Layering is when new rules and norms The dynamics posed by these various types
are established on top of or beside existing of change and change agents will be further ad-
ones. Drift occurs when institutions do not dressed in a power context later in the paper.
change formally, but their relevance and im-
pact change due to changes in their context. 3.2.3 Institutional Bricolage
Conversion also occurs when institutions do In contrast, institutional bricolage focuses more
not change formally, but change takes place as on the pragmatic ways actors address everyday
actors redeploy or reinterpret them to have a challenges by combining available institutional
new purpose, meaning, etc. practices, ideas and norms. Institutional brico-
The four types of actors, or change agents, lage merges aspects of path dependency and
are then determined according to whether they innovation in settings of everyday institutional
seek to preserve the institution and whether struggles and considers the dynamic interplay
they follow the institution’s rules: between actors and social structures (Cleaver
Mahoney and Thelen then categorize these 2012).
four types of change and four change agents Bricolage draws on the idea of a bricoleur
according to two main questions: “(1) Does who “uses everything there is to make transfor-
the political context afford defenders of the mations within a stock repertoire of furnish-
status quo strong or weak veto possibilities? (2) ings” (Douglas 1986: 66). This idea was intro-
Characteristics of Targeted Institution

Low level of discretion in High level of discretion in


interpretation/ enforcement interpretation/ enforcement

Strong veto Subversives Parasitic Symbionts


possibilities (Layering) (Drift)
Characteristics of the
Political Context
Weak veto Insurrectionaries Opportunists
possibilities (Displacement) (Conversion)
Source: Mahoney and Thelen 2010

16
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

duced by Lévi-Strauss (1966) and elaborated phasis), while discussions of authority, agency
on by Mary Douglas (1986); Douglas suggests and structure implicitly touch on the role of
that within institutions, patterns of precedence power. Institutional reproduction and change
offer an ever-present stock of materials which especially occur within a landscape of power,
can be combined, adapted and adopted by in- as described by Campbell (2010):
stitutional actors to ‘make transformations.’
These transformations are then justified by and … the notion of struggle, conflict, and ne-
accepted through the authority of the previous gotiation over institutions … reveals how
practices (Douglas 1986). Frances Cleaver, institutional reproduction and change are
among others, has further developed the con- flip sides of the same coin. That is, insti-
cept of institutional bricolage. Cleaver applies tutions are contested. So, depending on
it specifically to understanding how mech- the balance of power among those con-
anisms of natural resource management are testing them, they may change or not. In
fashioned from existing social formulae, for in- this sense the processes of institutional re-
stance particular styles of thinking or accepted production and change are mutually con-
social norms. Within this, Cleaver emphasizes stitutive–many of the forces that change
the tendency to reproduce inequalities in ac- institutions also stabilize them. (Campbell
cess to resources as entrenched social patterns 2010:108)
are readopted in new manners and situations
(Cleaver 2012). Power is thus integral in institutional change
Overall, institutional bricolage offers an and can reveal the nuanced dynamics and
insight into the often chaotic nature of insti- drives behind it; analyzing the role of the
tutional formation and change. It allows for power and forces which Campbell mentions
an understanding of institutions as “neither can address the ‘why’ of institutional change
completely new nor completely traditional but and explain what drives ‘struggle, conflict and
rather a dynamic hybrid containing elements negotiation over institutions.’
of ‘modern’, ‘traditional’ and the ‘formal’ and To do this, the concepts of power to be used
‘informal’” (Cleaver 2012: 45). In addition, it must be clarified. In identifying which con-
provides a coherent account of the interplay cepts of power would be most useful, it was
between structure and agency as actors initiate clear that they must be able to grasp and ex-
change according to the structural limitations plain the various dynamics within institutions,
of the materials at hand. This ‘dynamic hybrid’ including the role of actors, structure, formal
perspective on institutional change is both use- and informal practices, and social norms and
ful in practical analyses and in understanding ideas, among other things. This suggests the
power in institutional change. necessity of a broad, complex understanding
of power and led to the consideration of Fou-
3.3 Concepts of Power in the Context cault’s account of power:
of Institutions
As evident in the discussions above, there is … power must be understood in the first
an extensive role for power in concepts of in- instance as the multiplicity of force rela-
stitutions and institutional change. Mahoney tions immanent in the sphere in which
and Thelen (2010) explicitly define institu- they operate and which constitute their
tions as “distributional instruments laden with own organization; as the process which,
power implications” (2010: 8, original em- through ceaseless struggles and confronta-

17
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

tions, transforms, strengthens, or reverses and room for manoeuvre and subsequently
them; as the support which these force re- establish power. In this way, it will accom-
lations find in one another, thus forming modate actor-oriented accounts of power in
a chain or a system, or on the contrary, institutional change.
the disjunctions and contradictions which ‘Government’ then refers to systematized,
isolate them from one another; and last- regulated and reasoned forms of power. This
ly, as the strategies in which they take ef- is derived from the ideas behind Foucault’s
fect, whose general design or institutional own concept of ‘governmentality,’ which refers
crystallization is embodied in the state ap- to the ‘conduct of conduct’ (Lemke 2010), or
paratus, in the formulation of the law, in the systematic ways in which people and soci-
the various social hegemonies. (Foucault eties are governed. Foucault’s governmentality
1990: 92-93) originated in his study of the conduct of the
European state in the Middle Ages and offers
This conception of power reflects the struggle, helpful insights into the systematic nature of
conflict and negotiations considered by Camp- power in governance. A generalizable excerpt
bell (2010) and importantly also links easily of Foucault’s definition of governmentality de-
up to an institutional setting by considering scribes it as the “ensemble formed by institu-
the ‘chain or system’ and ‘institutional crystal- tions, procedures, analyses and reflections, the
lization’ of power. At the same time, Foucault’s calculations and tactics that allow for the exer-
conception of power leaves room for individu- cise of this very specific albeit complex form of
al agency and contestation and also takes into power” (Foucault 1991: 102). A notable aspect
account the social aspects of power, character- of governmentality, evident in this quote, is its
istics necessary to adequately engage with the rational, reasoned nature; “analyses and reflec-
theories of institutional change. tions, the calculations and tactics” contribute
Below, four specific types of power based on to a coherent, strategic character of this form
Foucault’s work on power are presented specif- of power. Contrary to the actor-based strategy
ically: strategic games, governmentality, domi- of strategic games, however, governmentality
nation and power-knowledge. retains a wider focus on the mechanisms of the
state in governing its territory and population;
3.3.1 Strategic Games, Government and Foucault (1991) states that governmentality is
Domination exerted to ‘reinforce, strengthen and protect’
From Foucault’s works on power, Thomas a government’s relations with its territory and
Lemke has derived three more specific forms subjects. In a study of climate change and me-
of power: strategic games, government and so-level institutions, governmentality can offer
domination (Lemke 2010). ‘Strategic games’ interesting insights into various institutions’
offers a concept of power ideally fitted to con- struggles and adaptive mechanisms to ‘rein-
siderations of strategic action. Lemke notes force, strengthen and protect’ their role within
that strategic games entail actors “structuring a dynamic and uncertain environmental and
the possible field of action of others” (2010: social situation.
53) and can include everything from ration- In addition, a broad understanding of gov-
al argumentation to economic exploitation. ernmentality offers an important analytical
In discussions of institutional change, it will tool for understanding informal conduct. This
thus be used in understanding how actors’ di- is essential for exploring issues of social norms
verse, strategic actions affect others’ options and social contracts, for example, or the infor-

