You are on page 1of 27

THE

PROFIT ORIENTATION OF MICROFINANCE INSTITUTIONS

AND EFFECTIVE INTEREST RATES

Peter W. Roberts*

Goizueta Business School

Emory University

1300 Clifton Road, Atlanta, GA, 30322

404‐727‐8585

404‐727‐6313

peter_roberts@bus.emory.edu


* The author is grateful for the helpful comments provided by David Kyle, Anand Swaminathan and

Peter Thompson.


 
THE PROFIT ORIENTATION OF MICROFINANCE INSTITUTIONS

AND EFFECTIVE INTEREST RATES

Since the arrival of for‐profit microfinance institutions (MFIs), commentators have been asking

whether the sector benefits by MFIs adopting a stronger profit orientation. We address this

question by analyzing their adoption of the for‐profit legal form, appointing private sector

representation and banking acumen to MFI boards, and participation in more extensive for‐profit

networks. The results consistently indicate that a stronger for‐profit orientation corresponds with

higher effective interest rates for MFI clients. However, these effects do not lead to greater

profitability and therefore sustainability because these variables are also associated with increases

in the major elements of an MFI’s costs.

Key Words: microfinance, global, interest rates, nonprofit


 
“Some Fear Profit Motive to Trump Poverty Efforts in Microfinance” – New York Times
headline, August 28, 2009

1. INTRODUCTION

Microfinance institutions (MFIs) are banking organizations whose primary purpose is that of

providing financial services to poor and otherwise marginalized clients (Mersland & Strøm, 2010).

Collectively, the microfinance sector is lauded for modifying standard banking practices in order to

effectively extend credit to the poor and in doing so helping to elevate their standards of living.

More specifically, the innovations that led to the modern microfinance movement overcame two

problems previously thought to prohibit lending to the poor: small loan sizes and little or no

collateral (Armendariz & Morduch, 2005).

The recent evolution of the microfinance sector can be viewed in terms of the rapid growth

in the number of active MFIs, increases in the volume of business they conduct, a broader range of

financial services on offer, and changes in the types and motivations of MFIs. In this latter respect, an

important marker in the sector’s evolution is the arrival of profit‐oriented MFIs. Although lauded by

many as critically‐important for the maturation of the sector, these MFIs also ushered in debates

about whether it is possible to effectively blend nonprofit ideals and for‐profit orientations and

practices (Morduch, 2000).

More practically, these debates are rooted in questions about whether MFIs with stronger

profit orientations are better able to sustainably address the needs of poor borrowers. Some

commentators clearly place emphasis on the anti‐poverty orientation of MFIs: “the first goal of MFIs

is to reach more clients in the poorer strata of the population, and the second goal is financial

sustainability (Mersland & Strøm, 2008a, pg. 663).” However, it is also believed that a large number

of (especially nonprofit) MFIs are not earning sufficient income to cover their full costs of operation

and expansion and must therefore rely on subsidies – in the form of grants and donations – to

sustain themselves. Concerns about the reliability of these funding sources makes the financial


 
viability of MFIs a major concern for sector participants (Mersland & Strøm, 2010).

In this respect, profit‐oriented MFIs are part of the movement toward a more ‘businesslike’

microfinance sector. With heightened business acumen and a stronger market orientation, profit‐

oriented MFIs are supposed to set more appropriate loan prices and deliver greater efficiencies,

and thus have an easier time attracting needed investment into the sector. This should, in turn,

allow the social impacts that they generate to be more sustainable (Hermes & Lensink, 2007).

The arrival of profit‐oriented MFIs also raises concerns about MFIs trading off social for

financial performance. In contrast, a greater focus on profitability might push concerns about the

well‐being of poor clients to the back burner. While these concerns clearly apply to for‐profit MFIs,

they also apply to nonprofit MFIs where attention to sustainability are leading some to emphasize

the generation of financial surplus, even if that surplus is never distributed to outside shareholders.

In both cases, many worry that we will see MFIs abandoning the poorest clients in search of more

reliable profit streams – something commentators call “mission drift” (Copestake, 2007).

Even MFIs that remain focused on the poorest clients might alter the mix of costs and

benefits that they offer as they strive for enhanced profitability (Yunus, 2011). We address this

latter question by examining the impact of MFIs having a stronger profit orientation on the effective

interest rates charged to clients. While this is not the only variable that matters to microfinance

clients (Cull, Demirguc‐Kunt, & Morduch, 2009), it does capture the effective price of credit access.

We examine differences between the effective interest rates charged by nonprofit versus

for‐profit MFIs. However, we also recognize that the profit orientation of an MFI extends beyond its

decision to operate as a for‐profit organization. It is also manifested in the more subtle choices and

commitments that an MFI makes. In particular, we examine the composition of MFI governing

boards to ascertain whether they contain private‐sector representation and/or individuals with

banking acumen. We also examine the extent to which the network support organizations (Cook &

Isern, 2004, pp., pg. 3) that an MFI participates in are themselves populated by numerous other for‐


 
profit MFIs. In the end, our analyses paint a somewhat sobering picture of the influence of a

stronger profit orientation on the effective interest rates charged to MFI clients. Each of these three

variables is associated with higher effective interest rates. However, these increases do not

manifest in higher MFI profitability and therefore sustainability because the MFIs that are more

profit oriented also tend to have higher costs.

2. PROFIT ORIENTATION OF MICROFINANCE INSTITUTIONS

The collective push to see a more profit‐oriented microfinance sector is most evident in the

relatively high incidence of for‐profit MFIs around the world. In 2009, 490 of the 1,169 MFIs (42%)

in the MIX Market database were for‐profit MFIs. They collectively controlled roughly two‐thirds of

the more than $65 billion in assets deployed in that year. Clearly, adopting a for‐profit legal form

suggests a stronger profit orientation. However, the decision to operate as a for‐profit organization

is not the only choice that indicates the profit orientation of MFIs. In fact, Mersland & Strøm

(2008b) recently concluded that MFI ownership (e.g., shareholder versus NGO) is not particularly

relevant in determining its social or commercial orientation. Rather, as Cull et al. (2009) suggest,

“earning profits does not imply being a ‘for‐profit’ bank.” Nonprofit MFIs can and do earn positive

profits that are simply not distributed to shareholders but are re‐invested in activities that further

service their clients. Therefore, we also look at several other organizational choices that plausibly

correspond with an MFI’s profit orientation.

