You are on page 1of 109

Enterprise Asset

Management

Improving asset availability, reliability and capacity


with next-generation digital asset performance
management solutions

View our ebook


Volume 17 • Number 1 • January/February 2019
magazine

Volume 17 • Number 1 • January/February 2019


www.ieee.org/power

on the 73
cover

©istockphoto.com/sibeRianaRt
people: ©istockphtoto.com/Rawpixel
icons: footage fiRm, inc.

features

contents
20 European Union Electricity Markets 53 A Change Is Coming
By Tomás Gómez, Ignacio Herrero, Pablo Rodilla, By Gianluca Fulli, Marcelo Masera,
Rodrigo Escobar, Salvatore Lanza, Amanda Spisto, and Silvia Vitiello
Ignacio de la Fuente, Maria Luisa Llorens,
and Paula Junco 67 Wholesale Electricity Markets
in the United States
32 Electricity Markets in the United States By Emma Nicholson and Arnie Quinn
By Eugene Litvinov, Feng Zhao,
and Tongxin Zheng 73 Three Waves of U.S. Reforms
By Benjamin F. Hobbs and Shmuel S. Oren
43 The New Zealand Electricity Market
By Andy Philpott, Grant Read, 82 PV-Battery Systems for Critical Loads
Stephen Batstone, and Allan Miller During Emergencies
By Chanaka Keerthisinghe,
Mareldi Ahumada-Paras, Lilo D. Pozzo,
Daniel S. Kirschen, Hugo Pontes,
Wesley K. Tatum, and Marvi A. Matos

columns &
departments
4 From the Editor 94 Society News
10 Letters to the Editor 98 Calendar
14 Leader’s Corner 104 In My View
18 Guest Editorial

94
Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/MPE.2018.2879124

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 1


magazine
IEEE Periodicals/Magazines Department
445 Hoes Lane, Piscataway, NJ 08854 USA
www.ieee.org/magazines
Editor-in-Chief M. Shahidehpour, G.B. Sheblé, J.C. Smith, Geraldine Krolin-Taylor, Senior Managing Editor
Michael I. Henderson, mih.psat@gmail.com M. Thomas, E. Uzunovic, S.S. Venkata, Janet Dudar, Senior Art Director
J. Wang, S. Widergren Gail A. Schnitzer, Associate Art Director
Associate Editors Theresa L. Smith, Production Coordinator
Spanish Editorial Board Felicia Spagnoli, Advertising Production Manager
John Paserba, History Enrique Tejera, Editor-in-Chief Peter M. Tuohy, Production Director
Editors: M. Baqueadano, G. Gonzalez, G. Valverde Kevin Lisankie, Editorial Services Director
Editorial Board Dawn M. Melley, Staff Director, IEEE Publishing
L. Barroso, A. Conejo, J. Feltes, N. Hatziargyriou, Advertising Operations
T. Hong, B. Johnson, B. Kroposki, N. Lu, Erik Henson, Naylor Association Solutions
IEEE prohibits discrimination, harassment, and bullying. For more infor-
B. Mather, M. Miller, M. O’Malley, N. Ochoa, +1 352 333 3443, fax: +1 352 331 3525 mation, visit http://www.ieee.org/web/aboutus/whatis/policies/p9-26.html.
J. Paserba, C.E. Root, H. Rudnick, ehenson@naylor.com
Promoting Sustainable Forestry

ieee power & energy society (pes)


SFI-01681

The IEEE Power & Energy Society is an organization of IEEE members whose principal interest is the advancement of the science and practice of electric power generation,
transmission, distribution, and utilization. All members of the IEEE are eligible for membership in the Society. Mission Statement: To be the leading provider of scientific and
engineering information on electric power and energy for the betterment of society, and the preferred professional development source for our members.

Governing Board S. Ninalowo, Women in Power Publications


S. Rahman, President J. Benedict, Marketing Publications Board Chair, M. Crow
F. Lambert, President-Elect M. Seif, Membership Development Editors-in-Chief
M. Armstrong, Vice President, Chapters IEEE Electrification Magazine, I. Husain
F. Rahmatian, Vice President, Technical Activities Technical Council
F. Rahmatian, Chair, V. Vittal, Vice Chair IEEE Power Engineering Letters, M. Fotuhi-
E. Uzunovic, Vice President, Education Firuzabad
B. Pal, Vice President, Publications H. Chen, Secretary, M. Sanders, Past-Chair
IEEE Trans. on Energy Conversion, J. Jatskevich
W. Bishop, Vice President, Meetings Technical Committee Chairs IEEE Trans. on Power Delivery, W. Xu
J.C. Montero Q, Vice President, Membership K. Schneider, Analytical Methods for IEEE Trans. on Power Systems, N. Hatziargyriou
& Image Power Systems IEEE Trans. on Smart Grid, J. Wang
S. Bahramirad, Vice President, New Initiatives/ K. Chen, Electric Machinery IEEE Trans. on Sustainable Energy, B. Chowdhury
Outreach W.T. Jewell, Energy Development & Power IEEE Power & Energy Technology Systems Journal,
N. Hadjsaid, Treasurer Generation S. Sudhoff
J. Bian, Secretary C. Ashton, Energy Storage & Stationary Battery IEEE Power & Energy Magazine, M. Henderson
D. Novosel, Past-President E. Bascom, Insulated Conductors eNewsletter, S. Fattah
D. Diaz, Region Rep., U.S. & Canada T. Koshy, Nuclear Power Engineering PES Representative to IEEE Press, Open
J. Milanovic, Region Rep., Europe, Middle East, M. Dood, Power System Communications Website, Open
& Africa & Cybersecurity
S. Leon, Region Rep., Latin America C. Vournas, Power System Dynamic Performance Meetings
D. Sharafi, Region Rep., Asia & Pacific J. McBride, Power System Instrumentation Committee Chairs
B. Enayati, Member-at-Large & Measurements General Meeting Steering, D. Hall
R. Kappagantu, Member-at-Large L. Barroso, Power System Operation Planning Joint Technical Committee Meeting Steering,
H. Koch, Member-at-Large & Economics S. Ward
J. Yu, Member-at-Large R. Patterson, Power System Relaying & Control Technically Cosponsored Conferences Steering,
S. Chandler, Smart Building, Load & J. Mitra
IEEE Division VII Director Transmission & Distribution Conference &
B. Meyer Customer Systems
J. Gravelle, Substations Exposition Committee for North America
Steering, C. Segneri
IEEE Division VII Director-Elect S. Hensley, Surge Protective Devices
Innovative Smart Grid Technology Conference–
M. Sanders T. Irwin, Switchgear
S. McNelly, Transformers Europe, D. Van Hertem
PES Executive Director G. Chang, Transmission & Distribution Innovative Smart Grid Technology Conference–
Patrick Ryan, +1 732 465 6618, Asia, TBD
fax +1 732 562 3881, p.ryan@ieee.org Technical Council Coordinating Committees Website, Open
D. Houseman, Intelligent Grid & Emerging
Standing Committee Chairs Technology Education
H. Louie, Constitution & Bylaws D. Alexander, Marine Systems Committee Chairs
V. Kolluri, Fellows D. Lew, Wind & Solar Power Power and Energy Education, S. Brahma
N. Hadjsaid, Finance Scholarship Plus, J. Peer
A. Apostolov, History Technical Council Standing Committees Website, Open
F. Lambert, Long-Range Planning M. Sanders, Awards
D. Novosel, Nominations & Appointments V. Vittal, Technical Sessions New Initiatives and Outreach
H. Chen, Organization & Procedures Committee Chairs
Chapter Representatives T. Burse, Standards Coordination IEEE Smart Village, R. Larsen, Chair
D. Diaz, B. Djokic, B. Gwyn, M. Hunt, D. Toland, Webmaster R. Podmore, Vice-Chair
J. Khan, N. Logic, A. Nassif, P. Pabst, Open, Industry Education Industry Outreach, J. Giri, Chair
M. Papic, M. Patel, S. Pawale, Website, K. Anastasopoulos
M. Stryjewski, C. Wong
Chapter Committee Chairs
Z. Wang, Electronic Communications
C. Diamond, Awards & Resources IEEE Power & Energy Magazine
N. Nair, Distinguished Lecturer Program IEEE Power & Energy Magazine (ISSN 1540-7977) (IPEMCF) is published bimonthly by the Institute of Electrical and
Z. Wang, Chapters Website Electronics Engineers, Inc. Headquarters: 3 Park Avenue, 17th Floor, New York, NY 10016-5997 USA. Responsibility for  the
contents rests upon the authors and not upon the IEEE, the Society, or its members. IEEE Operations Center (for orders, sub-
Membership & Image Committee Chairs scriptions, address changes): 445 Hoes Lane, Piscataway, NJ 08854 USA. Telephone: +1 732 981 0060, +1 800 678 4333.
T. Doggett, VP Deputy Individual copies: IEEE members US$20.00 (first copy only), nonmembers US$84 per copy. Subscription Rates: Society members
A. Vaccaro, Awards & Recognition included with membership dues. Subscription rates available upon request. Copyright and reprint permissions: Abstracting is permitted
J. Hofman, Young Professionals with credit to the source. Libraries are permitted to photocopy beyond the limits of U.S. Copyright law for the private use of patrons 1)
L.F. Gaitán, Social Media those post-1977 articles that carry a code at the bottom of the first page, provided the per-copy fee indicated in the code is paid through
the Copyright Clearance Center, 222 Rosewood Drive, Danvers, MA 01923 USA; 2) pre-1978 articles without fee. For other copying,
G. González, Web Site Development
reprint, or republication permission, write Copyrights and Permissions Department, IEEE Operations Center, 445 Hoes Lane, Piscat-
away, NJ 08854 USA. Copyright © 2019 by the Institute of Electrical and Electronics Engineers, Inc. All rights reserved. Periodicals
postage paid at New York, NY, and at additional mailing offices. Postmaster: Send address changes to IEEE Power & Energy Magazine,
Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/MPE.2018.2879125 IEEE Operations Center, 445 Hoes Lane, Piscataway, NJ 08854 USA. Canadian GST #125634188 printed in U.s.a.

2 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


Fully integrated power system analysis software

DIgSILENT announces

PowerFactory 2019
DIgSILENT has set standards and trends in power system modelling,
analysis and simulation for more than 25 years. The proven advan-
tages of the PowerFactory software are its overall functional integra-
tion, its extensive modelling and analysis capabilities for generation,
transmission, distribution and industrial networks, and its powerful
data management tools to ensure data consistency and traceability
while enhancing overall work efficiency.
The new version PowerFactory 2019 addresses two major goals for
the integrated analysis of power systems. A new Unit Commitment
and Dispatch Optimisation tool allows the network analysis to be
complemented by a market simulation, with a single entry point of
information for your simulation model, thereby maximising data
consistency and work efficiency. Secondly, the new co-simulation
for single and multiple time domains (RMS-RMS, RMS-EMT and
EMT-EMT) allows unlimited combination of RMS/EMT-type models of
different complexity requiring different integration steps. The mixed
co-simulation is particularly well suited for the analysis of systems
with high penetration of converter-based generation and power
electronics in general.
SELECTED NEW FEATURES:
G 08(1)
Type Gen 08
~
SG

Unit Commitment and Dispatch Optimisation tool


Bus 37(1) Line 26 - 29(1)
Line Type 26 - 29

2,00
Load 26(1) Load 29(1)
Trf Type 25 - 37 YNy0

General Load Type General Load Type


G 10(1)
Trf 25 - 37(1)

Type Gen 10 Line 26 - 28(1) Line 28 - 29(1)


Line Type 26 - 28 Line Type 28 - 29
~
SG

1,00
Bus 25(1) Bus 26(1) Bus 28(1) Bus 29(1)
Bus 30(1)
Line Type 26 - 27

Trf Type 29 - 38 YNy0


Line 26 - 27(1)

Line 25 - 26(1)
Trf 29 - 38(1)
Line Type 02 - 25
Trf Type 02 - 30 YNy0

Line 02 - 25(1)

Line Type 25 - 26
Trf 02 - 30(1)

0,00
Load 25(1) Load 28(1)
General Load Type General Load Type

to minimise generation and re-dispatch costs. Built-in


Bus 27(1)
Bus 38(1)
Bus 02(1) Line 17 - 18(1)
Line Type 17 - 27

Line Type 17 - 18
Line 17 - 27(1)

-1,00 Load 27(1) Bus 24(1) SG


Line Type 01 - 02

~
Line 01 - 02(1)

General Load Type


G 09(1)
Type Gen 09
Bus 18(1) Bus 17(1)
Line Type 02 - 03

-2,00
Line 02 - 03(1)

Load 24(1)
Line Type 03 - 18

Line Type 16 - 24
Line 03 - 18(1)

Line 16 - 24(1)

General Load Type

0,80 0,90 1,00 1,10 1,20 [s] 1,30


Bus 01(1)
Line Type 16 - 17
Line 16 - 17(1)

Load 18(1)
General Load Type

linear programming solver as well as support of the


G 06(1)
Type Gen 06
~

AC voltage (EMT)
SG
Bus 09(1): Phase Voltage A in p.u. Bus 03(1)

Bus 09(1): Phase Voltage B in p.u. Bus 16(1)


Bus 09(1): Phase Voltage C in p.u. Bus 35(1)
Line Type 01 - 39
Line 01 - 39(1)

Line Type 15 - 16
Line 15 - 16(1)

Load 03(1)
Line Type 16 - 21
Line Type 03 - 04

Trf Type 22 - 35 YNy0


Line 03 - 04(1)

Line 16 - 21(1)

General Load Type


Trf 22 - 35(1)

Load 16(1) Line 21 - 22(1)


Load 04(1) General Load Type Line Type 21 - 22
General Load Type
G 01(1)
Type Gen 01 Line 04 - 14(1) Bus 15(1)
Line Type 04 - 14
~
SG
Line Type 23 - 24
Line 23 - 24(1)

Bus 21(1) Bus 22(1)

external solvers IBM CPLEX and GUROBI


Line Type 14 - 15
Line 14 - 15(1)

EMT Simulation
Bus 04(1)
Load 15(1)
Line Type 16 - 19
Line 16 - 19(1)

General Load Type


Bus 39(1)
Line Type 04 - 05
Line 04 - 05(1)

Bus 14(1) Load 21(1)


General Load Type
Line Type 22 - 23
Line 22 - 23(1)

Load 39(1) Bus 05(1)


General Load Type Load 12(1)
General Load Type
Line Type 05 - 06
Line 05 - 06(1)

Load 23(1)
General Load Type
Line Type 13 - 14
Line 13 - 14(1)

1,30 Bus 06(1)


Bus 12(1)
Line Type 06 - 07

Trf Type 13 - 12 YNy0

1,10
Bus 19(1) Bus 23(1)
Line 06 - 07(1)

Trf 13 - 12(1)
Line Type 05 - 08

Trf Type 11 - 12 YNy0


Line 05 - 08(1)

Trf 11 - 12(1)
Line Type 06 - 11
Line Type 09 - 39
Line 09 - 39(1)

Line 06 - 11(1)

Trf Type 19 - 20 YNy0

Trf Type 23 - 36 YNy0

Fully integrated, easy to configure Co-Simulation for


Load 20(1)
General Load Type
Trf 19 - 20(1)

Trf 23 - 36(1)

Bus 07(1)

0,90
Trf Type 06 - 31 YNy0
Trf 06 - 31(1)

Trf Type 19 - 33 YNy0

Bus 13(1)
Trf 19 - 33(1)
Line Type 07 - 08
Line 07 - 08(1)

Bus 11(1) Bus 20(1) Bus 36(1)

0,70
Load 07(1)
General Load Type
Line Type 10 - 13
Line 10 - 13(1)

Trf Type 20 - 34 YNy0


Line Type 10 - 11
Line 10 - 11(1)

Trf 20 - 34(1)

SG
~

0,50
Bus 08(1) G 07(1)
Type Gen 07

0,80 0,90 1,00 1,10 1,20 [s] 1,30 0,40


Bus 31(1)
Line Type 08 - 09
Line 08 - 09(1)

Bus 10(1) Bus 34(1) Bus 33(1)

single and multiple time domain (RMS-RMS, RMS-EMT


AC voltage (RMS)
Load 08(1)
Trf Type 10 - 32 YNy0

Bus 29: Line-Ground Voltage, Magnitude A in p.u. General Load Type


SG
Trf 10 - 32(1)

~
Bus 29: Line-Ground Voltage, Magnitude B in p.u.

0,00
Bus 09(1) G 02(1) Load 31(1) SG SG
Type Gen 02 General Load Type ~ ~
Bus 29: Line-Ground Voltage, Magnitude C in p.u. G 05(1) G 04(1)
Type Gen 05 Type Gen 04

Bus 32(1)
G 08

-0,40
Type Gen 08
~
SG

Line 26 - 29(2) SG
Line Type 26 - 29 ~
G 03(1)
Type Gen 03
Bus 37

-0,80
Line 26 - 29
Line Type 26 - 29

and EMT-EMT). Co-Simulation with external solver via


Load 26 Load 29
Trf Type 25 - 37 YNy0

General Load Type General Load Type


G 10
Trf 25 - 37

Type Gen 10 Line 26 - 28 Line 28 - 29


Line Type 26 - 28 Line Type 28 - 29
~
SG

Bus 25 Bus 26 Bus 28 Bus 29


-1,20
0,80 0,90 1,00 1,10 1,20 [s] 1,30
Bus 30 Line 26 - 29(3)
Line Type 26 - 29

AC currents (EMT)
Line Type 26 - 27

Trf Type 29 - 38 YNy0


Line 26 - 27

Line 25 - 26
Line Type 02 - 25
Trf Type 02 - 30 YNy0

Trf 29 - 38

Line Type 25 - 26
Line 02 - 25
Trf 02 - 30

Load 25 Load 28
General Load Type General Load Type Line 26 - 29(2): Phase Current A/Terminal j in p.u.
Bus 27 Line 26 - 29(2): Phase Current B/Terminal j in p.u.

IEEE C37.118 communication interface


Bus 38
Line 26 - 29(2): Phase Current C/Terminal j in p.u.
Bus 02 Line 17 - 18
Line Type 17 - 27

Line Type 17 - 18

RMS Unbalanced
Line 17 - 27

Load 27 Bus 24 SG
Line Type 01 - 02

General Load Type ~


Line 01 - 02

G 09
Type Gen 09
Bus 18 Bus 17
Line Type 02 - 03
Line 02 - 03

Load 24
Line Type 03 - 18

Line Type 16 - 24

General Load Type


Line 03 - 18

Line 16 - 24

Bus 01
Line Type 16 - 17
Line 16 - 17

Load 18
General Load Type

G 06
Type Gen 06
~
SG
Bus 03

Simulation
Bus 16
Bus 35
Line Type 01 - 39

Line Type 15 - 16
Line 01 - 39

Line 15 - 16

Hosting-Capacity tool for the evaluation of spare gen-


Load 03
Line Type 16 - 21
Line Type 03 - 04

Trf Type 22 - 35 YNy0

General Load Type


Line 16 - 21
Line 03 - 04

Trf 22 - 35

Interconnection to Load 16 Line 21 - 22


General Load Type Line Type 21 - 22
Rest of U.S.A. / Canada Load 04
General Load Type
G 01
Type Gen 01 Line 04 - 14 Bus 15
Line Type 04 - 14
~
SG
Line Type 23 - 24
Line 23 - 24

Bus 21 Bus 22
Line Type 14 - 15
Line 14 - 15

Bus 04
Load 15
Line Type 16 - 19

General Load Type


Line 16 - 19

Bus 39
Line Type 04 - 05
Line 04 - 05

Bus 14 Load 21
General Load Type
Line Type 22 - 23

eration or load capacity in predefined network areas


Line 22 - 23

Load 39 Bus 05
General Load Type Load 12
General Load Type

0,80
Line Type 05 - 06
Line 05 - 06

Load 23
General Load Type
Line Type 13 - 14
Line 13 - 14

Bus 12
Bus 06

0,60
Line Type 06 - 07

Trf Type 13 - 12 YNy0

Bus 19 Bus 23
Line 06 - 07
Line Type 05 - 08

Trf Type 11 - 12 YNy0

Trf 13 - 12
Line 05 - 08

Line Type 06 - 11
Line Type 09 - 39

Trf 11 - 12
Line 06 - 11
Line 09 - 39

Trf Type 19 - 20 YNy0

Trf Type 23 - 36 YNy0

Load 20
General Load Type
Trf 19 - 20

Trf 23 - 36

0,40
Bus 07
Trf Type 06 - 31 YNy0

Trf Type 19 - 33 YNy0


Trf 06 - 31

Bus 13
Trf 19 - 33
Line Type 07 - 08
Line 07 - 08

Bus 11 Bus 20 Bus 36


Load 07

0,20
General Load Type
Line Type 10 - 13
Line 10 - 13

Trf Type 20 - 34 YNy0

Fast AC linearized contingency analysis using


Line Type 10 - 11
Line 10 - 11

Trf 20 - 34

SG
~
Bus 08 G 07
Type Gen 07

0,00
Bus 31
Line Type 08 - 09
Line 08 - 09

Bus 10 Bus 34 Bus 33

0,80 0,90 1,00 1,10 1,20 [s] 1,30


Swing Node
Load 08
Trf Type 10 - 32 YNy0

General Load Type


SG
~
Trf 10 - 32

Bus 09 G 02 Load 31 SG SG
Type Gen 02 General Load Type ~ ~

AC currents (RMS)
G 05 G 04
Type Gen 05 Type Gen 04

Line 26 - 29(2): Phase Current, Magnitude A/Terminal i in p.u.


