You are on page 1of 22

Accounting, Organizations andsociety, Vol. 10, No. 3, pp. 329-350, 1985. 0361-3682185 S3.00+.

00
Printed in Great Britain @ 1985 Pergamon Press Ltd.

THE USE OF FINANCIAL INFORMATION BY TRADE UNION NEGOTIATORS IN


PLANT LEVEL COLLECTIVE BARGAINING*

DAVID L. OWEN
Department ofAccounting and Business Finance, University of Manchester, UK

and

ANTHONY J. LLOYD
Member of Parliament forStretford (formerly Department of Business and Administration,
University of Salford L?K)

Abstract

The aim of this paper is to undertake a critical review of recently completed empirical work, carried out
under the auspices of the SSRC, on the use of information in individual company and plant level bargaining.
The authors also attempt to develop a strategy for further investigation of this important topic which high-
lights the importance of variations in the nature of the domestic organisation in relation to the potential
importance and usefulness of financial information for union negotiators,

Traditionally, union negotiators have tended to to be borne in mind when pursuing claims.
concentrate on factors such as rises in the cost of Hence there should be a demand from unions for
living, changes in productivity and compar- increased provision of financial information on
ability with other groups of workers rather than the part of employers, particularly in the private
a particular company’s ability to pay when sector of the economy.
negotiating pay rises. At best it would appear There is indeed at the national level some evi-
that statistics on ability to pay have been refer- dence of such a process taking place. Not only do
red to by unions as a “permissive” rather than we have examples of “shopping lists” of informa-
“determining” factor in wage claims (Foley & tion requirements being issued through the TUC
Maunders, 1977). However it can be argued that (e.g. TX-Labour Party Liaison Committee,
in the current economic climate, union 1982) but also individual unions such as the
negotiators’ concern with avoiding any redun- General and Municipal Workers Union (GMWU)
dancies arising from pay settlements reached have begun to seek, as a matter of policy, to sec-
( Daniel, 198 1) will encourage a consideration of ure information agreements with companies,
ability to pay as an increasingly important factor and have published advice for their shop stew-

l The authors wish to acknowledge the helpful comments of participants in Accounting seminars at the Universities of
Birmingham and Leeds, and at the AUTA Northern Accounting Group Conference at the University of Manchester (April
1982 ) on earlier drafts of this paper. Acknowledgement is also due to Anthony Hopwood for extensive commentary on an
earlier draft of the paper.

329
330 DAVID L. OWEN and ANTHONY J. LLOYD

ards on what types of information it is most use- potential usefulness, which however tended to
ful to ask for (GMWU, 1978). Other unions, not- outweigh the existing use made of such data.
ably the Transport and General Workers Union Daniel (1976) for example found that, whereas
(TGWU) began some years ago to adopt the the ability of employers to pay, as measured by
practice of using detailed financial arguments in trends in product demand, labour intensity, cash
pursuing certain “prestige” national wage claims flow and the changing size of the workforce,
(e.g. TGWU, 1971, 1977). appeared to have little infhtence over the wage
A number of writers have commented most increase agreed, financial circumstances it&t-
favourably on such trends. For example, Palmer enced management priorities and hence the
( 1977, p.55) writing of the United States experi- degree of difficulty associated with the negotia-
ence, which has had a profound effect on legisla- tions. Furthermore, inability of the firm to pay
tive developments in the United Kingdom, was cited more frequently than any other argu-
suggests that, “The increased infusion of ment put forward by management as being one
accounting data into the negotiations process that union negotiators felt to be persuasive. It is
should smooth the operation, raise the level of therefore somewhat surprising that Daniel
bargaining and improve the union/management found considerable evidence of management
relationship”, whilst Hawkins ( 1979, p.20) com- being disinclined to provide trade union officers
ments that “. . increased disclosure is likely to with information on the financial side of the bus-
have a tangible effect on the level of profes- iness! A further study worthy of note is that of
sionalism with which collective bargaining is Cooper & Essex (1977) on the role of shop
conducted on both sides of the table”. Indeed stewards. Surveying a sample of 230 stewards in
there appears to be a great deal of political con- the Greater Manchester area who were mem-
sensus, as evidenced by provisions contained bers of the Amalgamated Union of Engineering
within the Industrial Relations Act 1971, Workers (AUEW), Cooper & Essex asked them
Employment Protection Act 1975 and Employ- to rank the important justifying factors used in
ment Act 1982, that information disclosure has pursuing a pay claim. They found that profits
an important role to play in promoting more made by the firm ranked third in order of impor-
informed and rational bargaining. tance, behind the cost of living and comparision
Much interest in recent years has focussed with others in the same workplace. This marked
upon the extent to which the above evidence of a major departure from a ranking published in
apparent changes in union attitudes at national the 1968 Government Social Survey where pro-
level towards recognising the potential impor- fits of the firm appeared in ninth place. Cooper
tance of a financial information input into the & Essex concluded that, “Perhaps during the
collective bargaining process, is reflected in period between the two surveys shop stewards
individual company and plant level bargaining. have come to regard accounting profits as a good
This interest itself reflects an appreciation of the predictor of a firms willingness to pay a wage
importance of the plant as a level of pay settle- claim” (p.2 14).
ment. For example a study by Daniel (1976) Perhaps a word of caution is necessary when
which surveyed 254 plants, each employing interpreting the results of the Cooper & Essex
over 200 people drawn from the whole range of study, the authors themselves emphasising that
manufacturing industry, indicated that the plant their conclusions must be regarded as tentative
represented, by a considerable margin, the most in view of the forced choice questionnaire
important level of bargaining over pay, particu- employed imposing a particular image of reality
larly in engineering and metalworking. on respondents and the relatively poor (24.8% )
Early evidence produced by researchers response rate achieved. This need for caution is
suggested that ability to pay information was reinforced when one considers the fmdings of
being increasingly accepted by union recent studies of the use made of company infor-
negotiators at domestic level as possessing mation by trade unions in collective bargaining
THE USE OF FINANCIAL INFORMATION BY TRADE UNION NEGOTIATORS 331

at the domestic level conducted under a Social question the validity of certain decisions or
Science Research Council (SSRC) initiative. ’ propose alternative courses of action. In other
Jackson-Cox et al. (1984) for instance, found words they see an important role for information
that, “In general, managements’ provision of acquisition in extending collective bargaining
such information to trades union represent- beyond the traditional areas of concern, i.e.
atives was initiated in response to pressures terms and conditions of employment. Whereas
arising out of constraints imposed by the envi- we would not take issue with the SSRC resear-
ronment in which firms operated, rather than in chers wider definition of collective bargaining
response to trade union pressures or requests”. we would take issue with their tendency to
Mitchell et al. (1980, p.55) could find, “no evi- unquestioningly accept the potential impor-
dence to suggest that management had been tance of corporate financial information* to
under pressure from their work forces to dis- union negotiators in this context, and con-
close information. Trade union leadership . . sequent failure to consider fully possible expla-
had, in general merely been permissive”, whilst nations for the low rates of utilisation of such
Reeves & McGovern ( 198 1) could find little evi- information by union negotiators highlighted in
dence of financial information being used by the the studies. A further major reservation we have
union side in wage bargaining. concerning the studies is that, despite the richer
The SSRC studies are particularly noteworthy institutional context, we feel the possible impor-
in that not only have the researchers sought to tance of variations in the nature of the domestic
ground their observations in a generally richer organisation in relation to the potential impor-
institutional context than was the case with tance and usefulness of financial information for
earlier studies (Cooper & Essex, 1977; Foley & the union negotiator is not fully explored.
Maunders, 1977) but also they have not per- Indeed we observe a tendency for the studies to
petuated the error of identifying collective bar- assume the existence of a universal “identikit”
gaining solely with wage bargaining. Thus they union representative despite the deficiencies of
see acquisition of company information on the such a viewpoint highlighted in recent industrial
part of union negotiators being useful for pur- relations literature (Marchington & Armstrong,
poses extending far beyond a mere estimation of 1981).
ability to pay. For example, such information Our purpose in this paper is therefore to
may be used in order to arrive at an understand- undertake a critical review of the SSRC studies
ing of the rationale underlying management and, further, to develop a strategy for future
decisions, obtaining advance warning of issues investigations in this still largely uncharted area
or decisions, particularly those having repercus- of research. We commence with a brief review
sions on job prospects which may need to be of three of the studies3 in which we seek to high-
negotiated, and furthermore in enabling them to light the major points they raise, which we have