18
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

mal systems according to which societies are lation without the correlative constitution of
governed. Applying governmentality to these a field of knowledge, nor any knowledge that
informal systems will be particularly useful in does not presuppose and constitute at the same
accounting for the power dynamics inherent time power relations” (Foucault 1995: 27).
in both Social and Critical Institutionalisms. Power-knowledge opens up an important dis-
In addition, this aspect of governmentality cussion of the force and implications behind
links up to discourses and perceptions of pow- the knowledge of different actors and institu-
er-knowledge, which are also significant in so- tions, for example the ways in which knowl-
cial rules and norms, further discussed below. edge is used in claims to dominance, authority,
Governmentality shows itself to be extremely resources, etc. In climate change particularly,
accommodating as it also evokes many of the it presents an interesting dynamic within the
rational, regulated aspects of Rational Choice state of uncertainty, or knowledge scarcity,
Institutionalism and Mainstream Institution- characterizing climate changes. This paves
alism. Its explicit focus on power, however, the way for power manipulations, necessarily
offers an important counterpoint to Rational based on ambiguous assertions within condi-
Choice Institutionalism and Mainstream In- tions of uncertainty.
stitutionalism’s whitewashed perspectives of Regarding climate adaptation specifically,
power. power-knowledge is evident in multiple ways.
Lemke also includes ‘domination’ in his ty- In both developing and developed countries,
pologies of power to describe a “type of power for instance, claims of knowledge and exper-
relationship that is both stable and hierarchi- tise drive competition over funds newly allo-
cal, fixed and difficult to reverse” (2010: 53). cated to climate change adaptation and miti-
While domination describes a certain situation gation. Various ministries at the national level
of power, Lemke is careful to note that it does and other government institutions between
not explain the establishment of that situa- scales use these claims to establish authority
tion. Instead, “[t]echnologies of government and secure these financial resources, which can
account for the systematization, stabilization ultimately also confer dominance and power.
and regulation of power relationships that may While this illustrates the more formal power
lead to a state of domination” (Lemke 2010: claims based in knowledge, power-knowledge
53). It is thus the procedures and tactics of also allows for the analysis of less formalized
governmentality, if coherently established and knowledge. The power within perceptions and
entrenched, that contribute to a state of domi- discourses, for instance, can be highly signif-
nation where those dominated have very limit- icant in the workings of a society, including
ed room for manoeuvre. in the role of institutions. Foucault notes that
“[d]iscursive practices are not purely and sim-
3.3.2 Power-knowledge ply ways of producing discourse. They are em-
A final, essential concept of power to be used bodied in technical processes, in institutions,
in this paper is that of power-knowledge. Pow- in patterns for general behavior, in forms for
er-knowledge is based on the idea that power transmission and diffusion, and in pedagogi-
and knowledge mutually inform and consti- cal forms which, at once, impose and maintain
tute each other. Foucault asserts: “[w]e should them” (Foucault 1977: 200).
admit rather that power produces knowl- The exertion of this more subtle pow-
edge…that power and knowledge directly er-knowledge can been seen in the green
imply one another; that there is no power re- growth discourse, which has reshaped the cli-

19
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

mate discourse in a way that benefits corpo- and also the reproduction and changes of this
rate actors. A discourse initially based on the power. Importantly, when supplemented by
problematics of industrialization and growth an agency-oriented approach, it can also offer
now offers growth as a solution, and those space for interplay between institutional struc-
who may once have been perceived as part of tures and actors.
the problem can now become champions of a Together, the concepts of power-knowl-
climate change response. This powerfully re- edge and governmentality offer important
shapes the landscape of possible ‘winners’ and analytical opportunities. Power-knowledge
‘losers’ and ‘right’ and ‘wrong.’ It illustrates allows for the identification and analysis of
how deeply discourse and the power-knowl- claims to knowledge, expertise and authority
edge behind it can shape societal perceptions as dynamics of power, which will be useful in
and norms, irrevocably shaping society itself. analysing such claims by both institutions and
Knowledge aspects of power can thus be quite institutional actors at the meso level. In ad-
influential and are important in considera- dition, power-knowledge also recognises the
tions of the struggles informing institutional analytical importance of norms, perceptions
change. and discourses, which are formative aspects of
societies and institutions and will be essential
3.3.3 Meaning for Analysis to understanding institutional change. This
What Foucault describes as reinforcing and is supplemented by governmentality, which
strengthening an institution’s role closely mir- opens for engagement with systematic exer-
rors processes of institutional reproduction and cise of power through institutions’ procedures
change. The calculation and tactics Foucault and strategies. Governmentality also provides
describes are reflected in the constant politi- an understanding of institutional reproduc-
cal mobilization Mahoney and Thelen (2010) tion and change in a power perspective, in-
note in institutional continuity. In Mahoney cluding for the informal institutions which
and Thelen’s account, institutional actors con- regulate conduct, for instance norms and so-
stantly engage in “ongoing mobilization of po- cial contracts.
litical support as well as, often, active efforts to Through the calculations and tactics of
resolve institutional ambiguities in their favor” governmentality as well as the production
(Mahoney and Thelen 2010: 9). While Fou- or perpetuation of knowledge, institutions
cault’s account considers these strategies from a establish, claim and challenge territorial and
structural, institutional perspective, introduc- conceptual space (and thus power); pow-
ing an agency-based perspective such as that of er-knowledge and governmentality also cre-
Mahoney and Thelen offers space for produc- ate the analytical space necessary for engaging
tive interplay between agency and structure. with both structures and actors and informal
In addition, the same aspects of governmen- and formal aspects of institutions.
tality that reflect processes of continuity also
inform institutional change; as Campbell as- 3.3.4 Critique of Foucault
serts, “institutional reproduction and change The concepts of power offered by Foucault
are flip sides of the same coin…many of the provide notable analytical strengths; however,
forces that change institutions also stabilize they also come with possible weaknesses. One
them” (Campbell 2010: 108). Foucault’s gov- of these is the ubiquitous nature of power in
ernmentality is thus both helpful in describing Foucault’s account, a point which has drawn
the exertion of systematic, institutional power heavy criticism. Some critiques argue that this

