You are on page 1of 19

Sage Publications, Inc.

American Sociological Association

Mobilization and Participation: Social-Psychological Expansisons of Resource Mobilization Theory


Author(s): Bert Klandermans
Source: American Sociological Review, Vol. 49, No. 5 (Oct., 1984), pp. 583-600
Published by: American Sociological Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/2095417
Accessed: 27-10-2015 18:38 UTC

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/
info/about/policies/terms.jsp

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content
in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship.
For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Sage Publications, Inc. and American Sociological Association are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend
access to American Sociological Review.

http://www.jstor.org

This content downloaded from 130.237.29.138 on Tue, 27 Oct 2015 18:38:07 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
MOBILIZATION AND PARTICIPATION:
SOCIAL-PSYCHOLOGICAL EXPANSIONS OF RESOURCE
MOBILIZATION THEORY*

BERT KLANDERMANS
Free University,Amsterdam

Resource mobilization theorists have nearly abandoned social-psychological


analysis of social movements. In this paper a fresh case is made for social
psychology. New insights in psychology are combined with resource mobilization
theory in an attempt to overcome the weaknesses of traditional social-psychological
approaches to social movements. Expectancy-value theory is applied to movement
participation and mobilization. It is assumed that the willingness to participate in a
social movement is a function of the perceived costs and benefits of participation.
Collective and selective incentives are discussed. Expectations about the behavior of
others are introduced as an important expansion of expectancy-value theory to make
this framework applicable to movement participation. The theory is applied to
mobilization campaigns of the labor movement, and empirically tested in a
longitudinal study of a campaign during the 1979 collective negotiations in the
Netherlands. Outcomes support the theory. Theoretical and practical implications
are discussed.

Resourcemobilizationtheory was a reactionto pants in such divergentmovements as fascism


traditional social-psychological theories of in Germany (Oberschall, 1973), the student
social movements (Zurcherand Snow, 1981). movement (Kenniston, 1968), the civil rights
Those theories focused on what attracted movement(Morris,1981),the unionmovement
people to participationin social movements. (Moore, 1975), political protest movements
Amongst the explanations were: personality (Marsh, 1977; Barnes and Kaase, 1979), the
traits (cf. Kenniston, 1968;Kerpelman, 1969); environmental, antiabortion, and antinuclear
marginalityand alienation (cf. LeBon [1903] movements (Leahy and Mazur, 1978),and the
1968;Freud, 1922;Hoffer, 1951; Kornhauser, unemployed movement (Klandermans,1979).
1959);and grievancesand ideology (cf. Davies, The importanceof grievances and ideology as
1962; Toch, 1966; Geschwender, 1968; Gurr, determinants of participation in a social
1970; Rothman, 1974; Landsberger, 1976). movement has been ambiguous(Gerlach and
These explanationstended to be based on the Hine, 1970;McCarthyand Zald, 1976;Walsh,
assumption that participation in a social 1978;Leahy and Mazur, 1978;Tilly, 1979).
movement, like other forms of collective be- In contrast to traditional social-psycho-
havior, is an unconventional,irrationaltype of logical interpretations, resource mobili-
behavior (Schwartz, 1976).1 Thanks to re- zation theory emphasizes the importance of
source mobilization theorists themselves, structuralfactors, such as the availability of
these approaches became increasingly ques- resources to a collectivity and the position of
tionable. Attempts to show that movement individualsin social networks, and stresses the
participants have characteristic personality rationalityof participationin social movements
traitswere not very successful (Heberl6, 1968; (Oberschall, 1973; Gamson, 1975; Marx and
Roberts and Kloss, 1974; Klandermans, Wood, 1975; McCarthyand Zald, 1976; Zald
1983b).Marginalityand alienation, for exam- and McCarthy, 1979;Snow et al., 1980;Gam-
ple, were not the typical backgroundof partici- son et al., 1982). Participation in a social
movement is seen not as the consequence of
predisposingpsychologicaltraits or states, but
*Directall correspondenceto: Bert Klandermans, as the result of rational decision processes
Departmentof Social Psychology, Free University, wherebypeople weigh the costs and benefits of
Amsterdam,The Netherlands.
I wish to thank two anonymous reviewers who participation.
provided many insightful comments on an earlier Currently, resource mobilization theory is
version of this paper. the dominantapproachin the field. Paradoxi-
I Schwartzcontrasts the social-psychological"ir- cally, a demand for new social-psychological
rational"approachwith the structural"rational"ap- theories of mobilizationand participationhas
proach. I hope to show here that such a charac- developed (Gamsonet al., 1982;Jenkins, 1983;
terizationof social psychology is unjust. Walsh and Warland, 1983). Resource mobili-
American Sociological Review, 1984, Vol. 49 (October:583-600) 583
This content downloaded from 130.237.29.138 on Tue, 27 Oct 2015 18:38:07 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
584 AMERICANSOCIOLOGICALREVIEW
zationtheorywent too far in nearlyabandoning A generalcriticismof resource mobilization
the social-psychological analyses of social theory has been that it underestimates the
movements. In this papera fresh case is made significanceof grievances and ideology as de-
for a social-psychologicalanalysis of mobiliza- terminantsof participationin a social move-
tion and participationin a social movement.By ment (Carden, 1978; Fireman and Gamson,
combiningnew insightsin psychology with re- 1979; Useem, 1980; Isaac et al., 1980). This
source mobilizationtheory, the weaknesses of shortcomingresults from confusing the indi-
earlier social-psychologicalapproachesin the vidual and societal levels of analysis (see also
field can be overcome. Geschwender, 1968). The fact that grievances
and ideology cannot explain the rise of social
SOCIAL PSYCHOLOGYAND RESOURCE movements does not mean that they. do not
MOBILIZATIONTHEORY play a role in the decisions of individualsto
participatein a social movement. One of the
Social psychology can expand resource aspirationsof this social-psychologicalexpan-
mobilization theory in an importantway by sion of resourcemobilizationtheory is to find a
revealing processes of social-movement par- more satisfying theoretical solution for the
ticipationon the individuallevel. To resource problem of grievances and ideology as deter-
mobilization theorists, participation results minantsof participationin a social movement.
from "weighing"costs againstbenefits. How-
ever, little attentionis given to weighingthese PERSUASION AND ACTIVATION:A
at the individuallevel. Nor is much attention
given to the interaction between individuals SOCIAL-PSYCHOLOGICAL THEORY OF
that generates mobilization.2 MOBILIZATION AND PARTICIPATION
Identifyingthe interactionbetween individu- Participationin a social movement fluctuates.
als as the appropriatelevel of analysis has sig- Alternatingly,a movementhas its rankand file
nificanttheoreticalconsequences. It takes into in action and then it falls back on its cadre.
account the psychological truism that people Mobilizationplays an importantpart in these
behave in a perceived reality. Individualdeci- fluctuations.The remainderof this article will
sions to participatein a social movement are focus on participationin a social movement
based on perceived costs and benefits of par- and on the way it changes as a result of mobili-
ticipation.That perceived reality is capable of zation attempts.
being influenced, and both social-movement
leaders and adversariestry to do so. Persua- The Willingness to Participate
sion is an importantelementin every mobiliza-
tion campaign.The efficacy of a mobilization A person will participatein a social movement
campaignin persuadingthe individualis a key if s/he knows the opportunitiesto participate,if
determinantof participation. s/he is capable of using one or more of these
Movement participationdenotes activities opportunities,and if s/he is willing to do so.
rangingfromsigninga petitionto sabotage,and This paper elaborates the third condition by
frompart-timeor one-timeto full-timeactivity. applying expectancy-value theory to move-
The perceived costs and benefits for different ment participation.In general this theory "at-
activities can vary greatly (see also Tolbert, tempts to relate action to the perceived attrac-
1981).Moreover, there can be substantialdif- tiveness or aversiveness of expected con-
ferences in perceived costs and benefits be- sequences" (Feather, 1982:1).3The key ele-
tween individuals,across regions, and during
the life cycle of the movement. This has im- 3 Expectancy-valuemodels in psychology com-
portant implications for mobilization cam- prise such concepts as attitude, motivation, choice
paigns. By timing,and by their choice of strat- and decision. The motivationfor a certainbehavior
egy and arena, social-movementorganizations is a function of the expectation that it will yield
can profoundlyinfluencethe costs andbenefits certainoutcomes and the values of those outcomes
of participation. (Rotter, 1954, 1972; Mitchell, 1974; Campbelland
Pritchard,1977).The value of an outcome of behav-
2 A number of students of social movements ior is a functionof the instrumentalityof the primary
whose approachesare cognatewith resourcemobili- outcome for other, secondary outcomes and the
zation theory do pay attention to processes at the value they have. Expectancy-value theory is a
individual level (Schwartz, 1976; Mitchell, 1979; rational-choicetheory. It is one of the subjective
Oberschall,1980;Tolbert,1981;Gamsonet al., 1982). utility theories in psychology. As such, it is easily
Their analyses bear resemblances to the one pre- compatiblewith resourcemobilizationtheory. How-
sented here. They have in common, however, their ever, I do not want to suggestthat social psychology
lack of a systematic,psychologicallybased theoreti- has nothingmoreto offerthatis usefulto the studyof
cal framework.Moreover, they are not theoretical: social movements(see Gamsonet al., 1982;Pinard,
they provideno empiricaldataat the individuallevel. 1983;Ferree and Miller, 1984).