’ Four studies were conducted, the research teams being as follows: J. Jackson-Cox, J. McQueeney and J. E. M. Thirkel
(University of Kent at Canterbury). H. Levie and R. E. Moore (Ruskin College, Oxford). F. Mitchell, H. I. Sams and P. J, White
(University of Edinburgh). T. K Reeves and T. McGovern (Anghan Regional Management Centre). For detailed references
see Bibliography.
’ It should be pointed out that the SSRC researchers focussed their attention on the acquisition and use of company informa-
tion in general rather than corporate financial information in particular. However it is apparent that much of their analysis
does indeed concern “financiaI” information, in terms of information which could further the construction of a particular
economic reality. Thus we feel justified in restricting our attention to corporate financial information defined in a similar
wide manner so as to include, for example, information relating to investment decisions, production planning and associated
manpower requirements, marketing and pricing policy.
’ The project carried out by Mitchell et al. whilst suggesting an extremely minor role for financial information disclosure in
the conduct of industrial relations looks at disclosure techniques primarily in the context of provision of information to all
employees rather than union negotiators specitically. The results presented are thus not as relevant to the theme of this par-
ticular paper as those from the other projects.
332 DAVID L. OWEN and ANTHONY J. LLOYD

attempted to utilise in our development of a the ordering of priorities and the choosing of
strategy for further investigation. strategies or means to achieve them. Only by
developing forward thinking may trade
unionists avoid the trap of being “sucked into
THE SSRC SPONSORED STUDIES management”. In particular it is necessary for
union officials to get to know and understand the
Moore, Gold & Levie (1979); Moore & Levie company information system as well as
(1981) strengthening the union organisation in the
Moore and his colleagues at the Ruskin Col- company by developing a suitable structure,
lege Trade Union Research Unit conduct their enabling a clear picture of all the activities and
studies very much within a trade union institu- ramitications of the company to be obtained.
tional context, the trade unions involved having The latter point is of course particularly impor-
approached the research team for help. Thus tant in that it is easy for shop stewards to develop
their work at least exhibits the merit that value a parochial approach to plant bargaining
judgements are certainly made explicit (Cooper whereas many issues facing them, such as invest-
& Sherer, 1981) The dominant theme under- ment strategy, are not cot&ted to a particular
pinning their analysis is that the effective use of plant and may be best tackled by the adoption of
company information can, without doubt, aid a multi piant bargaining approach.
the union official in pursuing the interests of the It should be pointed out that the case studies
membership. utilised by Moore et al. to illustrate their argu-
Before turning to the later study it would be ments are all concerned with a major industrial
useful to summarise briefly the main points of change which either took place or was
the earlier pilot study (Moore et al., 1979). threatened.* As they indeed admit, it is easier to
Essentially Moore et al. adopt a “user” approach, develop a strategy to counter a one-off crisis that
advising officials to it is to use information on a continuing basis.
Nevertheless we feel that the constraints model
look to the use of information, not to the acquisition developed does provide useful lessons for union
of more, when considering how to gain more intluence negotiators in using information on a regular
within the enterprise. In particular information is a
basis both in order to assess a company’s ability
means to an end; it makes sense only within its context;
it must be used within a strategy; and a wedge of the
to pay a wage increase and in attempting to
union or unions has to cooperate together to ensure its extend collective bargaining.
effectiveness (p.34). Moore & Levie’s ( 1981) project investigates
further the context of disclosure and trade union
In practice a number of constraints have to be use of company information. A further set of con-
overcome before trade unionists can use infor- straints is added to their original model, con-
mation effectively. Such constraints fall into two straints created by the nature of the industry.
categories, firstly management constraints - Within this category the size and spread of
managerial attitudes, the organisation of indust- employers, the nature of employment, employ
rial relations, company structure, and secondly ment traditions and relations between unions
union constraints - union servicing, union pol- are specified as important factors. A case study
icy, union structure (including shop steward centred on the construction industry, focussing
organisation). In overcoming these constraints on the problems encountered by the Union of
union officials are urged to develop forward Construction Allied Trades and Technicians
thinking, entailing the selection of objectives, (UCA’IT) in gathering information about its

4 The case studies were concerned with the following issues: an anti merger campaign (Odharns); the introduction of a new
participation scheme (British Leyland); action taken to prevent a closure (British Steel, Ebbw Vale); and union re-organisa-
tion so as to cope better with company bargaining structures (Lucas).
THE USE OF FINANCIAL INFORMATION BY TRADE UNION NEGOTL4TORS 333

members earnings in order to consolidate the opposed to merely formal democratic proce-
wages structure in the industry, is utilised to dures. This requires,
illustrate these particular constraints. Important
a’ much higher level of involvement of the members
factors drawn to attention here are the fact that
and their representatives. It means a bargaining structure
construction industry national agreements that is present at every level of the company.It impliesa
cover a small number of major employers and an high level of co-operation, or at least discussion between
enormous number of small employers exhibit- and within unions. It means creating a new role for Full-
ing vast differences in management information Time Officers who no longer have to solve members
problems, but who enable them to solve their problems
systems used, the operation of the “lump”
themselves. It means an active education and research
together with high rates of labour turnover, programme that changes as collective bargaining
“Victorian” employment traditions and poor develops. It means a flexible organisation that is capable
relations between the major unions involved in of re-organising itself as the needs and problems of the
the industry (UCATT and the TGWU). members change (p.20).

The original constraints model, whilst


accepted as a useful diagnostic tool in a particu- Although, as in the earlier study, Moore &
lar industrial and company setting at a particular Levie do not look specifically at the problem of
point in time, is criticised in this later study on using company information on a regular basis,
the grounds that it is static, whereas disclosure for example in negotiating wage claims, they do
and use of information are dynamic factors. raise the suggestion that Information Agree-
Therefore Moore et al. go on to identify crucial ments are a useful way to incorporate informa-
dynamic factors that can change disclosure and tion rights in collective bargaining. Rejecting a
use of information dramatically. The factors shopping list approach they stress the need for,
identified are management style and strategy,
a procedural agreement specifying the conditions of
the state of the economy, i.e. companies are informationto be disclosed(timing level of details,relia-
more generally inclined to disclose information bility, format etc.) for whom it will be disclosed, how
when things are going badly, and, most impor- often and who is responsible for disclosure. Specifying
tantly, the ambitiousness of union demands. the substance of the information to be disclosed should
be a function of collective bargaining itself(p. 11).
The basic thesis adopted is that as union
demands become more ambitious in the context
of developing collective bargaining the union As is pointed out, empirical research on the
moves along the “information scale”. Starting at negotiation and use of such an agreement would
the bottom of the scale, with an acceptance of require a longitudinal research study to be car-
company information as it comes, the union ried out. indeed it is a possible criticism of many
moves through points such as asking for addi- studies carried out in the area of trade union use
tional information, seeking access to the man- of information in collective bargaining that they
agement information system and changing the are essentially short term and static in nature
system towards the ultimate point of developing (e.g. Reeves & McGovern, 1981; Mitchell et al.,
its own trade union information system. The 1980).
level of democracy in the union is considered to
be the yardstick of its ability to improve its use of Jackson-Cox, McQueeney & Tbirkell(I984)
company information. Whereas formal democ- Jackson-Cox et al. see the provision of com-
racy can be said to exist in all unions, the pany information as being, “particularly impor-
relationship between union officials and the tant in the development of ‘intelligence’ for the
membership ultimately resting on a voting identification of new issues relating to the com-
nexus, decision making within the union in pany and changes in management strategy
many cases has become an autocratic one way which may give rise to issues which are not yet
process. Moore et al.. in their use of the term fully developed or disclosed” (p.264). Thus
democracy are referring to the need for active as their approach differs somewhat from that of
334 DAVID L OWEN and ANTHONY J. LLOYD

Moore et al. (1979, 1981) who argued that ders such as conveners or senior stewards
union representatives should formulate objec- whose time will be principally devoted to union
tives and strategies for using information before duties, and forums such as joint shop stewards
taking steps to acquire it, in other words adopt- committees, in order to overcome segmenta-
ing a decision making approach. Some support tion, establish common criteria and standards in
for Jackson-Cox et d’s position is provided by relation to particular issues and possibly secure
Gospel ( 1978) who pointed out that the deci- membership consent to external trade union
sion oriented approach is not a one way process standards. Indeed they conclude horn the seven-
whereby development of priorities leads to the teen situational studies carried out that,
identification and use of information, but is in
Only if. uses of information are accompanied by the
fact a two way process.
development and recognition of institutions, leading to
changes in union expectations, will trade unions be able
For information itselfprovides a source of standards and
to challenge management’s prerogative to make many
criteria which can generate objectives. In other words,
unllateral decisions. In the meantime, the role of com-
disclosure can activate objectives by changing percep
pany information as inputs to trade union decision mod-
tions of such things as pay discrepancies, job security
els will continue to be extremely limited (p.269).
prospects, managerial efficiency etc. In this way, the
acquisition of information can lead to a stronger motiva-
tion for further disclosure of information (p.24).
As well as highlighting the crucial importance
of membership attitudes on shop steward
Jackson-Cox et al. however point out that approaches to information use, certain other
there are certain constraints to be overcome by observations made by Jackson-Cox et al. relating
the union side in. identifying and indeed to the possible importance of variations in the
legitimising issues within a particular bargaining nature of the domestic organisation are also
field. For identification of an issue only comes worthy of note. For example, some evidence is
about through the application of criteria and produced, albeit limited, of the approach
standards demonstrating its structural rele- adopted by full time officials to the disclosure
vance, furthermore for such an issue to be recog- issue. In one case (Company F) the full time offi-
nised as legitimate bilaterally agreed standards cial, who played a major role in the annual wage
must apply. The major problem here of course is negotiations, tried to initiate, unsuccessfully as it
that there are no external institutional standards turned out, a process of formal disclosure to the
relating to the provision of financial information, district office of the union rather than linking it
such as there are in the field of health and safety to specific workplace or company issues. A simi-
at work concerning for example the appoint- lar process was observed in two other cases
ment of both management safety officers and where full time officials encouraged generalised
trade union safety representatives as well as the disclosure requests by shop stewards but again
establishment of safety committees. didn’t relate such requests to specitlc issues or
A further major constraint may be provided by use them to develop the domestic institutions.
domestic trade union institutions, particularly Given this evidence of a restricted approach to
where there is segmented trade union represen- disclosure by full time officials it is perhaps sur-
tation and the shop steward’s source of criteria prising that Jackson-Cox et al. place such a high
and standards is derived internally from the degree of emphasis on the need for shop stew-
membership. In such a situation the shop stew- ards in developing their perceptual field to have
ards approach towards the acquisition and use access and commitment to external union stan-
of company information may well be con- dards and to mobilise external resources. Whilst
strained by the limited expectations and stand- recognising the need for suitable company wide
ards of the membership. Jackson-Cox et al. place steward organisations it could be argued that the
great emphasis on the development of work- factory consciousness exhibited by the Ford
place institutions, represented by position hol- shop stewards (Beynon, 1973) may promote
THE USE OF FINANCIAL INFOR!MATION BY TRADE UNION NEGOTIATORS 335