Bus 32 Line 26 - 29(2): Phase Current, Magnitude B/Terminal i in p.u.

sensitivity based method, which can be combined with


CoSim_39 Bus New England System Project: Example
Line 26 - 29(2): Phase Current, Magnitude C/Terminal j in p.u. DIgSILENT
39 Bus 10 Machine New England Power System Graphic: Grid
GmbH
Date: 06.11.2018
PowerFactory 2019 Beta Annex:
SG
~
G 03
Type Gen 03

the full load contingency analysis for fast screening of


contingency cases
User-defined data objects (classes) extending the
existing data extensions concept for a fully customisable
data model
Additional data security features, such as password se-
curity rules, authentication modes and privacy settings,
to comply with general data protection regulations

For further information about PowerFactory 2019 please visit our


website www.digsilent.de and see the What’s New document.

DIgSILENT GmbH | Heinrich-Hertz-Straße 9 | 72810 Gomaringen | www.digsilent.de | mail@digsilent.de


from the editor
Michael Henderson

electric markets
effective designs & flexible responses

I
In 2017, new england experI­ the system by providing demand elastic­
enced the second­lowest annual whole­ ity and flexibility.
sale electric market prices in more than How should the markets be design­
a decade. well­designed markets ed, given the increased amounts of
enhance the reliable and econom­ variable energy resources, energy
ic operation and planning of the efficiency, storage, and demand
system by providing incentives resources that have transform­
for improved performance and ed our industry? It is our hope
efficient investments. new that the contents of this issue

image licensed by ingram publishing


and existing resources show will trigger future discus­
extraordinarily high avail­ sions about possible market
ability, which generates re­ improvements that will en­
venue as well as energy. For hance the reliable, econom­
example, nuclear plants cur­ ical operation and planning
rently boast availabilities of the system.
above 95%, a considerable
improvement over the rates of In This Issue
65% that were common during The articles in this issue provide
the 1980s. The start­up times of a global view of electric markets
fossil units are much faster now and consider the large penetra­
than they were before the wholesale tions of variable energy resources
markets were introduced. Markets also and the ability of demand to provide
encourage capital improvements to the a flexible response. In their guest edi­
system, such as the addition of very torial, antonio J. Conejo and ramteen
efficient generating units that reduce op­ Sioshansi discuss the challenges and some
erating costs and lower emissions. Com­ market prices, which is often the primary of the potential solutions for effectively
petition has fostered the use of modern source of revenue for existing resources designing markets in europe, the United
combined­cycle generating units with heat in the current wholesale electric markets. States, and new Zealand. The issue also
rates below 5,700 Btu/kwh. Higher prices for other wholesale electric examines the effect of public policies on
The 1990s saw the advent of whole­ markets, such as for capacity and ancil­ the markets and power systems and sum­
sale electric markets in europe and the lary services, can make up for revenue marizes the wide experience of authors
United States. Since then, the grid has shortfalls and meet the system’s need for from europe, the United States, and new
been transformed by the large­scale de­ flexibility. when used in concert, prop­ Zealand. Six well­written articles discuss
velopment of variable energy, demand­ erly designed markets and the large­scale the following topics:
side, and distributed resources. Because addition of distributed resources can ✔ the current state of electric mar­
of their lack of fuel costs, new wind and greatly improve a system’s reliability and kets in europe, policies affecting
photovoltaic resources depress energy its economic and environmental perfor­ their integration across national
mance. The role of demand resources and boundaries, and how coordination
Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/MPE.2018.2877897
storage in these markets is noteworthy, can be achieved across different
Date of publication: 7 January 2019 as it can improve the overall operation of national and regional markets

4 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


Ready
To
ARC FLASH EVALUATION
SwiTch? Design safer power systems while ensuring compliance with NEC,
OSHA, BFPA, IEEE, NESC, and CSA standards

Receive up to 60% off Fully integrated with Short Circuit, Over-Current Coordination,
and Equipment Evaluation modules
when you switch Evaluate alternatives quickly and easily to establish an optimal design
to SKM. Improve safety margins with user-definable arcing fault tolerance
Save time by automatically generating arc flash labels and work permits
You’ll also receive Determine required PPE levels instantly
free service to convert Increase flexibility by creating custom labels in any size with
competing software user-defined logos, text, comments, and field placement.
Avoid potential fines, post productivity, and increased insurance
projects over to SKM! and litigation costs.
Compare results from multiple project scenarios in a single table

ADDITIONAL SOFTWARE FROM SKM


DAPPER® Integrated Electrical Analysis Software. Comprehensive AUTO DESIGN Automatically sizes Cables, Transformers,
“The main advantage with Three Phase Short-Circuit Studies, Load Flow Study, Demand Load Buses, and Protective Devices to achieve proper size and
Study, Feeder and Transformer Sizing Study, Impact Motor Starting ratings that meets criteria limits set by the Equipment Evaluation
Power*Tools for Windows is Study, and Load Schedules. (Unbalanced Studies also available) study. Utilize user-defined Design libraries. Best suited for new system
designs or to resolve undersized and/or overdutied equipment for
its user-friendliness. PTW is CAPTOR® Time-Overcurrent Coordination. Graphical Time-Overcurrent
Coordination. Integrated with one-lines, short-circuit modules, Equipment existing systems. (Requires Equipment Evaluation module)
Evaluation, and Arc Flash. Comprehensive protective device library. I*SIM Dynamic Simulation and Transient Stability. Model, Simulate,
easy to use and the ready- and Analyze Dynamic Responses to Power System Electro-Mechanical
AUTO COORDINATION & EVALUATION Instantly identify
Disturbances. Includes Generator Sizing and Stability, Rotor Angle and
to-use standard models coordination and protection issues by evaluating each
Voltage Stability, Flux Level Machine Representation, Identify Fault
equipment for adherence to the National Electric Code (NEC).
Clearing Times. User Defined Graphical Models for Exciter, Turbine
enable you to speed up Automatically make changes to resolve violations.
Governor, PSS, and other controllers.
CABLE AMPACITY Accurate calculation of ampacity and
your work. Changing data is temperature rise in various power cable installations. Based DISTRIBUTION RELIABILITY Calculates the reliability indices of
individual load points and the overall distribution systems with either
on and fully compliant with IEC 60287.
simple and makes evaluating A_FAULT ANSI Short-Circuit Study. Three Phase Short-Circuit Study
radial or loop configuration.

based on the ANSI/IEEE C37 Standards. Separate solutions for low, DC SYSTEMS ANALYSIS Battery Sizing, Load Flow, & Short Circuit
different cases very easy.” medium and high voltage systems and for symmetrical, momentary Analysis. Evaluate all loading conditions for DC duty cycle loads and
and interrupting calculations. (Unbalanced Studies also available) AC emergency loads. Complies with IEEE std. 485, 1115, 399, 946,
and IEC std. 61660.
EQUIPMENT EVALUATION Equipment Evaluation Report. Automatically
compares short-circuit ratings, withstand ratings. Applies de-rating GROUND MAT Substation Ground Grid Design and Analysis. Optimizes
adjustments and user defined pass/marginal/failed criteria. Includes grid design using general purpose finite element algorithm for

47
error checking for input data and topology. potential analysis and graphical facilities to validate grounding
systems efficiency.
th TMS Transient Motor Starting Simulation. Time-based motor starting
simulation with graphical output. Includes reduced voltage and Data Exchange Seamlessly share project data between
capacitor starting, graphical motor and load models. SKM projects and other third-party software. Exchange
format includes Tab Delimited, CSV, and SKM XML. Also includes
HI_WAVE Power Quality Investigation and Filter Design. Frequency
IVERSARY an interface to exchange data with Autodesk Revit and Intergraph
ANN Scan, Harmonic Current, Voltage Distortion, Harmonic Load Flow and
19 2 ~ 2019
SmartPlant Electrical.
7 Interactive Filter Design. Evaluate and correct harmonic distortions.

SKM Power*Tools Training Classes


Visit skm.com to find a class near you today! 101/102 Introduction to SKM Power*Tools
Hurry, classes fill up fast! 103/104 Intermediate Topics in SKM Power*Tools
201/202 Power System Application – Coordination & Arc Flash
Training more than five engineers? 204/205 Motor Starting and Harmonics
One Pearl Street
Email training@skm.com for a 206 DC System Analysis & Arc Flash
Redondo Beach, CA 90277
personalized On-Site Training quote. 207 Grounding and Applications
1-800-500-4SKM
www.skm.com • sales@skm.com Chosen By The Top 40 eleCTriCal engineering Firms in The World
✔ an overview of U.S. wholesale ✔ the historical and future evolution provided reliable and economical elec­
electric markets, their implemen­ of electricity markets, which needs tric supply to critical loads.
tation by independent system op­ to reflect lessons learned and in­
erators, challenges being faced, creased use of demand­side, re­ PES Updates
and potential future solutions newable, and distributed resources. The Ieee power & energy Society (peS)
✔ a history of the new Zealand mar­ The “In My View” column supports has almost 40,000 members located in
kets and how their restructuring is an opinion that the sound market prin­ 150 countries, with 258 local Chapters
meant to address inefficiencies in ciples used to introduce wholesale elec­ and 358 Student Branch Chapters. The
this isolated electric power system tric markets during the 1990s should “leader’s Corner” column by Saifur rah­
✔ a discussion of how policy deci­ still apply to systems with large pen­ man, peS president, discusses many key
sions affected the current euro­ etrations of renewable and demand re­ peS activities, including technical, stan­
pean Union electricity system and sources. Care must be taken with market dards, and education/training activities;
markets, new policy and regula­ implementation details. the peS Corporate engagement program;
tory initiatives aimed at redesign­ This issue also features a standalone remote working groups that promote the
ing these markets, and ideas about article, “pV­Battery Systems for Critical peS’s worldwide vision and focus; and
the interactions among regulatory loads during emergencies.” The extent publications activities. Our leadership
and technical advances and their of damage to infrastructure after natu­ welcomes your thoughts on future direc­
effects on future power systems ral disasters can be devastating. people tions. You and the peS benefit from your
✔ background on the role of the U.S. with severe medical conditions are par­ participation in the wide array of activities
Federal energy regulatory Com­ ticularly susceptible to long­term electri­ and outreach to new members.
mission in competitive wholesale cal outages, which can prove fatal. The
electric markets, the challenges it article discusses the sizing and operat­ Awards
faces, and principles for market ing experience of photovoltaic­battery Tight publication deadlines resulted in two
reforms to address key issues systems deployed in puerto rico, which awards not being mentioned in previous

World Leader in Developing


BIGWOOD SYSTEMS, INC. Powerful and Field-Proven
www.bigwood-systems.com
+1.607.257.0915 On-line and Off-line Tools
sales@bigwood-systems.com for Power Grid Modeling, Analysis, Assessment,
NY, USA
Head Office Branch Offices Enhancement and Optimization
Ithaca, NY Taipei, TWN | Beijing, CHN
Innovation prevails!

Network Applications for the Control Center


“Bigwood Systems’ Online Voltage • Real-time and Look-ahead Static and Dynamic Security
Stability product is simply the best in the Assessment (patented screening, ranking, and detailed
field.” - CAISO Project Leader analysis)
“BSI On-line Transient Stability • Reactive Power Reserve Monitoring, Management &
Assessment is a superb product.” Enhancement
- TEPCO Manager
• Actionable Control Recommendation engine to
“The BSI VAR Management System is a
eliminate violations and mitigate unstable contingencies
best practice tool for all utilities.” • New-Generation State Estimation for Transmission and
- SERC Audit Staff
Distribution Networks with a low number of measurements
using SCADA & PMU data
• Global Optimal Power Flow (for over 250,000 control variables with
AC/DC constraints)
• Distribution Network Management Tools
• Renewable Energy Forecasting, Uncertainty Modeling,
Representation & Management
• Advanced Measurement-Based Power System Modeling
(Generation, Transmission & Load)
World-Wide Customer Base
Over 40 electrical utilities served world-wide, including long-standing
customers such as California ISO, PJM Interconnection, Tokyo Electric
Power Company, Tennessee Valley Authority, and UK Power Networks,
among others. BSI’s advanced technology, innovation and satisfied
customers are key differentiators.

6 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


The Industry Standard for Electromagnetic
Transient Simulations
PSCAD™ / EMTDC™ has earned the trust of power
system leaders around the world for over 40 years.
Our software provides unparalleled reliability, speed,
and accuracy for a range of applications, including:

• Insulation coordination: lightning and switching;


• Harmonics, ferroresonance, and power quality;
• HVDC and FACTS;
• Wind, solar, and distributed generation;
• Protection and relays;
• Equipment failure analysis.

Start your simulations today.


Our technical support team is ready to help.

info@pscad.com
pscad.com
Available in accessible formats upon request. Powered by Manitoba Hydro International Ltd.
issues of this magazine. please congratu­ positions in 2019. Miriam p. Sanders ✔ vice president, Meetings: Thom­
late the following 2018 awardees: will hold the incoming division VII as w. Mayne, Mayne Consultants,
✔ Bhuvaneswari gurumoorthy for delegate­elect/director­elect position. In lacombe, louisiana
the Ieee peS wanda reder addition, the following peS board mem­ ✔ member­at­large, global Outreach:
pioneer in power award, “for bers took office on 1 January 2019: C.Y. Chung, University of Sas­
outstanding research in power ✔ vice president, publications: Bi­ katchewan, Saskatoon, Canada
quality converters and for educat­ kash pal, Imperial College, london ✔ member­at­large, global work­
ing new engineers” ✔ vice president, Meetings: wayne shops: luis (nando) Ochoa, Uni­
✔ Marina Mondello, for the Ieee Bishop, Omicron energy, Boston versity of Melbourne, australia.
peS wanda reder pioneer in ✔ member­at­large, global Out­
power award, “for leadership and reach: Yu Jun, State grid Corp Thanks
for serving as an inspiring role of China, Beijing a special note of appreciation to Mel
model and mentor to young wom­ ✔ member­at­large, global work­ Olken, who continues to provide guid­
en in the power industry.” shops: ramakrishna Kappagan­ ance and tutelage, and to the Ieee pub­
peS members are encouraged to submit tu, Bangalore, India. lications staff who make this publication
nominations for 2019 awards by 31 Our deepest gratitude goes to the possible. Thanks to the many contribu­
January 2019 at https://www.ieee­pes following outgoing peS Board Mem­ tors to this issue, especially our guest
.org/pes­communities/awards/pes­ bers for successfully completing their editors, antonio J. Conejo and ramteen
society­level­awards and https://www tenure and for their many significant Sioshansi, and our authors. a particular
.ieee­pes.org/pes­communities/awards. contributions to peS: note of appreciation to associate editor
✔ vice president, p ublications: John paserba and robert C. Henderson,
Changing of the Guard Mariesa l. Crow, Missouri Uni­ who provides editorial assistance.
we offer congratulations and wish all versity of Science and Technol­
p&e
the best to leaders assuming new Ieee ogy, rolla
letters to the editor

share your thoughts


send comments to mih.psat@gmail.com

R
ReadeRs aRe encouRaged to universities and the entrance grades is four Highers at the a grade and in-
share their views on issues affecting the required for admission to the courses cludes math, physics, or engineering sci-
electric power engineering profession. as being different from the rest of the ence. students studying a-levels, mainly
send your letters to Michael Henderson, united Kingdom. I agree with Martin in other parts of the united Kingdom, re-
editor-in-chief: mih.psat@gmail.com. Queen’s comments and will now explain quire three a-levels at grade B, including
Letters may be edited for publication. them for our readership. math and physics. However, students with
In england, Wales, and northern Ire- very good a-levels may be allowed direct
A View into U.K. Education land, most students joining a three-year entry into the second year of a scottish
the article in the september/october B.eng. or four-year M.eng. eee degree B.eng. course if they achieved grade a in
2018 issue, “electrical Power engineer- program will have successfully passed math, physics, and computing. emphasis
ing education: cultivating the talent in three or four advanced-Level general is placed on mathematics, engineering
the united Kingdom and Italy to Build certificate of education science, circuits, basic
the Low-carbon economy of the Fu- qualifications (referred electrical engineering,
ture” (IEEE Power & Energy Magazine, to as A-levels) at an ap- In Scotland, and computing during
vol. 16, no. 5, pp. 53–63, sept.-oct. 2018), propriate grade. they the first year of an eee
overlooked something fundamental in must include mathemat-
most students B.eng. course in scot-
the description of university education in ics and usually physics, study five so- land. It is possible for
the united Kingdom, which consists of and an appropriate grade some students—those
england, Wales, northern Ireland, and is normally an a*, a, or called Highers with high a-level grades
scotland. the article states that B.eng. B for a Russell group in appropr iate sub -
degrees in the united Kingdom are three university, which repre-
at school. jects—to complete their
years long and M.eng. degrees are four sents the top universities B.eng. degrees within
years long. this is not the case in scot- in the united Kingdom. these grades are three years, i.e., similar to the rest of the
land, where B.eng. programs require four obtained from a percentage numerical united Kingdom.
years of study and M.eng. degrees take mark, where a* > 90%, a = 80–89%, B the entrance requirement for a typi-
five years. the differences result from = 70–79%, c = 60–69%, d = 50–59%, cal five-year M.eng. eee course in
the secondary school structures in scot- and e = 40–49%. F < 39% indicates an scotland is five Highers at grade a in-
land and the rest of the united Kingdom, examination failure. cluding math, physics, or engineering
which also explains the differences in en- In scotland, most students study five science or three a-levels at grade B in-
trance requirements. so-called Highers at school. these are cluding math and physics.
generally awarded in the fifth year of sec- the second year of a four-year B.eng.
—Martin Queen ondary school and considered halfway or five-year M.eng. eee course in scotland
between the general certificate of second- is similar to the first year of a three-year
Author’s Response ary education and the a-level. advanced B.eng. or four-year M.eng. eee course
the article should have described the Highers are an optional qualification, nor- in england, Wales, and northern Ireland.
structure of B.eng. and M.eng. elec- mally studied in the sixth year of second- although the term similar recognizes that
trical engineering courses in scottish ary education and generally considered the exact contents of different B.eng. or
slightly more difficult than a-levels. M.eng. eee courses in u.K. universities
Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/MPE.2018.2877898
the entrance requirement for a typical vary significantly, all accredited B.eng. or
Date of publication: 7 January 2019 four-year B.eng. eee course in scotland M.eng. eee courses have been assessed

10 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


by one or more of the u.K. professional to assert that general electric (ge) and shallenberger. Benjamin Lamme,
engineering institutions, and all satisfy the was proposing “three phase” when the however, realized that the tesla system,
educational criteria for an incorporated or war of the currents was as tesla described it,
a chartered engineer. still raging at that time
could have been further
There is evidence would work properly.
Lamme traveled to
—Peter Crossley explained. as we know that several new York frequently
from Marc seife r’s with albert schmid so
Alternating Developments research, Forbes was Westinghouse that they could get ad-
My letter is in regard to the “History”
column in the september/october 2018
a university professor
from anderson’s uni-
Company vice from the master
on how to perfect the
issue, “the niagara alternators: com- versity, glasgow, scot- employees were motor and the entire ac
peting alternatives and Frequencies” land who had tested a system so that it would
(IEEE Power & Energy Magazine, vol. 16, number of inventions. jealous of Tesla. work at niagara. tes-
no. 5, pp. 96–104, sept.-oct. 2018). to He concluded that tes- la’s name is mentioned
read that Forbes did all of the design la’s invention of the induction motor and nine times on the patent plaque. schmid
work on the niagara alternators with- ac power system was by far the best one is mentioned twice, and so is stanley.
out any mention of the several patents and recommended it to the niagara Falls the system was clearly tesla’s, and
by tesla on those generators does not Power commission (see Wizard: The that’s why he spoke as the inventor at the
tell the complete story. to suggest that Life & Times of Nikola Tesla, p. 111). inauguration of the power system. ad-
“tesla’s motors were still under develop- there is evidence that several West- ams also credited tesla as the inventor.
ment” begs the question of his alternator inghouse company employees were
development, which is not mentioned. jealous of tesla, particularly stilwell —Thomas Valone

Advanced modeling and analysis features include:


Dynamic Security Assessment Software
• Comprehensive capabilities for voltage, transient, small signal, and
Offering a simple, user-friendly interface frequency stability assessment
with extensive analysis options, DSAToolsTM • Integration with EMS/WAMS for on-line DSA to assess security
is a suite of software tools for power system of real-time system conditions
analysis. The software is designed for • Computation of secure operation regions (stability limits)
applications in both off-line studies and • Recommendation of remedial actions
on-line dynamic security assessment.
Experience and support:
www.dsatools.com
• Prominent provider of the on-line DSA technology with over
40 installations worldwide including 7 out of 9 ISOs in North
America
• Consulting services for custom software and model development,
system studies, and training

VSAT TSAT SSAT

Contact us:
dsainfo@powertechlabs.com
81022-0005

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 11


Author’s Response focus on ge using three-phase ac. ge Lamme. that statement was made at the
I am not aware of tesla’s alternator de- was bidding on Forbes’s design, which request of edward dean adams for pre-
velopment. If the writer is referring to called for polyphase ac. In any case, by sentation at the close of the edison gold
tesla’s patents, these were not develop- this time, ge had realized that dc was a Medal ceremonies where the medal was
ments. It’s a long road from defining the limited market and by 1896 had signed a presented to Mr. Lamme. It is repro-
parameters of an ac polyphase system cross-licensing agreement with Westing- duced on pp. 409–421 of adams’s book,
to designing a working machine. In his house. see Harold c. Passer, The Elec- Niagara Power, Volume 2. In it, Lamme
book The Power Makers, Klein says, trical Manufacturers, p. 331. the war of states, “From the standpoint of arma-
“Westinghouse engineers resented tesla the currents may have been “still raging at ture reaction and reactance this machine
for his pomposity and the large sum he that time,” but ge was about to capitulate. [Editor’s note: this refers to the niagara
received for an invention they thought It is clear from the patents that tesla alternator based on Forbes’s design] was
worthless until scott and oliver shallen- invented the polyphase power system. excessively bad … the full load magne-
berger improved it.” the “History” col- It’s my contention that he didn’t design tomotive force was about three times as
umn tones this down a bit by using the the alternator. [Editor’s note: coinci- great as the no-load field magnetomo-
phrase “under development.” this is the dently, the “History” column from the tive, an inoperative condition from the
reference: “By december of 1892, West- november/december 2018 issue was modern standpoint.” He goes on to say
inghouse has submitted its two-phase on the subject of the tesla lab at 89 Lib- that the “polar construction would have
ac design …ge’s entry … employed erty street, new York city, which was rendered the machine inoperative.”
three-phase ac,” taken from Jill Jonnes, credited as the birthplace of commer-
Empires of Light, p. 291. cial polyphase power.] —Robert D. Barnett
this “History” column doesn’t elabo- the column uses information from
p&e
rate on this because the piece does not a statement prepared by Benjamin