Appointing individuals to the board of directors represents an important strategic decision

for MFIs. Advice from and oversight by these board members have consequences for decisions

taken within an MFI. Those interested in adopting best practices from the for‐profit world and from

the traditional banking sector might therefore tend to appoint individuals to their boards who bring

experience from these domains. More specifically, appointing individuals from the private sector, as

opposed to the government or NGO sectors, indicates a desire to be influenced in this direction. The


 
same can be said about appointing individuals with banking acumen. Thus, having private sector

representation and banking acumen on the board suggests a stronger profit orientation.

Another way that MFIs deepen their commitment to a profit orientation is by participating

in networks comprised of other for‐profits MFIs. Sociological and managerial research on networks

indicates that the behavior and performance of organizations is influenced by the networks in

which they participate (Brass, Galaskiewicz, Greve, & Tsai, 2004). From an organizational learning

perspective, the ties that make up organizational networks are conduits through which knowledge

and ideas flows. This effect is evident in a statement taken from the website of one prominent

microfinance network: “MicroFinance Network (MFN) is an international association of leading

microfinance institutions. Through the MFN, 31 members from 27 countries share ideas,

experiences, and innovative solutions to the challenges they face in search of continuous growth and

progress. MFN members seek to be models of what is possible in the industry (www.mfnetwork.org).”

The latter aspiration points to a second control aspect of networks. The predominant participants

in an organizational network tend to define the norms and practices in that network (Owen‐Smith

& Powell, 2004). If other MFIs that populate microfinance networks are largely for‐profit MFIs, then

the orientations and ideas that tend to flow through those networks will support and reinforce a

stronger profit orientation among network participants. This suggests that participating in

networks comprised of more for‐profit MFIs suggests a stronger profit orientation.

Assuming these variables indicate the profit orientation of an MFI, the question becomes

how this orientation influences behavior and performance. The optimistic view is that social

impacts will be improved by incorporating more market discipline and commercial acumen into the

traditionally non‐profit microfinance sector. In other words, “the lure of profit, economists assume,

motivates all entrepreneurs and managers and fosters efficient decision making by private firms

(Weisbrod, 1998, p. 70).” The pessimistic view suggests that this orientation is either distracting of

detracting from the pursuit of poverty reduction as an organizational goal. After all, “a nonprofit


 
organization has little incentive to skimp on quality of output or otherwise take advantage of poorly

informed customers (Weisbrod, 1998, p. 70).” In the former case, a focus on profits tends to lead

MFIs away from the commitment that improves their ability to effectively lend to the poor while the

latter suggests that a desire to improve profitability will lead to deliberate choices to cut services or

raise interest rates to meet the demands of higher profitability.

The middle ground between these two positions (and thus the null hypothesis in all that

follows) suggests that debates about the implications of profit‐seeking are quite irrelevant.

Mersland and Strom’s (2008a) analysis found that the impact of an MFI’s adopting a for‐profit

orientation on its performance is effectively null. This centrist position is based on the belief that

nonprofit and profit‐oriented MFIs can be equally concerned with both alleviating poverty and

financial sustainability: “A priori, one would consider that SHFs are more profit‐oriented than

NGOs. Similarly, that NGOs should care more about reaching the poorest clients than SHFs …

However, an alternative hypothesis may be that SHFs and NGOs do not perform differently, because

they may use the same business model to compete and serve customers in the microfinance market

(Mersland & Strøm, 2008b).”

Given the unsettled debates and the relative paucity of systematic empirical analysis

(Hermes & Lensink, 2007, pg. F2), the following sections provide a comprehensive analysis of the

implications for effective interest rates of an MFI having a stronger profit orientation.

3. DATA AND SAMPLE

Our analysis combines two different MIX data sources (www.mixmarket.org): their archive of MFI

financial information and their more recent Social Performance Reports. These latter reports

capture detailed information about specific choices and configurations that pertain to an MFI’s

social orientation. The 358 MFIs in our sample all completed Social Performance Reports in 2008 or

2009 and had corresponding financial data for 2009. To assess the representativeness of this


 
sample, we compare it to the broader sample of all MFIs in the 2009 MIX financial information file

and find it to be broadly comparable (see table 1).

Table 1 about here

Our analysis focuses on one variable that has direct implications for the clients of MFIs – the

effective interest rate charged on the funds that they borrow. Following accepted practice

(Gonzalez, 2010), our effective interest rate variable is real total earned interest income and fees

divided by the average gross loan portfolio. Among the sampled MFIs, the average effective interest

rate is 28.06%.

The MIX data also report the profit status of each MFI. We use this information to create a

‘For‐profit MFI’ dummy variable set to one for MFIs that operate as for‐profit organizations.

According to table 1, 35% of the sampled MFIs are for‐profit organizations. The MIX Social

Performance Reports ask respondents several questions about the composition of their boards.

Two questions are salient for this analysis. The first asks whether an MFI’s board has private sector

representation and the second asks whether banking acumen is present on the board. We use this

information to create two additional dummy variables: ‘Private sector on board’ and ‘Banking

acumen on board’.

Finally, the MIX website reports on the composition of roughly 100 network support

organizations that work with MFIs around the world. These networks “facilitate and provide

support to organizations that are committed to delivering financial services to the poor,” and can be

national, regional or international in orientation (Cook & Isern, 2004, pp., pg. 3). They range in size

from four to more than 150 members and provide a range of services to their members, including

financial and technical services, knowledge management, research and development and policy

advocacy. After recording the names of all MFIs participating in each network, we count the total

number of for‐profit MFIs that a focal MFI is tied to by shared network affiliation. The maximum

number of for‐profit ties is 56 and so we divide the observed number of ties for each sampled MFI


 
by 56 to obtain a normalized variable that ranges from zero (no ties to for‐profit MFIs) to one (the

maximum number of observed ties).