more efficient information usage than the approach to information disclosure (Gospel,
involvement of the external union would 1978).
achieve.
Evidence is also produced of ditIerences in Reeves G McGovern (1981)
approach to the disclosure issue adopted by Reeves & McGovern present ten case studies
white collar and blue collar union officials. of information disclosure ordered in such a way
to show that,
In some instances white collar union representatives
showed more interest in the acquisition of information as two key conditions namely shop stewards having
than their manual counterparts, but, with two excep- the interest or skill to utilise company information in bar-
tions, conditions for the establishment of institutional gaining, and management providing a negotiating or par-
mechanisms for the sharing of this expertise with manual ticipative structure in which they could do so, become
representatives were lacking (p.263). increasingly more favourable to the use of company
information by shop stewards, its use nevertheless
remains fairly limited (p.52).
In general it would appear that the manual
union representatives were unwilling to co-
However, it would be pertinent to point out at
operate with representatives from white collar
this stage that a careful scrutiny of the case
supervisory unions, or unable to do so due to
studies presented indicates that the conclusion
unfavourable membership attitudes, despite the
drawn tends to overstate the degree of manage-
specialist expertise the latter could contribute
ment “openness” in terms of information pro-
to the handling of information. It may well be
vided. For example, in no less than eight of the
that as many white collar unionists are used to
studies mention is specifically made of manage-
dealing with financial information in their daily
ment not disclosing information, on matters
work, thus making the obtaining and interpreta-
ranging from pricing policy and unit costs to the
tion of such information relatively easy, they will
contents of a consultants’ report on manning
view its use in the drawing up of annual wage
levels, or of management not providing informa-
claims more favourably than their blue collar
tion in a suitably disaggregated form. Further-
counterparts. Indeed it is interesting to note in
more, in one particular plant (Case 8) where a
this context that Jackson-Cox et al. point to one
participative scheme had been set up, the vehi-
example (Company C) of a white collar union
cle for participation being a joint management-
senior representative initiating a claim for dis-
union committee, it is noted that, “certain
closure as a mechanism to attract membership.
A major difficulty in promoting information
figures, however, were not revealed. One was
the profit made by the plant . . In line with this
usage in domestic bargaining is provided by
withholding of the profit figure, the plants
shop steward mistrust of management. Jackson-
period accounts were also not shown to JC rep-
Cox et al. state the problem succinctly,
resentatives” (p.37). Yet Reeves & McGovern
The willingness of management to provide information consider this as an example of existing condi-
in order to encourage wage restraint tended to re-inforce tions being very favourable to the use of com-
the belief amongst many stewards that they were better pany information by shop stewards! Indeed, the
off without company information, and made them suspi-
case studies presented (Cases 7-9) in which par-
cious of all information received directly, or indirectly,
from management; and hence their desire to check ticipative schemes were in operation provided
against information from other sources (p.266). examples only of joint consultation rather than
joint decision making.
Despite our reservations in respect of the
This would appear to reinforce the argument conclusions drawn by Reeves & McGovern they
of Moore et al. that it is vital for unions to seek do present a number of illuminating observa-
access to the management information system tions which are worthy of mention. In particular
and ultimately aim to develop their own infor- the problem of lack of membership support con-
336 DAVID L. OWEN and ANTHONY J. LLOYD

straining stewards in their use of company infor- expertise in handling financial data, lack of
mation, referred to by Jackson-Cox et al. is opportunity to obtain and use information at the
mentioned in six of the case studies. The prob- right level or lack of a strategy also seem to pro-
lem for the shop steward is concisely stated ‘I. . vide corroborative evidence of the validity of
bargaining over budgets, however theoretically Moore et al.‘s constraints model. A further con-
desirable, was believed to be something that straint worthy of note is also mentioned which
management would not acceed to lightly, whilst obviously affects the union side’s ability to use
their members would not be prepared to sup- financial information, that of lack of expertise
port them in what it was believed they would see caused by a high turnover of shop stewards
as a remote and irrelevant exercise” (Case 5, (Case 8).
p.24). Furthermore, in the only example Some evidence of company information pos-
encountered of company information playing a sessing a potential usefulness for shop stewards,
part in wage bargaining, shop stewards in this in view of their interest in acquiring “intelli-
case accepting management’s assessment of abil- gence” about a company in order to make some
ity to pay, the settlement provoked a very hostile assessment of job security, is provided, being
reaction from the membership despite job losses specifically referred to in five of the case studies.
being avoided (Case 3). In another case the exis- For example in Case 2 they write, “The main
tence of an explicit management policy on issues that concerned the union representatives,
employee communications, introduced in and indeed virtually the only purpose they had
response to criticisms from the workforce of the clearly in mind when seeking company informa-
way they were kept informed on company mat- tion, was whether anything was happening that
ters, did not result in any pressure being applied could affect the job prospects of their members”
on shop stewards by their constituents to use (p. 11). Similar evidence of a greater union
financial information in wage bargaining (Case interest in using financial information in respect
6). Finally, shop stewards were unable to of decisions concerning security of employment
mobilise membership support when they is also provided by Sherer et al. ( 1981). How-
attempted to employ financial arguments to ever Reeves & McGovern take the analysis a
counter the management proposal to close Dun- stage further by using a specific case study (Case
lop’s tyre factory at Speke on Merseyside (Case 10) to indicate the circumstances in which
10). union representatives will abandon their tradi-
Reeves & McGovern concur with Jackson Cox tional stance of merely reacting to managerial
et al.3 viewpoint that shop steward mistrust of initiatives in favour of using information in order
management presents a major dil3iculty in pro- to positively extend collective bargaining. In
moting information usage in domestic bargain- this particular case however, the Dunlop Case
ing. The effect of past experiences, leading to a study, the plan drawn up by the manual shop
general mistrust of management on the part of stewards in order to oppose management’s plan
shop stewards, is cited as a contributory factor to to close the factory came too late to have any
a lack of union interest in information disclosure effec?. This is hardly surprising, for, as Jackson-
in four of the studies. A number of other factors Cox et al. indicated, union representatives are at
cited by Reeves & McGovern as inhibiting shop a major disadvantage in dealing with non-
stewards in using information, such as lack of routine issues, of which redundancy questions

’ This case study also provides interesting evidence of the possible different approaches to use of information by different
unions. The managers belonging to the Association of Scientilic Technical and Managerial StaBs (ASTMS) drew up their own
plan to avert closure which entailed a large reduction in the manual workforce. Not surprisingly thii was totally unacceptable
to the manual unions looking, “too much like the kind of plan any management team might draw up in order to enforce redun-
dancies and reduce unit costs” (p.49).
THE USE OF FINANCIAL INFORMATION BY TRADE UNION NEGOTIATORS 337

are a prime example, as they only become and cost minimisation rather than, for example,
involved after management has taken the vital job protection or social costs and benefits aris-
initial decisions. ing from production. Nevertheless despite their
undoubted awareness of such political and
social bias Moore and Levies overriding theme
THE SSRC SPONSORED STUDIES: A CRITIQUE is that unions need more information not less.
For corporate financial information to play a
The role offinancial information in collective major role in the bargaining process there must
bargaining obviously be a large measure of specific and
The studies outlined above all tend to unques- shared calculative rationality inherent in union-
tioningly accept the potential importance of cor- management negotiations. In their acceptance
porate financial information to trade union of the potential importance of financial informa-
negotiators. Jackson-Cox et al. see a role for such tion we must assume that the SSRC researchers
information in developing the perceptual field of also accept the existence of such a rational
shop stewards, Reeves & McGovern appear to underpinning to negotiations. Other writers in
see financial information acquisition and use as the field seem to have adopted the same view-
being particularly useful in developing opposi- point. For example Maunders ( 1981) has
tion to closure and redundancy threats whilst suggested that where the union is regarded as
Moore & Levie regard the acquisition of further acting as the labour market agent of employees
information as being an essential first step in the economic arguments for disclosure are vir-
extending the scope of collective bargaining. tually identical to such arguments relating to
The latter study is indeed the only one to seri- shareholders, i.e. to facilitate the efficient alloca-
ously begin to develop a critical perspective tion of resources. In the latter case the purpose
towards information flowing from management of disclosure is to facilitate the efficient allo-
information systems. Whereas Moore & Levies cation of capital, in the former, labour. Further
emphasis on the union side increasing their use support for this rational view of the negotiating
of management accounting information echoes process is provided by Pope & Peel ( 198 1) who
earlier conclusions reached by Cuthbert & present a model of union decision-making which
Whitaker ( 1977) they go further in stressing the relies on expectations being formed “rationally”
need for seeking access to the management and based on the “optimal” use of information.
information system, so that data may be reformu- This assumption of specific and shared ration-
lated to take alternative criteria than those ality has however come under recent attack, not-
adopted by management into account for deci- ably from Ogden & Bougen ( 1985) who argue
sion making purposes.’ As an illustration of the that the bargaining process cannot usefully be
restrictive assumptions and value judgements modelled as a rational economic procedure con-
underpinning management information systems cerned with efficient resource allocation. As
they utilise an example of union trustees of a staff well as pointing to the underlying antagonistic
pension fund being unable to obtain financial basis of capital-labour relations they also ques-
information on potential investments which did tion whether many conventional management
not rely on “city” assumptions about what rep- decision making processes within the organisa-
resented a good investment rather than includ- tion are themselves the product of applied
ing social dimensions. Another form of bias in economic rationality. For example, they draw
the traditional information system is of course our attention particularly to studies highlighting
provided by its concentration on profitability the anarchic tendencies of decision processes