12 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


Aalborg, Denmark - June 4-7, 2019

Key Themes Location


KeyInternational
Themes CIGRE Symposium Location Aalborg has a rich and long history, going back to
The aim of the 2019 CIGRE International
Key organized by the Danish National Location
Committee the Vikings. Successful heavy industries have
aim ofThemes isAalborg has a rich and long history, going back to
The the 2019 CIGRE International Symposium to provide a forum for recent gradually transitioned into an environment of
the Vikings. Successful heavy industries have
International CIGRE Symposium
and issupported
Symposium to provide a forum
The aim of the 2019 CIGRE International
by eight
for recent
research results and system operations experience
Study Committees
research results and system
Aalborg has a richoperations experience
and long history, going back to
gradually transitioned into an environment of
the Vikings.
related to the technology-rich
rapid Successful heavy
transformation industries have
and challenges
technology-rich enterprises, a feat not least due to
relatedGoing offshore - Challenges of onthe future
Symposium is to provide a forum for recent enterprises, a feat not least due to the presence of Aalborg University, organizer of
organized to the rapid
research results and by the operations
transformation
system Danish National
and challenges imposed
experience Committee
gradually
networks
the presence
technology-rich
of and
transitioned
and markets
Aalborg supported
into
by
enterprises,
an environment of
increased
University,
a feat
by
organizer of eight
not least due to
Study Committees
the symposium. Aalborg Congress & Culture Centre
imposed
Going power
on
offshore
related
networksgrid and markets
to the rapid-transformation
Challenges
by increased
of the
and challenges amounts of
future powerrenewables
the in
grid
the symposium.
presence
the energy mix.
AalborgUniversity,
of Aalborg
Perhaps
Congress & Culture of
organizer Centre (uk.akkc.dk) will host all meetings and technical
amounts
imposedofon renewables
networks and in the energybymix.
markets Perhaps
increased exemplified more than anywhere,
(uk.akkc.dk) will host Northern
all meetings and technical
Aalborg, Aalborg,
Denmark
exemplified thanDenmark
- anywhere,
June 4-7, -mix.
June
2019 4-7, 2019 the symposium. Aalborg Congress & Culture Centre sessions, and is located centrally, only 6 km from
amounts ofmore
renewables in the energyNorthern Europe
Perhaps is about to increase
sessions, and
(uk.akkc.dk) isits
will
already
located
host
large share
centrally,
all meetings onlytechnical
and 6 km from Aalborg airport.
Europe is about
exemplified moreto increase its already
than anywhere, large share
Northern of wind powerAalborg
with further
airport.offshore plants and
ofEurope
wind power with sessions, and is located centrally, only 6 km from
is about tofurther
increase offshore plants
its already and
large share
offshore interconnectors.
Aalborg airport.The objective of the
offshore
of windinterconnectors.
power with further The objective
offshore of the
plants and symposium is to address recent technical advances
symposium is to address recent technicalofadvances
Key Themes and
offshore interconnectors.
policy that allow
The objective
transmission and
symposium is to address recent technical advances
the and policy that allow transmission and distribution
distribution
networks to enter their next era, in particular those
The aim of the 2019 CIGRE International
networks
and policy Symposium
to enter
that is toin provide
theirtransmission
allow next era, particular athose
forum
and distribution
related to offshore generation, transmission and
Key Themes
related
system
to offshore
networks
for recent research results anddistribution. to entergeneration,
operations Location
their next era,
experience
transmission
in particularand
related those
related to offshore generation, transmission anddistribution. The preferential topics reflect the
The preferential topics reflect the
to the rapid transformation andabove, challenges
and beyond,
distribution. Theimposedacross
preferential on networks
technology,
Aalborg topics and
planning,
hasreflect
a rich the above,
and long and beyond,
history, going back across
to technology, planning,
The aim of the 2019 CIGRE Internationaloperations
above, and and markets.
beyond, across technology, planning,operations and markets.
markets isbytoincreased
Symposium provide a forumamounts of
for recent renewables in the energy mix. Perhaps
operations and markets.
the Vikings. Successful heavy industries have
gradually transitioned into an environment of
exemplified
research more
results and thanoperations
system anywhere, Northern Europetechnology-rich
experience is about to increase enterprises, its a feat not least due to
large share of wind Programme
related to the rapid transformation and challenges
already power with further offshore plants of
the presence and Programme
offshore
Aalborg University, organizer of
imposed on networks and markets by increased Programme Abstracts
the symposium. Aalborg Congress & Culture Centre
interconnectors.
amounts of renewablesThe objective
in the of the
energy mix. symposium is take
Perhaps to address
The main symposium will(uk.akkc.dk) place on
recent
willWednesday
Abstracts
host all meetings and technical Abstracts
exemplified
technicalmore than anywhere,
advances Northern
and policy that
5thThe allow
main
June transmission
andsymposium
Thursday will
6th and
sessions,
take
June. placedistribution
and on
Tutorialsis Wednesday
located Abstracts
The main symposium will take place on Wednesday
will takecentrally, onlyParticipants
6 km from wishing to present papers are invited
Europe is about to increase its already large share 5th June and Thursday 6th June. Tutorials will takeare invited Participants wishing to present papers are invited
of networks
wind powerto enter
with their
further next plants
offshore era, 5th
in
place June and
particular Thursday
Tuesday 4ththose
and
Aalborg
6th June.
related
June and airport.
Tutorials
to
a technical visitwill
offshore to take Participants
Participants
to submit their wishing
wishing
synopsis toENGLISH
to present
in present
papers papers
before 12th are invited to submit their synopsis in
place Tuesday
offshore 4th June
wind power plantand a technical
ANHOLT to place TuesdayOctober
visitplace
will take 4th
to June
submit andto:
their
2018
a https:/
technical
synopsis visit
in ENGLISH to before
/cigreaalborg2019.dk/12th to submit their synopsis in ENGLISH before 12th
generation,
offshore transmission
interconnectors. and distribution.
The objective ofoffshore
the The
wind power
Friday 7th June. preferential
plant
Spouses’ tripANHOLT topics
will visitwill reflect
take place
Grenen, the
offshore
Art wind ENGLISH
power plantbefore
ANHOLT 12th
will October
take place 2018
October 2018 to: https://cigreaalborg2019.dk/ to: https://cigreaalborg2019.dk/
October 2018 to: https://cigreaalborg2019.dk/
symposium is to address recent technicalFriday advances
7th June. Spouses’ trip will visit Grenen, Friday
Art 7th June. Spouses’ trip will visit Grenen, Art
andabove, andallow
policy that beyond, acrossand
transmission technology,
Museum
distribution
Museum of
of planning,
Skagen
Skagen
and operations
Brøndums
andgroup
Brøndums
and
Hotel. markets.
Study
Hotel.areStudy Museum of Skagen and Brøndums Hotel. Study
committee and working meetings
networks to enter their next era, in particular those
Programme
related to offshore generation, transmission 4th
committee
organized and working
between group
Saturday 1stmeetings
June and are
and between Saturday 1st June and Tuesday
organized
June.
Tuesday committee and working group meetings are
organized between Saturday 1st June and Tuesday
The mainThe
distribution. symposium will take
preferential topics place
reflect on Wednesday 5th June and Thursday
theJune.
4th 4th June.
above, and beyond, across technology, planning,
6th June. Tutorials will take place Tuesday 4th June and a technical visit to
operations and markets.
offshore wind power plant ANHOLT will take place Friday 7th June. Spouses’ International CIGRE Symposium
trip will visit Grenen, Art Museum of Skagen and Brøndums Hotel. Study organized by the China National Committee
Programme
committee and working group meetings are organized between Saturday 1st and supported by six Study Committees
June
mainand Tuesdaywill4th
takeJune.
Abstracts
The symposium place on Wednesday
5th June and Thursday 6th June. Tutorials will take Participants wishing to present papers are invited
Towards active, sustainable digital networks
Location
place Tuesday 4th June and a technical visit to to submit their synopsis in ENGLISH before 12th that are resilient and integrated from UHV
offshore wind power plant ANHOLT will take place
Aalborg has a rich and long history, going back to October
Friday 7th June. Spouses’ trip will visit Grenen, Art
2018 to:
the Vikings. Successful More
More information
https://cigreaalborg2019.dk/
information to distribution
heavyofindustries
Skagen andhave gradually
Hotel.transitioned into an environment of
Museum
technology-rich
committee
Brøndums
enterprises,
and working group meetings
Study
are not least due to thePlease
a feat Pleasevisit
presence our
ourwebsite
of Aalborg
visit website for
for more information
more information
More information
Chengdu, China - September 20-25, 2019
organized between Saturday 1st June and Tuesday https:/ /cigreaalborg2019.dk/
University,
4th June. organizer of the symposium. Aalborg Congress & Culture
https:/Centre
/cigreaalborg2019.dk/ Please visit our website for more information
(uk.akkc.dk) will host all meetings and technical sessions, and is located
https://cigreaalborg2019.dk/
centrally, only 6 km from Aalborg airport.
Theme International CIGRE Symposium
Venue
organized are
Today, new global energy challenges by the China National Committee
emerging. Chengdu is one of the most famous historical
The application of the huge and supported
number of newby six Study Committees and cultural cites of China, and it is a city that
technologies and new equipment makes the
Towards active, sustainable digital you willnetworks
never want to leave once you come. It
International CIGRE Symposium
electric power systems more complex. The deep
that are resilient and integrated offers a great variety of attractions, entertainment
from UHV
organized by the Danish National integrationCommittee
of information technology and power
to distribution
and lifestyles. The Intercontinental Century
systems brings not only intelligence but also City Chengdu will be the venue for all technical
and supported by eight Study
More information Committees Chengdu,
International CIGRE Symposium
Going offshore - Challenges
challenges to the energy systems.
those new ofchallenges
the future
China
To deal with- September 20-25,
and achieve goals such as
sessions.2019

organized by the China National


Please visit our website for more information Committee and
the UN Sustainable Development Goals for 2030,supported by six Study Committees
Towards power grid
https:/active, sustainable digital
/cigreaalborg2019.dk/
Theme
Parisnetworks
Agreement and that air are resilient
pollution abatement,
Venue
and integrated from UHV to distribution
Chengdu,Aalborg, Denmark -20-25,
June we4-7,
need to 2019
reconsider and investigate the issue
China - September Today, new
2019
ofglobal
energy development
energy and provide effective
challenges are emerging. Chengdu is one of the most famous historical
The application of the huge number of new
systematic solutions for the upgrading of the and cultural cites of China, and it is a city that
technologies and new equipment makes the you will never want to leave once you come. It
power
electric power systems.
systems more complex. The deep offers a great variety of attractions, entertainment
Themes integration of information technology
The aim
systems brings of the
not only
attractions,
CIGRE
intelligence
and power
butsymposium
also
entertainment
Chengdu and
2019
City Chengdu
lifestyles.
and lifestyles. The Intercontinental
The Intercontinental Century
will be the venue for all technical
Century City Chengdu
Today, new global energy challenges are emerging. The application of the
challenges is totothe
huge provide willTobedeal
a forum
energy systems. forthe venueresearch
recent
with for all sessions.
technical
findings sessions.
those new challenges and achieve goals such as
and operation experiences related to sustainable,
number of new technologies and new equipment makesLocation the electricthe
power systems
UN Sustainable Development Goals for 2030,
Key Themes
more complex. The deep integration of information technology and power
active
Paris Agreement
systems
we need system(From
and
and airdigital
pollutiondevelopment
UHV
to reconsider and investigate
abatement,
toback
distribution),
the issue
of power
and in particular,
Aalborg has a of
rich anddevelopment
energy
long history, and
going
provide effective
to
brings
The aim ofnot
theonly
2019intelligence but also challenges to the energy
CIGRE International systems.
the Vikings. To deal
Successful
systematic withindustries
tosolutions
address
heavy recent have technical
for the upgrading of the
advances and policy
Symposium is to provide a forum for recent that
intoallow transmission of and distribution networks
those new
research challenges
results and system and
operations goals such as the UNgradually
achieveexperience transitioned
Sustainable Development
power systems.
tothe
an environment
enter
technology-richTheenterprises,
aim of CIGREa their
feat next
not
symposium era.due 2019
least
Chengdu to
Goalstofor
related the2030, Paris Agreement
rapid transformation andand air pollution abatement,
challenges we need
the presence is to
of to reconsider
provide
Aalborg aUniversity,
forum for recent researchof
organizer findings
imposed on networks and markets by increased and operation experiences related to sustainable,
and investigate the issue of energy development
amounts of renewables in the energy mix. Perhaps and provide effective
the symposium. systematic
Aalborg
active and
Congress
digital development
& Culture
of power
Centre
(uk.akkc.dk) will host all meetings and technical
solutions more
exemplified for the upgrading
than anywhere,ofNorthern
the power systems. system(From
sessions, and is
to located
UHV to distribution),
centrally,
address recent technical only
and in particular,
6 km and
advances from policy
Europe is about to increase its already large share
Programme Submission of synopses
that allow transmission and distribution networks
of The
windaim
powerof the
withCIGRE
further symposium
offshore plantsChengdu
and 2019 is Aalborg airport.
to provide a forum for recent
to enter their next era.

research
offshore findings andThe
interconnectors. operation experiences
objective of the related to sustainable, active and The technical programme sessions opens with Participants wishing to present and publish
symposium is to address recent technical advances
anddigital
policydevelopment of power and
that allow transmission system(From
distributionUHV to distribution), and in particular,
keynotes and welcome reception on September papers should submit synopses by the following
to address recent technical advances and policy that allow transmission
networks to enter their next era, in particular those and
Programme 23, 2019. Before Submission of synopses
that day, we will offer aSubmission of synopses
technical instructions on www.cigre2019-chengdu.org,
related to offshore generation, transmission and visit to±500kV convertor station or Zipingpu where the synopses and paper templates are also
distribution networks to enter their next era. Participants
The technical programme sessions opens with
wishing to present and publish papers should
Participants wishing to present and publish
submit synopses
papers, by
andthe
distribution. The preferential topics reflect the keynoteshydropower station.
and welcome reception Tour of Chengdu will
on September alsoshould
papers be submit synopses by available. All synopses,
the following presentations
Programme
above, and beyond, across technology, planning, 23, 2019. organized
Before that day, we following
for accompanying
will offer a
visit to±500kV convertor station or Zipingpu
instructions
persons. on www.cigre2019-chengdu.org,
technical instructions on must be in English.
www.cigre2019-chengdu.org,
where the synopses and paper templates are also
where the
Please synopses
note authors should be
operations and markets. Individual Study Committee meetings and Working available to present at the symposium.
The technical programme sessions opens with keynotes and welcome reception and paper
hydropower station. Tour of Chengdu will also templates
be are also available.
available. All synopses,
All synopses, papers, papers,
and presentations
organized Group meetings
for accompanying will take place from September
persons. 20 Please note authors should be
must be in English.
on September 23, 2019. Before that day, we will offer a technical visitIndividual
to±500kV
toStudy and presentations
21. Committee meetings and Working mustavailable
be in toEnglish.
present atPlease note authors should be available to
the symposium.
Programme Group meetings will take place from September 20
present at the symposium.
convertor station or Zipingpu hydropower station. Tour of Chengdu will
to 21.also be

organized
The for accompanying
main symposium persons.
will take place on Wednesday
Abstracts
Individual
5th June and Study Committee
Thursday meetings
6th June. Tutorials willand
takeWorking Group meetingswishing
Participants will take place papers are invited
to present
place Tuesday 4th June and a technical visit to to submit their synopsis in ENGLISH before 12th
from September
offshore wind power 20 toANHOLT
plant 21. will take place October 2018 to: https://cigreaalborg2019.dk/
More information More information
Friday 7th June. Spouses’ trip will visit Grenen, Art
Venue
Museum of Skagen and Brøndums Hotel. Study
Please visit our website for more information
Please visit our website for more information
www.cigre2019-chengdu.org
Chengduand
committee is one of the
working groupmost famousarehistorical and cultural cites of China, and it is
meetings
organized between Saturday 1st June and Tuesday
a June.
city that you will never want to leave once you come. It offers a great variety of
www.cigre2019-chengdu.org
4th

Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/MPE.2018.2885099

page-aalborg-chengdu.indd 2 22/10/18 15:54


leader’s corner
Saifur Rahman

increasing engagement
an update on Chapters & councils

I
I would lIke to update you will have budgets to support travel within implemented through the Ieee Corporate
on the progress and priorities of our their country or region, as appropriate. Membership program where a company
Society. Currently, we have more than these councils will facilitate peS activi­ or an organization can become a corporate
38,900 members, which is over 1,000 ties in their areas, focusing on these top­ member by paying the peS membership
more than last year. we are truly a global ics (and others as needed): fee for their employees so they can join
organization with members located in ✔ membership peS as professional individual members
150 countries, but we also value our con­ ✔ conferences (minimum 50 members).
nections at the local level through our ✔ technical activities to give our members outside North
Chapters, which provide us with our grass­ ✔ education, including certificate america the opportunity to participate in
roots contacts. the Ieee power & energy programs technical committee activities and stan­
Society (peS) now has 258 such Chap­ ✔ standards. dards development, we have formed vari­
ters (seven more than last year) and 358 Councils will interact with their nation­ ous remote working groups with the help
Student Branch Chapters (60 more than al/regional electrical engineering organi­ of the peS technical Council. For ex­
last year), in almost every country where zations to develop joint programs, build ample, the peS Smart Buildings, loads,
our members live. awareness among engineers and academ­ and Customer Systems (SBlC) technical
In addition to our technical, stan­ ics, and promote peS membership. So far, Committee has formed the asia­pacific
dards, and education/training activities, I such councils have been formed in China, working Group (apwG), whose scope
am focusing on developing stronger and India, and africa. plans are afoot to create includes meeting with stakeholders for
sustaining relationships with these pro­ councils in latin america, North america, SBlC within the asia­pacific region to
fessional Chapters and Student Branch and europe as well. regularly address issues within the scope
Chapters globally. Chapter members are another signature effort of peS to raise of the committee, generally described as
our foot soldiers, providing links to in­ awareness and build a stronger member­ electrical systems behind the meter, and
dustry engineers, government agencies, ship base is the peS Corporate engagement integration of such systems with grid ser­
and academics from all over the world. program. participation in this program of­ vices. the peS website, http://sites.ieee
they can respond to local needs and fers corporations and other organizations .org/pes­sblc/, has more details about our
priorities and bring important programs an opportunity to help their employees to committees and their activities.
to meet those needs. to strengthen the stay up to date on the latest advances, in­ these regional working groups hold
local Chapters and help them interact cluding renewable energy system design meetings in various locations in person,
more closely within their country or re­ and integration, smart grid technologies, with electronic access. For example, sever­
gion, we are now forming peS Chapter electric vehicles, wholesale market design, al meetings of the apwG have been held
Councils. these councils will directly and operation and asset management. By in Guangzhou, China, hosted by China
work with their respective peS Region interacting with peS through conferences, Southern Grid. the working group’s last
representatives and, therefore, have ac­ committee work, the distinguished lec­ meeting was held at the 2018 peS Gen­
cess to the peS governing board. they turer program, and so on, employees of eral Meeting in portland, oregon. these
an organization can have many opportu­ working group meetings have resulted in
Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/MPE.2018.2872428
nities to engage professionally with their the ongoing development of three project
Date of publication: 7 January 2019 peers all over the world. this opportunity is authorization requests (paRs), with two

14 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


ADVERTISEMENT


etap 19



ESMO 2019
NEW HORIZONS
BOUNDLESS
POSSIBILITIES
Early Bird Registration Now Open
June 24-27, 2019 | Columbus, Ohio | ieee-esmo.com

Where Engineering Principles


Meet Field Realities
ESMO 2019 is set to be the industry’s largest “how to” event in North America. ESMO serves electric utility
professionals, contractors, and consultants who are interested in hands-on solutions for the safe engineering,
construction, operation and maintenance of the world’s power delivery systems. The four day event features
two days of outdoor field demonstrations and exhibits and a two-day technical conference program with
indoor exhibits.
IEEE Power and Energy Society and American Electric Power have partnered together and pooled their
resources to bring you this unique event where manufacturers and service providers connect with those who
engineer, design, operate and maintain the electrical network. PES and AEP envision this conference to be
the premier Safety event in the industry and have engaged T&D World to help make that happen.

For Information & Program Updates, Visit: ieee-esmo.com.