Differing social and economic conditions across countries and regions have implications for

the supply of and demand for micro‐lending (Ahlin, Lin, & Maio, 2011). We control for locating

across the six regions isolated in the MIX databases – Africa, East Asia and the Pacific, Eastern

Europe and Central Asia, Latin America and The Caribbean, Middle East and North Africa and South

Asia – with a series of region fixed effects. At the country level, we account for local economic and

political problems by taking the average of the six dimensions of the World Bank’s Worldwide

Governance Indicator (http://info.worldbank.org/governance/wgi/index.asp): voice and

accountability, political stability and absence of violence, government effectiveness, regulatory

quality, rule of law and control of corruption. Because total population influences the demand for

microcredit, we also control for the natural log of each country’s total population in 2009.

Prevailing interest rates should also be influenced by the degree of microfinance sector

competition. Following a large body of organizational ecology research (Hannan & Freeman, 1989),

we proxy for the degree of competition by counting the number of MFIs active in each country in

2009 (as reported in the MIX database). The overall count ranges from a low of one (in Tunisia) to a

high of 163 (in India). Given the debates about the differential competitiveness of for‐profit and

nonprofit MFIs, we decompose this variable into for‐profit and nonprofit density measures. In

doing so, we see that some countries, like India, have large numbers of both for‐profits (62) and

nonprofits (95). Mexico has many for‐profits (55) but relatively few nonprofits (ten). On the other

hand, Bangladesh has many nonprofits (70) but relatively few for‐profits (3).

Due to economies of scale and experience effects, larger and older MFIs should be more

efficient (Gonzalez, 2007). We therefore account for the size (natural log of assets) and age (natural

log of the years since an MFI started its microfinance operations) of each MFI. There is also interest

in the role played by regulation in shaping the behavior and performance of MFIs (Cull, Demirguc‐


 
Kunt, & Morduch, 2011). We include a dummy variable set to one for banks that reported being

under the influence of a regulatory authority in 2009.

MFIs also vary in the complexity and scope of their offerings. In this regard, two variables

that might influence the cost and performance of MFIs are the extent to which they also engage in

deposit‐taking activities and their outreach levels. To capture the former effect, we include a

variable that measures the savings deposits‐to‐assets ratio for each MFI. We proxy for the degree of

outreach (in terms of number of individuals touched) by including another dummy variable set to

one for MFIs that are reported in the MIX database as having either medium or large outreach

levels.

Commentators also note that costs and therefore interest rates can be influenced by several

variables associated with the degree of difficulty associated with providing micro loans across

different client segments (Mersland & Strøm, 2010, pp., pg. 35). Absent direct measures of the

extent to which an MFI targets marginalized clients, accepted proxies include average loan size,

targeting women borrowers and targeting individuals in rural areas (Cull, et al., 2009). Our average

loan size variable is the median loan size as percentage of country gross national income per capita

(Gonzalez, 2010). The fraction of women borrowers is reported in MIX as the share of outstanding

loans held by women borrowers. The Social Performance Reports ask respondents whether their

MFI targets rural clients. We use this information to create another dummy variable. Finally,

published mission statements provide some indication of the extent to which poverty alleviation is

a central concern for an MFI. We examine the mission statement of each MFI and isolate those that

explicitly mention poor clients or poverty alleviation.

Our final control variable relates to the lending model adopted by each MFI. Following

Hermes and Lensink’s (2007) discussion of group (or joint liability) lending, we include a variable

that indicates whether an MFI employs individual, as opposed to group or village lending practices.

Table 2 reports descriptive statistics for, and pair‐wise correlations among all of the

10 
 
variables in our analysis.

Table 2 about here

4. ANALYSIS AND RESULTS

We begin by entering the control variables into an ordinary least squares regression model

(see model 1 in table 3). The significant coefficients reveal an interesting asymmetry between the

estimated effects of for‐profit versus nonprofit competition. The latter negative effect is consistent

with expectations. Greater competition from larger numbers of nonprofit MFIs drives down

effective interest rates. However, the estimated effect is opposite for the for‐profit competition

variable. We revisit these two results – which are robust across the various models that we

estimate – in the concluding section of the paper. The MFI size variable has the expected negative

effect on interest rates. As expected, MFIs that offer more cost‐effective larger loans also charge

lower interest rates. On the other hand, interest rates are significantly higher among the MFIs that

have medium or large outreach levels, those that target women clients, and those that emphasize

poverty‐reduction in their mission statements.

Table 3 about here

We are primarily interested in the organizational choices made by MFIs that indicate a

stronger commitment to profitability: adopting the for‐profit status, having private‐sector

representation and banking acumen on boards, and having more extensive ties to other for‐profit

MFIs. Model 2 introduces these variables into the effective interest rate model.1 The for‐profit MFI

variable is positive but not statistically significant at conventional levels (p=.0.11). Moreover, each

of the three board and network variables inflates effective interest rates. Having private sector
                                                            
1 Given concerns about multicollinearity, we checked the variance inflation factors (VIFs) and found the

highest (5.02) to be within the acceptable range. We also estimated four separate models that entered each of
the profit‐orientations variables individually and obtained the same results. Finally, we estimated an
(unreported) model that removed outlier observations (i.e., those for which the residual is more than two
standard deviations away from zero) and obtained the same pattern of results.