“Jaclson-Cox et al also stress the need for the union side to develop alternative criteria in the use of financial information
but don’t articulate their argument as fully as Moore & Levie.
338 DAVID L OWEN and ANTHONY J. LLOYD

(Cohen et al., 1972) and decision-making pro- representatives are excluded (Batstone, 1980).
cesses under conditions of uncertainty concem- Due to their apparently limited conception of
ing the objectives and cause-effect relationships the roles played by financial information and
of decision-making (Thompson & Tuden, 1959). consequent unquestioning acceptance of the
In the latter situation Burchell et al. (1980) potential importance of such information in the
point to the lack of scope for accounting systems bargaining process, the SSRC researchers fail to
to operate as “answer machines” in the context fully articulate possible explanations for the low
of purely computational decision-making and rates of utilisation of corporate financial infor-
argue that instead they are used as “ammunition mation by union negotiators found in the studies
machines”, to promote the positions of particu- undertaken. However in view of continued legis-
lar interested parties, in situations of high uncer- lative interest in the disclosure issue, exhibited
tainty over objectives, and as “rationalisation for example in Section 1 of the Employment Act
machines”, legitimizing and justifying actions 1982, a consideration of such explanations
that have already been decided upon, when seems merited. It is to this issue we now turn.
there is a high degree of uncertainty over cause
and effect relationships. Thus in the environ- Union objectives
ment of uncertainty characterising the collec- Certain researchers have looked at the provi-
tive bargaining context accounting information sion of information for collective bargaining
can function as an ideological mechanism for purposes in the context of the development of
propogating and re-inforcing managerial values decision models for union representatives
and purposes (Ogden & Bougen, 1985) rather (Climo, 1976; Cooper & Essex, 1977) entailing
than as an objective and neutral input into the initially a specificiation being made of union
bargaining process. This may be particularly objectives. However the search for universal
apparent in the limited range of arguments, objectives could prove ti-uitless. For example,
focussing on potential profitability, that workers the objectives of a traditional craft union may
are able to employ in relation to their employers well differ considerably from those of a manage-
in the case of plant closure and redundancy situ- rial white collar union, the former being largely
ations (Batstone, 1980). Such a role for account- concerned with the protection of long standing
ing information may of course provide an status and differentials, whilst the latter may
acceptable “rule of the game” for groups such as actively seek changes giving them greater par-
shareholders and creditors but cannot be ticipation in decision making.
acceptable to the union side when used in an Furthermore, such generalised objectives as
industrial relations context (Bougen & Ogden, are specified may not indicate an increased role
1981). for corporate financial information in collective
The assumption of specific and shared ration- bargaining. For, as Cooper & Essex ( 1977) point
ality based on economic considerations, and the out, it is unlikely that union objectives can be
consequent acceptance of the importance of considered purely in terms of economic factors,
formal information flowing from the manage- a more fundamental interest may indeed centre
ment information system in the collective bar- on contesting managerial control (Ogden &
gaining situation, may indeed be further ques- Bougen, 1985). Such an interest can only be pur-
tioned. For example, one may cite the preva- sued by seeking to change the whole nature of
lence of informal planning and assessment prac- organisational arrangements, i.e. the rules and
tices in organisations (Earl & Hopwood, 1980) procedures by which the organisation operates
and the consequent incompleteness of formal together with the system of values, goals and
rationality and routinisation leading to the priorities which permeate them (Batstone,
development of powerful informal management 1980). There appears little scope for using cor-
networks for the formulation of plans and prop- porate financial information in this context for
osals, networks from which workers and their very little can be achieved at individual organisa-
THE USE OF FINANCIAL INFORhIATlON BY TRADE UNION NEGOTIATORS 339

tional levels. Activity at a higher level is required minimisation constraints, in the union
as such objectives are most profitability pursued negotiators decision model.
by attempting to change the economic, social It should also be pointed out that pay settle-
and political status quo, i.e. in seeking changes in ments in individual plants or companies have a
the balance of power between classes in society macro, as well as micro, economic impact.
(Cooper & Essex, !977). Scargill ( 1978, p.4) Hence government incomes policies are de-
puts the point most forcibly, signed to hold down wage increases without
regard, in general, to particular company cir-
You can make all the plans that you want in society as far cumstances. Even in the absence of incomes
as your individual organisation is concerned, and both
policies, Galbraith ( 1967) argues that unions
the multinational and national capitalist organisations
will crush you with their iron heel. It is a nonsense, it play a significant role in economic planning by
is a fallacy, to believe for one moment that we can live in standardising wage costs between different
a capitalist society and attempt to work with it. industrial firms and ensuring that changes in
wages will occur at approximately the same
In so far as unions do pursue economic objec- time, thus greatly facilitating price maintenance
tives their aim here may well be to achieve a and control. A major drawback to many of the
“fair” settlement for all their members, regard- models developed of union decision making
less of the particular circumstances of the com- which place a high degree of emphasis on the
pany they work for. As Lindop ( 1979) points out, use of corporate financial information lies in
people tend to judge incomes on the basis of their concentration on micro-economic factors
other people carrying out similar jobs, this being and consequent underestimation of the impact
the basis on which fairness is determined. Thus of macro economic and wider social factors on
he forsees a move away from plant bargaining union objectives.
towards larger bargaining units when economic
circumstances worsen, as such agreements pro- The potential for integrative bargaining
vide a “safety net” for workers in plants Perhaps the strongest argument for a financial
adversely affected, who may depend on the sec- information input into the collective bargaining
urity of national or company wide structures and process is that a move towards integrative bar-
the mutual support of fellow trade unionists. gaining, which functions to find common or
Daniel ( 198 1) indeed suggests that in seeking complementary interests and to solve problems
social justice unions would prefer to restrain the confronting both parties to the negotiations, will
earnings of members in favourable cir- thereby be encouraged (Foley & Maunders,
cumstances rather than depress the relative pay 1977). Such a view owes much to the pluralist
of members in less favourable situations. Further school of industrial relations which, whilst
evidence of the importance of the comparability accepting conflict as being inherent in industrial
factor for union negotiators is provided by societies, assumes that accommodation will be
Brown & Sisson (1975) and Blackaby (1978) achieved between conflicting interest groups
who points to the union negotiator’s concern based on compromise (Fox, 1966). Whereas
with ensuring that the group he or she repre- some empirical support for the existence of
sents does not fall behind but gets at least the integrative bargaining is provided by Morley &
“going rate”. The other major concern of union Stephenson ( 1977) other writers such as Dob-
negotiators - to obtain increases for their mem- son ( 1982) have questioned the degree of
bers at least equal to the rise in the cost of living, pluralism in industrial relations pointing out that
may also reflect union concern with social jus- many managements adopt a unitarist approach,
tice. Such a concern with social justice suggests particularly in the realms of investment deci-
a very limited role for corporate financial data, sions, production methods and business policy
produced by management information systems generally. Blackburn (1973, p.180) puts the
operating under profit maximisation and cost point more strongly, “To imagine that the per-
340 DAVID L. OWEN and ANTHONY J. LLOYD

sormel manager, production manager or super- larly of manual unions, in plant level bargaining
visor has any choice other than to extract (Daniel, 1976). Even though these latter studies
surplus value as efficiently as possible from his may be criticised on the grounds that they
labour force is quite absurd. That is to say they ascribed a purely “answer machine” role to
seek to raise the value of what the worker accounting systems and tested the respondents
produces as much as possible above the cost of accordingly, nevertheless it would appear
hiring him”. Thus it would appear possible to necessary for union negotiators to understand
question the potential for integrative bargaining the operation of present accounting systems if
in many negotiating situations, particularly if they are to appreciate their limitations, particu-
one sees the interests of capital and labour as larly their role as an ideological mechanism, and
being diametrically opposed (Ogden & Bougen, develop suitable alternative systems and criteria.
1985) or the union-management relationship as For negotiators who are ill equipped to utilise
basically adversarial in nature (Craft, 1981). financial arguments effectively, due to lack of
Hence considerable doubts can be raised over understanding or poor union organisation, Gos-
the potential role of information disclosure in pel ( 1978, p.26) sounds a warning note arguing
promoting integrative bargaining. that in these circumstances, “greater disclosure
would be likely to prove at least ineffective and
The capacity of union negotiators to use at worst harmful, since it would serve to
financial arguments strengthen the position of management and
Wilders ( 1979) points to the lack of belief on reduce the independence of union representa-
the part of employees in many companies in a tives”.
direct relationship between profit and pay.
Given this situation one may question the extent Information as a power resource
to which union negotiators are motivated to use The proposition that information is a power
financial arguments if their success in bargaining resource has attracted much support in the field
is to be judged on comparability grounds by a of industrial relations and probably explains the
membership which perceives no causal link bet- reluctance of some managers to lend their sup-
ween high pay settlements and redundancies. port to the principle of increased financial infor-