For Exhibit & Supporter Information, Contact:


Sam Posa | Exhibit Sales | 800.525.9154 | sam.posa@informa.com
Steve Lach | Midwest, Canada | 708.460.5925 | steve.lach@informa.com
Matt Wintringham | Eastern US | 508.277.8397 | matthew.wintringham@informa.com

General Information, Contact:


Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/MPE.2018.2885105 Eriks Surmanis | e.surmanis@pdc-cables.com
Most importantly, a particular skill. to formalize various
training and lifelong learning opportu­
I hope all these activities will go a long
way to make peS even more relevant to
please remain nities, peS is in the process of estab­ the global working professional. as your
lishing the peS university under the president for 2018–2019, I would like to
engaged with Ieee umbrella. this will be a one­stop hear your suggestions, questions, and ad­
your Society and shop for members or groups of engineers
as well as students and faculty to learn
vice. But most importantly, please remain
engaged with your Society and ask your
ask your friends new technologies, processes, deployment friends and colleagues to join.
p&e
experiences, and so on.
and colleagues
to join.
approved from SBlC­apwG efforts ad­
dressing matters of interest to the com­
mittee for Quick Response of Customer
loads (submitted to the Ieee Standards
association in September 2018) and
p2781—load Modeling and Simula­ IEEE 1584 Updated for 2018
tion. an additional paR concerning the
integration of loads from electric rail is The Second Edition of IEEE 1584 - IEEE Guide for
being developed in coordination with the Performing Arc Flash Hazard Calculations is finally
Ieee Vehicular technology Society. we here. New challenges are ahead and include:
encourage our members outside North
america to engage with the peS tech­ · New data collection requirements
nical Council (https://www.ieee­pes.org/ · New electrode configuration considerations
technical­activities/technical­council) if · New enclosure size considerations
they want to form such working groups
that can operate remotely.
· New calculations and procedures
peS publishes six technical journals · New recommendations and limitations
and two magazines. In addition to hard Simplify a transition to the new standard with
copies, all of these periodicals are available EasyPower software.
online. one of the six journals, IEEE
Power & Energy Technology and Sys-
tems Journal, is open access, and papers
are practice oriented. In this journal, in­
dustry engineers can publish their case
studies, best practices, and unique field · Updated software
deployment experiences for the benefit
of working engineers, who can access · Intro to IEEE 1584-2018
the material for free. More details can
be found at https://www.ieee­pes.org/ · Comparing 2002 vs. 2018
publications/transactions/power­and­
energy­technology­systems­journal. · Instructional videos
peS is deploying significant resourc­
es for training and lifelong learning
· Practical guides
activities for our practicing engineer
members. there are numerous short Explore more online and
courses, webinars, and tutorials— request a free demo copy at:
both online and in person—available
for members throughout the world. un­ www.EasyPower.com/1584
der the peS Corporate engagement
program, we can also offer customized
courses at the company level for groups ®
of engineers needing to be trained in Power made easy.
guest editorial
Antonio J. Conejo and Ramteen Sioshansi

electricity market
a conversation on future designs

T
The firsT efforTs To resTruc­ incorporates weather­dependent renew­ The second article, “electricity Mar­
ture electricity markets in europe and the able producers and increasing demand kets in the united states,” by Litvinov,
united states were in the late 1990s. At flexibility. This issue of IEEE Power & Zhao, and Zheng, reviews the main fea­
that time, electricity production based Energy Magazine is intended to promote tures of electricity markets in the united
on variable weather­dependent sources such a conversation with the ultimate states that resulted from federal energy
was virtually nonexistent. As a result, goal of achieving increasingly efficient regulatory commission (ferc) order
those early efforts did not take into ac­ and fair markets for electricity. 888. The focus, in particular, is on pric­
count the properties of those resources. This issue contains six articles and ing and market­coordination issues and a
Today, such generators are dominant concludes with the “in My View” column. review of day­ahead and real­time energy,
in some markets, such as in california, The first three articles describe the evolu­ forward reserve, and forward capac­
Texas, the iberian Peninsula, and Den­ tion of market designs and forthcoming ity markets. A description of the market
mark. The contribution of variable re­ challenges in europe, the united states, management system components is given,
newable resources in other countries and and New Zealand (with the latter being a which is the internal architecture of the
regions is increasing at a rapid pace. highly renewable­dominated system). The system operator that allows it to effectively
on the flip side, electricity demand following two articles summarize market­ function. They identify the main challeng­
was largely fixed and inelastic in the design challenges from the perspective of es faced by markets in the united states
1990s, with the exception of some indus­ regulators in the united states and europe. today, including those that pertain to the
trial and large commercial customers. The sixth article gives an in­depth analysis grid, and provide ideas to tackle them.
These types of customers display more of current market designs from a historical The next article, “The New Zealand
price sensitivity in their loads, especially perspective and suggests redesign criteria. electricity Market,” by Philpott et al.
if energy constitutes a major input to their The “in My View” column, reviews and describes the historical evolution, main
production processes. even though elec­ clarifies the fundamental economic prin­ features, and governance of the New
tricity demand remains largely fixed to­ ciples on which markets rely. Zealand market. New Zealand pro­
day, new loads, such as those pertaining in the first article, “european union vides an interesting case study, as it is a
to electromobility, and behind­the­meter electricity Markets,” Gómez and his completely isolated island system with
production facilities are slowly increas­ coauthors provide an overview of the seasonal interannual variability in the
ing demand elasticity and flexibility. current state of electricity markets in availability of (hydroelectric) renewable
The operational and planning conse­ europe. They emphasize policies that energy resources. The authors survey
quences of these major changes (such have been pursued by european in­ the historical market and regulatory in­
as the dramatic increase in weather­de­ stitutions to achieve greater market efficiencies, which market restructuring
pendent electricity production and the integration of member states through in New Zealand has tried to address.
incipient increase in demand flexibility) the electricity Target Model. The day­ “A change is coming,” the fourth
need to be reflected in the design of elec­ ahead, intraday, and real­time markets article, by fulli et al. provides a vision
tricity markets of the future. it is crucial are revisited, detailing what has been of how the supply and use of electricity
to spur a conversation to scrutinize to achieved in terms of integration and within europe is expected to evolve over
what extent (if any) these formative mar­ what lies ahead. The capacity alloca­ the next 30 years. They show how regu­
ket designs need to be updated or sim­ tion and congestion management regu­ latory changes and research, demonstra­
ply replaced by a new design that better lation is particularly important as it tion, and development projects supported
Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/MPE.2018.2871737
allows coordination between different by european institutions will change
Date of publication: 7 January 2019 national and regional markets. the nature of customer interactions with

18 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


electricity. in the authors’ vision of the implementation details, not from the ing electricity markets increasingly effi­
future, customers are more engaged in underlying economic principles. cient and fair for all market agents. The
making electricity supply­and­demand our goal in putting together this issue ultimate goal, as stated by the electricity
decisions, as opposed to leaving these to is to spur a much­needed conversation on Authority of New Zealand, is promoting
utilities and supply companies. market redesign, which should involve “competition in, reliable supply by, and
in the fifth article, “Wholesale elec­ operators, regulators, market agents, and the efficient operation of, the electricity
tricity Markets in the united states,” the research community. such a conver­ industry for the long­term benefit
Nicholson and Quinn provide t hei r sation will certainly produce innovative of consumers.”
p&e
view of the ferc in regulating and ideas that will contribute to make exist­
reforming competitive wholesale elec­
tricity markets in the united st ates.
They discuss the means by which the
ferc has encouraged the development
of increasingly competitive wholesale making life visibly safer
markets. The authors also outline three
challenges that these markets will have
to contend with in the near future:
1) the effects of declining wholesale
prices on capacity investment, 2) the
need for a new fleet of flexible energy
resources and the most efficient means
by which to incentivize the develop­
ment of such assets, and 3) coordina­
SpanLite TM

tion between electric power and natural


Self-Illuminated
gas systems. Power Line Marker
in the final feature article, “The
Three Waves of u.s. electricity Market Meets FAA Advisory
reforms,” hobbs and oren provide a Circular 70/7460-1L
detailed analysis of the historical and (Dec. 2015)
future evolution of electricity markets.
Installs directly on
They identify this as taking place in
live lines up to 500 kV
three waves. The first, unbundling
and debunking the natural monopoly
myth, was the formative step in market
restructuring. The second, focus on
economic efficiency and incremental
improvements, was the natural genesis
of lessons learned from the california
market crisis of 2000 and 2001. The
third, making way for demand­side,
renewable, and distributed resources, is
the natural evolution that we are cur­
rently undergoing. They also introduce
us to some of the major figures of mar­
ket restructuring.
The issue concludes with an “in My
View” column by hogan. he insight­
fully notes that the basic premises of BirdMark® & FireFly® FAA Obstruction SpanMarkTM & QuikMarkTM
Bird Diverters Lights Low Line Markers
supply and demand, market clearing,
and pricing that applied when market
restructuring took place in the 1990s
will still apply to a future power sys­

making life visibly safer


tem with renewable energy supply and
demand flexibility. he concludes that 800-722-8078 • pr-tech.com
6851

any potential market flaws stem from

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 19


European
Union Electricity
Markets

Current
Practice and
Future View

Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/MPE.2018.2871739 ©istockphoto.com/tommasourbinati,


Date of publication: 7 January 2019 flag—©istockphoto.com/artJazz

20 ieee power & energy magazine 1540-7977/19©2019IEEE january/february 2019


By Tomás Gómez, Ignacio Herrero, Pablo Rodilla,
Rodrigo Escobar, Salvatore Lanza, Ignacio de la Fuente,
Maria Luisa Llorens, and Paula Junco

T
The european union (eu) aims To develop an provide a marketplace where wholesale buyers and sellers can
integrated electricity market as an efficient instrument to exchange electricity in an organized way, with a set of rules,
achieve the energy policy targets of security, affordability, and at public prices.
sustainability. many milestones have already been reached, Therefore, the two basic functions necessary in a deregu-
including the implementation of a european platform for lated power system, system operation and the organization
the simultaneous clearing of day-ahead markets, the design of competitive electricity markets, are split into two separate
of several platforms for coordinating intraday and regional entities: Tsos and nemos. This institutional framework is
balancing markets, and the enforcement of guidelines for the clearly different from the most common structure found in
design of capacity mechanisms (Cms). There are still many the united states, in which independent system operators
challenges ahead for this market: the integration of large perform both market and system operation functions. on
amounts of renewable energy, the proliferation of distributed top of these foundations, additional rules must be defined to
resources, higher consumer engagement, and the sheer scale achieve the main goal of the eu electricity market, which is to
and complexity of a market serving 500 million citizens. This allow cross-border trading of electricity and optimize the use
is a fascinating task that will keep us busy in the coming years. of interconnections, while pursuing a level playing field for
The formal beginning of the european electricity mar- all market participants. rules are set by defining framework
ket took place in 1996, when the european parliament and guidelines, which are then detailed in binding regulation as
the european Council approved the first electricity direc- network codes or guidelines. These are developed by the
tive (96/92/eC) aimed at liberalizing the energy sector by european Commission (eC), the agency for the Cooperation
establishing competitive electricity markets. The subsequent of energy regulators, the national regulatory authorities
energy packages continued the development and integra- (nras), and the european network of Transmission system
tion of european electricity markets, not only with an inter- operators for electricity in a cooperative process.
est in deregulation but as part of the overall european This cooperative process has led, slowly but steadily, to
energy policy. a great degree of integration among the eu electricity mar-
one of the eu’s main objectives is to share a single market kets. however, the process is still far from being fully com-
that guarantees the free movement of goods, capital, servic - pleted. This article reviews the major milestones that have
es, and labor. in this context, a single market for electric- already been reached in the integration of the eu electricity
ity allows greater integration of the member states, which is markets as well as the major challenges ahead.
also necessary for the eu to have a common and coordinated
external energy policy. Therefore, the electricity market has EU Target Model
been designed as an instrument to achieve the goals of supply The eu Target model refers to the institutional arrangements
security, affordability, and sustainability of the eu. and conceptual market definitions that have been developed
The common electricity market has been (and is being) to ensure efficient cross-border exchanges in the european
built gradually, beginning with its institutional arrangement. electricity market. The formal definition of those arrange-
The first major transition is the unbundling of generation, ments has been established in the Capacity allocation and
transmission, distribution, and retail activities. The eu leg- Congestion management (CaCm) regulations, which cover
islation allows some freedom to the member states to imple- cross-zonal capacity allocation in the day-ahead and intraday
ment different schemes for unbundling transmission, most time frames as well as in the Forward Capacity allocation
commonly the full ownership unbundling through a transmis- (FCa) regulations for long-term capacity allocation. in addi-
sion system operator (Tso), which owns and operates the grid tion, the Guideline on electricity Balancing (GleB) regula-
and must not have any interest in generation activities. The tion complements those regulations with common principles
other basic building block in this organization is the power and methodologies for the procurement and settlement of
exchange (pX) or, more specifically, the nominated electricity operating reserves and their activation in real-time operations.
market operator (nemo) when it refers to the operation of the The overall market model uses sequential markets: day-ahead,
integrated day-ahead and intraday markets. market operators intraday, and balancing.

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 21


The formal beginning of the European electricity
market took place in 1996.

in day-ahead markets, the nemos match demand and spain and portugal zones; epeX spot operates in the
supply bids to set hourly energy prices in each bidding zone. Germany, austria, France, Great Britain, The netherlands,
The european day-ahead market is a zonal price market, in Belgium, and switzerland zones; and nord pool operates
contrast with nodal price markets (as in the united states). in the norway, sweden, Finland, denmark, Great Britain,
as shown in Figure 1, most member states feature a single estonia, lithuania, and latvia zones. other nemos man-
bidding zone, but some are divided into several zones to age single-country zones, such as Gestore mercati energet-
reflect structural internal congestions, i.e., italy and swe- ici (Gme) in italy.
den. in addition, the nemos may manage several bidding in the intraday time frame, the nemos are working to
zones belonging to different member states. For instance, set a european continuous implicit trading platform. in the
the operador del mercado ibérico (omie) manages the future, intraday cross-zonal capacities will be priced reflect-
ing congestion. in some peripheral
markets, such as in the iberian pen-
insula, italy, and ireland, and more
recently in the nordic region, the
continuous market could be com-
SW1 plemented with intraday auctions
that increase liquidity and price
transparency. Cross-zonal capac-
NO4 ity was previously determined
SW2 FIN by the Tsos and then implicitly
NO3
allocated in day-ahead and intra-
NO5 NO1 day markets by the corresponding
SW3 clearing algorithms.
NO2 Currently in europe, most bal-
ancing markets for the procure-
SW4
DK1
ment and settlement of reserves
NI DK2 and real-time operation are local
in scope and mainly managed
IE GB
independently by each Tso. how-
NL PL ever, several regional initiatives
GE have already started to coordinate
BE
LX CZ the activation and exchange of dif-
SK ferent types of balancing energy
AU among neighboring Tsos, in line
HU
FR SZ with the mandates of the GleB
SLO regulation. The final goal of this
IT1
regulation is to set a progressively
pan-european market with a com-
IT2 mon merit order for activation of
PR IT3 balancing energy. These main
SP IT4 regulations (FCa, CaCm, and
IT5 GleB) are complemented with a
set of other network codes on grid
IT6 connection and system operation
that complete the presented eu
figure 1. The bidding zones in European power markets. (Image courtesy of the Of- Target model to ensure an inte-
fice of Gas and Electricity Markets, “Bidding Zones Literature Review.” London, United grated, efficient, and secure euro-
Kingdom, 2014.) pean electricity market.

22 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


NEMO Markets: Day Ahead and Intraday the CaCm does not trigger this process from scratch: many
countries already had well-established local markets, each
Role of the NEMOs of them having specific characteristics (e.g., the time for
The CaCm provides the legal definition, designation pro- opening and closing of the market session).
cess, and roles for the nemos. each member state has the The need to converge to harmonized rules entails that some
ability to assign the nemo role to one (legal monopoly) or or all parties must modify some of their existing characteris-
more (in competition) entities. market participants in a given tics (such as the price limits imposed on the market, the length
member state submit bids and receive market results through of the market session, and settlement rules). This, inevitably,
their assigned (in case of a monopoly) or preferred nemo, creates conflicts among parties, and it is fair to acknowledge
which gives them access to the european day-ahead- and/ the significant effort made by the nras and market partici-
or intraday-coupled markets. The most relevant task to be pants to bring the pCr project to fruition. Figure 2 shows the
performed by the nemos is the market coupling operator high level of harmonization already achieved in europe with
(mCo) function, defined as the task of matching orders for many markets using the pCr.
the day-ahead and intraday markets for different bidding most of the eu member states are already coupled under
zones and simultaneously allocating cross-zonal capacities. the so-called multi-regional Coupling (mrC) project, which
The mCo function is a fundamentally centralized task and, is based on the use of the pCr algorithm. only one mrC
therefore, requires tight cooperation and coordination among member (Bulgaria) is not physically coupled to the rest of the
nemos. in addition, given that day-ahead and intraday mar- mrC area. at this stage, there is another separate regional
kets in the eu perform the implicit allocation of intercon- coupling mechanism called 4mmC using the pCr algorithm
nection capacity, close coordination with Tsos is required that gathers four eu member states. other countries have
(since they are responsible for computing available transmis- plans to implement the pCr algorithm and couple with their
sion capacities). neighbors in the future. Finally, two other countries already
The CaCm assigns the mCo function jointly to all use the pCr algorithm but are not coupled to any neighbor-
nemos. This implies that the same entities required to ing country (independent users).
compete at the local level to perform the nemo role have
to cooperate at the central level to provide the mCo func- Benefits
tions. all designated nemos have a mandate to agree on a The benefits of integrating electricity wholesale markets
plan that sets out how to jointly set up and perform the mCo are multiple: efficient day-ahead capacity allocation, higher
functions. This plan was approved by all nras in June 2017, liquidity, wider relevant market, consistent energy price for-
and according to the CaCm, it must be implemented within mation with the same algorithm (known as euphemia), and
12 months. Consequently, all nemos in coordination with reduced information asymmetry across regions. Furthermore,
the Tsos achieved a number of
contractual milestones (i.e., a
cooperation agreement and sev-
eral operational agreements) and
technical milestones specific to
either the day-ahead or the intra-
day market.

Day-Ahead Markets:
Markets Coupled
PCR Initiative MRC

Implementation Challenges Markets in MRC


The price coupling of regions Not Fully Coupled
(pCr) initiative developed the
Markets Using PRC
methodology for the joint clear- Algorithm 4MMC
ing of the day-ahead market in
europe. as already introduced, Independent
this requires a common process Users
to calculate electricity prices
Future Markets
in all european bidding zones Foreseen for
and a single market-clearing Coupling
a lgor ith m, which calls for a
high degree of harmonization
among local markets. however, figure 2. The PCR users. (Data courtesy of PCR with our own elaboration.)

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 23


short-term efficiency (capacity is always implicitly allo- of nodes. Because of this approximation, commercial and
cated to those who value it the most) supports long-term effi- physical flows hardly coincide, which creates unscheduled
ciency (investment in additional capacity is based on reliable flows and loop flows.
scarcity signals).
it is difficult to provide a quantitative estimate of these Current Discussions Around Day-Ahead Markets
benefits in a wholesale electricity market serving 500 million To be approved by nras, the market-clearing algorithm
citizens. one of the most noticeable benefits is an improve- must comply with a number of requirements set out by the
ment in the use of interconnections. Figure 3 shows the usage CaCm. however, such requirements might turn out not to
of network capacity in the “right direction,” i.e., when day- be jointly attainable.
ahead market prices dictate that it is economical to do so.
Coordination among member states clearly improved as they Improvements to the Algorithm
joined the pCr initiative, which included the interconnec- according to the CaCm, “the algorithm aims at maximizing
tions in 30 of 42 eu borders by the end of 2016. the economic surplus,” which is also known as the total wel-
price convergence is also a desirable outcome of the single fare and is equal to the sum of the consumer surplus and
market. in this regard, it should be recalled that the eu Target the producer surplus. in practice, the time to run the algorithm
model is based on a zonal system; transmission congestion is limited, and the solution does not necessarily achieve the
between bidding zones is reflected in zonal price differences. maximization of the economic surplus. This entails a wel-
in principle, the bidding zones are defined so no structural fare loss, whose measurement is critical to assess which
congestion is expected within them, but the optimal configu- investments should be made by the nemos to improve the
ration of bidding zones is a controversial issue and difficult efficiency of the algorithm. For this reason, metrics (indica-
to implement in practice because it would also evolve with tors) are needed to assess the magnitude of the welfare loss
system evolution and changes. on the one hand, some argue and investment in algorithm improvements are required.
that if bidding zones are too small, market liquidity may be
negatively affected. on the other hand, if bidding zones are Scalability
too large, internal congestion is not solved through market- The pCr project, based on a voluntary agreement among
based capacity allocation mechanisms, and, consequently, some european pXs, had a limited geographical scope. The
an efficiency loss occurs. price convergence should not be CaCm requests the nemos to use the existing solution (i.e.,
achieved artificially, i.e., by merging bidding zones, but it the pCr) as a basis for extending day-ahead market coupling
should be attained through adequate interconnection capac- to all eu member states and even to go beyond the eu (nor-
ity among zones. additionally, it is worth noting that, in many way, switzerland, and some energy community contracting
cases, bidding zones coincide with member states; therefore, parties). since the project was not initially designed for such
political arguments play a nonnegligible role in the defini- a broad scope, scalability problems may arise. although the
tion of the bidding zone configuration. Finally, from a physi- pCr initiative developed its initial steps with ease (because
cal perspective, bidding zones are conventional aggregates few actors were involved initially), shifting from the pilot

100
90 15% 16% 14%
25% 23%
Net Transfer Capacity (%)

39% 33%
80
70
60
Available

50
40 85% 84% 86%
75% 77%
61% 67%
30
20
10
0
2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016

Capacity Used in the Right Direction Capacity Unused in the Right Direction

figure 3. The percentage of available transfer capacity used in the “right direction” under a >1€/MWh price differential
on 37 European electricity interconnectors. (Chart courtesy of the ACER/CEER, Annual Report on the Results of Monitor-
ing the Internal Electricity and Gas Markets in 2016, October 2017.)