This content downloaded from 130.237.29.138 on Tue, 27 Oct 2015 18:38:07 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
MOBILIZATIONAND PARTICIPATION 585
ments of the theory are expected outcomes Fleishman (1980) stressed the importance of
(expectations) and the value of these out- feelings of responsibilityand solidarityin this
comes. Theoretically,values and expectations connection. Schwartz (1976) and Oberschall
combine in a multiplicativeway. Even if the (1980)addedthe probabilityof success as very
value of an outcome is very high it will not important.In their analysis the probabilityof
motivate individuals as long as they do not success is related to the number of partici-
believe that the outcome can be producedby pants. Oberschall (1980) pointed out that the
their efforts. Usually differentoutcomes (ma- importantquestion for the individualis what
terial and nonmaterial)are distinguished.For his/her participation will contribute to the
each outcome a value-expectancyproductcan probabilityof success. From a hypothesized
be calculated.Motivationis definedas the sum relationship between the number of partici-
of these differentvalue-expectancyproducts.4 pants and the probabilityof success, the indi-
A rational-choiceframeworkdoes not imply vidualcontributionas a functionof the number
thatfeelings, emotions or sentimentsare unim- of participantscan be derived. Oliver et al.
portantin relation to movement participation. (1983)madeclear that there is a varietyof such
Nor does it arguethat potentialparticipantsare productionfunctions.
consciously multiplyingand addingvalues and These arguments do not touch the funda-
expectations.The usefulness of the framework mentalissue, namely, that persons have to de-
is that it provides a device for the systematic cide to participateat a point when they do not
analysis of the variety of beliefs, expectations know whetherothers will participate. There is
and attitudesthat are relatedto participationin a social-psychologicalsolutionto this problem.
a social movement (see Schwartz [1976] and Althoughpeople do not know what others will
Oberschall[1980]for defenses of the rational do, they have expectations. Based on their ex-
view of humanaction). pectationsaboutthe behaviorof others, people
However, before this general theoretical assess the probabilityof success and their own
frameworkcan be applied to movement par- contributionto it. The expectationthat partici-
ticipation,it has to be modifiedin an important pationhelps to producethe collective good can
way. The goals of social movements are "col- therefore be categorized as follows:
lective goods." Obtaininga collective good is a. expectationsabout the numberof partici-
not directly contingent on the decision of an pants;
individual to participate (Olson, 1977). Ra- b. expectations about one's own contribu-
tional individuals will not participate in the tion to the probabilityof success;
productionof a collective good unless selective c. expectationsaboutthe probabilityof suc-
incentives motivatethem to do so. ThoughOl- cess if many people participate.
son's argumenthas been criticized (Schwartz, These expectationscombinein a multiplicative
1976; Mitchell, 1979; Fireman and Gamson, way with the value of the collective good to
1979;Oliver, 1980), it clarified the distinction producethe expected collective benefitsof par-
between collective benefits and selective ben- ticipation.
efits. If one finds it untenable that only the Applying expectancy theory yields the hy-
latter motivates movement participation,one pothesis that the value of a collective good is a
must acknowledge that the relationship be- function of its instrumentality6 for social
tween participationand collective benefits is changes which the movementhopes to achieve
differentfromthe relationshipbetween partici- and of the value of changes. To form an opin-
pation and selective benefits. ion about this instrumentality,an individual
Collective benefits and participation. Both must have knowledgeaboutthe collective good
Gamson(1975)and Schwartz(1976)arguethat and its implications.
people participate in activities to produce a Participationand selective costs and bene-
collective goal precisely because they are
aware that the good would never be produced 5On the basis of the expectations distinguished,
if everyone sat back and waited for someone we can definethe free-riderproblemmoreclosely. A
else to do something. Oberschall (1980) re- free rideris someone who believes that his/herown
markedthat this was especially true for people contributionto the probabilityof success will be very
who are strongly in favor of the collective small, but who believes that the numberof partici-
good. Fireman and Gamson (1979) and pantsandthe probabilityof success are largeenough
to expect that the collective good will be produced.
See Klandermans(1983a) for a reconsiderationof
4 Thereis considerablediscussionin the literature the free-riderdilemmaalong this line. Oliver et al.
concerningthe mathematicalpartof the theory (see, (1983) propose a similarlimitationof the free-rider
e.g., Kuhl, 1982). Leaving aside the theoretical problem.
argument,in practicemost researchersuse multiple 6 In expectancy-valuetheory expectation is used

regression analysis to combine the different vari- for behavior-outcomerelations and instrumentality
ables. for outcome-outcome relations.

This content downloaded from 130.237.29.138 on Tue, 27 Oct 2015 18:38:07 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
586 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICALREVIEW
fits. Selective costs and benefits are by defini- negative, the other motives can be so strong
tion contingenton participation.Expectations that a person is willing to participate. If the
about, and values of, these incentives directly collective motive is strong, the social motives
influence the willingnessto participate.In the and/orrewardmotives can be negativewithout
literaturethere are different classifications of making a person unwilling to participate. Of
selective costs andbenefits(cf. Freeman,1979; course there are also situations in which the
Tolbert, 1981).An importantdistinctionis that collective motive does not outweigh negative
between expected reactions of significant social and/or reward motives, either because
others7and expected materialcosts and bene- the collective motive is too weak, or because
fits like money, time, injury, entertainment.8 the social and rewardmotives are too negative.
Motives. The willingnessto participatein a Figure 1 summarizesthe theory on the willing-
social movement can be defined as a function ness to participate.
of the perceivedattractivenessor aversiveness
of the expected consequencesof participation. Mobilization
This signifiesthat willingnessto participateis a
function of: Mobilizationattempts by a movement organi-
(a) the expectation that participation will zation have the aim of winning participants,
help to produce the collective good and the that is, persuading people to support the
value of the collective good-the collective movement organizationby material and non-
motive; (b) the expected selective costs and materialmeans. Mobilizationattempts always
benefits and the value of these costs and bene- containtwo components.These are called con-
fits. As distinguishedin the reactionsof signifi- sensus mobilizationand action mobilization.
cant others, these comprise the social motive. Consensus mobilization is a process through
As they relate to nonsocial costs and benefits, which a social movement tries to obtain sup-
they comprise the reward motive. port for its viewpoints.9It involves (a) a col-
Expectationsor instrumentalitiesand values lective good, (b) a movement strategy, (c)
combine in a multiplicativeway and the three confrontation with the opponent, (d) results
motives in an additive way. The value of a achieved. Neithercollective goods nor types of
collective good will be zero if it is not believed action are fixed quantities. They change, and
to be instrumentalfor valued societal changes, this requiresrenewed consensus mobilization.
or if the changesit is saidto be instrumentalfor Consensus mobilizationdoes not take place in
are not valued. The value of a collective good' a vacuum. Collective goods and actions are
will be negativeif it is believedto hindervalued often controversial. Opponents, counter-
societal changes, or if changes are valued movements, rival organizations counter the
negatively. arguments of a social movement. A social
If the value of the collective good is zero, the movement will have to go into these
collective motive will be zero. If this value is arguments.In short, a "paperwar"is waged to
negativethe motivewill be negative, unless the promote or to discourage the mobilizationof
expectation componentis zero. consensus. The degree of success with which
The collective motive will also be zero if the consensus is mobilized around the collective
expectation that participationwill help to pro- goods can be measuredby the extent to which
duce the collective good is zero: persons will these goods are known and valued. Whether
not be motivatedby the collective good if they people value a collective good depends on the
do not feel that their participationcontributes extent to which consensus mobilization suc-
to the probabilityof success, or do not believe ceeded in makingthem believe that this good is
that enoughother people will participate,or do instrumentalfor valued social changes.
not feel there is any chance of success even if Action mobilization is the process by which
many people participate. an organizationin a social movement calls up
Since the different motives combine in an people to participate.Consensus mobilization
additive way, they can compensate one an- does not necessarily go together with action
other. If the collective motive is weak, zero or mobilization,but actionmobilizationcannotdo
without consensus mobilization. Action
mobilization involves motivating people to
7To avoid circularity,it is importantto point out participate. Ideally, social movement organi-
who in a person's environmentwill be significant. zations will take a variety of approaches, ap-
Althoughit is difficultto give exhaustive enumera- pealing both to collective and to social and
tions, certainlyfriends, colleagues and family mem-
bers are among them.
8 These costs and benefits can vary greatly de- 9 Consensus mobilizationbears resemblances to
pendingon the situation and the kind of participa- the spread of generalized beliefs (Smelser, 1971).
tion. However, often the maincosts andbenefitsof a Consensus mobilization, however, is a purposeful
particularform of participationcan be specified. effort of a social-movementorganization.