Furthermore, even if a particular negotiator was mation disclosure. However, it should be


to accept the existence of a relationship bet- realised that the mere possession of information
ween pay and profits, considerable doubts may does little to change the balance of power in
be raised as to how well equipped are most union-management relations. As Pettigrew
negotiators at domestic level to employ financial (1972, p.189) stresses, “Power resources must
arguments. Such an approach to bargaining not only by possessed by an actor, they must be
requires well developed union research and cont?viled by him . . . Control, may not be
training facilities for use by shop stewards and enough, there is also the issue of the skillful use
full time local officials (Radice, 1971). However, of resources”. Furthermore he argues that, “The
available evidence indicates that most research final decision outcome will evolve out of the
departments are small and overworked (Marsh process of power mobilisation attempted by
& Rosewell, 1976) and trade union education each party in support of its demand” (p.202). In
services are overstretched and under financed the context of Pettigrew’s analysis one could
(Cuthbert & Whitaker, 1977). Thus evidence point out that:
provided by Lyall (1975) and Mitchell et al. ( 1) Management controls the communication
(1980) pointing to a very low level of com- process thus giving them a wide discretion
prehension of financial information by shop ste- over what to disclose, or not to disclose.
wards should cause us little surprise, although it
should perhaps give rise to some concern given (2) Management possession of the means of
the major role played by shop stewards, particu- production enables them to command
THE USE OF FINANCIAL INFORMATION BY TRADE UNION NEGOTlATORS 341

decision making procedures (Burkitt, adopt a more critical perspective towards the
1981).’ role of financial information in collective bar-
gaining, rather than to completely deny its
(3) There would appear to be a large difference
potential importance to the union negotiator.
in the degree of expert power in the use of
Certainly the TUC see information provision as
information operating in favour of manage-
providing the potential basis for a degree of de
ment and against the shop steward.
facto union control over aspects of a company’s
(4) The potential for union negotiators to activities (TUC, 1974) and, looking at the ques-
mob&se membership support based on tion from a d*erent perspective Craft ( 198 1)
detailed financial arguments, as opposed to fears that increased disclosure of information
comparability or cost of living claims, may lead to the union side questioning the
would appear to be limited given the lack of appropriateness of management allocation deci-
perceived relationship between pay and sions, seeking to focus negotiation on the budget
profits referred to earlier. process and challenging management on the use
of particular accounting and Bnancial practices.
Thus there is a real danger that the mere pos-
However we would argue that the potential
session of information by the union side without
importance and usefulness of financial informa-
any corresponding power to influence decision-
tion to the union negotiator not only depends
making, due to their exclusion from the key
upon how successful the union side is in
management policy making networks (Batstone,
developing alternative criteria to those used by
1980) will merely lead to them being “sucked
management for assessing organisational perfor-
into management”. Indeed management may
mance (Ogden & Bougen, 1985) but is also con-
adopt a policy of information disclosure in order
tingent upon the different objectives of, and
to increase employee identification with the
roles played by, the individual negotiators con-
company and hence lessen their identification
cerned.
with the union (Jackson-Cox et al., 1984).
Cooper & Essex ( 1977) put forward the view
As a final illustration of the contention that
that, “In assessing the information that will be
possession of information does not necessarily
relevant to employee representatives we must
lead to an increase in power we would cite the
specify the particular representatives involved”
argument of Smith & Manley ( 1973) that disclo-
(p.203). However, they fail to develop their
sure can do little to help groups of workers with
arguments sufficiently in that they only consider
little effective industrial strength to back up
the role of the full-time official in the context of
negotiating demands or groups with few
national wage negotiations, and, whilst suggest-
resources. Disclosure in, effect means more
ing that shop stewards in different unions, and
power to the powerful.
even the same union in different locations, may
perform dilTerent roles, omit to discuss this par-
ticular point further. Unfortunately, a similar fail-
ing is apparent in the SSRC sponsored studies.
THE IMPORTANCE OF VARIATIONS IN THE Whereas the situational studies themselves do
NATURE OF THE DOMESTIC ORGANISATION: succeed in highlighting important variations in
A STRATEGY FOR FURTHER INVESTIGATION the nature of the domestic organisation, the con-
clusions the researchers draw seem to point to a
Our intention in the preceding section was to mistaken belief in the existence of a universal
highlight the need for future researchers to “identikit” union representative, at least so far as

In particular empirical research has highlighted managerial control of strategic decision making, the union side being
restricted to a reactive stance enabling them to merely impede implementation of decisions with no power to initiate and
influence decision topics (Wilson ef al.. 1982).
342 DAVID L. OWEN and ANTHONY J. LLOYD

the potential role of financial information in the major role played by shop stewards in plant level
bargaining situation is concerned. collective bargaining (e.g. Daniel, 1976). The
Moore & Levie, for example, whilst recognis- increasing importance of the shop steward in
ing union structure as a particular constraint on workplace industrial relations is highlighted by
the effective use of information, nevertheless see Brown’s ( 1981) estimation that the number of
the ambitiousness of union demands as being a full-time stewards in manufacturing industry
universal change agent, notwithstanding the quadrupled in the decade 19661976, and that
structural differences both between different this rapid rate of growth continued at least dur-
unions and within the same union in different ing the following two years. Multi-unionism
locations. Whereas they suggest that trade union within the plant and the size of the workforce are
ambitions and trade union democracy are two suggested as being the major factors stimulating
dynamic variables that a union more or less con- the development of steward organisations. How-
trols itself, and can greatly enhance its use of ever, whilst accepting the importance of the
information, we would argue that changes in above rate of growth in numbers of stewards,
these variables hinge on the roles played by indi- and associated organisational developments
vidual union officials and their relationship to such as the emergence of joint shop stewards
their constituent members. Also Jackson-Cox et committees, the continuing role of the full-time
al. whilst highlighting the potential impact of a official in providing a link between the work-
number of variations in the nature of the domes- place organisation and the outside union move-
tic organisation, such as the importance of differ- ment should not be under-estimated. Such a link
ing membership attitudes, the roles played by is important in that it gives domestic bargainers
full-time officials and different approaches the strength they need to match the employers
towards information used by white and blue col- economic power (Jenkins and Sherman, 1977).
lar representatives respectively, still see the Indeed, the full-time official can play a major part
major role for company information as being to in collective bargaining, for example being cal-
develop generally the perceptual .fieId of an led into the negotiations when a “failure to
apparently homogeneous shop steward user agree” is registered between management and
group. Finally, whereas Reeves & McGovern plant level union representatives. The role of the
point to a considerable variation in the degree of full-time official in wage negotiations appears to
interest on the part of shop stewards in making be particularly important in white collar unions
use of the company information that was pro- (Batstone et al., 1977) and, potentially, blue col-
vided, they fail to develop a suitable analytical lar unions in smaller workplaces, where the full-
framework within which such variations may be time official is clearly a major resource for ste-
related to differences in roles and objectives of wards (Winch, 1980). Furthermore, there has
particular stewards. been recent speculation that the recently
We would strongly contend that further inves- diminished power of the shop steward in a time
tigations in this field must pay far more explicit of recession and high unemployment may lead
attention to the possible importance of varia- to demands on the part of trade unionists for
tions in the nature of the domestic organisation new union coalitions and a more centralised dis-
(Batstone et al., 1977). We therefore tentatively cipline (Brown & Sisson, 1983). The latter
present the following analytical framework development would undoubtedly increase the
which may provide a strategy to guide future influence of the full-time official on collective
researchers. bargaining and tend to erode that of the shop ste-
ward, even at plant level.
Possible differences in approach to the use of It is important to note that full-time officials
financial information by full-time union may have attitudes and objectives very different
officials and shop s&war& horn those of shop stewards. A full-time official
Much attention has recently focused on the has no link with a particular company and may
THE USE OF FINANCIAL INFORMATION BY TRADE UNION NEGOTlATORS 343