11 
 
representation on the board corresponds with an estimated increase in the effective interest rate of

3.53 percentage points. Ensuring that the board has banking acumen corresponds with a larger

4.06 percentage point increase. Finally, increasing ties to other for‐profit MFIs from zero to the

maximum level corresponds to a 6.97 percentage point increase in effective interest rates.2

Given the similar magnitudes of the estimated board and network effects, we performed an

F‐test to assess the null hypothesis that their coefficient estimates are equal. This test can not reject

the null hypothesis of equal effects (F=0.57; p=0.57). We therefore sum the three variables into a

single index that reflects the overall profit orientation of each MFI. This variable ranges from a low

of zero (in eight observations) to a high of 2.96, and averages 1.44. Closer inspection shows that this

profit orientation variable is significantly higher among the for‐profit MFIs; averaging 1.71

compared to 1.29 for the nonprofit MFIs (t=5.33; p=0.00). When the overall profit orientation index

is substituted into model 2, its effect is positive and significant; a unit increase corresponding to a

4.05 percentage point increase in effective interest rates (see model 3).

Some researchers express concerns about data quality in models evaluating MFI

performance (Mersland & Strøm, 2010). We therefore estimated an (unreported) variant of model

3 based on the 310 MFIs that received four or five stars for data quality from MIX. The results are

virtually identical to those reported in model 3. Two‐thirds of the nonprofit MFIs in this sample are

NGOs, with credit unions/cooperatives and non‐bank financial institutions comprising the

remaining third. Roughly 80% of the for‐profit MFIs are non‐bank financial institutions. The

remaining for‐profit MFIs are either banks or rural banks.3 To ensure that our results are not an

artifact of the legal form adopted by the sampled MFIs, we ran another (unreported) model that

                                                            
2 To assess whether the network ties effect simply reflects the overall degree of connectedness, we created a

second network variable that ranges from zero to one as an MFI moves from having no ties to other non‐
profit MFIs to one when it has the maximum number of observed ties (131). In an unreported model, the
coefficient on this new variable is negative and insignificant (=‐1.55; p=0.68) while the magnitude and
significance of the for‐profit tie variable remains positive and marginally significant ( =7.89; p=0.03).
3
 This distribution of legal forms in this sample is qualitatively similar to that reported by Cull et al (2009). 

12 
 
includes dummy variables for each legal form. Again, the results reported in model 3 are replicated.

Finally, to ensure that the estimated effects of the profit orientation variables are robust, we

estimated a variant of model 3 that replaces all region and country control variables with a set of

country fixed effects (see model 4). Because we only include observations from countries that have

at least three sampled MFIs, this reduces the sample to 339 MFIs. Again, the results from model 3

are replicated. In this model a unit increase in the profit orientation variable corresponds with a

3.60 percentage point increase in effective interest rates charged to MFI clients.

One of our basic premises is that the organizational choices that MFIs make to incorporate a

stronger profit orientation can have implications above and beyond that of adopting the for‐profit

form. Given pressures on nonprofit MFIs to act more like their market‐oriented for‐profit

counterparts, these choices should also influence their behavior and performance. Model 5 (in table

4) re‐estimates model 3 using the sub‐sample of nonprofit MFIs and shows a similar pattern of

effects. This time, a unit increase in the profit orientation variable is associated with a more

substantial 5.00 percentage point increase in effective interest rates. In the sub‐sample of 127 for‐

profit MFIs, the effect of a stronger profit orientation is still positive, although no longer statistically

significant. It seems that the more damaging effects of a stronger profit orientation (in terms of

higher interest rates charged to clients) are confined to nonprofit MFIs, although it is instructive to

observe that among the for‐profit MFIs, the variables that ought to correlate with improved

business and banking acumen do not help to lower the interest rate variable.

Table 4 about here

Many of the claims about the importance of a stronger profit orientation relates to the

ability of MFIs to encourage more investment to flow into the sector. In support of this claim, table

2 shows that for‐profit MFIs tend to be larger than their nonprofit counterparts and tend to operate

in more populous countries. Extending this line of thought, it is plausible that the stronger profit

orientation is more suited to larger MFI size. We might therefore expect to see the effects of the

13 
 
profit orientation variables disappear or reverse in the sub‐sample of MFIs that are above the

median sample size. In model 7, we do see a reduction in the estimated effect size of the profit

orientation variable. Relative to the sub‐sample of smaller MFIs, the adverse effect of a stronger

profit orientation is roughly halved; producing a 2.23 percentage point increase compared to a 5.44

percentage point increase in the smaller MFI sub‐sample. However, although the adverse effect of

the profit orientation variable on interest rates is less pronounced it is still significant.

(a) Costs and Sustainability

Effective interest rates are the sum of profits earned plus three major components of an MFI’s costs:

operating expenses, financial expenses and losses due to loan impairment. We continue our

analysis by looking at how the variables in model 3 also influence these three cost components.

Operating expenses are largely a function of salaries and staff productivity (Gonzalez, 2010). Thus,

the operating expense variable that we analyze is the sum of these non‐financial expenses (plus

depreciation and amortization and other administrative expenses) divided by the average gross

loan portfolio (Mersland & Strøm, 2008a). The variable that captures financial expenses is

calculated as the total financial expenses relative to the average gross loan portfolio. Finally, the

loan losses variable is the similar ratio of the value of loans written‐off divided by the average gross

loan portfolio.

Given the obvious interdependence among these three cost variables, we estimate the

effects of our covariates in a seemingly‐unrelated regression framework (Zellner, 1962). The

results from this system of equations – presented as model 8 in table 5 – suggest that most of the

systematic variance in MFI costs pertains to operating expenses. Having more nonprofit

competition in a country corresponds with lower operating expense ratios. The for‐profit MFI

competition variable has no discernible effect. The MFI size variable has a negative and significant

effect on operating expenses, corroborating expectations about economies of scale in the MFI

14 
 
sector. There is also evidence of the documented trade‐off between focusing on poverty alleviation

and cost efficiency (Hermes, Lensink, & Meesters, 2011). The estimated effects of targeting women

borrowers and emphasizing poverty reduction in the mission statement are positive and significant

in the operating expenses equation. On the other hand, the decision to target rural clients has a

marginally negative effect, perhaps due to lower land and labor costs in less‐developed areas.