20
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

ubiquity divests the concept of power of its 4.1 Path Dependency


meaning and analytical usefulness as, in the Even in Foucault’s most general concepts of
end, everything is power (Sayer 2012). For power, the tendencies found in path depend-
this analysis, however, the ubiquity becomes ency are evident. Foucault notes, “power must
a boon as it aids in locating diverse theories be understood as…the support which these
of institutional change within power. In ad- force relations find in one another, thus form-
dition, by focusing on specific concepts of ing a chain or a system” (Foucault 1990: 92;
power-knowledge and governmentality, the emphasis added). This system, or path depend-
paper seeks to offer more of a focus within ency, is supported by multiple factors, for in-
Foucault’s broad concept of power. stance those put forward by Campbell (2010).
Another criticism of power in Foucault’s Each of these factors represents a force in itself,
account is its lack of agency. This is partly constantly pushing for the continuation and
a symptom of the focus of his study, which reproduction of the existing institutional ar-
looks invariably at the systematic nature of rangement. When a confluence of these factors
power, the institutions which exert power and or forces arises, institutional arrangements be-
the manner in which power comes to govern come extremely secure and difficult to change.
the individual. For Foucault, the individual This shares multiple parallels with governmen-
then becomes the subject of power, rather tality, the “ensemble formed by institutions,
than a source of power or contestation (Lemke procedures, analyses and reflections…” (Fou-
2010). One social scientist notes, “a com- cault 1991: 102). Within path dependency,
pletely passive subject renders the very notion this ensemble of forces for stability additional-
of control meaningless” (Gordon 2002: 126). ly creates a more entrenched power, or a situa-
As stated in the discussion of governmentali- tion of domination. The continued exercise of
ty, however, this issue is addressed by supple- the strategies of governmentality allow for the
menting Foucault’s perception of power with reproduction of this domination.
a more actor-oriented perspective. His focus
on ‘struggles and confrontations’ creates room 4.1.1 Types of Change within Path Dependency
for the integration of individual agency, which Because of the situation of domination, one
simply adds a new dynamic to these strug- type of change permeates literature on path
gles and confrontations without disregarding dependency: critical junctures. As accounts of
the underlying systematic focus. path dependency do not consider significant
endogenous change a viable option, the only
possible recourse for change becomes exter-
4 LOCATING INSTITUTIONAL nal and necessarily extreme critical junctures,
CHANGE THEORIES IN A POWER which overcome the domination of a path
CONTEXT dependency (Campbell 2010). The ‘why’ of
change in this account is thus that external forc-
Having explored the conceptualisations of in- es overcome the domination, disabling some
stitutions, institutional change and power, this or all of the mechanisms of governmentality
chapter will combine these concepts by locat- which support it. Indeed, this contestation and
ing institutional change theories in a power interruption of a power trajectory is noted in
context, first considering path dependency, Foucault’s description of “the disjunctions and
then gradual institutional change and finally contradictions which isolate them [force rela-
institutional bricolage. tions] from one another” (Foucault 1990: 92).

21
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

By isolating the forces of stability from one isting institutional arrangements. Implicit in
another, foundational change is made possible. this is that not all actors benefit from existing
The less stringent conception of path de- arrangements and that without beneficiaries’
pendency, while acknowledging such founda- ‘strategic games,’ existing arrangements would
tional change in response to domination, also change. In other words, those at the institu-
allows space for incremental change (Sehring tional margins, the ‘losers’ of existing institu-
2009). Campbell describes this process of in- tional arrangements, contest these arrange-
cremental change, pointing out that, “change ments, bringing about incremental change.
typically occurs only at the margins, which in In addition, context also contributes to in-
turn means that institutions tend to change cremental change. For instance, in Sehring’s
only in incremental or evolutionary ways” (2009) concept of path dependency where
(Campbell 2010: 91). Campbell even equates actors duplicate successful strategies, chang-
this type of change with path dependency, de- ing contexts lead dominant actors, the ‘win-
scribing it as “more incremental or evolution- ners’ of institutional arrangements, to adjust
ary (i.e. path-dependent) change” (Campbell their strategies to optimize their benefits and
2010: 91). retain power. Within climate change specifical-
ly, this is evidenced in an example given pre-
4.1.2 The Role of Agency and Context in Path- viously, where national institutions compete
dependent Change for control over new climate change financing.
Explaining the ‘why’ of this incremental change Other examples include institutional compe-
is more complex, but points to two significant tition due to changes in resource access, e.g.,
aspects, agency and context. These two aspects water, arable land or grazing land, caused by
come to light due to the structural limitations climate change. Notably, such strategic games
of path dependency itself; when an existing or- and competition are often exercised through
ganizational structure becomes path-depend- power-knowledge, where institutions justify
ent, change must come from other sources, domination through claims to knowledge and
hence a focus on agency and context. expertise, for instance expertise in managing a
Returning to Foucault’s definition of power resource or administering funding or through
with agency in mind, we find that power in- discourses justifying their right to control the
cludes, “the process which, through ceaseless resource. This illustrates that, while institu-
struggles and confrontations, transforms, tions may be ‘sticky’ and difficult to change,
strengthens, or reverses” (Foucault 1990: 92) they operate within dynamic social and polit-
force relations. The inclusion of ‘struggles and ical settings, which actors necessarily respond
contestations’ offers extensive space for the role to in order to either maintain or contest power.
of agency in power, which is also quite clearly In a structural perspective as well, changes in
reflected in Lemke’s (2010) ‘strategic games.’ an institution’s context may render specific as-
These agency-based power concepts offer a pects of an institution’s structure redundant,
valuable starting point for understanding in- ineffective or obsolete, possibly also prompting
cremental change; they provide room for un- incremental change.
derstanding the strategies that contribute to
domination as well as to contestation by mar- 4.1.3 Returning to Concepts of Power
ginal actors. Contestation is the inherent flip These discussions reveal the dynamic, com-
side of the understanding of path dependen- plex landscape of power present within path
cy as enforced by actors benefitting from ex- dependency. What also becomes evident is the