24 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


version to the commercial one proved to be more challenging. extension based on readiness of the concerned nemos
however, the scalability issue is not limited to the geo- and Tsos.
graphical scope; the performance of the current version of
the algorithm can be seriously degraded, not only because of XBID Implementation Challenges
the number of selling and buying orders but also when some one of the main challenges of the XBid project has been the
challenging combinations of complex orders are used in the cooperation among project parties (some of them being com-
same bidding zone. in the future, many limitations should peting entities) with different positions and interests. For that
be removed by algorithmic and technological improvements, reason, one key issue was to ensure that all parties would be
but this process will likely require numerous incremental granted equal treatment by the trading system.
improvements. From the technical point of view, the main challenge was
to build a reliable and scalable trading system, capable of
Complex Orders processing a considerable number of transactions per sec-
as more member states joined the pCr, the market-clear- ond. also, the local nemo and Tso systems must comply
ing algorithm grew in complexity by incorporating new with demanding requirements to successfully interact with
order types from each nemo. This diverse set of order the central platform.
types allows market agents to reflect different operating at present, there are some intraday continuous trad-
and economic constraints, some of them depending on ing platforms at a regional scale, but these can hardly be
market results, complicating the computation of market considered a relevant benchmark for the XBid platform,
prices. Furthermore, the algorithm must apply the uni- which has a pan-european scope and is designed to com-
form pricing principle within each bidding zone. This ply with the requirements of the CaCm. The liquidity in
approach is, among other reasons, aimed at improving the XBid and the amount of offers that may be submitted
transparency: an accepted market order is always profit- to the system in peak times are difficult to predict. There-
able (in the money) at given market prices, facilitating fore, even though the project parties designed realistic
the verification of market results. however, some orders scenarios to test system performance, it will only be pos-
might be paradoxically rejected even if apparently in the sible to assess to what extent it serves market needs after
money. Because of the complexity of the algorithm, the XBid goes live. There are some pending future evolutions
reasons of the rejection may not always be clear or trans- and requirements, such as processing flow-based param-
parent to the market participants, hindering confidence in eters, incorporating losses on a high-voltage direct current
the clearing process. interconnector(s) between bidding zones during capacity
allocation, minimizing the number of bidding zone bor-
Intraday Markets: XBID Initiative ders on the path between the matched orders, allowing for
route prioritization using interconnector-specific cost coef-
Status ficients, and so on.
The Cross-Border intraday market project (also known as
XBid) is an initiative of several nemos (epeX, Gme, Current Discussions Around Intraday Markets
nord pool, and omie) to implement the eu Target model in the intraday time frame, the target of the CaCm is to have
for the intraday time frame, which is a continuous energy pan-european continuous energy trading, with reliable pric-
market with an implicit continuous allocation of cross- ing of intraday cross-zonal capacity reflecting congestion.
zonal transmission capacity. The XBid solution is based Where there is sufficient liquidity, regional auctions may com-
on a shared order book, linking the local trading systems plement the implicit continuous allocation mechanism.
operated by the nemos, and on a centralized capacity The rationale for promoting a pan-european continu-
management module, which gathers available cross-zonal ous energy market is based on the understanding that the
transmission capacities provided by the Tsos. Therefore, main purpose of the intraday market is to enable market
orders entered by market participants in one bidding zone participants to trade energy as close to real time as pos-
can be matched with orders submitted by market partici- sible to balance their position. indeed, the bulk of the
pants in any other bidding zone within the information energy trading is supposed to take place in longer-term
technology (iT) systems’ reach, provided there is cross-zonal time frames and be incorporated by the Tso in its pro-
capacity available. according to the CaCm, negotiation in gram. in practice, in many member states, the volume
the continuous intraday market should be possible until (at negotiated in the intraday time frame is rather low (around
least) 1 h before delivery time. one order of magnitude lower than the day-ahead nego-
after several years of project development, the XBid tiation). however, it is expected that an increasing share
platform became operational. The implementation plan of renewable generation and the expected development of
comprises local implementation projects, which means demand flexibility will result in increased negotiation in
that the operations of XBid will not start at the same time the intraday market. Furthermore, in the day-ahead market,
in all member states. There will be a stepwise geographical market participants implicitly pay for cross-border capacities

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 25


In day-ahead markets, the NEMOs match
demand and supply bids to set hourly energy
prices in each bidding zone.

whereas they currently use it for free in continuous trad- the cross-border capacities available for balancing, incorpo-
ing. Therefore, shifting trading volumes from day ahead to rating nemos’ nominations for intraday schedules. Besides
intraday might be economically convenient for some mar- this, balancing gate-closure timing also relies on previous
ket participants. intraday timing.
The continuous market provides a platform where any Balancing markets have not yet reached the harmoniza-
market participant may adapt its position at any time, until tion of day-ahead and intraday markets. They differ in sev-
1 h before the time of delivery, if allowed by market condi- eral important aspects that need to be addressed before the
tions, i.e., enough availability of buy/sell orders and avail- full integration of balancing markets across europe can be
able transmission capacity. on the other hand, intraday reached. First, the definition of the balancing products, i.e.,
auctions allow participants to adjust their positions only at the operating reserve types to be used, should be established.
specific times, which is less agile but helps to pool liquid- Three categories have been defined:
ity and, most importantly, provides a single clearing price ✔ Replacement reserve (RR): manually activated bal-
for all of the associated transactions. Therefore, intraday ancing reserve characterized by the slowest activation
auctions may be preferred by smaller market participants time (up to a 30-min activation time).
who cannot operate in a continuous market as effectively as ✔ Manual frequency restoration reserve (mFRR): equiv-
larger players. alent to tertiary reserve (less than a 15-min activation
regarding the pricing of cross-zonal capacity in a con- time, mostly provided by spinning reserve).
tinuous trading framework, pursuant to the CaCm, all the ✔ Automatic frequency restoration reserve (aFRR): equiv-
Tsos proposed to organize at least an intraday auction near alent to secondary reserve (regulation reserve in unit-
the end of the day ahead of delivery that would allocate the ed states).
available capacities in an implicit way, originating conges- The definition of these balancing products is currently
tion rents. Besides, the CaCm also allows for complemen- under harmonization. modifying the definition of balancing
tary regional auctions. products requires significant changes to the Tso operating
There is a general problem with price formation mecha- procedures and their corresponding iT infrastructure. mar-
nisms in the target model: the day-ahead market is based on ket participants also need to adapt, mainly balancing service
implicit auctions (uniform clearing price for energy reflect- providers (Bsps) and balance responsible parties, as defined
ing cross-zonal congestion), whereas the intraday market is in the GleB. For this purpose, the Tsos are closely cooper-
organized in a dual manner. For example, in the continuous ating with european market stakeholders to define technical
trading mode, energy is priced pay as bid with the associ- rules and products.
ated cross-zonal capacity allocated for free until conges- settlement rules for balancing products also need to be
tion is reached, whereas, in the intraday auction, the pricing harmonized. Currently, several countries apply marginal pric-
is equivalent to the day-ahead mechanism. This dual intraday ing while others apply pay as bid, or regulated prices. Figure 4
market may produce some inconsistencies in prices since illustrates the different settlement systems for mFrr energy
the bidding behavior of market players is adapted to each in europe.
allocation mechanism. This can create confusion and be
detrimental to the less-sophisticated market players. Benefits
an integrated european balancing market should unlock
Balancing Markets synergies between Tsos, such as the netting of balancing
needs of different signs, upward and downward. netting
Status cross-border imbalances would bring important benefits by
european balancing markets put the “latest” price on energy, reducing the amount of balancing energy activated, which
reflecting real-time imbalances and the corrective actions would not only reduce balancing costs but also imply higher
of the Tsos to ensure the balance between generation and availability of reserves, which could further reduce operat-
demand at every moment. The Tsos organize and are respon- ing reserve needs.
sible for these markets that involve real-time operational higher Tso coordination would facilitate renewable
security and the deployment of reserve capacities. There- production integration, and similarly to the day-ahead and
fore, they require close coordination so the Tsos can update intraday markets, a wider balancing market is expected to

26 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


In the intraday time frame, the NEMOs are
working to set a European continuous
implicit trading platform.

increase liquidity and improve competition. The implementa- mainly procured by european Tsos in local reserve markets of
tion of cross-border balancing energy exchanges will also different types. These markets present even more differences
help to optimize the use of interconnection capacities and from one member state to another. some Tsos organize daily
reinforce operational security in europe. Therefore, building auctions, whereas, in other cases, the Tsos rely on weekly,
the european integrated balancing market is fully aligned monthly, or even longer commitments for reserve procurement.
with the achievement of european energy policy objectives.
a cost-benefit analysis for 2013 estimated that the net ben- Future Balancing Markets
efits that would be gained if six neighboring european coun- The GleB regulation became effective in december 2017,
tries [involved in the Trans-european replacement reserves and its main goal is to create european balancing platforms at
exchange (Terre) project described later] cooperated different time scales, while harmonizing different aspects of
in the activation of replacement reserves would amount local balancing markets. Besides this, it promotes the pro-
to €150 million per year. in addition, it was shown that those vision of balancing services from renewable units, flexible
benefits would increase significantly if some of the cross- demand and energy storage units under the same conditions as
border interconnection capacities were upgraded. conventional generation units, and the application of marginal
on the other hand, the described harmonization effort pricing (rather than pay as bid) for the settlement of balancing
among european balancing markets is focused on the acti- energy. The GleB regulation also aims at an absence of price
vation of balancing energy. Currently, balancing capacity is caps and floors.

Frequency Restoration Reserve (Manual)–Energy–Settlement Rule


Definition of Question
Settlement Rule The pricing rules for settlement.

Definition of Answer
Hybrid Combination
Marginal Pricing Marginal pricing is the change in total cost arises
when the quantity produced changes by one unit.
Pay as Bid Contracted parties who provides a service are
paid based on their offer price.

Regulated Price The price for this service is based on a price that
is set by the relevant regulatory authority.

Key
Missing Data
N/A
Pay as Bid
Marginal Pricing
Regulated Price
Hybrid

figure 4. The different settlement rules of the mFRR energy in Europe. “Missing data” refers to the TSOs that did not re-
spond the questionnaire, and “N/A” refers to the TSOs that did not answer to this specific question. (Image courtesy of the
ENTSO-E, Survey on ancillary services procurement, balancing market design, March 2017.)

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 27


The CACM provides the legal definition,
designation process,
and roles for the NEMOs.

another relevant point is the harmonization of gate- platform. The iT platform liBra is composed of different
closure times for Bsps to submit bids to the corresponding modules: 1) an optimization algorithm for a common balanc-
balancing platforms, for which the prior harmonization of ing market merit order and 2) a settlement and capacity man-
intraday gate-closure times (as described above) is crucial. in agement module. The Tsos from France, italy, portugal,
addition, a harmonization of imbalance settlement periods to spain, switzerland, and Great Britain are actively participat-
15 min is encouraged before January 2025. The GleB also ing. in the future, additional countries may be incorporated
encourages the financial settlement of unintended deviations, into the rr platform, including romania, Czech repub-
in contrast with the current scheme in continental europe lic, poland, hungary, and Bulgaria. The energy exchanged
based on the pay-in-kind approach (which nets energy deliv- in this platform will make use of the remaining cross-border
ery at equivalent peak/off-peak periods). Finally, the GleB capacity after the last intraday market.
considers the possibility of cross-border capacity reservation
for balancing purposes when justified through a previous The mFRR Activation and Platform
cost-benefit analysis. unlike the rr activation that is only mandatory for coun-
tries using the rr, the mFrr activation, under the GleB
Implementation Steps regulation, is mandatory for all european interconnected
The gradual implementation of the GleB would be facilitated Tsos. The current reference project for the future mFrr
by regional cooperation through the development of different activation platform is the manually activated reserves ini-
platforms to allow information exchange among the Tsos tiative. This project is currently in a design phase involv-
and market participants. each balancing process will require ing 19 european Tsos, and six Tsos are in the process of
a separate platform, and each platform will involve a different becoming observers.
set of the Tsos and entail different technical complexities,
so each will face a different deadline, as shown in Figure 5. The aFRR Process and Platform
in Figure 5, two different deadlines are set for each platform. The aFrr activation will be voluntary for european inter-
The first deadline establishes when the platform should be connected Tsos. For instance, Great Britain and ireland do
implemented according the GleB requirements. The second not currently use the aFrr. The reference project is called
deadline is when all concerned Tsos should be integrated in the platform for the international Coordination of the auto-
the platform. Both deadlines are the same for the rr activa- matic Frequency restoration process and stable system
tion platform and the imbalance netting (in) platform. operation. This project is under design, and eight european
Tsos are full members of this initiative, including Tsos
RR Activation and Platform from Belgium, austria, The netherlands, and France as well
The Terre project has been launched and was designated by as the four Tsos from Germany. The remaining european
enTso-e (european network of Transmission system oper- interconnected Tsos using the aFrr are currently in the
ators for electricity) as a reference to implement the future rr process of joining this initiative.

Platforms 2017 2018 2019 2020 2021 2022 2023 2024


Replacement Reserve
Manual Frequency Restoration Reserve
Automatic Frequency Restoration Reserve
Imbalance Netting

GLEB Entry into Force


Deadline for Implementation of the Platform According to the GLEB
Deadline for Integration of all Concerned TSOs

figure 5. The road map for the implementation of European/regional balancing energy activation platforms.

28 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


In the future, intraday cross-zonal capacities will be
priced reflecting congestion.

IN Platform observability, and, therefore, forecasting imbalances is more


The goal of the in platform is to minimize the activation of the difficult. in this case, aFrr, sometimes complemented with
aFrr energy by counteracting the systems’ aFrr real-time mFrr for resetting the usage of aFrr, is the main resource
imbalance requirements of opposite sign (upward and down- used by the Tsos to counteract imbalances. reactive bal-
ward). The in platform, called the international Grid Coop- ancing is used in markets with intraday gate closures very
eration Control (iGCC), is already in a go-live stage, and is close to real time, e.g., 30 min before delivery in the German
operated by the German Tso Transnet BW. For nordic Tsos, case, and also a high level of interconnection capacity with
joining the platform is optional, since they belong to a differ- the rest of the neighboring systems.
ent synchronous area. The united Kingdom and ireland do not
currently use the aFrr, so they cannot be involved either. Central Versus Self-Dispatch
The in platform is envisaged, in principle, as a tempo- in centrally dispatched systems, such as those in poland and
rary process, since the aFrr platform, once established, italy, Tsos assume the responsibility of physically rescheduling
will also perform implicitly imbalance netting as part of the resources immediately after the day-ahead market gate closure,
economic optimization. although the in platform does not so intraday markets only play a financial role at centrally dis-
use economic information, it minimizes the activation of patched systems. alternatively, self-dispatched systems (most
the aFrr by taking advantage of synergies among systems european systems) still allow market actors to change their
with opposing aFrr needs subject to available cross-border physical schedules until the gate closure of intraday markets.
capacities and additional exchange security limits. This plat-
form has been proven useful because reducing upward and Future View
downward aFrr activations, through the netting process,
can significantly reduce balancing costs, since aFrr energy Clean Energy for All Europeans
is, by nature, the most expensive balancing energy. The eu energy policy sets decarbonization commitments for
member states for 2030 and beyond. different instruments,
Additional Features of GLEB such as renewable and energy-efficient mandatory targets and
The GleB road map will face the following inherent hetero- carbon dioxide emission pricing, are promoted and imple-
geneity aspects of the interconnected european systems that mented at the national or european level. in particular, the
will likely remain in the future. electricity sector is called to play a central role in this transi-
tion. The increasing shares of renewable electricity genera-
Proactive Versus Reactive Balancing tion (mainly from wind and solar), electrification of vehicles
proactive balancing actions take advantage of forecast- and buildings, and adoption of distributed energy resources
ing tools, for demand and the production of wind and solar by electricity prosumers create new challenges for the design
resources, to activate slow balancing products (rr) that com- and operation of the integrated european electricity market.
pensate for forecast deviations in advance. The aim is to solve in this context, in november 2016, the eC presented the
imbalances as soon as they are identified, therefore using bal- Clean energy package, a set of legislative proposals for nearly
ancing energy that is expected to be less costly. The accuracy every energy-related sector. These proposals allow glimpses
of forecasting tools relies on the real-time observability of the of the upcoming challenges in the implementation of the elec-
system. Therefore, Tsos using proactive balancing actions tricity market.
make use of all balancing products (rr, mFrr, and aFrr) regarding renewable energy integration, the challenges are
in sequence. This approach is typically adopted in systems not exactly new. as reviewed in this article, integrating all
with a high level of system observability (high accuracy of european power markets requires major market reforms in the
forecasts) and where intraday markets’ gate closure takes directions signaled by the CaCm and GleB regulations. Well-
place up to 1 h before real time. This is the case of Tsos in functioning and coordinated intraday and balancing markets are
France, spain, portugal, the united Kingdom, italy, poland, an increasingly important way to achieving the much-needed
and hungary, among others. in these contexts, proactive use flexibility necessary to complement intermittent and variable
of manual reserves avoids making excessive use of more wind and solar generation. To ensure the best possible outcome,
expensive balancing energies (mFrr and aFrr). these markets should be open to the participation not only of
reactive balancing actions wait until deviations are conventional generators but also of new flexible resources, such
almost detected very close to real time. There is a lack of as demand response and storage. at the same time, all market

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 29


30
Capacity Auction Strategic Reserve
(Since 2014, First (Since 2007)
Delivery in 2017/2018)

Strategic Reserve
Capacity Payments (Since 2004), Gradual
(Since 2007) Considering Phase-Out Postponed
Reliability Options to 2025

ieee power & energy magazine


Capacity Requirements Network Reserves
(Certification Started
1 April 2015,
First Delivery in 2017) Strategic Reserves

Capacity Payments Strategic Reserves


(Since 2008, Part of Them (Envisaged End 2018)
Do Not Apply to New
Capacity Installed as of
1 January 2016)–Tendering Strategic Reserve
for Capacity Considered (from 2016 on, Extended
But No Plans Until the End of 2019)

Capacity Payments Strategic Reserve


(Since 2010 Partially (Since 1 November 2014)
Suspended
Between May 2011
and December 2014)
Tender
(Since November 2013)
Reliability Options (The
Date for the First Auction
Has Not Been Set. First (Capacity Payments
Delivery of Contracted Existed from 2006 to 2014)
Capacity Is Expected New Capacity Payments
in 2020. Ongoing from 1 May 2016 to 30
Discussions with the EC) April 2017 Approved by
the EC

No CM (Energy-Only Market) CM Proposed/Under Consideration CM Operational

january/february 2019
figure 6. The CMs in Europe. The main changes compared with 2015 are highlighted in red. (Image courtesy of the ACER/CEER, Annual Report on the Results of Moni-
toring the Internal Electricity and Gas Markets in 2016, October 2017.)
participants must bear the same responsibilities, including balanc- are caps on wholesale market prices, retail price regulation,
ing production schedules (from which renewable generation support schemes for fossil or nuclear generators that do not
has traditionally been exempt, as a way of promotion). incentivize a flexible operation, and the previously discussed
harmonized market rules across europe enable the real- poor designs of intraday and balancing markets.
ization of synergies between energy resources in different
member states, guaranteeing an efficient operation of the For Further Reading
power system. however, an integrated market also requires a european Commission. (2016, nov.). proposal for a directive
higher level of cross-border interconnections among member of the european parliament and of the Council on common
states, and the eC has identified increasing interconnection rules for the internal market in electricity november 2016.
capacity as a strategic objective. Building consensus around europa. [online] available: http://ec.europa.eu/
the development of new transmission projects, and especially Commission regulation (eu) 2015/1222 of 24 July 2015
about the cost allocation of such projects, is an ongoing pro- establishing a guideline on capacity allocation and con-
cess led by the Tsos and regulators. gestion management. entsoe. [online]. available: https://
electricity.network-codes.eu/network_codes/cacm/
New Resources, Complexity, and Scalability Commission regulation (eu) 2017/2195 of 23 november
The Clean energy package envisions a power market in which 2017 establishing a guideline on electricity balancing. entsoe.
consumers can engage in demand response, self-consump- [online]. available: https://electricity.network-codes.eu/
tion, or self-generation and participate in markets. distributed network_codes/eb/
energy resources, such as decentralized generation, storage, and nemo Committee. (2017, July 24). all nemos proposal
demand response would be allowed to participate in wholesale for the mCo plan approved by all nras of the eu on 26 June
electricity markets directly or through aggregators meeting the 2017. europex. [online]. available: http://www.europex.org/
required technical capabilities, in a level playing field with con- all-nemos/all-nemos-mco-plan/
ventional generators. That would involve changes not only in the agency for the Cooperation of energy regulators. (2017,
design of current retail and wholesale markets but also in the oct. 6). annual report on the results of monitoring the in-
interactions and coordination between the Tsos and the distri- ternal electricity and gas markets in 2016. aCer. ljublja-
bution system operators. na, slovenia. [online]. available: https://acer.europa.eu/
in general, the presence of distributed energy resources official_documents/publications/aCer%20market%20
will increase the number of market participants, challenging monitoring%20report%202016%20%20document%20
the implementation of a power market that is already under histo/aCer%20market%20monitoring%20repor t%
great strain due to its computational complexities. Future 202016%20-%20eleCTriCiTY%20-%20original.pdf
developments in day-ahead and intraday markets will be i. J. perez-arriaga, C. Knittel, a. Bharatkumar, m. Birk, s.
characterized by the unavoidable conflict between the need Burger, J. p. Chaves, p. duenas-martinez, i. herrero, s. hun-
to simplify implementation due to technical constraints and tington, J. Jenkins, m. luke, r. miller, p. rodilla, r. Tabors,
to allow for the more complex participation models required K. Tapia-ahumada, C. vergara, and n. Xu. (2016, dec.). utility
by new resources such as demand flexibility or storage. of the future: an miT energy initiative response to an industry
in transition 2016. miT energy initiative. [online]. available:
Scope of Markets http://energy.mit.edu/research/utility-future-study/
The Clean energy package makes a clear statement in favor
of markets as the best tool to enable efficiency and transpar- Biographies
ency for participants. Well-functioning “energy-only” markets, Tomás Gómez is with the universidad pontificia Comillas,
as presented in this article, have been considered the most spain.
efficient design for an integrated european electricity market. Ignacio Herrero is with the universidad pontificia
however, this paradigm has been, and is frequently, challenged Comillas, spain.
by adequacy concerns that lead to different types of Cms. Pablo Rodilla is with the universidad pontificia Comillas,
Figure 6 shows that a significant number of member states have spain.
already implemented or plan the implementation of different Rodrigo Escobar is with the operador del mercado
national Cms. ibérico, spain.
The eC has provided guidelines for member states to jus- Salvatore Lanza is with the autorità per l´energia, italy.
tify the need for Cms and, if that is the case, to implement Ignacio de la Fuente is with the red eléctrica de españa,
Cm designs that minimize distortions in the functioning of spain.
short-term markets and support neighboring areas in case of Maria Luisa Llorens is with the red eléctrica de
adequacy problems. in addition, it recommends that mem- españa, spain.
ber states identify the market flaws that may constitute an Paula Junco is with the red eléctrica de españa, spain.
obstacle to the provision of adequacy and only if these flaws
p&e
cannot be removed to resort to a Cm. among those obstacles