Finally, taking in more deposits, and thereby increasing organizational complexity, corresponds

with higher average operating expenses.

Table 5 about here

Turning to the variables of interest, the profit orientation variable is associated with

significantly higher operating expenses (=5.77) and higher loan impairment expenses (=0.67). Its

effect on financial expenses is also positive but not significant. The estimated effect of the for‐profit

MFI variable is also positive in all three equations, albeit only marginally significant in the financial

expenses equation. Thus, there is no evidence of the expected efficiency benefits of adopting a

stronger profit orientation. These findings are consistent with Hudon and Traça (2011), who find

that MFIs that receive higher levels of subsidies – which are probably the less profit‐oriented MFIs

in this sample – are actually more efficient. More generally, the pattern reinforces a core finding of

Mersland and Strom (2008b), who find no evidence that shareholder‐owned MFIs are

systematically more cost‐effective than their NGO counterparts.

One justification for the higher interest rates charged by MFIs who demonstrate a stronger

commitment to profitability relates to the need for MFIs to be financially sustainable. In theory, by

providing more business acumen and market discipline, a stronger profit orientation reduces the

need for MFIs to rely on subsidies. Instead, higher interest rates and/or lower costs allow them to

earn the surpluses that allow them to sustain operations on their own terms.

An MFI’s financial self‐sufficiency ratio equals its net income divided by its total costs.

Values greater than one indicate that an MFI is able to cover its costs and therefore sustain itself

15 
 
over time. We create a dummy variable set to one for MFIs with financial self‐sufficiency ratios

greater than one and analyze its covariates in a logistic regression model. Arguably, these are the

MFIs that generated enough profit in 2009 to sustain themselves over time. The significant

coefficients in model 10 (in table 6) suggest that greater competition from other for‐profit MFIs

increases the probability than an MFI is financially self‐sustaining. Whether or not a variable leads

to significant financial sustainability differences depends on the extent to which the estimated

interest rate and cost effects offset one another. In this respect, the fact that competition from other

for‐profit MFIs increases the likelihood that an MFI will be financially self‐sustaining is explained by

the fact that its estimated impact on interest rates (=0.27 in model 3) is greater that the

corresponding effects on costs (consistently null across the three equations in model 9). On the

other hand, emphasizing women in lending portfolios and poverty‐alleviation in mission

statements both reduce the likelihood that an MFI is financially self‐sustaining. MFIs that place

greater emphasis on women tend to have higher operating costs (=18.90 in the operating

expenses equation in model 9) that are not fully accounted for by the relatively higher interest rates

that they charge their clients (=9.11 in model 3). This leads to the overall negative effect on the

probability of being financially self‐sustaining. A similar set of observations applies to MFIs that

emphasize poverty in their mission statements.

Table 6 about here

The profit orientation variable exerts no significant effect on sustainability. This overall null

effect is explained by the fact that the positive effect on interest rates charged (=4.05 in model 3)

is more than fully offset by its adverse effects on operating expenses and loan impairment expenses

(=5.77 and =0.23 respectively in model 9). Similarly (although estimated with less provision) for‐

profit MFIs tend to charge higher interest rates but also operate with higher expenses, especially

financial expenses.

16 
 

5. DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION

“A review of microfinance policy reports reveals that most of them highlight the
strengths of SHFs and the weaknesses of NGOs. In particular, they emphasis that NGOs
are less commercial and professional because they lack owners with the pecuniary
incentive to monitor management (Mersland & Strøm, 2008b).”

As the microfinance sector matures, more questions will be asked about whether it is evolving in a

way that advantages the poorest people on the planet. In particular, we expect that “the role of

fully‐commercial, profit‐seeking institutions in providing such microfinance loans [will continue to

be] controversial (Cull, et al., 2009).” Profit‐oriented MFIs are expected to be more efficient but

then distribute more of their earned surplus to outside shareholders. Nonprofits are expected to be

less concerned about generating surplus for owners but also less operationally efficient.

The baseline expectations about the effects of a stronger profit orientation – which have

been challenged elsewhere – are not at all supported in this analysis. The variables that suggest a

stronger profit orientation do not lower any of the major components of an MFI’s cost. Nor do they

significantly improve MFI sustainability. The only thing that we can conclude is that the effective

interest rates charged by MFIs with stronger profit orientations are significantly higher on average.

In light of the persistent commentary regarding the need for a more market‐based orientation in

the sector, this offers a somewhat sobering account of the implications of MFIs having stronger for‐

profit orientations.

The effects revealed in this analysis suggests that advisory inputs from individuals with

private‐sector backgrounds, with traditional banking acumen or experience running for‐profit MFIs

do not help MFIs navigate the trade‐offs between efficient service delivery on the one hand and

organizational sustainability on the other. They also reinforce an observation made by Armendariz

and Morduch (2005), who note how “pioneering models grew out of experimentation in low‐

income countries … rather than from adaptations of standard banking models in richer countries.”

17 
 
It seems that the insights that are required to achieve poverty alleviation along with financial

sustainability will similarly not come from the importation of advice from those familiar with

standard banking models.

The variables that indicate a stronger profit orientation never seem to produce the expected

benefits for MFI clients. So, we conclude the paper by joining others in stressing that “rather than

concentrating on an MFIs ‘commercialization,’ attention should be focused on how to reduce costs

per client (Mersland & Strøm, 2010, pg. 35).” Given the strong correspondence between variables

that systematically influence both MFI costs and effective interest rates, it seems that discussions of

how to stimulate stronger profit orientations should be replaced with those which more directly

address MFI efficiency. For instance, consideration might be given to how one might induce more

nonprofit competition, or to effectively scaling efficient and effective MFIs – both nonprofit and for‐

profit – as both of these variables seem to reduce operating costs and lower effective interest rates

(the latter with increased profitability).