This content downloaded from 130.237.29.138 on Tue, 27 Oct 2015 18:38:07 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
MOBILIZATION AND PARTICIPATION 587

Attitude theory
Motivation theory
value of social
change advocated
Il value of collective
x 0 good

familiarity instrumentality of x
with collec- 0. collective good for II
tive good social change advo- expectation that
cated participation will
help to achieve the
collective good*

- participation contributes to probabi-i value of reaction


lity of success of significant
- expected numberof participants i
i
others
- expected success. if many people
participate
+ willingness
x +-
+ to parti-
cipate

expected reaction
of significant
others to partici-
pation and to
non-partici pation

value of costs
and benefits

expected costs and


benefits of parti-
cipation and non-
partici pation

means a multiplicativerelationship.
a X
+ means an additive relationship.
Figure 1. A Theory of the Willingnessto Participatea

rewardmotives (Gamson, 1975;Carden, 1978; of free-riderbehavior. Since free riderstake a


Snow et al., 1980).They have every reason to positive standon the collective good but do not
do so. Participationbecause of collective mo- believe that its production depends on their
tives means that both the collective good and participation,it is not of much use to appealto
the type of participationare attractive. But it collective motives. What remains is to try to
will seldom be the case that each and every mobilize them using social and/or rewardmo-
member of a collectivity is won over to the tives. Here, again, the chance that a social
collective good and the form of participationin movementdecides to do this will be greaterif a
the time available. Particularly if nearly higher degree of participationis required.'0
unanimousparticipationis demanded,there is
always a certainpercentagewho, lackingcom- "I Not all types of action are equallyvulnerableto
plete consensus, will have to be mobilized nonparticipation(cf. Fireman and Gamson, 1979;
using social and/or reward motives. Another Klandermans,1983a;Oliver et al., 1983). This will
factor to be contended with is the occurrence differ for differenttypes of action.

This content downloaded from 130.237.29.138 on Tue, 27 Oct 2015 18:38:07 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
588 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICALREVIEW
A mobilizingorganizationwill try to make ployment. The campaign started in August
the benefits of participationand the costs of 1978 when the chairman of the IB FNV
nonparticipationas high as possible, and the launched the 35-hourwork week as the chief
costs of participationand the benefits of non- demandin the 1979negotiations.The campaign
participationas low as possible. Apart from included numerous publications in the press
influencing the three motives directly, a andappearanceson radioandtelevision, issues
movement also has indirect means of control- of the union'smagazine,posters, bulletins,and
ling the costs and benefits of participation. pamphlets, work by union officials and by
Two importantones are (a) the choice of the members. The union, however, quickly went
type of action and (b) the choice of the scene. on the defensive. Not just their opponent, but
A movement can choose amongseveral types public opinion and even many "friendly"
of action, from moderateto militant. With its economists or politicians turned against it. In
choice of the type of action, a movement can an effort to break this massive resistance, the
determineto a large extent the costs and bene- union twice changedits goals: first, by replac-
fits of participation. A movement can fight ing the 35-hourweek with a 39-hourweek, later
where it is strongest,that is, in sectors of soci- by dropping the shorter work week and de-
ety with strong movement networks where it mandingextra days off.
can organizemany people. Resource mobiliza- Collective bargainingis a series of events.
tion literaturehas shown that people are more Our study was devoted to some of them. One
easily mobilized in such sectors (cf. Ragin et did have a greatdeal of influence:the failureof
al., 1982).The premisehere is that this is prob- a 6-week strike againstthe West Germansteel
ably because a more favorable cost-benefit industryin which the 35-hourwork week was
ratio can be created in such sectors. at stake. This failure made the union keenly
Psychologically speaking, there will be an aware of its small chances of success, even if
elementof projectionin estimatesof the number militantaction were taken. Thus no action was
of participantsin a movement. A person who taken in the Netherlandsthat year. Ultimately,
does not wish to participatewill make a lower however, an agreementwas reached giving a
estimate of the numberof participantsthan a few extra days off. Although the members
person who does wish to take part."IIn a col- were not markedlydissatisfiedwith this result,
lectivity this has all the look of a self-fulfilling many regretted the meager results. Few be-
prophecy:if manypeople thinkthatfew people lieved it would have a favorableeffect on em-
will participate,many people will have doubts ployment.
about the efficacy of their own participation.
Thus a downwardspiral ensues which is fatal
to the willingness to participate.Mobilization Research Design
efforts attempt to reinforce the view that Mobilization campaigns often last several
"many people will participate."If this is -not months. In this case the campaign started in
successful, the prophecy fulfills itself. August 1978, and the negotiations were not
completeduntil June 1979. In such a situation,
METHOD longitudinalresearch is to be preferred.From
the end of November 1978 throughJuly 1979
The theory of mobilization and participation we interviewed a group of union members
has been applied in research on mobilization about once a month. We chose the timing so
campaigns of the union movement, the that the interviews fell shortly before or-after
women's movementand the peace movement. an importantevent. Althougha total of seven
This paper presents data from a study of the waves were held, for methodologicalreasons a
effects of a mobilizationcampaignby the In- design was developed which ensured that no
dustrial Workers'Union of the Dutch Union respondent would be interviewed more than
Federation, the largest union of industrial three times. Seven groups of members were
workers in the Netherlands. selected, and they were interviewedaccording
to the schedulein Figure2. Whenthe similarity
The Campaign of the seven groups was controlled on a
number of variables, the differences found
In 1979, the Industrial Workers' Union (IB were so few that the groups can be used for
FNV) tried to mobilize its members for a comparison with no difficulty.'2 In addition,
shorter work week. It was argued that
shorteningthe work week would reduce unem- 12 To
check whetherthe differencesfoundaffected
the outcomes, analyses of covariance were carried
I See Granbergand Holmberg(1983) for an in- out on all effect variables,with the variableswhich
terestingelaborationof a similarassumptionregard- had shown significantdifferencesas covariates. Not
ing voting behavior. once did they lead to differentconclusions.

This content downloaded from 130.237.29.138 on Tue, 27 Oct 2015 18:38:07 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
MOBILIZATION AND PARTICIPATION 589

group I 1st 2nd 3rd


interview interview interview

group II 1st 2nd 3rd


interview interview interview

group III 1st 2nd 3rd


interview interview interview

group IV 1st 2nd 3rd


interview interview interview

group V 1st 2nd 3rd


interview interview interview

group VI 1st 2nd


interview interview

group VII 1st


interview

Nov. 20-29 Jan. 29- Feb. 19- Apr. 3-18 May 18- June 11-
|an. 4-18 Fe15. 9 Mar-. 2 June 1 July 11

Figure2. Design

this design13has many advantages.We can get The Interviews


a picture of the course of the campaign by The interviews were held at the participants'
comparing the outcomes of the successive homes andwere carriedout by the Netherlands
interviews. We can also study the effect of a Instituteof OpinionPolls. Each questionnaire
single event by comparingthe outcomes of the consisted of one part that was the same each
interviews before and after that event while time and another that changed. The initial
controllingfor repeated measurement. interview included a general list of personal
data.
Respondents
Membersof the IB FNV were interviewedat The Questionnaire
three plants belongingto the AKZO concern: The variablesfrom the theory of willingnessto
Enka in Emmen; Enka in Ede; and AKZO take action were operationalizedas follows. (I)
Pharmain Oss. A sample of 746 persons was The familiaritywith the collective good was
taken from the membershiplists of the union. measuredby the following questions: Are the
The data set includes 490 complete series of unionsdemandingshorterworkinghours?(yes,
interviews (66%), well distributedover plants no, don't know). In what way do they want to
and interview waves. The first interview had shorten working hours? (open question). (II)
the highest nonresponse rate. This interview The instrumentalityof the collective good for
was completed with 565 members (76%). the social change advocated:We asked the re-
Slightly less than half the dropouts refused to spondents if they felt that a "shorterworking
take partin this interview.The others were not week would make a contributionto reducing
at home, were no longer members, no longer unemployment"(definitely, I think so, I don't
worked for the company, were sick, or had think so, definitely not). (III) The value of the
moved. The refusals(1/8 of the originalsample) social change advocated: From the responses
may have damaged the representativeness. to variousquestions we were able to infer that
Small percentagesagain fell off at the second the interviewees almost without exception at-
(4%) and third interviews (6%). Half of the tached much value to reducingunemployment.
dropoutsat the thirdinterview were members Theoretically,this means that the value of the
who had already left for vacation. social change advocated equals 1 for each re-
spondent.
The questionon the motives to participatein
II The design is one of the variantsof the separate unionaction always distinguishedbetween two
sample-pretest-posttestdesign (Campbelland Stan- types of action: militant action, such as a
ley, 1963): strike; and moderate action, such as holding
meetings on work time, a slowdown, a short
R 0, x 02 work stoppage, etc.
R x 02 Collective motives. (IV) The value of the