therefore be far more concerned with average ling to exchange strategic planning information
earnings levels in his or her particular area than in order to gain an insight into likely union reac-
fighting to achieve higher settlements for groups tions to planned courses of action. In pursuing
of workers in more profitable companies. Thus such a strategy management may deal solely
detailed financial data relating to a particular with a small number of “key” stewards (Terry,
company may be of little relevance to the full- 1982) thereby fostering strong leadership ten-
time official and, in any case, due to the shortage dencies in the stewards so recognised (Batstone
of full-time officers in most British trade unions et al., 1977) a point we shall return to later.
(Clegg, 1979), the workload undertaken, in Of course in the bargaining situation stewards
terms of the number of companies dealt with, have a need for information over and above that
must limit the amount of time available for offered by management (Partridge, 1978) and
spending on one particular set of negotiations. do indeed gain informal access to information
Furthermore, whereas the services of the through a network of sources and contacts
union’s research department may be called upon which frequently bemuse the personnel man-
in the case of certain “prestige” wage claims, ager. For example, information may be obtained
such facilities are unlikely to be available for from the work process itself, in which case
plant level negotiations. By contrast, as Pedler the steward’s knowledge of the information
(1973) indicates, shop stewards, although gathering process may encourage a critical
essential to the union and hardly less so to man- appreciation and questioning of data supplied by
agement, are mainly responsible to their mem- management, or alternatively, from the steward
bers. Thus, although stewards often place great and union network. Empirical studies by Cooper
emphasis upon the importance of the larger & Essex ( 1977) and Sherer et al. ( 1981) have
union as the embodiment of union principles highlighted the importance of the latter source
and as a basis for their self identity (Batstone et of information to the steward. Nevertheless it
al., 1977) they may still exhibit a high degree of should be stressed that, despite such oppor-
factory consciousness (Beynon, 1973) and tunities to gain informal access to, presumably
hence pay far more attention to the financial cir- less biassed, information being exploited by
cumstances of their particular company in carry- shop stewards, there is little evidence of ste-
ing out wage negotiations than would the full- wards being able to use the information
time official. obtained in order to contest managerial control
Although the steward’s exclusion from key over strategic decision making (Wilson et al.,
management coalitions (Batstone, 1980) may 1982).
act as a constraint on the acquisition and effec- Whilst Batstone et al. (1977) point to an
tive use of sensitive information, this effect may important process of accommodation and
be countered somewhat by the possibility of mutual interdependence between full-time offI
informal acquisition and access to informal net- cials and the shop steward network, reflecting
work sources. As Partridge (1978) points out, their broad consensus upon goals and a recogni-
management itself is not a unitary phenomenon tion of each other’s power, certain areas of
and different parts of management have different mutual suspicion and potential conflict exist.
perspectives about their organisations. Hence Hemingway ( 1978) highlights this point in con-
management-Workgroup bargaining does not sidering everyday union government as, “a pro-
take place along one link, rather it is a multiplex cess of bargaining at all levels of trade union
relationship with rival management coalitions organisation”, and, in the context of our particu-
and stewards bargaining informally amongst lar argument, Foley & Maunders ( 1977) indicate
themselves. Informal contact between senior that one reason why the official union structure
stewards and individual managers may thus pro- is anxious to be the prime focus for information
vide a useful means of information acquisition disclosure is that direct disclosure to stewards
for the steward, with management possibly wil- confers recognition, status and authority which
344 DAVID L. OWEN and ANTHONYJ. LLOYD

may one day constitute a challenge to existing increase in union density amongst white collar
structures. The different viewpoints of full-time employees in manufacturing in recent years.
officials and shop stewards are further evi- Given the contrast in work situations and possi-
denced by their respective attitudes towards bly in orientations to work and the union
shop steward training. The prime interest of the (Batstone et al., 1977) white collar union rep-
former group appears to be that of focusing resentatives may well adopt a different approach
training on the affairs of the union, in order to to the bargaining situation than do their blue
cement loyalty to and involvement with the collar counterparts, in particular their attitudes
union, whereas stewards themselves wish to towards the use of financial information may dif-
acquire skills in handlingworkplace problems so fer considerably. Before considering this point
as to represent their members more effectively further two additional factors relating to white
(Lover, 1976). collar bargaining should be borne in mind.
Whereas we have, in discussing the possible Firstly full-time officials tend to play a more
differences in attitudes, and roles played by, prominent role in collective bargaining than
shop stewards and full-time officials, suggested appears to be the case in manual unions (Clegg,
that shop stewards may, due to their factory con- 1979). For example, Batstone et al. suggest that
sciousness and access to informal information stewards on the stti side tend to defer to full-
sources, adopt a more positive approach to the time officials and are more generally inclined
use of corporate financial information it is as to accept their leadership in terms of ideas and
well to note that an alternative viewpoint contributions. However there is a growing ten-
appears tenable. Thus Mills ( 1978) suggests that dency in certain industries, notably engineering,
only by strengthening central union authority for stewards to play a more central role in the
over the membership will unions be enabled to negotiating process, due to the greater preva-
play a role in strategic planning, a role which, as lence of decentralised bargaining at establish-
we have already noted, is at present denied ment level. Therefore we shah confine our atten-
to them (Wilson et al., 1982). Furthermore, tion to the role of the shop steward, although
according to Mills, union amalgamations will earlier remarks concerning the possible differ-
assist the development of such a role as the ence in objectives and attitudes of full-time offi-
resulting larger unions will be stronger in terms cials may be of particular relevance in the con-
of negotiating power and ability to finance the text of white collar bargaining and should be
necessary research and other supporting ser- borne in mind.
vices. Secondly, white collar bargaining in manufac-
Whichever viewpoint one accepts there does turing industry is often extremely fragmented
appear to exist sutEcient grounds for hypothesis- (Clegg, 1979) with each main union bargaining
ing that the approaches of the shop steward and separately with management. Such fragmen-
the full-time official to the question of informa- tation contrasts with the unified approach
tion acquisition and use will be very different, adopted by the manual unions, which tend to
and that future researchers would do well to bargain as a unit at plant level, and must have
bear this in mind. Furthermore care should be considerable repercussions on the degree of
taken not to underestimate the actual and poten- “power” at the disposal of the union negotiator
tial role of the full-time official in collective bar- involved. Furthermore, given the differences in
gaining, particularly in view of the possible areas membership characteristics between white col-
of conflict with shop stewards. lar unions, some representing mainly super-
visors and middle managers, whilst others draw
Possible differences in approach to the use of the bulk of their membership from lower grade
financial information by white collar and clerical workers, their approaches to bargaining
blue collar union representatives may differ considerably. Whereas we shall con-
Clegg ( 1979) points to an exceptionally rapid sider white collar unions as a unit, as distinct
THE USE OF FINANCIAL INFORMATION BY TRADE UNION NEGOTlATORS 345

from blue collar unions, the possibility of differ- A study by Nicholson et al. ( 1980) indicates
ences in values and objectives between different that only a minority of white collar stewards
unions should be realised and indeed serves to share the critical stance on union matters of a
highlight the necessity to pay due regard to the majority of their members and that they are in
individual nature of the organisation concerned fact attitudinally closer to blue collar stewards
when conducting empirical investigations. than they are to their own members. Batstone et
Attention was drawn earlier to the important aI. also found some evidence of white collar ste-
effect of membership attitudes on shop steward wards espousing a conflict image of industry,
approaches to information use (Jackson-Cox et although the strength of this observation is tem-
al., Reeves & McGovern). Interestingly there is pered somewhat by an observed greater degree
some evidence of profound ditferences in work- of ambivalence over the nature of relationships
place attitudes on the part of white collar and in industry, a less certain commitment to “union
blue collar workers. For instance Foley & Maun- principles” and a more ready espousal of a belief
ders ( 1977) point out that traditionally the loy- in industrial harmony and individualism than
alty of white collar workers was assumed to be was expressed by blue collar stewards. Certainly
direct to the company and Batstone et al. find Batstone et al. found enough white collar
evidence indicating less of a commitment to stewards placing emphasis on the role of the ste-
what may generally be defined as trade unionism ward in “ensuring harmony with management”
amongst staff workers than on the shop floor. to suggest that corporate financial information
Mercer & Weir (1972) suggest that the white could be of potential usefulness to them in the
collar worker’s involvement in trade unionism is negotiating situation. However, it is questiona-
based on instrumental considerations, relating ble whether many white collar stewards have
to the possible efficacy of trade unions in obtain- the necessary resources under their control so
ing tangible benefits for their members, as much as to be able to pressure management into dis-
as on ideological considerations. Also Mercer & closing information, and to enable them to use
Weir point to an overall belief on the part of that information effectively.
white collar workers that unions should main- Batstone et al. point out that the union plays a
tain effective consultation with management at more central role in the lives of shop floor work-
all levels which seems to evidence a functional ers, due to the greater degree of control exerted
and consultative view of the ordering of intra- over the everyday work situation and, via closed
organisational relationships. shop agreements, on recruitment, than of the
The closer identification of the white collar white collar staff. The nature of shop floor work
worker with the company and associated instru- is such as to promote collective behaviour, thus
mental approach to trade unionism appears to shop floor workers take their problems to their
suggest a potentially more important role for stewards, whereas the individualistic nature of
financial arguments in white collar collective tasks performed, and of the reward structure,
bargaining, particularly in the context of leads staff workers to approach management
mobilising membership support, than in blue individually. Thus the status of the steward is
collar bargaining. This process may be encour- reduced in the eyes of both membership and
aged by the suggested tendency of white collar management, and with it the power of the union.
workers to attach greater importance and cre- On the shop floor due to the greater collective
dence to financial information than their blue power of the workforce and stronger union
collar counterparts, due to greater exposure to organisation, management faces greater uncer-
such information in the daily work situation. tainty which it seeks to reduce by the establish-
However, whether this potential role is realised ment of strong bargaining relationships with
depends to a large extent on the objectives, stewards, based on mutual trust. Therefore blue
attitudes and roles played by the individual shop collar stewards tend to have more contact with
steward involved in the negotiations. managers, particularly senior managers, and it
346 DAVID L OWEN and ANTHONY J. LLOYD