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 31


Electricity
Markets in the
United States

F
Following order 888 From the Federal regulatory energy
Commission (FerC) in 1996, the u.S. power industry began its restructuring pro-
cess. this undertaking involved a transition from a vertically integrated utility
structure where generation, transmission, and distribution are combined to serve
consumers. through advancing to a market environment, generation companies
(genCos) can compete with each other to provide energy through open transmis-
sion and distribution systems managed by transmission (transCos) and distribution
companies (disCos). the goals of the restructuring are the efficient produc-
tion of electricity and efficient generation investment through competition. under the

Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/MPE.2018.2872300


Date of publication: 7 January 2019

32 ieee power & energy magazine 1540-7977/19©2019IEEE january/february 2019


©istockphoto.com/vector, store window items—image licensed by ingram publishing

restructured environment shown in Figure 1, wholesale electricity markets are managed by independent system
operators (iSos) or regional transmission organizations (rtos), whose responsibility is reliable system opera-
tion, market administration, and system planning. genCos, large consumers, load aggregators, marketers, and
load serving entities (lSes) buy and sell electricity through FerC-regulated wholesale electricity markets.
Small consumers like individual households, some large consumers, lSes, marketers, and load aggregators
can transact energy either at a regulated retail rate overseen by the public utility commission (PuC) or through
retail competition. the restructuring process has been complex, especially in trying to harmonize the whole-
sale and retail sides, and involves many stakeholders from both public and private sectors (see Figure 1).
u.S. electricity markets have been considered largely successful,
and the rto footprint continues to grow. today there are seven rtos
Power Industry operating in the united States (see Figure 2), bringing substantial
benefits to end users. the benefits achieved by iSo new england’s
Restructuring (iSo-ne’s) wholesale electricity markets are summarized in table 1,
as one example.
Processes for the wholesale electricity markets evolved with changes in regulatory
policy, technological innovations, and economic conditions since the
Present and Future start of electric restructuring. during the past two decades, the u.S.
power industry has experienced a transformation with the retirement
of coal, oil, and nuclear resources; increased electricity production
and investment in natural gas facilities due to environmental and sit-
ing factors as well as relatively low gas prices; increased penetration
of renewable resources as a result of state environmental policies; and an increase in demand resources and
distributed generation technologies. these changes have created challenges to power system operation and
planning and electricity market design. we will review the main features of existing wholesale electricity
markets and several key components. as pricing is particularly important for an effective market design,
we will discuss ongoing pricing issues. Finally, we will take a brief look at the evolution of the electric grid
and future challenges and then identify and discuss several key market design initiatives stemming from
these challenges.

By Eugene Litvinov, Feng Zhao, and Tongxin Zheng

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 33


coupled with the inefficiency of the uplift payment-based con-
Small gestion management model, led the wholesale electricity mar-
GenCo LSE Aggregator
Customer kets to gradually converge to a pool-based model similar to
those of PJm and nyiSo. today this model involves a set of
ISO Retail common features, including the two-settlement system [day-
TransCo
Wholesale DisCo Regulation/ ahead market (dam) and real-time market (rtm)], lmP, co-
Market Competition optimization of energy and ancillary services, zonal reserve
products, financial transmission rights, and a forward capac-
Large Large ity market (FCm).
Marketer
Customer Customer
the goal of wholesale electricity markets is to increase the
power system’s economic efficiency without compromising
FERC PUC
its reliability. therefore, market products traded in most u.S.
electricity markets are designed according to the needs of bulk
figure 1. The deregulated power industry in the United States. power system operation and planning. as a result, electricity
markets always interact with the physical power system plan-
ning, scheduling, and operation. Figure 3 presents markets with
Main Features of different time frames and their corresponding physical systems.
U.S. Wholesale Electricity Markets we will discuss the main market products and major features
wholesale electricity markets emerged in the united States associated with each of the markets in more detail.
in the late 1990s with different models. PJm and new york
iSo (nyiSo) started locational marginal pricing (lmP)- Energy
based energy markets with a two-settlement system in 1998 energy is the main product traded in u.S. electricity markets,
and 1999, respectively. California iSo (CaiSo) adopted a which typically include the dam and the rtm. although
day-ahead power exchange with the real-time energy market in market designs vary in different iSo regions, all have struc-
1998. iSo-ne opened its real-time energy market with a single tured the two markets in a two-settlement system with the for-
market clearing price and an uplift payment-based congestion ward dam and the spot rtm. all markets also have a similar
management model in 1999. after the California energy crisis objective of maximizing the total social surplus, and lmP is
in the early 2000s, the power exchange model was considered used to manage the transmission congestion.
to be prone to market power abuse and gradually abandoned electricity producers and consumers may be located at
in the united States. FerC’s standard market design efforts, different areas but are connected through the grid. delivering

ISO New
England
Midcontient ISO
NYISO

PJM Interconnection

Southwest
Power Pool
CAISO

Electric Reliability
Council of Texas

figure 2. The U.S. ISOs/RTOs (Online: https://www.ferc.gov/industries/electric/indus-act/rto.asp).

34 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


energy from a generator to a consumer at a different loca-
table 1. ISO-NE wholesale market benefits.
tion not only incurs energy losses but also may overload
the transmission lines. this, in turn, prevents low-cost Generation Increased from 75% in 1997 to
generation from being delivered to the customer, a phe- Availability 88% in 2016
nomenon often called congestion. lmP recognizes the Emissions reductions 29% lower carbon dioxide emissions
locational differences in energy production and consump- between 2001 and 73% lower nitrogen oxide emissions
2016 98% reduction in sulfur dioxide
tion and has been the main approach to pricing electric- emissions
ity and managing congestion in the transmission system. Wholesale energy 2016 average annual energy market
lmP reflects the cost of serving an increment of load at prices prices were lowest since 2003
a specific location in the transmission system. electric- Private investment More than US$8 billion
ity producers and consumers are paid or charged by the
New resources More than 15 GW of new generation
corresponding lmP at their locations. as a type of uni- since 1999 and about 2.7 GW of new
form pricing, lmP provides strong incentives for truth- demand
ful bidding in energy markets and long-term investment
signals for building new generators at the locations where
they are needed (indicated by higher lmPs), including Because iSo systems are connected by interties to facili-
the effect of marginal losses. mathematically, lmP can tate the power exchange among neighboring iSos, specific
be decomposed into energy, congestion, and loss com- locations are used for pricing of imports or exports of energy.
ponents, where the congestion component in the dam is Currently, most iSos assign a proxy bus for pricing energy
used to settle Ftrs. imports and exports. the selection of these proxy buses is
lmP calculations solve an economic dispatch (ed) prob- often arbitrary and may not conform to the actual power
lem. due to the nonconvex features such as unit commitment flow. as a result, the interchange schedule between iSos is
(uC) decisions that are not modeled in the ed, out-of-mar- often inefficient.
ket side payments to the generators are often used by iSos the dam is often considered a forward financial market
in addition to the uniform lmP-based market payment. the where participants submit bids to buy or offers to sell elec-
total payments then allow generators to recover their start-up tricity at each market location. the bids and offers can be
and no-load costs. the out-of-market payments distort the physical and associated with generating units or demands
market and are not transparent, therefore creating problems or virtual and not associated with any physical assets. Bids
in market participants’ risk hedging. reducing these out-of- and offers come in the form of price–quantity pairs in a
market payments has been a difficult problem that will be descending or increasing price order at any market location.
discussed in later sections. in addition, each physical asset submits its physical operating

Real-Time Operation Short-Term Planning Midterm Planning Long-Term Planning


System Monitoring and Alarming Outage Coordination Generator Maintenance Resource Adequacy
Automatic Generation Control Load Forecasting Scheduling Transmission Planning
Load and Wind Forecasting Reliability Assessment Transmission Outage Strategic Planning
Security Analysis Operations Planning Scheduling
Economic Dispatch
Emergency Operation
Look-Ahead Unit Commitment Physical System Operation and Planning
Transaction Scheduling
Intraday Reliability Assessment

Real-Time Day-Ahead Forward Reserve Market Forward


Market Energy Market FTR Market Capacity Market

Market Operation

figure 3. The markets and systems. FTR: financial transmission rights.

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 35


parameters, such as economic minimum and maximum, except that only physical units are considered and no market
ramp rate, start-up and no-load costs, and minimum up and clearing prices are produced. the ruC process may be run
down times. the market clears at the point where supply again throughout the operating day to look ahead a few hours
meets demand at a maximal social surplus subject to net- and determine possible needs for additional resources.
work security constraints. the market clearing problem is with the committed units from the dam and ruC, iSos
called the security-constrained UC (SCUC) problem. dam run the rtm, which determines the generation schedule and
results are financially binding, which leaves only the real- rtm clearing prices. market participants are allowed to sub-
time deviations from the day-ahead schedules to be exposed mit rtm bids that differ from their dam bids. iSos solve an
to the real-time price (two-settlement system). as a result, the SCed problem that minimizes the total dispatch cost subject
iSo’s dam design provides a way for market participants to to network and individual unit constraints. different iSos
hedge against rtm price volatility or arbitrage between the may model SCed differently. iSo-ne implements a sin-
two markets. gle-interval dispatch for its rtm, whereas nyiSo solves a
the dam closes at a particular time of the day prior to multi-interval dispatch problem. Special pricing rules for the
the delivery date. market participants submit their bids into the fast-start resources are often considered in the rtm to reflect
market before the closing time. once the market closes, the their deployment costs in addition to the incremental costs in
market administrator runs software solving a 24-h (or longer) the lmP calculation. these rules often differ among rtos
SCuC problem. the problem is typically a mixed integer lin- but share the similar principle of eliminating the nonconvex-
ear program (milP) because it involves both hourly binary ity of the resources by relaxing certain characteristics, such
on/off decisions for physical generating units and continuous as relaxing the minimum output level to be zero or amortiz-
unit output level decisions. dam clearing prices, or locational ing the commitment costs into the dispatch costs.
market prices, are determined from the constraint shadow energy trading in the iSo-managed wholesale markets
prices calculated by the ed process for each hour. often creates two financial positions for each market partici-
the rtm is a spot market where electricity is physically pant: dam and rtm (cleared transaction quantity). a two-
delivered to the consumers in a least-cost and reliable fash- settlement system is adopted to settle each financial position.
ion. it is closely coupled with the power system operations the dam settles on the dam position with dam lmPs, and
by including all of the system and security constraints into the rtm settles on the energy deviations from the cleared
the market clearing problem, i.e., security-constrained ed dam position with rtm lmPs. under such design, physi-
(SCed). different from the dam, the rtm usually does cal players, such as generators and loads, are able to hedge
not require demand bids due to loads’ lack of response to their risk by locking in the price of their transactions with
rtm prices. dam locational market prices. Financial players who place
in practice, after the dam is cleared and prior to the virtual transactions in the dam without delivering in rtm
operating day, iSos often run a 24-h or longer reliability can arbitrage the price difference between dam and rtm
uC (ruC) process committing additional units that have not for their cleared dam quantity. the two-settlement system
been selected in the dam to meet the forecasted load (which has worked well in u.S. electricity markets, closing the gap
may exceed the dam cleared as-bid load). the reliability between dam and rtm prices.
commitment problem is similar to the dam uC problem, although lmP reflects the marginal cost of producing
an increment of energy, it does not capture the entire cost
of generation, such as the start-up cost of an online unit. as
(US$/MWh) a result, the generation as-bid cost of a resource may not be
fully recovered by the lmP payment. an illustration of cost
rve
Cu and payment is shown in Figure 4, where the as-bid cost is
er
n Off represented by the area under the generation offer curve
r atio
G ene B (i.e., areas a and B) and the lmP payment received by the
LMP generator is lmP multiplied by the generation output (i.e.,
C
areas a and C). when the cost exceeds the payment (i.e.,
A A + B 2 A + C), the generator has a revenue shortage of
B-C. Compensation for such revenue shortage, often termed
(MW) a make-whole payment or an uplift payment, is needed and
Generator Output has been widely used in existing iSo markets to incentivize
Generator Cost = A + B generators to follow iSo dispatch instructions.
LMP Payment = A + C uplift payments are caused by the nonconvexity of the bids,
Uplift Payment = B – C e.g., the integer commitment costs and the presence of mini-
Uplift = max {0, Cost-Payment} mum generation level. they are unit specific as opposed to the
uniform market clearing price lmP and are often opaque to
figure 4. An illustration of uplift payment. the market participants as being very difficult to hedge. iSos

36 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


have been striving to reduce such out-of-market payments, but, i.e., Ftr underfunding. to remedy the problem, iSos often
due to generators’ nonconvex physical characteristics, they are auction a reduced transmission capacity in the Ftr auctions.
unlikely to be eliminated. an alternative approach is to force
one-part bidding and thereby eliminate the physical param- Forward Capacity Product
eters that cause nonconvexity in their bids. this effectively generation investment is a key step to secure the long-term
removes the uplift payment at the cost of increased risk for supply of electricity to meet demand growth in the future.
participants that have to embed the nonconvexity-related costs in some regions, responsibility for resource adequacy has
into their convex bids, and it presents increased difficulty for remained with vertically integrated utilities. in other regions,
market power monitoring. Currently, all u.S. markets have such as iSo-ne and PJm, where utilities divested their gen-
adopted the three-part bidding (i.e., incremental cost, start- eration assets, resource adequacy is generally met through the
up, and no-load cost) and uplift payments approach instead of wholesale markets. due to the presence of price caps in the
the convex bidding seen in some other countries. energy markets and the manual actions of system operators
that may depress the energy price, revenues from the energy
Ancillary Services market alone may not be sufficient to cover a unit’s capital
in addition to meeting the system load, power system operators investment cost. this phenomenon is termed the missing
have to prepare for generation contingencies and load fluctua- money problem. Facing the revenue shortage risk, generating
tions in real time. these additional reliability needs can be units may not be available when needed, potentially causing
satisfied by ancillary service products besides energy, e.g., reg- a shortage of capacity and, therefore, reliability issues. one
ulation, reserves, and ramping. resources with these additional solution to the problem that has been implemented in iSo-
capabilities are compensated through the ancillary service ne is the FCm, where units’ generating capacity is obtained
markets. ancillary service products could be quite different in advance and compensated through the capacity product
among iSos because the iSo systems may have different reli- and the corresponding market clearing price. an important
ability needs. Consequently, the ancillary service markets are enhancement to the FCm, the pay-for-performance mecha-
diverse. CaiSo, e.g., considers a 5-min ramping product, mid- nism, reduces revenues for resources that do not perform and
continent iSo projects a 10-min ramping product, and iSo-ne rewards resources that perform during critical system events.
does not currently have a ramping product. with the increasing the FCm provides a steady revenue stream in advance for
penetration of renewables, new system features arise and may existing resources to recover the missing money and for new
create a need for new ancillary services. resources to reduce the investment risk.
Because energy and ancillary services share the capacity as a forward market, FCm auctions run several years
of generation units and transmission network, they are often to several weeks ahead prior to the real-time operation of the
co-optimized to achieve the most efficient capacity alloca- capacity commitment period, depending on different market
tion of resources, leading to an SCed optimization problem designs. Qualified resources, existing or new, are required to
that simultaneously determines the energy and ancillary ser- submit their capacity offers to the iSo, which, in turn, clears the
vices designations for resources. Similar to energy lmPs, FCm auction amounts and determines the clearing price. local
the clearing prices for ancillary services are obtained from capacity zones may be modeled in the FCm to reflect local reli-
the dual variables of the SCed problem. ability needs. Capacity requirements are administratively set
by the iSo through reliability simulations that are similar to
Financial Transmission Rights other loss of load expectation resource adequacy studies.
an Ftr is a financial instrument for hedging against trans- with fixed capacity requirements, the FCm auction clear-
mission congestion; it has a source and a sink location as well ing prices may be volatile, i.e., the market clearing price
as a megawatt quantity and entitles its holder to collect con- tends to substantially increase when there is any capacity
gestion revenue based on the difference of lmP congestion shortage from the fixed requirement and plummet when there
components between the sink and source locations. Ftrs is a capacity surplus. Such price volatility increases the risk
have been implemented in all u.S. iSos. existing Ftrs for capacity investment and load payment and impedes the
are point-to-point annual or multiyear products and can be formation of adequate price signals for long-term investment.
obtained through corresponding Ftr auctions or allocated to Furthermore, such a market may be prone to market power.
market participants based on grandfathered rights. to remedy this issue, iSo-ne has replaced the fixed require-
iSos sell the Ftrs and collect the auction revenue in the ments with demand curves based on the tradeoff between
annual Ftr auction. depending on the region, the Ftr auction reliability and cost of capacity.
revenue is allocated to the lSes, transmission owners, or other
entities in accordance with the market rules. Ftrs are usually Interchange Scheduling
settled on the dam prices. due to the discrepancy between and Market Coordination
the transmission model used in the Ftr and the model used the evolution of the power grid has led to today’s large inter-
in the dam, the congestion revenue in the dam and rtm connected power systems, each operated by an iSo. an iSo
may not cover 100% of the entitled payments to Ftr holders, has complete information of its own control area but may not

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 37


have information from other iSos, such as network model, uC, ed, security analysis, and pricing. the uC determines
generation offers, and system condition. Furthermore, iSos the integer on/off decisions for generation units. the preced-
may run electricity markets with different designs. as a ing components can be combined to solve different problems.
result, the dispatch solutions of individual areas may not be the security analysis, e.g., is iterated with ed until there
optimal for the entire interconnected system, i.e., economic are no security violations. the components can be organized
efficiency could be impaired. Such a problem caused by the in different ways depending on the market requirements. Fig-
heterogeneous market designs and insufficient information ure 6 shows an implementation of the SCuC with these compo-
sharing is termed the seams issue. to achieve higher eco- nents. notice that the architecture has two loops. the inner
nomic efficiency, coordination among neighboring iSos is loop is often termed SCED. the individual components are
needed. the purpose of such coordination is to drive each explained as follows.
iSo’s area dispatch solution toward the optimal solution of
the entire region’s dispatch problem. UC
the coordination between two markets can be performed the uC component is an optimization problem that determines
through interchange transaction scheduling and generation each unit’s on/off status for each time interval by respect-
redispatch. there are two market-based interchange schedul- ing the unit-level constraints, such as minimum up/down
ing approaches. one is scheduled by market participants by time, ramping limit, and system constraints, such as energy
submitting bids to buy from one market and offers to sell to balance and security. typically, the dam involves a 24-h or
another market. Both buy bids and sell offers must be cleared longer uC module for hourly on or off decisions. the uC prob-
in both markets to schedule the physical interchange flow. lem is generally hard to solve because its integer solution space
this scheduling process is generally conducted on an hourly grows exponentially as the number of generation units increases.
basis. another is the coordinated transaction scheduling (CtS) the most commonly used solution techniques for the uC are
implemented by iSo-ne, PJm, and nyiSo. in this approach, lagrange relaxation and milP. enabled by the increasing com-
market participants submit CtS bids that represent their will- puting power in recent years, the milP solution that allows
ingness to buy or sell energy based on the price difference more modeling flexibility has become a dominant approach to
between two markets. the CtS market commonly runs on uC. the milP performance can be much affected by the prob-
15-min intervals to increase the scheduling efficiency. in addi- lem formulation. therefore, an efficient milP formulation is
tion to interchange scheduling, a market-to-market coordina- very important. Studies on tightening uC formulations can be
tion scheme is also available for coordinated congestion man- found in the literature. however, it is generally considered that
agement. under this scheme, two markets exchange the cost of there is no universally good formulation for all uC problems
redispatch in their markets and relieve the congestion through due to the various factors that affect the path of a milP solver.
dispatching more efficient generation.
ED
Market Management System Components the ed component is an optimization problem that deter-
the market management system (mmS) components are mines each unit’s generation output, subject to unit and system
central to the operation of wholesale electricity markets in constraints. the objective of the optimization problem is to
iSo control centers. the aforementioned market features minimize the total dispatch cost based on units’ submitted cost
are all implemented in this system. different from financial curves. the uC statuses determined by the uC problem are
market operation, electricity market operation, especially fixed, so there are generally no integer decisions for the ed
real time, requires constant interaction with the underlying component. depending on the offer curve characteristics, the
physical power system, making the mmS an essential part of ed problem can be formulated as a linear or quadratic program.
system control. a typical mmS is shown in Figure 5, where it
interacts with the physical control system, such as the energy Security Analysis
management system (emS), and the financial settlement the security analysis component examines the dispatch solution
system. the physical system provides essential operating against n-1 contingencies. For each contingency, a power flow
parameters, such as load forecast, system topology, and trans- problem is solved to check and identify any network constraint
fer limits to mmS, which determines generation schedules violations. the violated constraints are linearized and fed back
(a type of control signal) for the emS and market clearing to the next iteration of the ed problem, forming the inner loop
prices for the financial settlement system. mmS is complex of SCed. if the SCed cannot resolve all security constraint vio-
but made up of several basic building blocks, e.g., uC, ed, lations, then the remaining violated constraints are fed into the
security analysis, and pricing. next iteration of uC until all violations are resolved, forming the
SCuC problem.
Architecture Security analysis could be time-consuming due to the
typical electricity market systems produce generation sched- large number of contingencies. Because the simulation of
ules and clearing prices by solving an optimization problem. different contingencies is independent, parallel computing
the common components in the optimization problem are techniques are often adopted.