This content downloaded from 130.237.29.138 on Tue, 27 Oct 2015 18:38:07 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
590 AMERICANSOCIOLOGICALREVIEW
collective good: Union members were asked Willingness to take action. (IX) We mea-
how they stood on a shorterwork week. They sured the willingnessto take part in action by
could reply on a 5-point scale from very posi- asking, "If it comes to action for the negotia-
tive to very negative. tions, will you take part in moderate/militant
(V) The expectation that participationhelps action?"(definitely,I thinkso, I don't thinkso,
to achieve the collective good: (a) The expec- definitely not).14
tation about one's own contribution to the
probabilityof success was operationalizedin RESULTS
the followingtwo statements:"It reallydoesn't
make much difference whether or not I take The Theory of the Willingness to Participate
partin action.""It is importantthat I take part Tables I and 2 summarizethe overall evalua-
in action, because in doing this I supportthe tion of the theory. Table 1 concentrateson the
union" (agree entirely, agree, disagree, dis- attitudetowardsthe collective goal andTable2
agree entirely). (b) The expectation about the on the willingness to participate.
numberof participantswas establishedas fol- Table 1 presents the correlations between
lows: "In your estimate, how many people at beliefs about the instrumentalityof shorter
your plantwill participatein moderate/militant workingtime for unemploymentreductionand
action in connection with the negotiations?" the attitudetowardshorterworkingtime in five
(very few, not so many, quite a few, very successive interviews.The data show a signifi-
many). (c) The expectation about success if cant relationshipbetween these two variables
many people participatewas measuredby the at all five points in time. It could be that people
question:"Imaginethat very manypeople take- believe that shorterworkinghours reduce un-
part in moderate/militant-action. Do you think employmentas a rationalizationfor theirdesire
that this will induce the employersto take into to have a shorterwork week. Thatis, it may be
account the union standpointin the negotia- that the attitudesproduce the beliefs about in-
tions?" (definitely, I think so, I don't think so, strumentalityratherthan the reverse. The sec-
definitely not). ond part of Table 1 examines this issue. This
Social motives. (VI) Three categories of partof the table presentsthe correlationsof the
people seemed significant:members of one's changes in the variables.15The argumentthat
family, colleagues, and direct superiors. A instrumentalityproducesattitudesis confirmed
variableindicativeof social motivationto par- if changesin one are correlatedwith changesin
ticipatewas calculated.Basic data were (a) the the other, for it is unlikely that other possible
value a person attaches to reactions of family determinantsof the attitude (for instance, the
members,colleagues, anddirect superiors,and need for more leisure time) change in the same
(b) the expected reactions of these persons to way. As Table I shows, changes in the vari-
participationand to nonparticipation.The so- ables are significantlycorrelated.
cial motivationscore is the sum of the products Table 2 is derived from six hierarchicalre-
of values and expectations. If persons expect gression analyses with stepwise inclusion
favorablereactions if they participateand un- (three for moderateand three for militantac-
favorableones if they do not, then the score is tion).16 Following a procedure suggested by
positive. If they expect unfavorablereactionsif
they participateand favorableones if they do
not, then the score is negative. 14 To overcome the drawbackthat an important

Rewardmotives. Two types of costs seemed variablewould only be measuredby one question,
important: (a) financial sacrifices, and (b) other questions were asked at other points in the
worsening of a person's position in the com- interviewsabout the attitudetowardaction. The an-
pany. (VII) For the financial sacrifices, we swers to these questions correlatedreasonablywell
asked: "Suppose that it would cost money if with those to the directquestionon the willingnessto
take partin action(meanr = .50 for moderateaction,
you took part in any action in connection with and .67 for militantaction), and they did not show
the negotiations. Do you feel this is not too any differences in their relationshipsto other vari-
detractive,detractive,or very detractive?"By ablest
this formulationwe set the expectancy compo- 15 Residualscores were computedby substracting
nent at 1 and restrictedourselves to the value from the score on time 2 the score on time 1 multi-
component.(VIII)For the position in the com- plied by the correlationbetween the two scores.
16 Originally,expectancy-valuetheory prescribed
pany, we assumed that no one would be indif-
ferent about his/her position in the company simple addition of the separate motives. This un-
assumes that different motives are
worsening. We set the value of a worsened realistically
mutuallyindependentand have the same weight. A
position at -1 and restrictedourselves to this more realisticapproachis to accountfor intercorre-
expectationby askingwhethera person'sposi- lations and different weights by using regression
tion in the company would worsen by par- analysisratherthan simple summation(cf. Mitchell,
ticipatingin moderate/militantaction. 1974).

This content downloaded from 130.237.29.138 on Tue, 27 Oct 2015 18:38:07 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
MOBILIZATION AND PARTICIPATION 591

Table 1. The Attitudes Towards Shorter Working Time and the Instrumentality of Shorter Working Time for
Reducing Unemployment: Pearson Correlations of Single and Change Scores
Instrumentality
Nov. Jan. Early Feb. End of Feb. April
a) Single Scores
Attitude Towards
-shorter working hours .47*** .37** .44*** .38*** .48***
-shorter working week .35** .34** .33** .38*** .21*
Early Feb.! End of Feb.
Nov./Jan. Jan./Early Feb. End of Feb. April
b) Change Scores
Attitude Towards
-shorter working hours .35** .29* .39*** .44***
-shorter working week .19* .36** .25* .11
* p<.05.
** p<.o1.
p<.OO1.

Finn and Mattson (1978), in each regression types of action(4 and 10percentin the last step
analysis the variables connected with one of and 20 and 31 percentin the first step). Militant
the three motives are included in the last step. actions are more controversialthan moderate
The data show that the contribution of each of actions. Thus, reactions of significant others
the three motives in this last step is significant; will be more pronouncedand have more influ-
each helps to account for the variance in the ence. Theoretically significant is the large
willingness to participate in action. Together contribution of the collective motives even
the motives account for 43 percent of the vari- when the othermotives are accountedfor. This
ance in the willingness to participate in militant is in oppositionto Olson's (1977)argumentthat
action and 38 percent of the variance for mod- persons are not motivated to participate in
erate action. collective behaviorby the collective good but
The contribution of reward motives is rela- only by selective incentives. For a better
tively small, possibly because these costs only theoreticalunderstandingit is useful to break
really count when it actually comes to action, down the collective motive again. Most of the
and then especially if the action goes on a long membershad a positive attitudetowardshorter
time. Alternatively, it may be that the kinds of working time (see next paragraph);hence it
costs asked about (financial sacrifices, wors- follows thatwhethera personwill be motivated
ening of the position in the company) are all in to participateby the collective good depends
the game for many people; only by becoming upon the expectancy component. The expec-
too high might they dissuade these people from tancy componentis madeup of three elements:
participation. There is a wide difference in the the expectation that participationcontributes
contribution of the social motives for the two to the probability of success; -the expected
numberof participants;and the expected suc-
cess if many people participate.The correla-
Table 2. Regressionof Motives on the Willingness tions between these elements were low, which
to Participate in Moderate and Militant underlinesthe fact that each plays his/herown
Action: R2 ChangesWhen a Motive is In-
troducedin the Last Stepa role in the decision to participate.This is made
clear by the /3 coefficients in Table 3. The
Moderate Militant prominence of two elements (a2 and b) de-
Action Action serves some comment. Feelings of solidarity
A R2 A R2 and responsibilityare reflected in the willing-
Collective Motives 13%*** 7%*** ness to supportthe union. Its weight validates
Social Motives 4%*** 10%*** Fireman and Gamson's (1979) argumentthat
RewardMotives 0.8%* 1%** groupsolidarityis an importantdeterminantof
a
This table reflects the results of six stepwise
participation.The significanceof expectations
regression analyses; the percentage in the table about the numberof participantsconfirms the
appliesto the motiveon the left when it is introduced argumentthat the expected numberof partici-
in the last step. pants is a self-fulfillingprophecy. Contraryto
* p<.05. Olson's logic, the willingnessto participatein
** p<.Ol. collective action appearsto be strengthenedby
*** p<.oo1. the belief that many others will participate.