would appear are thus in a far stronger position Possible differences between individual shop
to push management into disclosing information stewards in their approach to the use of
than are their white collar counterparts. financial information
There are indeed a number of other factors Whereas we have suggested that, due to their
contributing to the relatively weak position of generally more powerful union organisation,
white collar stewards in the context of pressing shop floor stewards are in a stronger position to
management to disclose information. In particu- push management into disclosing information it
lar, white collar steward organisations tend to be should also be pointed out that the membership
less closely knit than blue collar organisations, are less likely to support such a course of action
with shop steward committees and conveners than are the white collar membership. There-
playing a far less dominant role, thus making it fore, much will depend on the extent to which
more dihicult to mobilise membership support the blue collar steward is able to adopt a leader-
across the plant (Batstone et aZ.>. There is also ship role, as opposed to acting merely as a dele-
evidence to suggest that white collar stewards gate for membership aspirations. Batstone et al.
are less experienced both in terms of handling consider leaders as being those stewards who, in
negotiations and strikes (Nicholson et al., acting as representatives, strive to implement
1980). Finally, due to diEerences in membership union principles, and distinguish them from
expectations, white collar stewards find it more “populists” who, in acting as delegates, do not
difficult to adopt a leadership role, being far adopt union principles.’ Willman (1980) takes
more likely to act as delegates of the member- Batstone et al. to task for their linking of the con-
ship (Batstone et al.) which again must lessen cept of leadership with the pursuit of union prin-
their status in the eye of management. ciples. He points out that stewards in manage-
The above analysis suggests that whereas the ment sponsored organisations may well adopt a
membership of white collar unions may view leadership role in promoting policies which
favourably any moves made by their represen- assist the rationalisation of personnel administ-
tatives towards using financial arguments in col- ration, as opposed to policies which seek to
lective bargaining, the representatives them- exert worker intluence on the effort bargain
selves may find great dficulties in employing such as may be adopted by leader stewards in
such arguments due to the weakness of the independent organisations. For the purposes of
union organisation. The fragmentation of white our discussion we intend to follow Willman and
collar bargaining and lack of co-operation with divorce the concept of leadership from the pur-
blue collar unions together with the generally suit of union principles, which are in any case
more dominant role of the full time official also never satisfactorily defined by Batstone et al.
appear to represent major constraints on the Batstone et al. point out that strong bargaining
effective use of information by white collar ste- relationships, in terms of the exchange of confi-
wards. These issues again seem important dential information and mutual support, are
enough to merit the attention of future resear- more likely to develop between management
chers in the field. and leader stewards than between management

a Batstone et al. consider two other leadership styles; “nascent leaders” who though committed to union principles fail to gain
the support of other stewards or the shop Boor, and “cowboys”, who play a representative role in promoting the short term
interests of their members and do not adhere to union principles. Both these styles are less prevalent than the “leaders” and
“populists”, the stewards concerned tending to either change their style of leadership or be removed from office. Later
research by Marchington & Armstrong ( 1983) suggests that Batstone ef al’s summary dismissal of these latter styles is prema-
ture. For the sake of clarity of exposition we shall adhere to the Batstone et al. analysis whilst bringing to the reader’s attention
the possibility of other leadership styles persisting in the long term. Certainly Marchington & Armstrong’s contribution to the
debate is worthy of the attention of future researchers in this field.
THE USE OF FINANCIAL INFORMATION BY TRADE UNION NEGOTIATORS 347

and populists. The potential for a financial input (Batstone et al.).


into the negotiations therefore appears to be From the above analysis it can be seen that
much greater where leader stewards are even for a “leader” steward to successfully press
involved, particularly in view of Morley & management into disclosing information, mem-
Stephenson’s ( 1977) argument that, “Delegates bership support must be mobilised, which, given
have to champion a group position and, if they the traditionally reactive role of blue collar
capitulate, must convince their parties that they stewards, may be particularly difficult. Three
have good reason for doing so. Leaders, on the further factors which may inhibit the shop ste-
other hand, presumably do not face such severe ward in using any financial information acquired
problems of intra-organisational bargaining and are also worthy of note. Firstly, in many indus-
are more likely to be persuaded to move by tries there tends to be a high turnover of shop
other negotiators” (p.37). However, it should be stewards leading to a shortage of suitably experi-
stressed that even leader stewards need to enced stewards. For example, of the stewards
mobilise membership opinion to enable them to studied by Batstone et al. only 12 per cent of
operate effectively. As Batstone et al. point out, populists had been in office for more than five
rejection of steward recommendations is a years, and 30 per cent of leaders. Furthermore,
major check upon steward behaviour for such an whereas leaders appear to have greater stability
outcome reduces the credibility and status of in office than populists in many cases the service
the union in the eyes of both membership and had not been continuous. Secondly, lack of
management. Pedler (1973) also stresses the resources, particularly in the form of full time
importance and power of the membership in conveners and suitable shop steward organisa-
considering leadership to be a group property tions, can pose a major problem. This is felt in
which is situationally specific. “On some issues acute form in smaller workplace organisations
where the representative has access to the and, as Winch ( 1980) points out, may indicate a
necessary information, a ‘leader’ role tends to be potentially more important role for the full time
adopted. On other issues, where the matter in official, particularly in view of the higher rates of
question is central to the norms of the group, a shop steward turnover in such organisations.
vote is taken and the representative is simply a Finally, as the studies by Jackson-Cox et al. and
‘mouthpiece”’ (p.56). Broad (1983) concurs Reeves & McGovern showed, in certain cases,
with this viewpoint and argues that, “an elastic- shop steward mistrust of management, due to
ity of shop steward leadership characterises past negotiating experiences, may have very
workplace interactions where the Workgroup much soured stewards attitudes towards the use
itself imposes sanctions on stewards who over- of financial information.
stretch their power or stray from the group
norm” (p.61). This may particularly occur
where a tightly knit leading steward group fails CONCLUSIONS AND PROSPECTS FOR
to develop adequate communications with the FURTHER RESEARCH
membership (Schuller & Robertson, 1983). Also
of course a shop steward must retain the support Our purpose in this paper has been to under-
of the membership to stay in office. It would take a critical review of recent research into the
seem that the steward has anything but security use of company information by trade union
of tenure, being not only subject to annual re- negotiators in collective bargaining at the
election but also, as many stewards claim, facing domestic level, and to tentatively outline a
removal from office at any time if sufficient feel- strategy for further investigations in this im-
ing exists in their constituencies (Pedler, 1973). portant, but still largely unexplored, area of
Thus a steward elected by only a small majority research.
is in a particularly delicate position and may find We have had two major criticisms to make of
it extremely dficult to adopt a leadership role the research projects conducted under the SSRC
348 DAVID L. OWEN and ANTHONY J. LLOYD

initiative. Firstly, we discern a tendency for the in the area should pay far more explicit attention
researchers to accept without question the to the possible importance of variations in the
potential importance of financial information to nature of the domestic organisation and in par-
the union negotiator, and hence a failure to ticular to the differing objectives, and roles
explore fully possible explanations for the low played by, the individual union negotiators con-
rates of utilisation of such information by union cerned. We have tentatively suggested an initial
negotiators highlighted in the studies. We have analytical framework within which future
therefore attempted to begin to remedy this research may be conducted involving a consid-
deficiency. Secondly, despite the generally eration of possible different approaches to finan-
richer institutional context within which the cial information use by full-time officials and
researchers concerned have sought to ground shop stewards, white and blue collar union rep-
their observations, as compared to many earlier resentatives, and “leader” as compared to “dele-
studies in this field, there is still evidence of an gate” stewards. Of course such a hanrework is
implicit assumption being made of the existence probably over simplified and will need refining
of a universal indent&it union repesentative. further in the course of future investigations.
Perhaps this is not surprising as such an assump- One such refinement may involve a considera-
tion appears to have underpinned much of the tion of the impact of institutional arrangements,
recent theoretical literature in the area (e.g. in terms of the general pattern of bargaining pre-
Climo, 1976; Cooper & Essex, 1977; Pope & vailing, on the potential for corporate financial
Peel, 1981) where there has been an over- Information input into the negotiating process.
reliance on the normative approach in an For example it may well be the case that where
attempt to specify a universal decision model for is more potential for using information of a “cor-
the domestic trade union representative. How porate” nature the more centrahsed bargaining
ever, as Foley & Maunders ( 1977) indicate, “The is within the company concerned. In view of the
normative, model building approach can only be recent re-emergence of the disclosure issue as a
useful if, ultimately, its assumptions about user subject of heated debate, largely due to develop-
behaviour and objectives correspond with real ments within the European Economic Commun-
world conditions - something which requires ity, we feel that the urgent need for such investi-
‘positive’ confhmation” (p. 188). gations to be undertaken is self evident.
Our major contention is that future research

BIBLIOGRAPHY

Batstone,E., Systemsof Domination,Accommodation and IndustrialDemocracy, in Burns, T. et al. (eds)