38 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


Pricing and Settlement as well as emS to calculate uplift payments and so-called set-
whereas all of the preceding components are intended to tlement positions for each market product and time frame.
obtain a secure commitment and dispatch solution for all
units, the clearing price is critical for a good market design Electricity Pricing Challenges
because it acts as the signal to the market participants. if prop- Pricing is a critical part of a market because proper market
erly priced, a unit will have no incentive to deviate from the prices provide the right signals to market participants for
iSo’s schedule, which is a desired market design property that achieving an efficient market outcome. Pricing in electric-
allows market participants to bid truthfully. as we will discuss ity markets could be complex in the presence of transmis-
next, pricing could be particularly challenging in the presence sion congestion and losses. Furthermore, nonconvexity in a
of market nonconvexity or multiple-interval dispatch. market is known to cause problems for conventional linear
with the market clearing prices, settlement is defined by a prices. unfortunately, nonconvexities are abundant in elec-
set of market rules of who pays or gets paid and by how much. tricity markets as a result of physical unit characteristics.
the settlement component collects information from the mmS Pricing with nonconvexity has therefore become one of the

System Planning
Market Operation Financial Settlement
and Operation

Day-Ahead Scheduling DAM Energy Trading Two-Settlement System

Mitigated
Outage Operations
Offer, Unit Energy
Coordination Planning
Topology, Schedule Awards
Limits LMP
DAM Energy
Load Market UC ED SFT and Uplift
Forecasting Mitigation
Awarded
Reserve
Security UC Schedule
Transmission Reservation RMR
Transaction Constraints
FTR Payment

CRF
Real-Time RTM Energy
Operation Trading
EMS System
Cost Allocation

Conditions
SCADA
Load and RUC
Renewable RTM Energy
State Estimation
and Uplift
UC
Market
Contingency Short-Term Schedule
Clearing
Analysis Outage
RTUC
Short-Term RTM Ancillary
Load Limit Service
Calculation Fast Start Payment
UC Schedule
System
Monitoring Tie-Line
Scheduling
Constraint RTM
Performance
Management AS&
AGC Units Payment
Capacity Tie-Line
AGC Analysis Schedule
Unit Dispatch

figure 5. The MMS architecture. RTUC: real-time UC; AGC: automatic generation control; SCADA: supervisory control
and data acquisition; CRF: congestion revenue fund; RMR: reliability must run units; SFT: simultaneous feasibility test.

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 39


Pricing could be particularly challenging in
the presence of market nonconvexity or
multiple-interval dispatch.

central topics in electricity markets. a less discussed pric- mitment decisions. as a result of the fundamental mathematical
ing problem, but attracting more interest recently due to the properties of nonconvex problems, there’s no such set of per-
emerging ramping needs in several iSos, is the appropri- fectly consistent prices for the uC problem. Consequently, for
ate pricing and settlement design with multiple scheduling any given market clearing prices, some units may have incen-
intervals. this problem is further complicated by the practi- tives to deviate from their optimal schedule. recognizing this
cal implementation of multi-interval scheduling with rolling nonexistence of perfect prices, in reality, markets are designed
horizons. we will discuss the solution of a multisettlement to pursue a second-best set of prices with certain criteria.
system as an extension to the existing two-settlement system. most of the existing markets use the uplift payment as the
additional compensation alongside the market clearing prices
Nonconvexity for units to follow the iSo’s optimal commitment and dispatch
wholesale electricity prices, or lmPs, are typically produced instructions. the total uplift payments are then allocated to
from the shadow prices of the SCed problem. Because the demands in the market. different markets may have differ-
SCed problem is often convex, i.e., being a linear program or ent uplift calculation and allocation rules. most iSos pay the
a quadratic objective function with linear constraints, the con- make-whole payment for online units to cover the revenue
straint shadow prices exist and can be conveniently used to cal- shortage, although some iSos (e.g., iSo-ne) also pay the so-
culate market clearing prices. these prices are consistent with called lost opportunity cost (loC) for certain situations even
the optimal dispatch solutions in the sense that, given the prices, when the unit has no revenue shortage. nevertheless, the uplift
each unit will not have financial incentives to deviate from the payments cannot be efficiently allocated through a market
dispatch results. in reality, however, a unit’s decisions are also mechanism and are often considered nontransparent. many
based on the commitment costs in addition to the incremental iSos have explored ways to reduce the uplift payments by
costs. the clearing prices from the convex dispatch problem adopting alternative market clearing prices in place of exist-
reflect the marginal cost of dispatch but do not capture commit- ing lmPs. one approach, termed convex-hull pricing, uses the
ment costs and thus may not be consistent with the unit’s com- dual variable solutions of the nonconvex uC problem to arrive
at the minimal level of total uplift
and loC (although the uplift pay-
ment may actually increase). other
SCUC
approaches typically relax the non-
Supply Offers UC convex features of the problem, such
Demand Bids as removing the minimal genera-
tion output parameter or allowing
Commitment
Schedules
Constraints

partial commitments of units for


Unit
Schedules LMPs obtaining a price that at least relates
Publishing to the commitment costs. a variety
Binding
Constraints of different relaxations have been
implemented by the iSos; how-
Outage ED ever, in theory, there is no perfect
Scheduler price that can eliminate the need for
Unit Schedules
Constraints

uplift payments due to the presence


Schedules

SCED

External
Transaction Schedules of the duality gap for nonconvex
problems. the practical question
Constraints remains: what are the objectives and
Security desired properties of the pricing?
Analysis different iSos may have different
External answers. the decision on the trad-
Transactions eoff between the level of noncon-
vexity and appropriate set of prices
figure 6. The SCUC architecture. is central to a good market design.

40 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


The power industry is facing yet another
revolutionary change.

Pricing Multi-Interval Solutions they went from a decentralized, loosely coupled grid to
given that uC and dispatch decisions are temporally coupled large, highly interconnected, and centrally controlled sys-
through ramp limits and minimum up/down time constraints, tems. the sheer size, large number of components, and pro-
the market clearing prices for different time intervals are liferation of power electronics have made the electric grid a
naturally related. although the multi-interval dispatch problem complex cyberphysical system.
can be convex, and the prices for each interval conveniently Currently, the power industry is facing yet another revo-
produced out of the dual variables, the challenge of pricing lutionary change. government directives to lower the carbon
with multiple intervals lies in its real-time applications that footprint and, as a consequence, high penetration of renewable
run on the rolling horizon. nyiSo and CaiSo, for exam- energy resources and smart grid technologies are transform-
ple, solve a multi-interval dispatch problem but only use the ing power system planning and operational paradigms. dis-
first interval prices for settlement; prices for other intervals tributed energy resources (ders) are being built deeply into
are only advisory and will be determined when the interval the distribution networks, and the boundary between transmis-
becomes first in later runs. with the rolling horizon, each sion and distribution is blurring. a significant part of ders is
multi-interval dispatch run includes new time intervals that unobservable to the transmission system operators, introduc-
are not modeled in the previous intervals. as a result, the ing an unprecedented level of uncertainty not only spatially
prices produced from different runs for the same interval but also temporally due to the intermittent nature of renewable
could be different. the iSo’s settlement typically uses the resources. even the concept of contingency is changing from
prices from the latest run where the interval being priced being binary (e.g., on and off events) to continuous, e.g., the
is the first. these prices for different intervals are from system load or generation can swing by several gigawatts in a
different runs, and so they may not be consistent with the comparatively short period of time. this behavior, previously
dispatch solutions for different intervals. this may cause the considered as abnormal or emergency, becomes part of normal
incentive compatibility problem, i.e., deviation from the iSo operation. as a result, system operators will be challenged to
instructions, as the units chase the settlement prices. deal with completely different patterns in the new grid archi-
a natural way to remedy this problem is to make all tecture, such as the one shown in Figure 7. another property
prices from different runs financially binding, i.e., one inter- of large cyberphysical systems is high interdependence with
val would be settled multiple times instead of just for the different infrastructures. not only do we have to monitor the
last time. this effectively requires a multisettlement design electric grid contingencies but also the failures in communica-
where multiple levels of markets in addition to the existing tion, information technology, and fuel delivery systems. today’s
dam and rtm are involved. iSo-ne is developing a new preventive approach to power systems planning and operation,
approach to appropriately price ramping constraints.

New Market Initiatives µGrid µGrid µGrid


the existing market designs are shaped by the historical,
physical, and regulatory features of the system as manifested
by the difference in the designs of different iSo markets.
Currently, the power industry is undergoing a major transfor-
mation toward a system with a lower carbon footprint, more Transmission Backbone
decentralized controls, and an increasingly flexible load.
these changes bring fundamental challenges to power sys-
tem operations, planning, and market design. in the follow-
ing, we highlight the new challenges associated with the new
electric grid, wrapping up with a discussion on future market
design to accommodate the challenges. Virtual Power Demand PHEV
Plants Aggregators Aggregators
A New Electric Grid
modern power systems went through different stages of evo- figure 7. A new power grid. PHEV: plug-in hybrid electric
lution driven by technical, economic, and regulatory events. vehicle.

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 41


i.e., every contingency is treated with equal probability and no reserve market. iSo-ne has recently developed system and
contingency is allowed to cause violation of the n-1 reliabil- zonal capacity demand curves for its FCm based on tradeoffs
ity criteria, becomes economically prohibitive in the new between the costs of reliability and capacity. the development
grid era. more corrective actions must be introduced to make of these demand curves based on different reliability needs is
power system planning and operation less expensive. this all a promising direction of the new market design.
requires a significantly different control paradigm, new mod- the electric industry is moving into a new era with new car-
els, and new algorithms. in response, the market design needs bon emission limits, new resilience needs, and the zero mar-
to be changed as well to accommodate these new changes in ginal cost economy where the incremental cost of producing a
physical systems. good approaches zero. all of these new features bring signifi-
cant challenges for electricity pricing. with the carbon limits
Future Market Design and resilience needs, prices for these features need to be defined
although the changes in the electric grid impose significant for the market. the existing marginal cost pricing may lead to
challenges to power system operation, planning, and control, zero or negative market clearing prices, when more and more
adapting existing electricity market designs and developing renewable resources with zero marginal costs and state/federal
new design solutions to address these challenges is an even subsidies participate in the market. therefore, the marginal
more daunting task, given the relatively short history of elec- pricing principle may need to be augmented with some new
tricity markets. in this section, we discuss several key market constructs, including new scarcity pricing rules.
design problems that are likely to occur in the near future and
suggest possible solutions. Acknowledgment
the unprecedented level of uncertainty due to the high the views expressed in this article do not represent those of
penetration of renewable resources and ders requires more iSo new england, inc.
flexibility to deal with uncertainty. this leads to the need
for a new flexibility market mechanism to create incentives For Further Reading
for investment in flexible technologies. Some iSos, such as e. litvinov, t. Zheng, g. rosenwald, and P. Shamsollahi,
CaiSo, have introduced a 5-min ramping product to accom- “marginal loss modeling in lmP calculation,” IEEE Trans.
modate the steep change of the net load curve due to significant Power Syst., vol. 19, no. 2, pp. 880–888, 2004.
swings in photovoltaic production. the design of such a new e. litvinov, “design and operation of the locational mar-
product should consider its interaction with existing products, ginal prices-based electricity markets,” IET Generation,
such as reserves. it is important that the new products provide Transmission, Distribution, vol. 4, no. 2, pp. 315–323, 2010.
unique and different services from the existing products so as F. Zhao, t. Zheng, and e. litvinov, “Constructing demand
to attract targeted flexible resources. curves in forward capacity market,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst.,
an alternative way of addressing these uncertainty challenges vol. 33, no. 1, pp. 525–535, 2017.
is to manage them through more sophisticated commitment and F. Zhao, e. litvinov, and t. Zheng, “a marginal equiva-
dispatch processes. instead of the existing deterministic com- lent decomposition method and its application to multi-area
mitment and dispatch problems currently solved by the iSos, optimal power flow problems,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst.,
stochastic programming or robust optimization that explicitly vol. 29, no. 1, pp. 53–61, 2014.
models the uncertainty within their formulation through scenario d. Schiro. (2017). Flexibility procurement and reimbursement:
tree and uncertainty set seem to be promising. however, a bigger a multi-period pricing approach. iSo new england. [online].
issue is how to appropriately price the market clearing decision available: https://www.ferc.gov/CalendarFiles/20170623123635-
and compensate the selected resources based on multiple possible Schiro_FerC2017_Final.pdf
realizations of uncertain parameters. From the market design w. w. hogan. (2013). electricity scarcity pricing through op-
perspective, transparent compensation schemes, proper informa- erating reserves. harvard univ. Cambridge, ma. [online]. avail-
tion policy, and incentive compatibility issues should be resolved able: https://sites.hks.harvard.edu/fs/whogan/#working papers
before we adopt these advanced risk management techniques. r. li, Q. wu, and S. S. oren, “distribution locational mar-
direct demand participation (where demand bids are sub- ginal pricing for optimal electric vehicle charging management,”
mitted to the market) in the rtms can bring significant ben- IEEE Trans. Power Syst., vol. 29, no. 1, pp. 203–211, 2014.
efits to system operation. it enhances system reliability and
also improves the price formation in the electricity market. Biographies
however, an increasing level of indirect demand participation Eugene Litvinov is with iSo new england, holyoke, mas-
(demand responds to the price on its own) can create chal- sachusetts.
lenges in load forecasting, system control, and, thus, real-time Feng Zhao is with iSo new england, holyoke, massa-
pricing. to overcome these issues, more and more iSos start chusetts.
incorporating iSo-developed demand curves into the market. Tongxin Zheng is with iSo new england, holyoke,
the electric reliability Council of texas, for example, has massachusetts.
p&e
applied the operating reserve demand curve to its real-time

42 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


The New Zealand
Electricity Market

T
Trading in The new Zealand wholesale difference from other jurisdictions, and speculates on some
electricity market (nZeM) pool began on 1 october 1996. The possible future directions.
new Zealand pool market was the first one to use two ele­ new Zealand is subject to the vagaries of a south Pacific
ments of what has since become the north american standard climate, is geographically prevented from importing or ex­
market design, with locational marginal pricing and ancillary porting power, and has a high penetration of renewable
service cooptimization, but it was implemented in a physical electricity. Key considerations include promoting the most
and regulatory environment that differs markedly from that in economical use of stored water and ensuring security of sup­
north america. This article reflects on 20 years of experience ply. Unlike most north american markets, the new Zealand
with new Zealand’s 1996 market design, assesses its points of design currently does not include any form of capacity market

By Andy Philpott, Grant Read,


Stephen Batstone, and Allan Miller

Challenges of a
Renewable Energy System

Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/MPE.2018.2871705


©istockphoto.com/NZsteve
Date of publication: 7 January 2019

january/february 2019 1540-7977/19©2019IEEE ieee power & energy magazine 43


or payment or day­ahead market, and, at least initially, the associated new canals, roads, and towns, despite gradually
market did not provide any financial transmission rights and increasing environmental opposition. new Zealand pioneered
was not overseen by any sector­specific regulator. the development of large­scale geothermal generation during
the 1960s. The backbone of the national transmission system
Historical and Physical was built in the same period, with new Zealand pioneering
Context of the NZEM the use of long­distance underwater high­voltage dc transmis­
geographically, new Zealand is comparable in size and shape sion to link the two islands in 1965.
to the islands of Britain and ireland or Japan. But it is much less Until the construction of a small coal­fired firming sta­
densely populated and too remote to allow interconnection tion in 1958, almost all of the developments were hydro. Culy
with any other country. Moreover, it is uneconomical to build et al. question whether this was actually the most economi­
facilities to import relatively small volumes of liquefied natural cal strategy, but it reflected a philosophical commitment to
gas just for occasional electricity generation in years with low exploiting free renewable resources to further national devel­
hydro inflows. Thus, new Zealand must be self­sufficient in opment in ways that were seen to be environmentally benign,
electricity, gas, and generally also coal, with occasional recent if not beneficial, at the time. in the late 1960s and 1970s, the
imports of the latter. The layout of the country’s transmission direction of development changed, as public attention focused
grid is shown in Figure 1, and the evolution of its generation more on the negative environmental impacts of hydro devel­
mix is shown in Figure 2. opment, and new discoveries made gas­fired electricity gen­
Culy et al. (1996) describe the history of electricity in new eration economical. new coal­ and oil­fired stations were
Zealand, starting with developments by private companies in also built to cope with wet/dry­year output variations in an
the 1880s. From the early 20th century, however, all signifi­ isolated hydro system where reservoirs large enough to store
cant power stations were government built and owned. From water from year to year were (and still are) considered to be
1945 to 1978, electricity was supplied to local distribution environmentally unacceptable.
authorities by a government department, which was able to in 1979, the electricity department was integrated into a
develop the system in ways the private sector probably could Ministry of energy, which controlled demand­side manage­
not have. large­scale hydro schemes were developed, with ment programs and the planning, production, and pricing of not

50,000 1
45,000 0.9
North Island
1,700 MW Hydro 40,000 0.8
1,000 MW Geothermal 35,000 0.7
600 MW Wind
1,700 MW Gas and Coal 30,000 0.6
(GWh)

48 MW Solar 25,000 0.5


4,400 MW Maximum Demand
20,000 0.4
15,000 0.3
10,000 0.2
1,240-MW
High-Voltage dc Link 5,000 0.1
South Island 0 0
1975
1977
1979
1981
1983
1985
1989
1991
1993
1995
1997
1999
2001
2003
2005
2007
2011
2013
2015
2017

3,500 MW Hydro
60 MW Wind
14 MW Solar
2,200 MW Maximum Demand Gas (12.8%/15.3%) Coal (2.3%/2.6%)
Oil (0%/0%) Other Renewable (1.4%/1.4%)
Solar (0.1%/0.2%) Geothermal (17.5%/17.3%)
Major Generation Center Wind (5.4%/5.1%) Hydro (60.4%/58%)
Major Load Center
% Renewable (84.8%/82%)
High-Voltage ac Lines
High-Voltage dc Lines
figure 2. The generation by type in New Zealand, with re-
newable generation. In the legend, the numbers listed beside
figure 1. A map of New Zealand showing the main genera- each generation type give the proportion of generation in
tors, largest lines in the transmission network, and maximum 2016/proportion of generation in 2017. Hydro was reduced
loads over the year ended 31 December 2017. Over this in 2017 because of low inflows up to July 2017. (Data from
period, the North Island grid consumption was 24,735 GWh New Zealand Energy Quarterly, Ministry of Business, Innova-
and the South Island grid consumption 14,557 GWh. tion, and Employment, June 2017 quarter, 5 October 2017.)