Other findings from tables 3 and 4 warrant further scrutiny. Consider, for example, the

asymmetric effects of the levels of for‐profit and nonprofit competition. The results that pertain to

nonprofit competition are consistent with our understanding of how markets are supposed to

operate. Greater numbers of suppliers force MFIs to become more cost efficient in order to attract

clients. The combination of competition and induced efficiencies drives down effective interest

rates. This is the specific dynamic that commentators want to see within the sector. However, the

corresponding effects of increased numbers of for‐profit MFIs are counter‐intuitive. Here, larger

numbers tend to correspond with significantly higher effective interest rates (for all MFIs and for

the sub‐sample of nonprofit MFIs) and higher MFI profitability. This result is so robust in these data

that it seems odd to equate the increased numbers of for‐profit MFIs with increased MFI

competition. These asymmetric competitive effects are clearly worthy of further analysis. In the

meantime, we must question the net benefit of inducing greater participation of MFIs with stronger

18 
 
profit orientations. In addition to their adverse direct effects on interest rates, their proliferation in

a country leads to even further interest rate increases.

In closing, we propose that this kind of research allows practitioners and commentators to

look beneath broad generalizations about the direction of the microfinance sector and appreciate

the diversity in observed outcomes that are attributable to the more specific choices that both for‐

profit and nonprofit MFIs make. In this respect, it may not be that important to determine whether,

on average, the MFI sector is experience what some are calling mission drift. It may not even be

important to ascertain whether, on average, for‐profit and nonprofit MFIs are making different

choices and trade‐offs. What is important is the knowledge of how the specific decisions taken by

MFIs are able to more or less effectively meet the twin challenges of addressing poverty while

sustaining and scaling these impacts.

That said, we must also stress the need for an appropriate interpretation of these cross‐

sectional results. All we can say for sure is that in 2009, MFIs that displayed stronger profit

orientations tended to charge higher effective rates while operating at higher cost. These findings

are germane to those that seek to offer advice on what kinds of MFIs tend to produce what kinds of

performance outcomes and social impacts. They are also important to those responsible for

directing funds toward more impactful and sustainable MFIs. Here, one might stress the need for

those with available funds – even funds that seek market returns – look past the for‐profit versus

nonprofit distinction and look to lend to MFIs that are operating efficiently and pricing

competitively. However, our results are silent on the causal effects of an individual MFI moving

toward (or away from) a stronger for‐profit orientation. Addressing this kind of question, which is

clearly part of the policy questions that pertain to how existing MFIs might better serve their

clients, requires a longitudinal analysis of MFI’s that switch to become for‐profit organizations, that

change the composition of their boards, or that change the extent to which their networks are

dominated by for‐profit MFIs. Given the benefits associated with isolating such exogenous impacts

19 
 
on MFI behavior and performance, this kind of data and analysis will be most useful, and will surely

add rigor to the debates addressed in this paper.

20 
 
TABLE 1. CURRENT SAMPLE

All MIX
Market
Sample (2009)
N 358 1,169
Share of for‐profit MFIs 35% 42%
Average assets (log) 16.34 15.84
Average effective interest rate 28.06 25.38

21 
 
TABLE 2. DESCRIPTIVES AND CORRELATIONS

Mean (0) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14) (15) (16) (17)
(0) Effective interest rate 28.06
(1) Country problems 65.38 ‐0.15
(2) Country population (log) 3.27 ‐0.03 ‐0.12
(3) For‐Profit MFIs in country 15.93 0.17 ‐0.19 0.67
(4) Nonprofit MFIs in country 25.37 ‐0.27 0.00 0.59 0.51
(8) Assets (log) 16.34 ‐0.30 ‐0.02 0.09 0.10 0.18
(9) Age (log) 2.43 ‐0.06 ‐0.05 ‐0.10 ‐0.15 0.02 0.22
(5) Regulated 0.54 ‐0.17 0.06 0.06 0.15 ‐0.05 0.35 ‐0.18
(6) Deposits to Assets 0.15 ‐0.20 0.19 0.05 0.06 0.06 0.31 0.18 0.20
(7) Medium/Large Outreach 0.60 0.00 0.03 0.16 0.22 0.15 0.66 0.09 0.21 0.10
(10) Average loan size (log) 0.33 ‐0.35 0.20 ‐0.30 ‐0.23 ‐0.20 0.29 0.01 0.25 0.27 ‐0.05
(11) Fraction women borrowers 0.62 0.29 ‐0.11 0.32 0.32 0.33 ‐0.07 0.02 ‐0.23 ‐0.23 0.21 ‐0.50
(12) Poor/poverty in mission 0.44 0.16 ‐0.02 0.25 0.17 0.18 0.00 ‐0.08 ‐0.08 ‐0.12 0.22 ‐0.24 0.33
(13) Target rural clients 0.77 ‐0.06 0.09 ‐0.18 ‐0.08 0.00 0.12 0.14 0.00 ‐0.04 0.12 0.00 0.04 0.08
(14) Lend to individuals 0.88 ‐0.12 0.15 ‐0.28 ‐0.24 ‐0.20 0.10 0.08 0.11 0.14 ‐0.13 0.25 ‐0.36 ‐0.24 0.06
(15) For‐profit MFI 0.35 ‐0.01 ‐0.01 0.18 0.31 0.03 0.25 ‐0.30 0.50 0.11 0.12 0.20 ‐0.15 ‐0.09 ‐0.17 0.08
(16) Private sector on board 0.36 0.11 0.02 0.12 0.19 0.08 0.09 ‐0.20 0.14 ‐0.11 0.24 ‐0.03 0.17 0.10 ‐0.07 ‐0.08 0.18
(17) Banking acumen on board 0.82 0.17 ‐0.03 0.17 0.20 0.02 0.18 ‐0.12 0.18 ‐0.06 0.25 ‐0.09 0.13 0.08 ‐0.08 ‐0.04 0.22 0.28
(18) Ties to for‐profit MFIs (norm) 0.26 0.18 ‐0.13 ‐0.02 0.25 0.02 0.32 0.08 0.20 ‐0.08 0.28 ‐0.05 0.14 0.00 0.06 ‐0.02 0.14 0.11 0.13