22
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

ability of power concepts to encompass and ex- mentality.3 Governmentality can thus be seen
plain such complex dynamics of change, abil- as the institutionalization of strategic games,
ities which path dependency lacks. Campbell where the strategies of the most successful ac-
notes, “we need a more nuanced approach to tors are established and reproduced to govern
explain institutional change than those found the possibilities for others.
typically in arguments about path depend-
ence” (Campbell 2010: 91). 4.2 Gradual Institutional Change
This issue is evidenced in path dependency’s Complex power dynamics in institutional
simplistic dichotomy of incremental, endoge- change become more evident in certain ac-
nous change and extreme, exogenous change. counts of Gradual Institutional Change. In
Here, path dependency may gloss over the Mahoney and Thelen’s perspective of gradual
interrelated nature of these factors and over- institutional change particularly, institutions
look the drivers behind endogenous and exog- “not only emerge and break down; they also
enous incremental changes. This paper would evolve and shift in more subtle ways across
instead suggest highly complex processes of time” (Mahoney and Thelen 2010: 2). This
change, where endogenous and exogenous in- perspective is “grounded in a power-distri-
fluences and structures and actors all interact butional view of institutions that emphasizes
to shape change, both incremental and ex- ongoing struggles within but also over prevail-
treme. A power perspective including the roles ing institutional arrangements” (Mahoney and
of agency and context can help provide this Thelen 2010: xi). The book title itself Explain-
complexity. For instance, take the case above ing Institutional Change: Ambiguity, Agency and
where changes in an institution’s context cause Power also emphasizes this focus on power and
shifts in dominant actors’ strategies. Thinking contestation. Power is thus an essential ele-
in terms of Foucault’s power concept, this may ment in their conception of why institutions
open up new space for contestations by actors change. This section will explore this element
on the margins, possibly contributing to the of power more deeply, specifically how it re-
more significant change of a critical juncture. lates to the concepts of power discussed above.
By bringing to light the struggles and contesta-
tions informing change, it becomes clear that 4.2.1 Mahoney and Thelen’s Account of
the lines of causation blur and multiple factors Change
from various sources can ultimately be linked Mahoney and Thelen’s account of institutional
to change. change goes beyond the simplicity and lock-in
These reflections on complexity are also of path dependency. With their assertion that
useful in considering the concepts of power “there is nothing automatic, self-perpetuating,
themselves. They offer an important reminder or self-reinforcing about institutional arrange-
that domination conceals contestation, which ments” (Mahoney and Thelen 2010: 8), they
is an important point of analysis for change. offer a fundamental contradiction to the per-
In addition, they suggest a more complex per-
spective of governmentality, where instead
of a single ruler establishing an ensemble of
rules and strategies, many actors converge to 3 Importantly, this detracts from the rational nature of a
determine the procedures and rules of govern- governmentality. Assuming the rational choice of the in-
dividual actors, they will act in their best interests, likely
undermining a cohesive, rational trajectory within the gov-
ernmentality.

23
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

petuation inherent in path dependency. Specif- es, powerfully affecting its role in practice. Fi-
ically, they focus on the endogenous dynamics nally, drift, rather than reflecting a major shift
of institutional change and ground their expla- in power, illustrates instead a situation where
nations of change in the distributional nature the meaning of an institution changes due to a
of institutions and the idea of actors’ compli- shift in context.
ance to institutional norms and rules as a varia- Power can also be seen in other aspects
ble (Mahoney and Thelen 2010). This creates a of Mahoney and Thelen’s (2010) gradual in-
situation where actors, through strategic games stitutional change. The ‘change agents,’ for
and power-knowledge plays, struggle to secure instance, all exercise power through strategic
optimal benefits by affecting institutional rules, games, where they attempt to limit the pos-
procedures and outcomes. According to Ma- sibilities for other agents and optimize their
honey and Thelen, this actor-oriented account benefits through governmentality and pow-
of change takes place in the space created by in- er-knowledge. Domination, however, is not as
stitutions’ structural weaknesses, the ‘soft spots’ evident as in path dependency; Mahoney and
between rules and their interpretation and en- Thelen’s dynamic conception of institutions
forcement (Mahoney and Thelen 2010). makes the establishment of dominance more
difficult and thus less frequent.4
4.2.2 The role for power
While Mahoney and Thelen (2010) present a 4.3 Institutional Bricolage
highly complex account of change, the ‘why’ of Institutional bricolage offers a less structured
change is, quite simply, struggles over resource perspective of institutional change with its
distribution. Returning to where this change concept of ad hoc processes of change enact-
takes place, the ‘soft spots’ of the interpreta- ed in response to everyday challenges. Here,
tion and the enforcement of the rules, relevant structures and actors interact more fluidly as
parallels can be drawn with power-knowledge actors adopt and adjust institutional struc-
and governmentality. Change occurring due tures to address new challenges and situations.
to change in the interpretation of the rules can Within this, power plays an essential role as
be tied to power-knowledge, where a changing “[b]ricolage is an authoritative process, shaped
interpretation or understanding of the rules by relations of power” (Cleaver 2012: 49). In
can bring about substantive changes in their fact, these relations of power permeate process-
application and use. Change surrounding the es of bricolage and determine their outcomes,
enforcement of the rules is then linked to gov- offering key roles for different modes of power,
ernmentality, where the procedures and appli- discussed below.
cations through which the institution adminis-
ters the rules change. 4.3.1 Power and the Bricoleur
Power-knowledge and governmentality are Bricolage offers a unique role for institutional
also helpful in the consideration of what type actors, who can become institutional brico-
of change occurs and why. Some of these types leurs, (re)forming and affecting institutional
of change include important roles for power.
Displacement and layering are clear examples
of governmentality, where rules and their en-
forcement change. Conversion presents an 4 For an example of dominance in Mahoney and Thelen’s
(2010) conception of gradual institutional change, see Dan
explicit role for power-knowledge, where the Slater’s account of authoritarianism in Indonesia (Chapter
interpreted meaning of an institution chang- 5, same volume).

24
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

structures. The strategic games of these ac- Importantly, actors’ strategic games are
tors thus become extremely important as they restricted by structural limitations. Cleaver
play a formative role in determining bricolage states explicitly that “exercising agency and
outcomes. However, these strategic games are deploying resources is not simply a matter of
themselves shaped by power. More than the individual choices or preferences. For exam-
other theories of institutional change, insti- ple, wider relations of power and authority are
tutional bricolage emphasizes the power dis- implicated in the exercise of agency” (Cleaver
parities of the institutional actors who shape 2012: 41). Such limitations include those of
institutional change. Cleaver points out that norms and power discussed above. These in-
“[i]ndividual bricoleurs are able to exercise formal conceptions of social order and rules
different levels of influence over the formation shape people’s perception of possible action,
and functioning of institutions, as a result of consequently structuring the perceived field of
their social positions. Authority, reputation, action for possible bricoleurs (Cleaver 2012,
status and assets (or a lack of them) all matter Giddens 1984). In addition, the bricoleur is
when it comes to making and breaking institu- also limited by both the informal and formal
tional rules” (Cleaver 2012: 45). The resulting materials at hand. As the role of the bricoleur is
dynamics are similar to that of gradual institu- to recombine institutional procedures, practic-
tional change, where actors struggle to estab- es and arrangements, the choices of the brico-
lish institutions that suit their needs best. leur are necessarily limited by which of these is
Cleaver’s bricolage takes one step back, available (Cleaver 2012). Structure thus comes
however, and looks at the foundational power to play an important and unique role in brico-
aspects that inform this struggle. Among them, lage, which must not be overlooked in a focus
both formal and informal expressions of pow- on bricoleurs’ strategic games.
er-knowledge and governmentality are influen-
tial. Power-knowledge is especially evident in 4.3.2 Power-knowledge in bricolage
the informal aspects of power on which brico- Beyond the more self-evident role of govern-
leurs draw. Authority and status, for instance, mentality in the procedures, practices and
are based on social norms, which as discussed arrangements in institutional bricolage, pow-
above are products of power-knowledge. They er-knowledge also plays a key role. Specifically,
are built on societal discourses, in this case the it shapes the materials at hand and the out-
cognitive perception or knowledge of what comes of bricolage. Cleaver (2012) illustrates
constitutes authority and the implications of this in a discussion of development policy for-
this authority. Governmentality then plays a mulation, and the insights from this discussion
role as these perceptions, widely adopted and can shed light on the role of knowledge in in-
adhered to, translate into rules and proce- stitutional change more broadly.
dures which informally govern a society. These Power-knowledge is essential in determin-
modes of power subsequently shape the abil- ing the materials at hand for the bricoleur. As
ity of the bricoleur to successfully engage in the procedures, practices and arrangements
strategic games with other actors. “Negotiation of institutions are permeated by particular
and contestation, involving competing claims knowledge and norms, recombining practic-
to tradition or modernity, or particular sources es from institutions sharing the same basic
of authority, is therefore an inevitable part of norms reinforces the power and prevalence of
bricolage” (Cleaver 2012: 49). these norms. This leads to the domination of a
certain kind of institutional ‘material,’ which