This content downloaded from 130.237.29.138 on Tue, 27 Oct 2015 18:38:07 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
592 AMERICANSOCIOLOGICALREVIEW
Table 3. Regressionsof the Four Componentsof the Expectationthat ParticipationHelps to Achieve the
Collective Good on the Willingnessto Participate
ModerateAction MilitantAction
B /3 B la
al. My participationdoesn't matter .066 ** .052 .08*
(.027)a 11(.029)
a2. I participatebecause I want to supportthe union .296 39*** .282 35***
(.035) * (.038)
b. Numberof participants .236 .28*** .29 .33***
(.039) (.040)
c. Expected success if many people participate .654 11** .075 12**
(.027) (.029)
R2 .57 .56
a Standarderrors.
* .15<p<.10.
** p<.05.
*** p<.001.

The remainderof this discussion concerns knowledge is never more than a condition for
the results over the course of the campaign. the spreadof a positive attitudetoward a col-
Table- 4 gives a brief chronology of major lective good. The key concept here is the in-
events in the campaignin relationto the seven strumentalityof the collective good for social
interview waves. changes felt to be worth fightingfor or for the
preservation of a desirable situation. Cam-
Consensus Mobilization paignsfor the mobilizationof consensus strive
to make such instrumentalityplausible, often
Knowledge. Adequate diffusion of knowledge in the face of counterargumentsby the oppo-
of the collective good is the cornerstone of nent. The 1979 campaignfor a shorter work
every mobilization campaign. Collective week failed in this respect. The central ques-
goods.,however, are not invariablequantities. tion was whether a shorter work week would
They can change, influenced by circum- have a positive effect on employmentopportu-
stances, interaction with the opponent, etc. nity.
For a social movement,two dangerscan arise: As Figure 4 shows, after an initial increase
(a) the collective good as it is defined initially there is a dramaticdecrease in the extent to
does not become widely enough known; (b) which union membersbelieved that a shorter
changes in the definitionof the collective good work week would reduce unemployment.
do not become widely enough known. As can
be seen from Table 4, there were two policy
changes in the 1979negotiations.
Figure 3 clearly shows that both policy
changesled to difficultiesaboutthe knowledge
of the goals. After a quite adequateinitiallevel
(70-80Woknew what the goals were), with the 90
1st policy
change
first policy changethe numberof people aware 80 4
of the changedgoals was cut in half. A month 70 2nd policy
change
and a half later this number was once again 60
rising, but it did not reach the level of early
50
February.At the end of May the second policy
40
change took place, and again the number of
correct answers was cut in half. 30

In general, the union "elite" (the members 20


with a highereducationand/orlevel of partici- 10

pation in the union)was better informedof the


goals of action after policy changes. Members end of mid- early end of mid- end of
outside these categories were less well in- Nov. Jan Febr. Febr. April May
Note Responses to first interview
formed and more vulnerablewhen it came to
disseminationof knowledge about changes in Figure 3. Percentages of Union Members Who
policy. Could CorrectlyFormulatethe Demands
Beliefs and attitudes. Dissemination of for a ShorterWork Week

This content downloaded from 130.237.29.138 on Tue, 27 Oct 2015 18:38:07 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
MOBILIZATIONAND PARTICIPATION 593
Table 4. MajorEvents in the Campaign
August 1978 The chair of the IB FNV proposes the 35-hourwork week; mobilization
campaignstarts; discussion on shorterwork week begins.
November20-29, 1978 1st interview
November27, 1978 Governmentand employerorganizationsrefuse to negotiatea nation-wide
agreementon a shorterwork week.
December 1978 Steel strike in West Germanyfor a 35-hourwork week.
January4-18, 1979 2nd interview
End of January1979 Steel strike in West Germanylost.
January29-February9 3rd interview
Beginningof February1979 First policy change: 35 hours becomes 39 hours.
February19-March2 4th interview
March/April Negotiations with AKZO make no progress.
April3-18 5th interview
April 17 Negotiationswith AKZO break down.
April24 Second policy change: 39 hours becomes a few days off.
May 15 Negotiationswith AKZO start again.
May 18-26 6th interview
May 23 Agreementwith AKZO
June 5-18 Membershipmeetings:membershipagrees with contract.
June 11-July 11 7th interview

From the end of February onwards a majority instrumentality of the collective good for
no longer believed this. As expected, the de- valued social changes. Very often, as in the
velopments in the attitude toward a shorter case of reducing unemployment, the social
work week show the same picture, although change itself is above all discussion. The real
without becoming negative. These results problem is to make people believe that the
make clear the importance of beliefs about the collective good will advance this change.

Action Mobilization
definitely
instrumental
2.00 A mobilizingorganizationwill try to make the
.40 benefits of participationand the costs of non-
\30 participationas high as possible, and the costs
.20 . of participation and the benefits of non-
\

.10 participationas low as possible. There are


0?- various ways of doing this: (a) choosing the
-.10
type of action; (b) choosing the scene, and (c)
-.20 influencing the motives to participate. This
-.30
mustbe viewed in the context of maneuversby
\

-.40
the opponent and/or external events which
-2.00 A
may influencethe costs and benefits of partici-
definitely
not instru-
end of
Nov.
mid-
Jan.'
pation. The degree of success achieved in an
early
Febr.
end of
Febr.
mid-
April
mental
action-mobilizationcampaigncan be readfrom
Note to first
Responses
Significant
the willingness to take action.
interviews.
trend: F-lineair = 7.29, p <.01, df = 1.
Difference jan. Figure 5 presents the developments in the
- april: p<.01

willingnessto participatein moderateand mil-


Figure4. MeanPerceivedInstrumentalityof Shorter itant action. The figures for Ede and Oss did
WorkingHours for Reducing Unemploy- not differ significantly, so they are presented
ment together. In the establishmentsin Ede and Oss

This content downloaded from 130.237.29.138 on Tue, 27 Oct 2015 18:38:07 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
594 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

Moderate action Militant action


Willing to Willing to
participate participate
1.00 1.00
.40 .40
.30 .30
.20 - .20 -

0?0~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~
0~~~~~~~~~~~
- .20 -~~0~ .20 ?

- -~~~
.10 03 ~~ 0~~~~~~~~~~~
- .10 ?~~?
01 0

_O.,5 , -- ,-- - 00 0- -0
0-~~ - -O
- .30 - . 30--

- .40- - .40

Notwilling to late mid- early late mid- Notwilling to late mid- early late mid-
rarticipate Nov. Jan. Febr. Febr. April participate Nov. Jan. Febr. Febr. April

Ermen - -- Ec O-SS Dnen - F- Ede / Oss

Notes Ede and Oss, no significant differences between groups; no significant trend.
Emren, moderate action: linear trend; F-unique = 5.711, df = , p< .05; F-step = 5.554. df 1,
p < .05. Militant action: no significant trend; difference Nov. - April: p = .12.

Figure5. Mean Willingnessto Take Action

there was a weak willingness to participatein number of participantscould vary from very
moderateaction, and no willingness to partici- few to very many. Because membersestimated
pate in militant action throughout the entire the efficacy of an action based on the number
period. In Emmen,willingnessto participatein ot participants,the percentage that expected
both types of action was comparativelyhigh at very many colleagues to participate was of
first, but it gradually melted away. Initially, interest.
Emmen had the most potential participants, Figure 6 concentrates on the outcomes for
but by April the opposite was true. one of the three establishments(Emmen) be-
Fromthese results we can conclude that the cause of dramaticchanges there. In the other
union did not succeed in mobilizing its mem- two the percentageswere low throughoutthe
bers. In two of the three establishmentsthere campaign.
was a willingness to participate in moderate As Figure6 shows, the percentagesof union
action, it is true, but it very soon became clear memberswho expected very manyparticipants
that moderateaction would not be of any help, decline rapidly, indicating that the campaign
and the initialwillingnessto participatein mil- was losing its momentum.After an initial in-
itant action in the third establishment disap- crease (up to 58 percentin the case of moderate
peared. action and 39 percent in the case of militant
Changes in the costs and beliefits of partici- action), startingin Januarythere was a sharp
pation. Theoretically, the willingness to take decline which reached 4.5 percent in April, or
action is a function of collective, social and the level at Ede and Oss at the time.'7
rewardmotives. We have already shown that
the collective good lost in value. Over the same
periodthe expectationthat participationwould '' If, instead of the percentage that expect very
help to achieve the collective good lost its many participants, we use changes in the mean esti-
force, not because membersno longerbelieved mate of the number of participants, we find the same
that theirparticipationwould contributeto the pattern, except that the mean runs somewhat less
steeply. For moderate action, we found a significant
probabilityof success, but because they grew quadratic trend (F-unique = 7.074, df = 1, p = .01;
more and more pessimistic about the number F-step = 6. 181, df = 1, p = .01). For militant action
of participantsand the probabilityof success we foUnd a marginally significant linear trend (F-
even if many people were to participate. tunique - 3.33, df = 1, p = .08( F=step = 3.075, df =
Niuminber (f particip(lats. Estimates of the I, p .0)X.