22 
 
TABLE 3. EFFECTIVE INTEREST RATES CHARGED BY MICROFINANCE INSTITUTIONS

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4
(Controls) (Profit (Single (Country
Orientation) Index) Fixed Effects)
Country problems 0.01 0.01 0.01 ‐
(0.05) (0.05) (0.05)
Country population (log) 0.76 1.08 1.02 ‐
(0.70) (0.69) (0.68)
For‐Profit MFIs in country 0.33** 0.25** 0.27** ‐
(0.05) (0.05) (0.05)
Nonprofit MFIs in country ‐0.26** ‐0.23** ‐0.24** ‐
(0.04) (0.04) (0.04)
Assets (log) ‐1.96** ‐2.52** ‐2.40** ‐1.21*
(0.59) (0.59) (0.58) (0.55)
Age (log) 0.21 0.46 0.61 0.98
(1.01) (1.03) (1.02) (0.97)
Regulated ‐0.74 ‐2.26 ‐2.13 ‐2.92¥
(1.48) (1.53) (1.52) (1.57)
Deposits to Assets ‐3.39 ‐1.20 ‐1.31 ‐2.67
(3.10) (3.04) (3.03) (3.10)
Medium/Large Outreach 5.02** 3.97* 3.92* ‐0.44
(1.92) (1.89) (1.88) (1.73)
Average loan size (log) ‐8.61** ‐8.47** ‐8.76** ‐8.65**
(2.50) (2.45) (2.43) (2.60)
Fraction women borrowers 11.26 ** 8.85 * 9.11* 9.91**
(3.01) (2.93) (2.96) (2.97)
Poor/poverty in mission 3.86** 4.14** 4.14** 2.72*
(1.31) (1.27) (1.27) (1.21)
Target rural clients ‐1.86 ‐0.65 ‐0.67 ‐1.18
(1. 43) (1. 41) (1. 41) (1. 34)
Lend to individuals ‐0.13 ‐0.86 ‐0.83 0.52
(2.02) (1.97) (1.96) (1.80)

For‐profit MFI ‐ 2.49 2.46 2.42
(1.55) (1.55) (1.55)
Profit orientation ‐ ‐ 4.05** 3.60**
(0.88) (0.86)
‐ Private sector on board ‐ 3.53 ** ‐ ‐
(1.31)
‐ Banking acumen on board ‐ 4.06* ‐ ‐
(1.62)
‐ Ties to for‐profit MFIs (norm) ‐ 6.97* ‐ ‐
(2.93)

Fixed region effects (yes) (yes) (yes) (no)
Fixed country effects (no) (no) (no) (yes)

N 358 358 358 339
Adjusted R2 0.48 0.51 0.51 0.65
** p<0.01; * p<0.05; ¥ p<0.10

23 
 
TABLE 4. MODERATING FACTORS: FOR‐PROFIT STATUS AND SIZE

Model 5 Model 6 Model 7 Model 8
(Nonprofit (For‐Profit (Larger (Smaller
MFIs) MFIs) MFIs) MFIs)
Country problems ‐0.04 0.11 0.01 0.04
(0.06) (0.09) (0.06) (0.07)
Country population (log) 1.16 0.92 0.37 2.14*
(0.82) (1.33) (0.85) (1.05)
For‐Profit MFIs in country 0.12¥ 0.40** 0.37** 0.10
(0.07) (0.09) (0.06) (0.09)
Nonprofit MFIs in country ‐0.17** ‐0.26** ‐0.27** ‐0.19**
(0.06) (0.06) (0.04) (0.07)
Assets (log) ‐2.39** ‐2.50** ‐1.59¥ ‐2.44*
(0.82) (0.85) (0.81) (1.18)
Age (log) 0.62 1.46 1.76 ‐1.02
(1.36) (1.69) (1.25) (1.60)
Regulated ‐0.55 ‐5.19 ‐2.88 ‐3.13
(1.93) (3.25) (1.93) (2.46)
Deposits to Assets ‐2.76 ‐1.54 2.52 ‐11.53*
(4.31) (4.69) (3.48) (5.60)
Medium/Large Outreach 3.89 2.99 1.58 5.84*
(2.45) (3.43) (2.73) (2.94)
Average loan size (log) ‐11.43** ‐8.04** ‐9.12** ‐14.86**
(4.15) (3.16) (2.61) (4.78)
Fraction women borrowers 7.44 * 4.46 8.40 * 9.92*
(3.76) (5.99) (3.84) (4.79)
Poor/poverty in mission 2.26 6.23** 3.28* 4.55*
(1.60) (2.23) (1.50) (2.06)
Target rural clients ‐2.02 2.09 1.93 ‐2.67
(1.88) (2.20) (1.71) (2.30)
Lend to individuals ‐2.31 4.15 ‐2.88 0.83
(2.27) (4.07) (2.61) (2.97)

For‐profit MFI ‐ ‐ 2.75 3.29
(1.85) (2.65)
Profit orientation 5.00** 1.51 2.23* 5.44**
(1.14) (1.48) (1.09) (1.40)

Fixed region effects (yes) (yes) (yes) (yes)