25
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

because of its ubiquity is more likely to be re- cymakers’ preference for (and perpetuation of )
produced. Cleaver notes that “the ways that natural-science based ideas of resilience versus
understandings of the world are cognitively more critical social science perspectives which
institutionalized often means that policy re- include issues of power, inequality and vulner-
produces dominant views and power relations” ability. This differentiation of knowledge be-
(Cleaver 2012: 151). tween types of actors is also addressed by Nor-
Furthermore, Cleaver suggests that domi- man Long, who asserts that, “discursive means
nant views, once established, are exceedingly or types of discourse…vary and are not simply
difficult to shift. In a policy-related case, she inherent features of the actors themselves: they
notes that certain dominant views were “em- form part of the differentiated stock of knowl-
bedded in institutionalized power relations edge and resources available to actors of differ-
permeating the state from national to local ent types” (Long and Long 1992: 24). This re-
levels” (Cleaver 2012:151). Foucault similarly production of certain types of knowledge and
reflects on the embedded nature of discourse, the goals and perspectives implicit in them is
saying “[d]iscursive practices are not purely a notable sub-trend of dominating societal dis-
and simply ways of producing discourse. They courses.
are embodied in technical processes, in insti-
tutions, in patterns for general behavior, in
forms for transmission and diffusion, and in 5 INCORPORATING POWER
pedagogical forms which, at once, impose and CONCEPTS INTO INSTITUTIONAL
maintain them” (1977: 200). This suggests a CHANGE ANALYSES
broader reproduction of dominant discourses
beyond merely in state institutions, pointing As the chapters above indicate, there is a clear
to such reproduction as a far-reaching social and formative role of power in institutional
occurrence affecting diverse institutional ar- change which has important implications for
rangements and everyday realities. Thus, not change outcomes, analyses of institutional
only does power-knowledge determine the change and institutional interventions. Fou-
materials at hand, it subsequently predisposes cault himself applied the concepts of power
bricolage outcomes. used above to understand the very real and
Such predisposition can also be found in a tangible impacts of discourse, governance,
more diverse and fragmented manner. Various knowledge and authority on people’s lives.
kinds of institutions and the actors associated To support further exploration of the impacts
with them prioritize different types of knowl- they have in regards to institutions, this chap-
edge depending on their goals and values. Thus, ter presents methods of operationalizing a
on a smaller scale, certain discourses become power analysis.
dominant in certain institutions, and may be
highly incompatible with those of other types 5.1 Operationalizing a Power-Based
of institutions, even within the same society. Analytical Framework
Cleaver (2012) gives the example of how ac- To operationalize a power-based analytical
ademic institutions prefer and prioritize criti- framework, it must first be determined what
cal knowledge, while political institutions put such a framework would include. Relation-
more weight on technical knowledge that is ships of power are of course essential, so strate-
seen as helpful in formulating policy solutions. gic games, governmentality and power-knowl-
In adaptation contexts, this is evident in poli- edge must be included, along with dynamics of

26
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

domination to which they can contribute. In tween change elements, context and internal
addition, formal and informal structures and institutional dynamics offer an important
relations are critical elements, along with both foundation for further analyses and discus-
institutional structures and actors. Changes in sions.
any one of these key elements informing insti-
tutional formation and change – which I will 5.2 Applying these Relationships in
simply refer to as ‘change elements’ – can affect Analysis
the others as well as the institution undergo- While the section above illustrates the key
ing change. Shifts in the underlying context relationships and elements that a power-based
must also be acknowledged and considered, analysis should take into account, applying
especially in a climate context, where climate these offers a further challenge. Such an anal-
changes can have a significant effect on any ysis follows no singular institutional change
and all of the aspects informing institutional theory, and because of the complexity and

Figure 1: Factors Informing Institutional Change

Internal
dynamics which
influence change

‘Change elements’
which inform
institutional
The context of an Institution formation and
institution informs undergoing change – they
institutional influence each other
formation and change and are impacted by
change as well as the surrounding
the ‘change context as well
elements’
CONTEXT

change. Ultimately, dynamics within the insti- interconnected nature of the change elements
tution undergoing change must be recognized, presented above, identifying the influences
as they determine how external changes are ex- and relations that ultimately contribute to a
perienced and internalized by the institution. change can be challenging. However, a struc-
An overview of these aspects is included in the tured strategy for identifying and analysing
figure below. change, informed by the theoretical discus-
While this diagram is clearly a simplified sions of earlier chapters and supplemented by
account of the elements within institutional insightful questions and a thorough approach
change, the complex relations it portrays be- offer a strong foundation for such an analysis.

27
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

An example of what such a strategy could look specific role in the change; the first will
like and the questions which would direct it likely provide insights into the second.
are explored below. 4. Analyse the power elements involved in
establishing the change and how they are
These steps include the following actions and deployed (by whom and through which
considerations: channels). Use the types of power dis-
cussed earlier as well as examples from the
1. Identify a singular institutional change of different institutional change theories of
interest within the event study, and the key how power can drive institutional change.
actors and institutions which play a role in Also consider insights from or parallels
the change. with innovation theories. Keep in mind
2. Consider the political, social and eco- contextual power elements, e.g. societal

Figure 2: Power Analysis Structure

nomic context surrounding the event and norms, and also power elements within
the change. Try to understand the wider the institution undergoing change which
dynamics in which the change occurs might play a role. Figure 1’s depiction of
and how the key actors and institutions various change elements can be used as a
fit into these dynamics. What is going on tool to consider different combinations of
politically, socially and economically? How these elements which might be at play, e.g.
might that affect the change and impact ‘domination (through) formal structures’
the interests and roles of the key actors and or ‘strategic games (through) informal
institutions? (relations between) actors’.
3. In light of the contextual background, 5. Draw conclusions on the role of power in
determine the interests and roles of key ac- institutional change. What kinds of power
tors and institutions. This should be both a were exercised by whom to establish the
wider exercise in determining their role in change? How does this link up to wider
political/social/economic dynamics and a contextual dynamics and roles?
more focused exercise in determining their