This content downloaded from 130.237.29.138 on Tue, 27 Oct 2015 18:38:07 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
MOBILIZATION AND PARTICIPATION

employers went down to 25 percent, and for


moderateaction to 10 percent.
60
Due to failingconsensus mobilization,action
mobilization which lost its momentum, and
50 . externalevents that made success unlikely,the
collective motive to participate vanished. It
40 /
was weak in two of the three establishments
30 /
fromthe outset, and it disappearedin the third.
Since the rewardmotives had been negativefor
20 manypeople fromthe beginnning,18 only social
motives might have compensatedfor this loss
10
in motivation.In Emmen, however, the social
motives diminished as well, although not in
the same dramaticway as the collective mo-
end of mid- early eind of mid-
Nov. Jan. Febr. Febr. April tives. In Ede and Oss the social motives for
participationin militantaction were negative,
- militant action ----- moderate action so they strengthenedthe aversion to militant
Figure6. Percentagesof Union Membersin Emmen action. In the case of moderate action, how-
Who Expect that Very Many Colleagues ever, the social motives were positive and did
will Participate in Action, by Type of compensate for the absence of collective mo-
Action tives. This explains why we found a weak
willingness to participatein moderate action
there.
Probability of success. Perhaps more than Type of action. Differentcosts and benefits
the other determinantsof the willingness to are associated with participationin different
participate,the probabilityof success is influ- types of action. Table 5 summarizesevidence
enced by external events. The 1979 negotia- on the interactionof motives and moderateor
tions provide a good example. militantaction in relationto willingnessto par-
In 1979,at the startof the negotiationsin the ticipate. Persons who only wish to take partin
Netherlands, a strike broke out in West Ger- moderate action are compared with persons
manyin which a shorterwork week was also at who are also willing to take part in militant
stake. The strike lasted six weeks. Both sides actions.'9 The first groupis of interestbecause
played hard. Ultimately the West German they perceive such differencesin the costs and
unions lost the strike, and early in February benefits that they are not willingto participate
they concluded an agreementwhich made no
reference to a shorter work week. This out- militant action is
40%1
come also affected the negotiations in the definitely
effective
0
Netherlands, and this was expressed most 30%-
- - nmerate action is
definitely
clearly in the expected success of actions effective

there. Figure 7 shows the changes in those 20%


expectations. Since we found no significant
differencesbetween the establishments,the re- 10% - _ - -

sults are here combined.


Even before the disappointingend to the
West Germansteel strike,the adamantattitude late
Nov.
mid-
Jan.
early
Febr.
late
Febr.
mid-
April
of the Dutch employers had already made it
clear that little could be gained by moderate Note derate
p 4.01;
action linear trerd, F-unque = 7.313, df = 1,
F-step = 7.71, df = 1, p < .01.
action. The numberof unionmemberswho felt Militant
F-step =
action F-unique = 6.21, df = 1, p .05;
6.17, df = 1, p < .05.
moderateaction would be effective showed an
immediate and rapid decrease. Members re- Figure7. The Effectiveness of Trade Union Action
mained optimistic longer about the effective- in Attainingthe Goal of a Shorter Work
ness of militantaction. But this optimismalso Week
suffereda setback when, around mid-January
and early February,the metal unions in West
"I For instance, on the average, 50%feared wors-
Germanylost their strike. Of the union mem- ening of their position in the companyin the case of
bers questioned in early February,60 percent participationin militantaction, and 32%in the case
felt this would make the negotiations in the of moderateaction.
Netherlandsa good deal more difficult. Figure '9 Seventy-threepersons were not willing to par-
7 reflects this gloomy outlook; the percentage ticipatein any kindof action. They are omittedfrom
of union members who were confident that this table because they are not relevantfor this dis-
militantaction would change the minds of the cussion.

This content downloaded from 130.237.29.138 on Tue, 27 Oct 2015 18:38:07 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
596 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICALREVIEW
Table 5. Mean Costs and Benefits of Participationin Moderateor MilitantAction by Willingnessto Take
Action
Wishes to Participatein
Wishes to Participatein Both Moderateand
ModerateAction Only MilitantAction
(n = 79) (n = 200)
Collective Motives
a. How many colleagues will partici-
pate in moderateaction? 2.41 2.82
same for militantaction 1.69 2.54
b. Is moderateaction effective? 0.51 0.25
same for militantaction 0.51 0.85
Social Motives
c. moderateaction 0.26 0.56
militantaction -0.68 0.44
RewardMotives
d. Will position in company grow
worse as a resultof participation
in moderateaction? -0.33 -0.25
same for militantaction -0.66 -0.40

in militantaction. The first column of Table 5 collective motive is strongerfor militantaction


reveals these differences, especially in the so- because such action is perceived to be more
cial and reward motives. In the perceptionof efficacious. If one has to accept costs anyhow,
these persons, for militantaction the costs of the more efficacious type of action is to be
participationare considerablyhigher than for preferredeven if the costs are higher.
moderate action. Such differences could be Different plants. There were large dif-
balanced by collective motives. A look at ferences amongthe three plantsin the strength
Table5, however, makes it clearthat this is not of the union (Table 6). Of the three establish-
the case. There are no differencesin perceived ments, the union was strongest in Emmen. In
efficacy, and regarding the number of col- accordance with resource mobilization lit-
leagues, these persons are more pessimistic erature, at the start of the negotiations the
about militant action. In their perception, willingness to take action was the highest in
moderate action has a higher probability of Emmen; Table 6 shows why. To summarize
success because they expect more people to be the evidence: the strongerthe position of the
willingto participate.So why shouldthey take union, the greateris the chance that colleagues
the higher costs of militantaction? will motivate people to participate;the less
A comparisonof this group with the group they fear for worsening their position in the
that supportedmilitantaction shows important company, the more favorable can be the ex-
differences in social and collective motives. pected number of participants.The result is
Whereasthe social motives of the "moderate" that the membersare more easily mobilized.A
group are negative, those of the "militant" union can capitalize on this state of affairsby
group are positive. Optimism about the effi- fightinga conflict where it is strongest,that is,
cacy of militantaction and the numberof par- in plants that are highly unionized and have a
ticipants results in strong collective motives strong union network. This does not imply,
amongthe "militant"groupas comparedto the however, that the union can be assured of
"moderate"group. willingness to take action in such plants. This
It is of interest to note that the differences only refers to the potential which may be
between the two groupson the rewardmotives mobilized. A campaignthat does not go well,
are not very large. In both groups many per- counterpropaganda,and setbacks can also
sons expect a worseningof theirposition in the crush willingnessto take action in such plants.
company. Nevertheless, all these people are The negotiationsof 1979were a vivid example
willing to participatebecause other motives of this.
compensate for the costs.
The evidence in Table 5 warrantsa final re-
DISCUSSION
mark. The differences in perceived costs and
benefits of each type of action for the "mili- The theory formulatedin this paper aims at a
tant"group suggest that for this group militant break with both the traditional social-
action is more attractive. The social and re- psychologicalapproachesto social movements
ward motives differ only slightly, whereas the and the neglect of social-psychological

This content downloaded from 130.237.29.138 on Tue, 27 Oct 2015 18:38:07 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
MOBILIZATIONAND PARTICIPATION 597
Table 6. The Strengthof the TradeUnion, the Expected Reactionsof Colleagues,the Fear for a Worsened
Position, and the Expected Number of Participantsin the Three Plants
Trade Expects Positive Fears for a Expects
Level of Union Reactions of Worsened Very Many
Organization Network Colleaguesa Positiona Participantsb
Enka-Emmen 65% + 60% 32% 39%
Enka-Ede 30% - 23% 59% 5%
AKZO-Pharma-Oss 15% + 25% 59% 5%
a Expectanciesof participationin militantaction. Mean
percentagesfrom the series of interviews.
b
Expectanciesof participationin militantaction. Highest percentage.