N 231 127 179 179
Adjusted R2 0.50 0.57 0.53 0.50
** p<0.01; * p<0.05; ¥ p<0.10

24 
 
TABLE 5. THREE ELEMENTS OF MFI COSTS

Model 9a
Operating Financial Loan
Expenses Expenses Impairment
Country problems ‐0.24* ‐0.06¥ 0.03
(0.11) (0.03) (0.02)
Country population (log) 3.04* 0.32 0.06
(1.52) (0.42) (0.26)
For‐Profit MFIs in country ‐0.03 0.01 ‐0.02
(0.12) (0.03) (0.02)
Nonprofit MFIs in country ‐0.35** ‐0.03 ‐0.01
(0.08) (0.02) (0.01)
Assets (log) ‐6.38** 0.12 0.01
(1.30) (0.36) (0.22)
Age (log) ‐2.75 ‐0.02 0.33
(2.27) (0.63) (0.39)
Regulated ‐2.38 ‐0.48 ‐0.00
(3.41) (0.95) (0.58)
Deposits to Assets 16.67** 1.49 ‐2.32*
(6.78) (1.88) (1.15)
Medium/Large Outreach 3.02 ‐1.12 0.12
(4.21) (1.17) (0.71)
Average loan size (log) ‐4.05 0.70 0.59
(5.42) (1.50) (0.92)
Fraction women borrowers 18.90** 1.60 0.90
(6.62) (1.84) (1.12)
Poor/poverty in mission 11.83** ‐0.07 0.09
(2.84) (0.79) (0.48)
Target rural clients ‐5.22¥ 1.29 ‐0.61
(3.16) (0.87) (0.54)
Lend to individuals ‐5.05 ‐0.85 1.20
(4.38) (1.22) (0.74)

For‐profit MFI 3.47 1.86 ¥ 0.23
(3.46) (0.96) (0.59)
Profit orientation 5.77** 0.55 0.67*
(1.97) (0.55) (0.33)

Fixed region effects (yes) (yes) (yes)

N 358
“R2” 0.37 0.09 0.12
** p<0.01; * p<0.05; ¥ p<0.10
a Seemingly unrelated regression model

25 
 
TABLE 6. SELF‐SUFFICIENCY (SUSTAINABILITY)

Model 10a
Sustainability
Pr(F.S.S.>1)
Country problems 0.01
(0.01)
Country population (log) 0.01
(0.16)
For‐Profit MFIs in country 0.04**
(0.01)
Nonprofit MFIs in country 0.00
(0.01)
Assets (log) 0.21
(0.15)
Age (log) 0.50*
(0.25)
Regulated 0.01
(0.37)
Deposits to Assets 1.85*
(0.95)
Medium/Large Outreach 0.20
(0.46)
Average loan size (log) ‐0.49
(0.59)
Fraction women borrowers ‐1.46*
(0.74)
Poor/poverty in mission ‐0.66*
(0.31)
Target rural clients 0.34
(0.34)
Lend to individuals ‐0.64
(0.48)

For‐profit MFI 0.06
(0.37)
Profit orientation ‐0.14
(0.21)

Fixed region effects (yes)

N 358
Log‐Likelihood ‐168.78
** p<0.01; * p<0.05; ¥ p<0.10
a Logistic regression model

26 
 
REFERENCES

Ahlin, C., Lin, J., & Maio, M. (2011). Where does microfinance flourish? Microfinance institution 
performance in macroeconomic context. Journal of Developmental Economics, 95, 105‐120. 
Armendariz, B., & Morduch, J. (2005). The Economics of MicroFinance (Second ed.). Cambridge, MA: MIT 
Press. 
Brass, D. J., Galaskiewicz, J., Greve, H. R., & Tsai, W. (2004). Taking stock of networks and organizations: 
A multilevel perspective. Academy of Management Journal, 47, 795‐817. 
Cook, T., & Isern, J. (2004). What Is a Network? The Diversity of Networks in Microfinance Today. 
Copestake, J. (2007). Mainstreaming microfinance: Social performance management or mission drift? 
World Development, 35, 1721‐1738. 
Cull, R., Demirguc‐Kunt, A., & Morduch, J. (2009). Microfinance meets the market. Journal of Economic 
Perspectives, 23, 167‐192. 
Cull, R., Demirguc‐Kunt, A., & Morduch, J. (2011). Does Regulatory Supervision Curtail Microfinance 
Profitability and Outreach? . World Development, 39, 949‐965. 
Gonzalez, A. (2007). Efficiency drivers of microfinance institutions (MFIs): The case of operating 
costs.Unpublished manuscript. 
Gonzalez, A. (2010). Analyzing microcredit interest rates: A review of the methodology proposed by 
Mohammed Yunus.Unpublished manuscript. 
Hannan, M. T., & Freeman, J. (1989). Organizational Ecology. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. 
Hermes, N., & Lensink, R. (2007). The empirics of microfinance: what do we know? The Economic 
Journal, 117, F1‐F10. 
Hermes, N., Lensink, R., & Meesters, A. (2011). Outreach and efficiency of microfinance institutions. 
World Development, 39, 938‐948. 
Hudon, M., & Traça, D. (2011). On the efficiency effects of subsidies in microfinance: An empirical 
inquiry. World Development, 39, 966‐973. 
Mersland, R., & Strøm, R. Ø. (2008a). Performance and governance in microfinance institutions. Journal 
of Banking and Finance, 33, 662‐669. 
Mersland, R., & Strøm, R. Ø. (2008b). Performance and trade‐offs in microfinance organisations—Does 
ownership matter? Journal of International Development, 20, 598‐612. 
Mersland, R., & Strøm, R. Ø. (2010). Microfinance mission drift? World Development, 38, 28‐36. 
Morduch, J. (2000). The microfinance schism. World Development, 28, 617‐629. 
Owen‐Smith, J., & Powell, W. W. (2004). Knowledge networks as channels and conduits: The effects of 
spillovers in the Boston biotechnology community. Organization Science, 15, 5‐21. 
Weisbrod, B. A. (1998). Institutional form and organizational behavior. In W. W. Powell & E. S. Clemen 
(Eds.), Private Action and the Public Good (pp. 69‐84). New Haven, CT: Yale University Press. 
Yunus, M. (2011, January 14, 2011). Sacrificing Microcredit for Megaprofits. New York Times,  
Zellner, A. (1962). An efficient method of estimating seemingly unrelated regressions and tests for 
aggregation bias. Journal of the American Statistical Association, 57, 348‐368. 
 

27 
 

You might also like