28
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

Taken together, these steps provide the foun- aspects of what may be larger processes
dational structure for a power analysis. To fur- of change. Establishing a limited focus is
ther explore how they would be approached in key as the elements involved in a change
practice, the following section will apply them can be many and the processes complex;
to the work of the CCRI project specifically. having too broad a focus can undermine
the feasibility of the analysis. In Vietnam,
5.3 CCRI as a Power Analysis Case for example, CCRI fieldwork has indicated
To further explore how to apply this approach, that there has been an increased prioriti-
the work of the CCRI programme will be used zation and perceived importance of flood
as an example. Specifically, the findings from and storm control by the civil service and
Vietnam will be used, but aspects relevant to the Communist Party at multiple levels as
the program more broadly will also be dis- well as corresponding changes in structures
cussed. The case will be examined step-by-step, and procedures. While this fits well with
according to the structure presented above, CCRI’s focus on meso-level institutional
and will consider the increasing involvement change regarding climate change, these
of Vietnam’s Communist Party in flood and broad changes are not a feasible focus of
storm control issues. First, however, a brief study, and a more limited case must be
background to the situation, specifically the identified within it.
role of the Communist Party, is provided. One thing that seemed especially inter-
In Vietnam Communist Party structures esting during the fieldwork conducted in
run parallel to many other organizational July and August of 2013 was the increased
structures, including the civil service. While role of the Communist Party in the civil
it is safe to assume that the vast majority of service’s responsibilities for flood and
civil service members are also Communist storm control preparedness and response,
Party members, it is important to make a clear as presented in the box below.
distinction between the two. The civil service, This is both a feasible and also interest-
while influenced by Communist Party values ing case to look at in regards to both power
and ideologies, retains a focus on fulfilling and institutional change. While further
everyday governmental duties. The Commu- fieldwork and in-depth analysis of this
nist Party then offers a parallel structure aimed specific case has not yet been conducted,
at furthering a certain political ideology and a brief initial power analysis is presented
securing the Communist state and therefore here.
does not necessarily represent or serve the pub- Having identified the key change, the
lic interest. In practice, the Communist Party main actors and institutions involved must
can also be extremely influential for everyday also be identified. From three different
governance decisions, and on the individual cases of Communist Party involvement,
level as well, the Communist Party can make the key players seem to include meso-level
or break careers and determine access to future civil servants involved in flood and storm
opportunities within a wide range of fields and control and Communist Party officials,
industries. With that background in mind, the and the key institutions seem to be pro-
specific case will now be discussed step-by-step. vincial and district level flood and storm
control committees and Communist Party
1. Identifying a change to study is largely leadership.
about focusing in on the most relevant

29
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

Cases of Increasing Communist Party Involvement

Thai Binh Province Director of Radio and Broadcasting


In June 2013, the Director of TV and radio broadcasting of Thai Binh Province failed to en-
sure proper broadcasting of flood and storm warnings. The broadcasting organisation is obli-
gated to broadcast important messages regarding storms and floods, but when a storm came,
only 2 of the 8 warnings that should have been broadcast were sent out. Because of this lapse,
the Provincial Chair suspended the Director for 15 days to investigate his responsibility in the
matter. Because he is also a member of the Communist Party, the Party inspection committee
met and attempted to determine if he was responsible or if there were technical problems
which hindered broadcasting. The Director claims that there were technical problems with
his telephone which prevented him from communicating regarding the warnings, so he re-
tained his position and was not punished. A key informant, however, notes that though he is
still allowed to work, he will likely face difficulties in the future, for instance lower pay and
slow advancement.

Hue Province, Quang Dien District Chair


In this case, the Communist Party in Quang Dien district involved itself in Flood and Storm
Control Committee leadership. Interviewees suggested that due to observation of and previ-
ous experience in other districts, Party leadership decided that it would be more effective to
have the District Chair as head of the Flood and Storm Control Committee instead of the
Vice Chair. It is thought that due to his higher position, he may be better able to coordinate
and lead the district departments in Flood and Storm Control. (This was decided by the Dis-
trict Standing Committee of the Communist Party, which is the small, powerful group which
manages the daily work of the Party between the meetings every 3 months.) As this has to be
approved by the District Chair himself, it is not decided by the Party autonomously, though
the Party can be seen to have notable influence in the matter.

Communist Party Official Checks Preparedness in Hai Phong


In Hai Phong, as a flood/storm was coming, the Provincial Secretary of the Communist Party
decided to check flood and storm preparedness. He went out and performed random checks
within the province. When he was returning, the ferry was closed as per regulations due to
the coming storm. To check the response of ferry personnel, he offered them a bribe to let
him take the ferry (without revealing his identity), and they accepted it. He crossed the river
and called the Director of Transportation and Communications to make him aware of the
lapse. However, the Director was not available as his phone was out of battery. As a result, he
was fired. The Vice Director was also fired and the Vice Deputy Director’s salary was docked
and he was demoted.

30
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

2. The political, social and economic con- affected by pressure to secure rural liveli-
text must then be considered. While the hoods and growth and stand in a particu-
dynamics of these cannot be presented larly precarious position between economic
here fully, it was evident that in relation security, increasing climate unpredictability
to flood and storm control issues, many and fulfilling their responsibilities. Many
things are coming into play. Vietnam is officials interviewed have noted that they
moving further into middle income status, have increased their own emphasis on cli-
and there is pressure from the population mate issues and time spent on attempting
to continue the trend of high levels of to solve these issues, which corresponds to
economic growth. Socially, demographics the increased national emphasis on flood
are shifting as many desire higher incomes and storm control.
and leave rural areas of Vietnam to travel However, Communist Party officials
to cities and other countries to find other who have stepped into flood and storm
work. In rural areas, the populations are control issues have done so due to per-
experiencing decreasing economic security ceived weaknesses of civil service actors
due to climate changes and unpredictabil- and structures in fulfilling flood and storm
ity. Politically, the government (the civil control duties. The Communist Party,
service, though with influences from the as the single and controlling party in
Communist Party) feels the pressure for Vietnam, has a clear interest in securing
growth and in rural areas specifically, to economic stability and growth as well as
secure rural livelihoods. Taken together, securing popular opinion, and flood and
these wider issues are also impacted by storm control issues often provide particu-
the government’s perceived and accepted larly publicized and widespread impacts
responsibility to provide economic growth and threats. By increasingly emphasizing
and stability. Most obviously, economic flood and storm control, the Communist
and political ramifications and concerns in Party fulfils expectations of its responsi-
connection to flood and storms were grow- bilities as the ruling party. In this change,
ing increasingly acute in the case study the Communist Party is assuming a role
areas and there has been a broadly-ob- of greater oversight and authority over
served increase in prioritization of and civil servants in flood and storm control
funding for flood and storm control over situations and, more broadly, attempt-
roughly the last 15 years, from national ing to address issues that could threaten
to household levels. Overall, this com- the Party’s legitimacy and social contract
plex context creates sharp trade-offs, most with the people. Interestingly, however,
particularly between addressing underlying Communist Party action has been limited
factors of climate risk and securing eco- to issues of flood and storm control and
nomic growth, which affect the Party and response, and has not included disaster risk
meso-level governments’ decision-making. reduction. This may be due to the highly
3. To establish the roles of the key actors, in publicized nature of flood and storm con-
this case Communist Party officials and trol, but also to the complex trade-offs and
government officials involved in flood and subsequent conflicts presented in disaster
storm control, the dynamics above provide risk reduction, for instance in relation to
a starting place. The government officials livelihoods, socio-economic security and
in charge of flood and storm control are future growth.