analyses by resource mobilization theory. not participate in a social movement unless


Contraryto the traditionalsocial-psychological selective incentives motivate them to do so.
approach,participationin a social movementis Resource mobilizationtheory does not really
assumedto be rational.The emphasisis not on solve that problem. Concepts like ideological
personality characteristics or psychological incentives (Gamson, 1975; Carden, 1978),
states, but on the psychological process of feelings of solidarity (Gamson and Fireman,
weighingcosts and benefits. One of the objec- 1979) or responsibility(Fleishman, 1980), the
tions to the traditionalapproachis that it de- perceived indispensability of an individual's
fines participationas tension release, and thus contribution (Tolbert, 1981), differences be-
it does not matterin which movementa person tween action forms in vulnerabilityto free rid-
participates. In the theory presented in this ing (Gamsonand Fireman, 1979;Oliver, 1980),
article it does. Participationis seen as a ra- different production functions (Oberschall,
tionalchoice in the situationas the person per- 1980; Oliver et al., 1983), or thresholds
ceives it, and as a way to obtain desired out- (Granovetter, 1978) do not really touch the
comes. In the eyes of the participant,partici- heartof the matter,which is-that persons have
pation is a means of reachingvalued goals. to decide at a point when they do not know
These goals and theirrelationto factors such whether others will participate.20 This article
as relative deprivation and frustration have argues that the problem can be solved on a
been the subject of much discussion in social- social-psychologicallevel. Since people have
movement literature. Resource mobilization expectations about others' behavior, they can
has ruled this discussion out of order without formulate their "own" production functions.
solving the problem. The theory developed in As the evidence presented demonstrates,this
this articleattemptsto reconcilethe social psy- production function heavily influences the
chological and resource mobilization ap- willingnessto participate.On a collective level,
proaches in this respect. Feelings of relative the expectation that others will participate
deprivationor frustrationdo not necessarily works as a self-fulfillingprophecy. Counterto
evoke agreementwith the goals of a movement Olson's argument,a collective good can moti-
which pretendsto remedy these feelings: goals vate persons to participatein a social move-
have to be perceived as instrumentalto the ment if they expect that others will also par-
eliminationof these feelings. The research re- ticipate.
sults support the validity of this argument. 'Moreover,if the expectancy componentis a
Theoreticalemphasismust thereforeshift from little larger than zero, a collective motive to
relative deprivation to the perceived instru- participatecan exist if the collective good is
mentalityof the collective good for the elimi- valuedhighly(cf. Oberschall,1980).If a person
nation of relative deprivation. Such percep- comes from a supportive social background
tions do not originatespontaneously.Consen- (positive social motive) then there can be quite
sus mobilizationis needed for this. Campaigns a few nonsocialcosts of participation(negative
are needed which explain the situation and rewardmotive) before the balance turnsto the
make clear why the collective good will bring negative. Oliver et al.'s (1983) theoretical no-
relief (cf. Schwartz, 1976).Agreementwith the
goals of the movement does not necessarily
20 Pinard (1983) arrived at the same conclusion.
lead to participation:a person may doubt
whether participationwill help to achieve the Using an expectancy-valueframework,Pinardtried
goals, social and/orrewardmotives may be too to solve the problem primarilyby expanding the
value componentwith moralobligationas a separate
negative. force. He mentioned expectancy of success as a
Theoriesthat stress the rationalityof partici- factorbut did not elaborateit in detail. In contrastto
pation in a social movementhave to solve the Pinard,the solutionhere is soughtin the expectancy
problemof the dilemmaof collective behavior. component by introducing "expectations about
As Olson (1977)stated it, rationalpersons will others' behavior"as a separatefactor.

This content downloaded from 130.237.29.138 on Tue, 27 Oct 2015 18:38:07 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
598 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICAL REVIEW

tions about the differentproductionfunctions (Oberschall, 1973) are important in this re-
that characterizethe relationshipbetween in- spect. Influencing reward motives demands
dividual contribution,the number of partici- manipulationof rewardsand punishments,for
pantsand the productionof the collective good instance, by creating organizations that can
are not invalidatedby this argument.In par- help victims, decreaserisks or collect money in
ticular, their hypotheses concerning the dif- supportof activists (cf. Morris, 1981).
ferentialmobilizabilityof people dependingon
the partof a functionthat is relevantfor them
still stand. We must keep in mind, however, REFERENCES
that individualsconstruct their own functions
based on their expectations; although these Barnes, Samuel H. and Max Kaase
expectationsneed not be real, they are real in 1979 PoliticalAction. Mass Participationin Five
WesternDemocracies. London: Sage.
their consequences. Campbell,Donald and JulianC. Stanley
The evidence presented makes it clear that 1966 Experimentaland Quasi-ExperimentalDe-
such expectations, in combinationwith selec- signs for Research. Chicago: Rand Mc-
tive costs and benefits, are of greatimportance Nally.
for the choice a person makes among alterna- Campbell,John P. and Robert D. Pritchard
tive forms of action. For instance, in the eyes 1977 "Motivationtheory in industrialand orga-
of some respondentsthe goal could be reached nizationalpsychology."Pp. 63-131 in Mar-
by moderateaction. Why shouldthey take the vin D. Dunnette(ed.), Handbookof Indus-
higherrisks of militantaction? For those who trial and Organizational Psychology.
Chicago:Rand McNally.
did not believe moderateactionto be effective, Carden,MarenL.
it did not make much sense to accept the costs 1978 "The proliferationof a social movement,
of such action. They preferredto participatein ideology and individual incentives in the
militant action, even though the perceived contemporary feminist movement." Pp.
costs were higher. 179-96 in Louis Kriesberg(ed.), Research
People's expectations are based on past ex- in Social Movements,Conflictand Change,
periences. In a mobilization campaign a Volume 1. Greenwich,CT: JAI.
movementorganizationtries to influencethese Davies, James
1962 "Towardsa theory of revolution."Ameri-
expectations. Resource mobilization theory can Sociological Review 27:5-19.
has used the mobilizationconcept in a rather Feather, N.
unspecific way. By makingthe distinctionbe- 1982 Expectations and Actions: Expectancy-
tween consensus and action mobilizationwe Value Modelsin Psychology.Hillsdale,NJ:
separatedthe processes of convincing and ac- Erlbaum.
tivating. The researchresults on the spreadof Ferree, Myra M. and FrederickD. Miller
knowledge and the beliefs about the instru- Forth- "Mobilizationand meaning:towardan inte-
mentalityof shorterworkingtime showed the com- grationof social psychologicalandresource
importanceof consensus mobilizationas a sep- ing perspectives on social movements."
Sociological Inquiry.
arate process. Schwartz(1976)made a similar Finn, J. D. and I. Mattson
distinctionbetween "ignorancereduction"and 1978 MultivariateAnalysis in Educational Re-
"organizational disciplinization." The im- search. Chicago: InternationalEducation
portance of such distinctions is that they Service.
specify convincing and activating as two dif- Fireman,Bruce and WilliamA. Gamson
ferent processes with different determinants. 1979 "Utilitarianlogic in the resource mobiliza-
In yet another way, research on mobilization tion perspective." Pp. 8-45 in Mayer N.
would do well,to specify mobilizationefforts. Zald and John D. McCarthy (eds.), The
Attemptsto influencedifferentmotives require Dynamics of Social Movements. Cam-
bridge, MA: Winthrop.
different efforts. Influencing the collective Fleishman,John A.
motive demands consensus mobilization for 1980 "Collective action as helping behavior:ef-
the collective good, but also attemptsto influ- fects of responsibilitydiffusion on contri-
ence the expectations about the behavior of butions to a public good." Journalof Per-
others, the probabilityof success, and the indi- sonality and Social Psychology 38:629-37.
vidual contributionto the probabilityof suc- Freeman,Jo
cess. For instance, by means of tryouts it can 1979 "Resource mobilization and strategy: a
be proved that others will participate.This is a model for analyzingsocial movementorga-
delicate affair, because one can make persons nization actions." Pp. 167-89 in Mayer
N. Zald and John D. McCarthy(eds.), The
believe that enough people will participateand Dynamics of Social Movements. Cam-
that their participationis not necessary. Inten- bridge, MA: Winthrop.
sifying social motives requires influencing a Freud, Sigmund
person's social environment. Social networks 1922 GroupPsychologyandthe Analysisof Ego.
(Snow et al., 1980) and mobilizationen bloc London: Hogarth.