Work and Power (London: Sage, 1980)
Batstone,E., Boraston,I. & Frenkel,S.,Shop Stewurds in Action (Oxford: Blackwell, 1977)
Beynon, H., WorkingforFord (Allen Lane, 1973)
Blackaby, F., The Reform of the Wage Bargaining System;National Institute Economic Review (August
1978)
Blackbum, R, The New Capitalism,in Blackbum, R. (ed) Ideology in Social Science:Readings in Critical
Social Tkny (Fontana, 1972)
Bougen, P. & Ogden, S.,Power ln Organisations:Some Implicationsfor the use of Accounting in Industrial
Relations,Managerial Finance (1981) pp. 22-26.
Broad, G., Shop Steward Leadershipand the Dynamics of Workplace IndustrialRelations,Indusfrial Re-
lationsJournal ( 1983) pp. 59-67.
Brown, W., The Changing Contours of BrftfsbIndustrialRelations (Oxford: Blackwell, 1981)
Brown, W. % Sisson,K. The Use of Comparisons in Workplace Wage Determination,BritishJournal of
IndustrialRelations ( 1975) pp. 23-5 1.
THE USE OF FINANCLAL INFORMATION BY TRADE UNION NEGOTL4TORS 349

Brown, W. & Sisson, K, Industrial Relations-The Next Decade, IndustrialRelationsJournal( 1983) pp.
9-21.
Burchell, S., CIubb, C., Hopwood, A., Hughes, J. & Nahapiet, J., The Role of Accounting in Organizations and
Societp,Accounting, Organizations and Society ( 1980) pp. 5-27.
Burkitt, B., Excessive Trade Union Power: Existing Reality or Contemporary Myth? Industrial Relations
Journal(198l)pp.65-71.
Clegg, H. A., The Changing System of fndusb-ial RelaNons in Great Britain (Oxford: Blackwell, 1979)
Climo, T., Disclosure of Information to Employees Representatives: A Wage Bargaining Decision Model,
unpublished University of Kent ( 1976).
Cohen, M. D., March, J. G. & Olsen, J. P., A Garbage Can Model of Organizational Choice, Administrative
Science Quarterly (March 1972) pp. l-25.
Cooper, D. & Essex, S., Accounting Information and Employee Decision Making, Accounting Organiza-
tions and Society ( 1977) pp. 201-2 17.
Cooper, D. & Sherer, M., Shareholder Interests and the Social Value of CorporateAccounting Reports:
Towards a Political Economy of Accounting paper presented to AUTA Northern Accounting Group,
University of Birmingham (September 1981)
Craft, J. A., Information Disclosure and the Role of the Accountant in Collective Bargaining, Accounbng,
Organizations andSociety ( 1981) pp. 97-107.
Cuthbert, N. H. & Whitaker, A., Disclosure of Information and Collective Bargaining: A Re-examination,
Journal of Business-Finance and AccounNng ( 1977) pp. 37%378.
Daniel, W. W., Wage Deienninution in Industry, (PEP Report No. 563,1976)
Daniel, W. W.. Influences on the Level of Wage Settlements in Manufacturing Industry, in Blackaby, F. (ed.)
The Future of Pay Bargaining (London: Heinemann, 198 1)
Dobson, J. R., What is Good Industrial Relations? EmployeeRelalions ( 1982) pp. 5-10
Earl, M. J, & Hopwood, A., From Management Information to Information Management, in Lucas H. C.,
Land, F. F., Lincoln, TJ. and Supper K, TbeInforma~ion SystemsEnvironment (North-Holland, 1980)
Foley, B. J. & Maunders, K T., Accounting Information Disclosure and Collective Bargaining (London:
Macmillan, 1977)
Fox, A., Managerial Ideology and Industrial Relations, BritishJournal of Industrial Relations ( 1966) pp.
366-378.
Galbraith, J. K., The Newfndusirial State (Hamish Hamilton, 1967)
General and Municipal Workers Union, Disclosure of Information Guide (GMWU, 1978)
Gospel, H., The Disclosure of Information to Trade Unions: Approaches and Problems,lndustrzalRelations
Journal ( 1978) pp. 18-26.
Hawkins, K, The Future of Collective Bargaining, Industrial Relations Journal ( 1979) pp. It%? I.
Hemingway, J.. Conf7ict and Demwacy: Studies in Trade Union Government (Oxford: Oxford Univer-
sity Press, 1978)
Jackson-Cox, J., McQueeney, J. & ThirkeII, J. E. M., The Disclosure of Company Information to Trade
Unions: The Relevance of the ACAS Code of Practice on Disclosure, Accounling, Organizations and
Society (1984) pp. 253-273.
Jenkins, C. & Sherman, B., CollecriwBargaining (Routledge and Kegan Paul, 1977)
Lindop, E., Workplace Bargaining: The End of an Era, Industrial Relations Journal ( 1979) pp. 12-2 I.
Lover, J., Shop Steward Training: Conflicting Objectives and Needs, Industrial Relations Journal ( 1976)
pp. 27-39.
Lyall, D., Opening the Books to the Workers, Accountancy (1975) pp. 42-44.
Marchington, M. & Armstrong, R. Employee Participation: Problems for the Shop Steward, Indusfrial Re-
lationsJournal ( 198 1) pp. 46-6 I.
Marchington, M. & Armstrong, R., Typologies of Shop Stewards: A Reconsideration, lndusrrial Relations
Journal ( 1983) pp. 34-48.
Marsh, A. & Rosewell, R, A Question of Disclosure, IndustrialRela~ionsJournal(l976) pp. 4-16.
Maunders. K T.. Disclosure of Company Financial Information to Employees and Unions: The State of the
Art,ACXARevieuj(l98l)pp. 5-19.
Mercer, D. E. & Weir, D. T. H., Attitudes to Work and Trade Unionism Among White Collar Workers,
Industrial Relations JournaI ( 1972) pp. 49-60.
Mills, L., The Role of Trade Unions in Strategic Planning, Long RangePlanning ( 1978).
Mitchell, F.. Sams, K I., Tweedie. D. P. & White, P. J., Disclosure of Information: Some Evidence from Case
Studies, IndustrialRelarionsJournal ( 1980) pp. 5s2.
350 DAVID L OWEN and ANTHONY J. LLOYD

Moore, R., Gold, M. & Levie, H., TheShop StewardsGuide to the Use of Companylnfomzation (Spokesman,
1979)
Moore, R. & Levie, H.. Constraints Upon the Acquisition and Use of Company Information by Trade
Unions (Trade Union Research Unit, Ruskhr College, Occasional Paper no. 67, 1981)
Morley, 1. & Stephenson, G., The Social Psychology of Bargaining (London: George Allen and Unwin,
1977)
Nicholson, N., UrselI, G. % Blyton, P., Social Background, Attitudes and Behaviour of White Collar Shop
Stewards, British Journal of Industrial Relations ( 1980) pp. 23 1-239.
Ogden, S. & Bougen, P., A Radical Perspective on the Disclosure of Accounting Information to Trade Unions,
Accounting, Organizations andsociety (1985) pp. 21 l-224.
Palmer, J. R., The Use of Accounting Information in Labour Negotiations (National Association of
Accountants, 1977)
Partridge, B., The Activities of Shop Stewards, Industrial Relations Journal ( 1978) pp. 28-42.
Pedler, M. J., Shop Stewards as Leaders, ZndustrtalRelations Journal (1973) pp. 43-60.
Pettigrew, A. M., Information Control as a Power Resource, Sociology ( 1972) pp. 187-204.
Pope, P. F. & Peel, D. A., Information Disclosure to Employees and Rational Expectations, Journal of
Business Finance and Accounting (1981) pp. 139-146.
Radice, G., Research and the Unions, Management Today (November 1971) pp. 27-34.
Reeves, T. K & McGovern, T., How Shop S&war& Use Company Information Ten Case Studies of
Information Disclosure (Anglian Regional Management Centre, 1981)
Scargill, A., Wise, A. & Cooley, M., A Debate on Workers Control (Institute for Workers Control pamphlet
No. 64.1978)
Schuller, T. & Robertson, D., How Representatives Allocate Their Tie: Shop StewardActivity and Member-
ship Contact, BritishJournal ofIm.iustrialRelation (1983) pp. 33&342.
Sherer, M., Southworth, A. & Turley, S., An Empirical Investigation of Disclosure, Usage and Usefulness
of Corporate Accounting Information, Managhal Finance ( 1981) pp. 6- 11.
Smith, R. & Manley, P. S., Company Information and the Development of Collective Bargaining, ThreeBanks
Reuiew (September 1973) pp. 27-46.
Terry, M., Organising a Fragmented Workforce: Shop Stewards in Local Government, BritishJournal of
Industrial Relations ( 1982) pp. l-19.
Thompson, J. D. & Tuden, A., Strategies, Structures and Processes of Organisational Decision, in Thompson,
J, D. et al. (eds) ComparativeStudies in Administration (University of Pittsburgh Press, 1959)
Trades Union Congress - Iabour Party Liaison Committee, Economic Planning and Industrial
Democ~cy: TheFrameuwk fat Full Employment (The Iabour Party, 1982)
Transport and General Workers Union, The Ford Wage Claim (TGWU, 1971 and 1977)
Wilders, M. G., The Disclosure of Financial and Related Information, Joumal of General Management
(Autumn 1979) pp. 12-22.
Wilhnan, P., Leadership and Trade Union Principles: Some Problems of Management Sponsorship and
Independence, Industrial Relations Journal ( 1980) pp. 39-49.
Wilson, D. C., Butler, R J., Gray, D., Hickson, D. J. & Mallory, G. R., The Limits of Trade Union Power in
Organisational Decision Making, BritishJournal of Industrial Relations ( 1982) pp. 322-34 1.
Winch, G., Shop Steward Tenure and Workplace Organisation, Industrial Relations Journal (1980) pp.
5ti2.

You might also like