31
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

4. Using Figure 1 as a starting point, it seems of the Communist Party are endowing
that this change involves dynamics of both flood and storm control with a growing
governmentality and domination. The political significance, which, when con-
governmentality occurs in the first example sidered in terms of the contextual ele-
through formal procedures, while in the ments addressed in step 2, may relate to
last two, it is conducted through informal the increasing threat climate events pose
procedures. It is these last two instances to the Party’s interest in a content popu-
especially which thus indicate an institu- lation experiencing growth and security.
tional change as new roles and responsi- The Party’s increasing management of
bilities are being adopted. It is also these flood and storm control issues could thus
two examples which indicate a growing be interpreted as a bid to preserve polit-
situation of domination; while the Com- ical resources of legitimacy and a strong
munist Party is clearly dominant in Viet- social contract.
nam, these instances reveal its increasing 5. When taken together, the considerations
assumption of power in flood and storm of the fourth step indicate a growing
control through governmentality. As these governmentality by the Communist Party
actions go uncontested by civil servants, in flood and storm control issues. It is
they quickly solidify a new institutional conducted by layering new procedures
arrangement of dominance by the Com- over existing flood and storm control
munist Party regarding flood and storm procedures and establishes a new authority
control. and domination of the Party over existing
When considering these changes in structures and procedures; it also creates
light of the discussions of institutional a new, informal institutional structure of
change and innovation theories, they seem domination. In a resource distributional
to link up most closely to governmentality perspective, this can be seen as a bid to
within gradual institutional change. The secure the Party’s political resources of
increasing authority of the Communist legitimacy, authority and social contract
Party in the enforcement of flood and with the people.
storm control ‘rules’ corresponds to the
change in enforcement of rules which While this example is brief and straightfor-
Mahoney and Thelen (2010) discuss. ward, it offers insights into key aspects of such
Specifically, this change can be identified an analysis, specifically regarding understand-
as layering, where new rules and norms ing the institutional landscape, considering
are established on top of or beside existing context and incorporating local insights and
ones. In this case, the Communist Party’s perspectives. Regarding the first of these, many
involvement is layered over the existing in- diverse actors are often involved in a single in-
stitutional arrangements, in a way creating stance of change, though this example offered
a new, informal institutional structure of only a simplistic presentation of what would
domination, with the Communist Party likely be a much more lengthy and complex
acting as a powerful ‘watch dog’. process of analysis involving many actors and
Mahoney and Thelen (2010) also focus institutions. Such a situation of complexity is
on the distributional aspects of institu- made evident in Cleaver’s (2012) consideration
tions, which could offer an interesting of a case of irrigation management in Tanzania;
perspective in this example. The actions Cleaver notes at least 22 various types of insti-

32
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

tutions involved in irrigation and pastoralism 6 INSTITUTIONAL AND


in the case study area – not including individ- INNOVATION THEORIES IN
ual water users or highly informal institutions POWER ANALYSES
such as norms or discourses. Such plurality is
important to keep in mind to avoid overly sim- This chapter will offer final reflections on insti-
plistic and inaccurate analyses. tutional change and innovation theories as well
The example also indicates the importance as what a power analysis can contribute. It will
of considering the wider context; the Commu- first discuss conclusions and reflections of the-
nist Party’s actions link up to broader political, ories of institutions and institutional change,
social and economic shifts, and understanding before considering innovation theories and ul-
the impacts and pressures these create is essen- timately offering final conclusions.
tial for a complete understanding of the institu-
tional change at hand. Ultimately, an informed 6.1 Theories of Institutions and
perspective also requires the input of local per- Institutional Change
spectives in the analysis. In the CCRI project, The discussions above indicate the significant
this is incorporated through country teams, role for power in Path Dependency, Gradual
including local researchers and PhD students Institutional Change and Institutional Brico-
who are able to offer invaluable insights and lage. In addition, they point to the importance
inputs into understanding the nuances of each of an inclusive account of institutional change
country context. – there is no single method or mode of insti-
Likely the most effective approach to un- tutional change; it is instead a complex, mul-
derstanding these multifaceted institutional ti-faceted process, with many possible inputs
changes is through thorough qualitative field- and outcomes.
work; this is especially relevant for grasping These findings offer critical insights into
the nuanced relationships between different the usefulness of the main schools of institu-
change elements and identifying informal in- tional thought. Particularly, they suggest that
stitutions and relationships, tasks which can the more simplistic, technocratic perspectives
be difficult or even impossible through a doc- behind Mainstream Institutionalism and Ra-
ument analysis or other types of desk study or tional Choice Institutionalism are less useful
by using quantitative data. In addition, contact for in-depth analyses of institutional change.
with a range of actors and institutions, which Instead, the more complex accounts presented
is important in building up an understand- in Critical Institutionalism as well as Historical
ing of context, is also an essential aspect of a and Sociological Institutionalism offer a much
power analysis to which thorough fieldwork stronger foundation for nuanced, insightful
can contribute. When looking at meso-level discussion of institutions and institutional
government as the CCRI project does, for in- change.
stance, it is important to get perspectives from For both analysis and practice, acknowl-
both different levels of meso-level institutions edgement of institutional complexity and
as well as internal and external (government power aspects are therefore an essential starting
and non-government) perspectives of these point. Any other approach would disregard the
institutions. This contributes to a more holis- critical dynamics presented in the preceding
tic, nuanced consideration of the institutional chapters, producing a significantly enfeebled
landscape, which may offer important insights analytical output or project outcome.
in a power analysis.

33
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

6.2 Innovation Theories support more thorough, complex understand-


In addition, the findings offer important re- ings of the drivers and processes of institution-
flections on innovation theories. Much as with al change, ultimately addressing the ‘why’ of
institutional change theories, they suggest that institutional change.
simplistic accounts of innovation are incom-
plete as they disregard the complex realities
and interactions of the structures and actors
which allow for and drive innovations. This
therefore supports more complex accounts of
open innovation through multi-actor systems.
It also supports the process-based accounts of
innovation as learning, which are predicated
upon the idea that innovations are not the re-
sult of single, one-off interventions. These con-
clusions severely undermine the suitability of
linear perceptions of innovations, especially in
a context of climate uncertainty and change.