This content downloaded from 130.237.29.138 on Tue, 27 Oct 2015 18:38:07 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
MOBILIZATION AND PARTICIPATION 599

Gamson, WilliamA. extensions, critique." Pp. 125-63 in Nor-


1975 The strategyof Social Protest. Homewood, man T. Feather (ed.), Expectations and
IL: Dorsey. Actions. Hillsdale:Erlbaum.
Gamson, William A., Bruce Fireman and Steve Landsberger,Henri A.
Rytina 1976 "Labormovements, social movementsand
1982 Encounters with Unjust Authorities. social mobility." Pp. 839-77 in Robert
Homewood, IL: Dorsey. Dubin (ed.), Handbookof Work Organiza-
Gerlach,LutherP. and VirginiaH. Hine tion and Society. Chicago:Rand McNally.
1970 People, Power, Change:Movementsof So- Leahy, Peter and Allen Mazur
cial Transformation. Indianapolis: 1978 "A comparisonof movements opposed to
Bobbs-Merrill nuclearpower, fluoridationand abortion."
Geschwender,James A. Pp. 143-54 in Louis Kriesberg (ed.), Re-
1968 "Explorations in the theory of social search in Social Movements, Conflictsand
movementsandrevolutions."Social Forces Change, Volume 1. Greenwich,CT: JAI.
47:127-35. LeBon, Gustave
Granberg,Donald and Sbren Holmberg [1903] "The mind of the crowds." Pp. 6-11 in
1983 "Modelingthe relationshipsamong prefer- 1968 Louis E. Genevie (ed.), Collective Behav-
ence, expectations and voting behavior." ior and Social Movements. Itasca, IL:
Departmentof PoliticalScience, University Peacock.
of Gdteborg. Marsh, Alan
Granovetter,Mark 1977 Protest and Political Consciousness.
1978 "Thresholdmodels of collective behavior." London/BeverlyHills: Sage.
AmericanJournalof Sociology 83:1420-43. Marx, Gary T. and James L. Wood
Gurr,Ted Robert 1975 "Strandsof theory and research in collec-
1970 Why Men Rebel. Princeton,NJ: Princeton tive behavior." Annual Review of Sociol-
University Press. ogy 1:363-429.
Heberle, Rudolf McCarthy,John D. and Mayer N. Zald
1968 "Social movements I: types and functions 1976 "Resource mobilizationand social move-
of social movements."Pp. 438-44 in D.L. ments: a partialtheory." AmericanJournal
Sills (ed.), InternationalEncyclopedia of of Sociology 82:1212-93.
the Social Sciences. New York:Macmillan. Mitchel, Robert C.
Hoffer, Eric 1979 "National environmentallobbies and the
1951 The True Believer. New York: Harper. apparentillogic of collective action." Pp.
Isaac, Larry,ElizabethMutranand SheldonStryker 87-121 in CliffordS. Russell (ed.), Collec-
1980 "Politicalprotest orientationsamong black tive Decision Making Applications from
and white adults." American Sociological PublicChoiceTheory.Baltimore:The Johns
Review 45:191-213. Hopkins University Press.
Jenkins,J. Craig Mitchell, Terence R.
1983 "Resource mobilization theory and the 1974 "Expectancy models of job satisfaction,
study of social movements." Annual Re- occupational preference and effort: a
view of Sociology 9:527-53. theoretical, methodological and empirical
Kenniston,Kenneth appraisal." Psychological Bulletin
1968 Young Radicals: Notes on Committed 81:1053-77.
Youth. New York: Harvest. Moore, Robert S.
Kerpelman,Louis C. 1975 "Religion as a source of variation in
1969 "Student political activism and ideology: working-class images of society." Pp.
comparativecharacteristicsof activists and 35-55 in Martin Bulmer (ed.), Working-
non-activists."Journalof CounselingPsy- Class Images of Society. London: Rout-
chology 16:8-13. ledge and Kegan Paul.
Klandermans,P.G. Bert Morris,Aldon
1979 "Werklozen en de werklozenbeweging." 1981. "Black Southern student sit-in move-
Mens en Maatschappij54:5-33. ments: an analysis of internal organiza-
1983a"The expected numberof participants,the tion." American Sociological Review
effectiveness of collective action, and the 46:744-67.
willingness to participate:the free riders
dilemmareconsidered."Paperpresentedat Oberschall,Anthony
the 1983AmericanSociologicalAssociation 1973 Social Conflictand Social Movements.En-
Annual Meeting, Detroit. glewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
1983b "Rotter's I.E.-scale and socio-political 1980 "Loosely structuredcollective conflict: a
action-taking:the balance of 20 years of theory and an application."Pp. 45-68 in
research."EuropeanJournalof Social Psy- Louis Kriesberg(ed.), Research in Social
chology 13:399-415. Movements, Conflictand Change, Volume
Kornhauser,William 3. Greenwich,CT: JAI,
1959 The politics of mass society. Glencoe, IL: Oliver, Pamela
Free Press. 1980 "Rewardsand punishmentsas selective in-
Kuhl, Julius centives for collective action: theoretical
1982 "Expectancy-value approach within the investigations." American Journal of
theory of social motivation: elaborations, Sociology 85:1356-75.

This content downloaded from 130.237.29.138 on Tue, 27 Oct 2015 18:38:07 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions
600 AMERICAN SOCIOLOGICALREVIEW
Oliver, Pamela, GeraldMarwelland Ruy Teixeira microstructuratapproachto differentialre-
1983 "Group heterogeneity, interdependence cruitment."AmericanSociological Review
and the productionof collective goods: a 45:787-801.
theory of the critical mass, I." Madison, Tilly, Charles
WI: Departmentof Sociology, University 1979 "Repertoiresof contentionin Americaand
of Wisconsin. Britain, 1750-1830."Pp. 126-156 in Mayer
Olson, Mancur Zald and John McCarthy (eds.), The
1977 The Logic of Collective Action. Public Dynamics of Social Movements. Cam-
Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cam- bridge, MA: Winthrop.
bridge, MA: HarvardUniversity Press. Toch, Hans
Pinard,Maurice 1966 The Social Psychology of Social Move-
1983 "Fromdeprivationto mobilization."Paper ments. London: Methuen.
presented at the Annual Meetings of the Tolbert, Pamela
American Sociological Association, De-
troit. 1981 "Determinantsof social movement partici-
Ragin, Charles C., Shelley Coverman and Mark pation." Paper presented at the Annual
Meetingsof the AmericanSociologicalAs-
Hayward
1982 "Major labor disputes in Britain 1902- sociation, Toronto.
1938." American Sociological Review Useem, Bert
47:238-53. 1980 "Solidaritymodel, breakdownmodel and
Roberts Ron E. and Robert Marsh Kloss the Boston anti-busingmovement."Ameri-
1974 Social Movements Between the Balcony can Sociological Review 45:357-69.
and the Barricade. Saint Louis: C. V. Walsh, EdwardJ.
Mosby. 1978 "Mobilizationtheoryvis a vis a mobilization
Rothman,Jack process: the case of the United Farm
1974 Planningand Organizingfor Social Change. Workersmovement."Pp. 155-77 in Louis
New York: ColumbiaUniversity Press. Krnesberg(ed.), Research in Social Move-
Rotter, JulianB. ments, Conflicts and Change, Volume 1.
1954 Social Learning and Clinical Psychology. Greenwich,CT: JAI.
Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. Walsh, EdwardJ. and Rex H. Warland
1972 "Beliefs, social attitudes and behavior: a 1983 "Social movementinvolvementin the wake
social learninganalysis." Pp. 335-51 in Ju- of a nuclearaccident:activists and free rid-
lian B. Rotter, June E. Chance, and E. ers in the ThreeMileIslandarea."American
JerryPhares(eds.), Applicationsof a Social Sociological Review 48:764-81.
LearningTheoryof Personality.New York:
Holt, Rinehart& Winston. Zald, Mayer and John D. McCarthy
Schwartz, Michael 1979 The Dynamics of Social Movements: Re-
1976 RadicalProtest and Social Structure.New source Mobilization, Social Control and
York: Academy Press. Tactics. Cambridge,MA: Winthrop.
Smelser, Neil J. Zurcher,Louis A., Jr., and David A. Snow
1971 Theoryof Collective Behavior.New York: 1981 "Collective behavior: social movements."
Free Press. Pp. 447-82 in MorrisRosenbergand Ralph
Snow-,DavidA., Louis A. Zurcher,Jr., and Sheldon H. Turner (eds.), Social Psychology,
Ekland-Olson Sociological Perspectives. New York:
1980 "Social networksand social movements:a Basic.

This content downloaded from 130.237.29.138 on Tue, 27 Oct 2015 18:38:07 UTC
All use subject to JSTOR Terms and Conditions

You might also like