6.3 Contributions of a Power Analysis


Ultimately, these discussions also indicate the
two major contributions of power analyses of
institutional change. First, such analyses ena-
ble consideration of the complexity of institu-
tional change. The diverse power concepts and
the relations they entail, for instance between
actors and structures and formal and informal
arrangements, have the capacity to both de-
scribe and explain a wide range of institutional
arrangements and dynamics, including why
and how these might occur.
Second, power analyses of institutional
change allow for the combined use of insti-
tutional change theories despite their diverse
theoretical underpinnings. By conceptually
locating the theories in a shared context of
power, such analyses can avoid segregated con-
sideration of either one or another account of
institutional change. They thus evade the sub-
sequent weaknesses of such analyses, which
are inevitable in situations where adhering to
theoretical delineations takes precedence over
analyzing the realities of institutional change.
Power analyses can therefore contribute val-
uably to studies of institutional change; they

34
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

WORKS CITED

Anderson, Ole Johan. 2008. A bottom-up perspective on innovations: Mobilizing knowl-


edge and social capital through innovative process of bricolage. Administration and Soci-
ety, vol. 40, no. 1: 54-78.
Bell, Stephen. 2011. Do we really need a new “Constructivist Institutionalism” to explain
institutional change? British Journal of Political Science, vol. 41, no. 4: 883-906.
Boesen, Nils and Ole Therkildsen. 2004. Between naivety and cynicism. Copenhagen: Minis-
try of Foreign Affairs, Danida.
Campbell, John L. 2010. Institutional reproduction and change. In Oxford handbook of com-
parative institutional analysis, eds. Glenn Morgan, John L. Campbell, Colin Crouch, Ove
K. Pedersen, and Richard Whitley. New York: Oxford University Press.
Cleaver, Frances. 2012. Development through bricolage: Rethinking institutions for natural re-
source management. New York: Routledge.
Cochrane, Willard Wesley. 1958. Farm prices, myth and reality. Minneapolis: University of
Minnesota Press.
Douglas, Mary. 1986. How institutions think. Syracuse: Syracuse University Press.
Douthwaite, Boru. 2002. Enabling innovation: A practical guide to understanding and foster-
ing technological change. London: Zed Books.
FAO. 2005. Communication for development roundtable report: Focus on sustainable de-
velopment, ftp://ftp.fao.org/docrep/fao/008/y5983e/y5983e00.pdf, 3-10-2013
Ferguson, James. 1994. The anti-politics machine: “Development,” depoliticization, and
bureaucratic power in Lesotho. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.
Foucault, Michel. 1977. History of systems of thought. In Language, counter-memory, practice: Se-
lected essays and interviews by Michel Foucault, ed. D. Bouchard. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Foucault, Michel. 1990. The history of sexuality: Volume 1. New York: Pantheon Books.
Foucault, Michel. 1991. Governmentality. In The Foucault effect: Studies in governmentality,
eds. Graham Burchell, Colin Gordon and Peter Miller. Chicago: University of Chicago
Press.
Foucault, Michel. 1995. Discipline and punish: The birth of the prison. Westminster: Vintage.
Friis-Hansen, Esbern and Henrik Egelyng. 2007. Supporting local innovation for rural devel-
opment: Analysis and review of five innovation support funds. Copenhagen: Danish Institute
for International Studies.
Giddens, Anthony. 1984. The constitution of society: Outline of the theory of structuration.
Berkley & Los Angeles: University of California Press.
Gordon, Neve. 2002. On visibility and power: An arendtian corrective of Foucault. Human
Studies, vol. 25: 125-145.
Greenwood, Royston and C. R. Hinings. 1996. Understanding radical organizational
change: Bringing together the old and the new institutionalism. The Academy of Manage-
ment Review, vol. 21, no. 4: 1022-1054.
Hall, Peter A. and Rosemary C. R. Taylor. 1996. Political science and the three new institu-
tionalisms. Political Studies, vol. 44, no. 5: 936-957.
Horsky, Dan and Leonard S. Simon. 1983. Advertising and the diffusion of new products.
Marketing Science, vol. 2, no. 1: 1-17.

35
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

Hubbard, Michael. 1997. The ‘new institutional economics’ in agricultural development:


Insights and challenges. Journal of Agricultural Economics, vol. 48, no. 1-3: 239-249.
Khoumbati, Khalil, Marinos Themistocleous and Zahir Irani. 2006. Evaluating adoption
of enterprise application integration in health-care organizations. Journal of Management
Information Systems, vol. 22, no. 4: 69-108.
Kimberly, John R. and Michael J. Evanisko. 1981. Organizaional innovation: The influence
of individual, organizational, and contextual factors on hospital adoption of technolog-
ical and administrative innovations. The Academy of Management Journal, vol. 24, no. 4:
689-713.
Lemke, Thomas. 2010. Foucault, governmentality and critique. Rethinking Marxism: A Jour-
nal of Economics, Culture and Society, vol. 13, no. 3: 49-64.
Lévi-Strauss, Claude. 1966. The savage mind. Paris: Librairie Plon.
Li, Tanya Murray. 2007. The will to improve: Governmentality, development, and the practice
of politics. Raleigh: Duke University Press.
Long, Norman and Ann Long. 1992. Battlefields of knowledge: The interlocking of theory and
practice in social research and development. London: Routledge.
Lund, Christian. 2006. Twilight institutions: Public authority and local politics in Africa.
Development and Change, vol. 37, no. 4: 685-705.
Mahoney, James and Kathleen Thelen, eds. 2010. Explaining institutional change: Ambiguity,
agency and power. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Mahoney, James. 2000. Path dependence in historical sociology. Theory and Society, vol. 29,
no. 4: 507-548.
Moore, Sally Falk. 1978. Law as process: An anthropological approach. London & Boston:
Routledge &Kegan Paul.
PHILA. 2005. Post-harvest innovation learning alliance flyer, http://projects.nri.org/phila/
reports/Flyer-Zw-Oct05.pdf, 1-10-2013
Pretty, Jules. 2002. In Norman Uphoff, ed., Agroecological innovations: Increasing food pro-
duction with participatory development. London & Sterling: Earthscan Publications Ltd.
Rodrik, Dani. 2004. Getting institutions right. Cambridge: Harvard University. http://files.
wcfia.harvard.edu/807__ifo-institutions%20article%20_April%202004_.pdf, 2013-3-
10
Rogers, Everett. 1962. Diffusion of innovations. New York: Free Press of Glencoe.
Röling, Niels. 2006. Conceptual and methodological developments in innovation. http://
www.worldfishcenter.org/sites/default/files/Conceptual%20and%20methodologi-
cal%20developments%20in%20innovation%20shared%20by%20Ann%20Waters%20
Bayer.pdf, 3-10-2013
Sayer, Andrew. 2012. Power, causality and normativity: A critical realist critique of Foucault.
Journal of Political Power, vol. 5, no. 2: 179-194.
Sehring, Jenniver. 2009. Path dependencies and institutional bricolage in post Soviet water
governance. Water Alternatives, vol. 2, no. 1: 61-81
World Bank. 2010. World development report 2010: Development and climate change. http://
documents.worldbank.org/curated/en/2010/01/11831971/world-development-re-
port-2010-development-climate-change, 3-10-2013.

36
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

37
DIIS WORKING PAPER 2013:20

38

You might also like