44 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


only electricity at the wholesale level but also of fuels supply­ still acted as the primary retailers in each local network but
ing and competing with electricity. The goal was to facilitate a were required to accommodate competitive entry. Full retail
more consistent and economical approach, and significant prog­ competition, including the forced separation of distribution
ress was made in trimming back the most extreme development and retail, followed in 1999, at which point the remainder
proposals, rebalancing hydro and thermal investment, using con­ of eCnZ’s assets were formed into three separate compa­
sistent shadow pricing of thermal fuels across sectoral develop­ nies, with all still under government ownership, but partially
ment plans, and optimizing the reservoir management strategy. privatized in 2012. From that point on these four major enter­
oil­fired stations were built and then mothballed while work prises, along with a fifth controlling a collection of smaller
continued on increasingly expensive and controversial hydro hydro plants, have accounted for most of the market.
developments. The government of the day also preferred to boost
demand by pursuing a controversial “Think Big” program pro­ Market Developments and Features
posing discounted sales to new smelters, rather than scaling back The new Zealand market pioneered the implementation of
development to match lower demand growth. nodal pricing concepts developed in north america, moti­
end­user pricing remained inconsistent throughout that vated by the fact that, in a relatively long and sparsely devel­
period of government control. Prices to the public were held oped transmission system, even marginal losses can create
artificially low, while even lower prices were occasionally significant marginal cost variations across the network. The
offered to a few major industries to boost national develop­ details of the pricing and dispatch system are described by
ment. But prices for most commercial and industrial users were alvey et al. (1998).
much higher. as long as the system remained 100% renewable, The new Zealand dispatch model included the novel con­
the bulk supply tariff (BsT) charged to distribution authorities cept of ancillary service cooptimization, which was seen to
was based solely on peak load, reflecting the economics of a be important because, in this small system, even the loss of
system most often constrained by transmission capacity limits. a 250­Mw unit requires significant contingency response, in
as thermal power became more important, an equal weighting the 6­ to 60­s time frame. This ancillary service requirement
was introduced on energy and peak demand, but no attempt is also a major driver of locational price differences because
was made to reflect the wide variation in marginal costs from interisland transfers are often more limited by the need to
year to year due to hydrological variations or even changing provide reserve support against link failure than they are by
economic conditions. power flow congestion. at times, there has been more capacity
starting in 1984, though, a new government instituted sweep­ on contingency reserve duty in the receiving island than has
ing reforms, liberalizing all aspects of the economy and corpora­ been actually generated there. Thus, much of the congestion
tizing most productive activities previously undertaken by govern­ rent produced by locational price differences is actually due to
ment departments. The electricity Corporation of new Zealand these constraints and also to losses rather than to line capacity
(eCnZ) was formed and was expected to act in a normal com­ limits, as may be typical elsewhere. Therefore, the market set­
mercial manner, with a view to privatization, if possible. tlement surplus is partly needed to pay actual loss and ancil­
The BsT was replaced by a new regime under which all lary service costs, and the remaining risk profile differs from
wholesale electricity was bought and sold using hedge con­ that assumed in classical financial transmission right (FTr)
tracts written against a half­hourly pseudospot price calcu­ theory. This partly explains why U.s.­style congestion­based
lated a week in advance using eCnZ’s operational optimi­ FTrs, which had originally been part of the market design
zation model. internal generation groups were formed and concept, were only recently introduced into the new Zealand
given incentives to improve efficiency, and experiments were market. But the unavailability of such rights encouraged each
conducted with a form of internal market coordination. generator to seek customers close to its generation base and
The transmission system was also separated out into a sep­ then to see little need for FTr support.
arate government­owned corporation (Transpower), which
was intended to recover its costs under a pricing regime com­ Regulation
bining nodal spot pricing and what was called beneficiary given its long history of direct government control over
pays funding of new projects, with costs already sunk at the electrical infrastructure, new Zealand had no institutional
establishment date being allocated using a flow­tracing algo­ history of sectoral regulation similar to that in, e.g., the
rithm. This controversial regime was not implemented as United states. initially, the market was implemented with­
planned, and transmission pricing remains contentious. out any sectoral regulator at all. This was a deliberate deci­
The institutional arrangements just described were all sion, partly motivated by a perhaps excessively pure economic
intended to lay the foundations for development of an elec­ view that the electricity sector should not be treated differ­
tricity market, the design of which was debated at great ently from others and partly by a more pragmatic assessment
length in the early 1990s, with eventual implementation in of the overheads involved in maintaining a full­blown regu­
1996. at that time, a collection of eCnZ assets was formed latory function for a relatively small sector. This approach
into a new company and privatized, competing with the rest has since been abandoned, with the formation of the electricity
of the eCnZ as a duopoly at the wholesale level. distributors Commission in 2003 and then the 2010 establishment of the

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 45


electricity authority (ea), which performs the role of an The regulatory oversight of hydro­dominated systems is
independent market regulator. also more challenging than for purely thermal markets. in
regulatory market oversight of the new Zealand whole­ systems dominated by hydro, electricity prices reflect the
sale market by the ea is relatively loose by international marginal value that agents place on stored water, a number
standards. Pricing above short­run marginal cost is widely that depends on their prediction of future inflows and assess­
regarded in the electricity industry as a tolerated mecha­ ment of shortage risks that could be caused by dry winters,
nism for recovering the long­run marginal costs of gen­ outages, and the limitations of small, isolated fuel networks
eration. This view is not inconsistent with the doctrine of with little flexibility to trade or adjust supply. when a poten­
workable competition espoused by the ea, in which the tial water shortage looms, price increases are typically a
electricity sector is expected to behave like a normal mar­ risk­averse, opportunity­cost response to a perceived risk of
ket as much as possible and competition is encouraged by future energy limitations and interactions in an almost com­
focusing on low barriers to entry, so that market power is pletely closed system, rather than to clear capacity limits in
curbed by potential new entrants rather than explicit market the electricity sector. Therefore, perfectly competitive out­
oversight. with no formal price cap and capacity market, comes become difficult to determine with any certainty, let
the new Zealand system relies on prices (either spot prices alone to regulate. The ea has constructed a historical market
or those of derivatives) rising enough from scarce situations database and is developing an understanding of the effects of
to yield the required rents to cover long­run costs. uncertainty on wholesale prices.

Shortage Risk
although new Zealand’s electricity system is dominated by
4,500 renewable energy, storage­based hydro can easily accom­
4,000 modate short­term variations in demand and wind. But it
3,500
remains susceptible to periods of sustained low inflows, so
the challenges for system operation are more about varia­
3,000
tions in fuel over seasons rather than minutes and hours, as is
2,500
(GWh)

the case for most other countries with high­renewable ambi­


2,000
tions. This fuel risk is compounded by the fact that inflows
1,500 tend to be at their lowest during midwinter, when national
1,000 demand is highest.
500 There are no mandatory contractual arrangements for
0 hedging the risk of shortage. as originally conceived in 1992,
the new Zealand market was to have included a firm energy
y

ch

ay

ly

y
be

be
ar

ar
Ju
ar

M
nu

nu
em

em

mechanism similar to that subsequently implemented in


M
Ja

Ja
pt

ov
Se

Colombia, under which retailers would have been required to


N

(a) hold call options with a strike price set around the marginal
600 operating cost of an open­cycle gas turbine (oCgT) unit. Thus,
while the market price was to have been uncapped, consum­
500
ers would effectively have been protected against exposure to
400 price spikes above the oCgT level. The scheme was rejected,
NZ$/MWh

though, partly because it proved difficult to define exactly


300 what capacity measure should be used in each region. also,
200 there was a capacity surplus at the market start, and consumers
would have been paying a kind of insurance premium account­
100 ing for a substantial proportion of the market value.
That leaves new Zealand with no market price cap, with
0
participants potentially exposed to prolonged periods of very
y

ch

ay

ly

high prices under dry­year conditions that might be expected


be

be
ar

ar
Ju
ar

M
nu

nu
em

em
M

approximately once every 20 years. in theory, participants in


Ja

Ja
pt

ov
Se

(b) the wholesale market should expect to encounter high prices


when energy shortages loom. one can see this behavior in
Controlled Storage recent years in Figure 3(a) and (b), where the national reservoir
2017 2016 2015 2014 2013 storage and generation­weighted electricity price are plotted.
The risks of energy shortage are monitored by Transpower
figure 3. (a) The historical controlled reservoir storage in New in its role as the system operator. The shortage risks are rep­
Zealand and (b) the generation-weighted electricity price. resented by the curves in Figure 4, which displays the actual

46 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


storage trajectory and a set of storage levels that indicate delivered in a balancing market on the day of operation. This
increasing levels of risk at that time of year. process enables operators of large thermal plants to plan their
unit commitment, subject to start­up and ramping constraints.
Vertical Integration and Contract Markets The day­ahead market is typically dispatched using a mixed­
originally, a strict vertical separation was planned, with integer program (MiP) that accounts for these indivisibilities.
generators banned from retailing and retailers from gener­ in contrast, the australian and new Zealand wholesale
ation. Thus, they would all be required to interact by arms­ markets are single­settlement systems. The fixed costs and
length trading in contracts. it was soon realized that retail­ constraints of thermal plants are internalized in the prices of
ers with little capital and no secure customer base would be their energy offers that are then dispatched in real time in merit
unable to enter into the kind of long­term power purchase order. in new Zealand, with very few large thermal plants, the
contracts needed to support new capacity investment. nor advantages of using a MiP for unit commitment are minimal,
could investors in 1996 rely upon what was then considered so a single­settlement market seems sensible.
a dormant fledgling contract market. on the other hand, new Zealand is dominated by hydro­
while traditional vertical integration (combining genera­ electricity, and the dispatch of hydrostations down a river chain
tion, transmission, and distribution) was banned, generators within a day involves a dynamic element that could benefit from
were then allowed to purchase retailers. The risks of illi­ the coordination provided by a day­ahead dispatch. indeed, a
quidity in contracts were highlighted in 2001, when a major day­ahead market was established at the market start, but no
retailer competing solely on the basis of bilateral contracting trading ever occurred. To improve river­chain coordination, a
was forced, by substantial financial losses, to exit the market design was also considered in which intraday river­chain man­
after failing to purchase enough forward cover in a dry year. agement was directly incorporated into the real­time market.
Consequently, the market is now dominated by five main so­ But technical difficulties led to this being abandoned in favor
called “gentailers,” plus several small stand­alone retailers. of a regime under which river­chain managers are dispatched to
This degree of vertical integration is a disincentive to trad­ aggregate station offers to match their planned flow regime but
ing contracts, so establishing a liquid contract market became are then allowed to rebalance generation among their units—
a major goal for the ea. spot market participants now also e.g., to operate units at peak efficiency—as required between
trade various contracts to reduce exposure to risk, both bilat­ market clearing and actual dispatch time.
erally (over the counter) and via a futures exchange. The most
popular are fixed­volume contracts for differences, with a pay­
out per megawatthour to the purchaser equal to the difference
of the observed spot price and the contract price. 4,500
4,000
Capacity Market 3,500
having rejected the original capacity market proposal, new
3,000
Zealand has operated, to date, as a one­part or energy­only
2,500
(GWh)

market. australia adopted a similar design but implemented a


2,000
market price cap. That cap is set at a very high level, adjusted to
1,500
generate enough revenue to support oCgT entry if the market
1,000
runs out of capacity and prices reach the cap for 4.5 h per year,
which corresponds to a specified reliability standard. 500
new Zealand has no such standard and no market price cap. 0
July January July January July January
instead, the ea relies on the prospect of high prices, reinforced 2016 2017 2017 2018 2018 2019
through a regulated stress­testing regime that highlights the
financial risks associated with dry years, to provide both gen­ Nominal Full Controlled Storage
Mean–All Records Mean–Last 20 Years
tailers and stand­alone retailers the incentives to invest in or con­
1% Risk 2% Risk 4% Risk
tract for dry­year capacity to meet their wholesale purchase obli­ 6% Risk 8% Risk 10% Risk
gations for customers. a penalty regime also applies in the event HRC Received
that the 10% risk storage levels occur (see Figure 4), whereby all
retailers are required to pay customers nZ$10 per week during
figure 4. The historical hydro risk curves. The available
the savings campaign that is triggered by this event.
controlled storage is plotted in blue. Dotted curves indicate
storage levels that would incur the displayed probability of
Day-Ahead Markets the controlled storage falling to zero if all thermal plants
nearly every spot market pool in north america and europe were fully dispatched. If the controlled storage meets the
consists of two markets, with a two­settlement system. Com­ 10% risk curve (red), the system operator will launch an
mitted generation is cleared in a day­ahead market on the official conservation campaign, in which consumers will
day prior to dispatch, and then flexible plant production is be asked to conserve electricity.

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 47


Since 2010, the number of retail brands in the market has increased
from ten to over 30, with the market share of the five largest
gentailers declining from 97% to approximately 90% at present.

Retail Market Competition Until recently, though, the tariff structure for a domestic
since its establishment in 2010, the ea has been especially electricity consumer (as well as many mass­market business
active in promoting retail competition. Possibly the most sig­ customers) was almost exclusively a fixed­price, variable­vol­
nificant development here was the establishment of an electric­ ume tariff. new tariffs are emerging, however, most notably a
ity futures exchange, which enabled small independent retailers spot­based tariff offered by two retailers. one of these, Flick
to hedge the significant medium­term price volatility charac­ energy, acquired over 20,000 customers (~1% of the market)
teristic of new Zealand’s hydro­driven market. since 2010, the in a little more than three years. But 2017 was the first high
number of retail brands in the market has increased from ten wholesale price year since Flick’s entry, and it remains to be
to over 30, with the market share of the five largest gentailers seen how durable the company’s customer base is in the face
declining from 97% to approximately 90% at present. of temporary high prices at the meter or whether the insula­
when full retail competition was introduced in 1999, tion from wholesale signals (via a fixed­price, variable­vol­
smart meters were required only for larger typically industrial/ ume contract) is ultimately preferred by customers, albeit at a
commercial consumers. studies suggested that the costs of higher average price.
mandatory smart meter installation exceeded the benefits for
most households. This was left up to the market, except for a Investment and Entry
regulation requiring recertification of all meters by 2015. The as discussed previously, investment in generation capacity is
smart metering rollout is relatively high now, at around 70%, at the discretion of market participants and solely incentivized
but this seems to have been driven more by the opportunity for by participants who form views on future electricity prices in
retailers to reduce meter­reading costs than by a strong desire an energy­only market, with revenue partially underwritten
by consumers to actively manage their consumption patterns. by contracts with other market participants or retail custom­
while recent growth has been strong, only a small proportion ers. while investment is largely price driven, price projec­
of households actually face half­hourly spot prices, and, while tions depend on electricity demand growth and the investment
they receive real­time alerts of looming price spikes, they actu­ intentions of all market participants. new investment was low,
ally see their own data only about two days after real time. in the years immediately following deregulation, but accel­
There has been some consolidation in the smart meter market erated after 2004. This investment was dominated by wind
to two main service providers and two main meter types. and geothermal but also the construction of a large combined­
cycle gas turbine (CCgT) in 2006, bringing the total fleet of
CCgTs to four. although several hydro proposals have been
extensively investigated, environmental opposition has been
8,000
Change Since 2007 (GWh)

significant, and no substantial hydro project has actually pro­


6,000
ceeded since the market commenced in 1996.
4,000 Figure 5 shows the relative changes in both net supply
2,000 and demand (in terms of annual expected production) since
0 2007. over this period, electricity demand has remained
–2,000 largely flat, an unprecedented ten­year trend. while there
–4,000 have been some industrial closures during that period, we
–6,000 believe this trend is largely driven by energy efficiency. over
07
08
09
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17

this time, participants continued to invest in renewables,


20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20

perhaps expecting demand growth to eventually recover. as


New Generation (Gigawatthours Expected)
Decommissioned Generation (Average Output) a result, thermal generation was increasingly displaced by
Change in Demand Versus 2017 renewables, leading market participants to decommission
Net Supply Balance over 1,000 Mw of thermal capacity since 2013 (over 10% of
total capacity). a bilateral contracting arrangement between
figure 5. The new generation and decommissioned plant market participants has delayed the mothballing of a further
generation in New Zealand, 2008–2017. (Image courtesy of 480 Mw (two units at a 30­year­old coal/gas rankine plant)
Whiteboard Energy.) until the end of 2022, amid concerns about the security of

48 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


supply. it remains to be seen whether these ad hoc contracting of ownership models for edBs, including local government,
arrangements can continue to keep sufficient lightly utilized private investor, community­owned trust, and a combination
thermal capacity viable to provide supply security in an era of private investor and community trust. Being considered
of increasing renewable investment. monopolies, edBs are subject to price­quality and informa­
looking forward, the major disincentive to further invest­ tion­disclosure regulation, with strict limits on generation
ment continues to be lack of demand growth. This is com­ or retail activities. The Commerce Commission determines
pounded by some degree of uncertainty over the future of a a default price­quality path, but edBs determine their own
large aluminum smelter, which makes up 12% of the country’s pricing structures and access arrangements, within limits.
total demand. on the other hand, as fossil fuels are phased out, national retailers must create package offerings that deal
the electrification of transport and heat will put significant with many different cost structures, which poses a barrier to
upward pressure on demand. given new Zealand’s present retail competition and innovation.
and potential renewable resources, it is in an enviable position
to fuel this electrification while contributing to its international Photovoltaic Solar
commitments regarding carbon emissions. however, the rapid There has been no development of grid­connected photovol­
expansion of renewables implied by some future scenarios will taic (PV) solar in new Zealand, but Figure 6 shows the his­
have to deal with considerable public concern about the visual torical growth of rooftop PV solar, which is relatively low in
and environmental effects of both wind and hydro. dry­year new Zealand, at about 13.7 wp per person. watt peak (wp) is
security will be an increasing challenge. the peak power that can be produced by a solar energy system
under ideal sunlight and temperature conditions. The actual
New Developments power produced will vary substantially from the peak power
in the Distribution Sector as sunlight (irradiation) and panel efficiency change with
during the reform process, the number of distribution temperature, shading, and surface cleanliness. about 90% of
authorities was substantially reduced, but new Zealand still the PV solar capacity is small­scale residential rooftop.
has nearly 30 electricity distribution businesses (edBs) serv­ Unlike many other countries, the new Zealand govern­
ing a total population of 4.5 million people. There is a range ment has never provided explicit subsidies for rooftop PV

80

70

60
Installed Capacity (MW Peak)

50

40

30

20

10

0
2009-1
2009-3
2009-5
2009-7
2009-9
2009-11
2010-1
2010-3
2010-5
2010-7
2010-9
2010-11
2011-1
2011-3
2011-5
2011-7
2011-9
2011-11
2012-1
2012-3
2012-5
2012-7
2012-9
2012-11
2013-1
2013-3
2013-5
2013-7
2013-9
2014-11
2014-1
2014-3
2014-5
2014-7
2014-9
2014-11
2015-1
2015-3
2015-5
2015-7
2015-9
2015-11
2016-1
2016-3
2016-5
2016-7
2016-9
2016-11
2017-1
2017-3
2017-5
2017-7
2017-9
2017-11
2018-1
2018-3

Year and Month

figure 6. The PV solar installed capacity in New Zealand. The capacity reached 74 MWp (13.7 Wp per person) in April
2018. (Data through to September 2013 courtesy of the GREEN Grid project and data post-2013 courtesy of the EA.)

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 49


solar. although some gentailers offered buyback rates of Electric Vehicles
around nZ$0.17/kwh prior to november 2014, these were new Zealand has no automotive industry and accounts for only
then reduced to approximately the average wholesale price of a minuscule proportion of global demand. in fact, the majority
nZ$0.08/kwh. growth in solar is still indirectly encouraged of new Zealand households buy used vehicles from Japan and
by a low­use tariff regulation, which requires edBs to charge thus choose from whatever was sold there several years ear­
residential consumers with low consumption a low daily fixed lier. Thus, new Zealand has no discernible impact on global
rate, forcing transmission and distribution costs to be recovered research and development priorities or even manufacturing
through a per­unit electricity price well above the wholesale strategies, so there is little economic incentive to foster experi­
energy price, which is supposed to reflect the marginal energy mentation with new automotive technologies. The potential
cost. This encourages energy efficiency but also incentivizes value of electric vehicles in the new Zealand context is also a
potentially uneconomic use of nonelectric heating as well as complex question, depending heavily on correlations between
installation of rooftop solar water heating and PV. charging requirements, other loads, and renewable generation
studies, such as that by Miller et al. (2016), show that PV sources across daily, weekly, and annual cycles, over a wide
solar is already commercially attractive for some households variety of meteorological combinations.
with low discount rates and for some commercial customers, still, the government has provided a fund for innovative
even though the latter typically have a much lower variable marketing and support of electric vehicles. electric vehicles
price and higher fixed price than residential consumers. in currently account for 0.16% of all light vehicles in the coun­
fact, with current distribution pricing arrangements and fall­ try, but Figure 7 shows that adoption has grown strongly in
ing PV prices, new Zealand seems close to a rapid adop­ the last two years, as more models become available interna­
tion of PV solar by residential customers, especially in those tionally, range increases, and marketing ramps up.
regions with high irradiation.
But it remains to be seen whether PV solar can make a sig­ Battery Storage
nificant positive economic contribution, given new Zealand’s Batteries seem unlikely to contribute much to new Zealand’s
relatively cloudy climate and demand patterns dominated by main supply security issue: storing enough excess production
heating rather than cooling requirements. PV solar capacity in wet years to cover dry conditions occurring perhaps every
factors can be as high as 18% in the north of both islands, 20 years or fewer. Batteries face stiff competition with exist­
where solar growth is highest, but only around 12% in the ing hydro storage as a way of dealing with supply/demand
south of the south island, and that is mainly during sum­ fluctuations over minutes, hours, or days. at a system level,
mer, whereas load peaks on long, dark, cold winter nights. they will not make much contribution until solar and/or wind
This contrasts with capacity factors well above 20% in parts output becomes so high that hydro cannot be backed off any
of australia and north america, in regions where demand further and energy must be spilled.
also tends to peak on hot, sunny days. nor does solar hedge at a household level, storage batteries can make PV solar
low hydro reservoir inflows, which fall to their lowest level more attractive by maximizing self­consumption. But the cost
around June and July, when PV solar output is also lowest. for this use alone is prohibitive, adding at least nZ$0.4/kwh

7,000
Number of Light Electric Vehicles

6,000 New Light Pure Electric


Used Light Pure Electric
5,000
New Light Plug-In Hybrid
4,000 Used Light Plug-In Hybrid

3,000

2,000

1,000

0
2014-1
2014-2
2014-3
2014-4
2014-5
2014-6
2014-7
2014-8
2014-9
2014-10
2014-11
2014-12
2015-1
2015-2
2015-3
2015-4
2015-5
2015-6
2015-7
2015-8
2015-9
2015-10
2015-11
2015-12
2016-1
2016-2
2016-3
2016-4
2016-5
2016-6
2016-7
2016-8
2016-9
2016-10
2016-11
2016-12
2017-1
2017-2
2017-3
2017-4
2017-5
2017-6
2017-7
2017-8
2017-9
2017-10
2017-11
2017-12
2018-1

Year and Month

figure 7. Light electric vehicles in New Zealand. Up to January 2018, the total number was 6,526 vehicles, a small
fraction of the approximately 3.6 million light vehicles in the country. (Data courtesy of the New Zealand Vehicle Fleet
Statistics, New Zealand Ministry of Transport.)

50 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


While New Zealand’s greenhouse gas emissions
are small on a global scale (about 0.15%), its per capita
emissions are comparatively high.

to the average cost of energy in a PV solar system. greater and operating challenge. Moreover, new Zealand has ratified
benefit can be gained by situating batteries behind the meter, the Paris agreement, with its nationally determined contribu­
thereby enabling one battery to deliver a bundle of network, tion (ndC) requiring a reduction in equivalent carbon dioxide
PV solar, demand response, and ancillary service potential ben­ emissions by approximately 40% of current levels by 2030 and
efits. even so, studies suggest that it will be some time before net zero emissions by 2050. while new Zealand’s greenhouse
batteries become economical in new Zealand. nevertheless, gas emissions are small on a global scale (about 0.15%), its per
some edBs are experimenting with in­home and larger­scale capita emissions are comparatively high, mainly due to the
batteries to manage specific constraints in their networks. as high level of methane and nitrous oxide emissions from agri­
with interruptible­load systems, however, the regulators may culture. studies have shown that the electrification of private
find it difficult to ensure equal access to the many benefits that vehicle transport and most stationary heating, and converting
batteries may bring, while also allowing them to be bundled of the remainder of electricity generation to renewable sources,
effectively. household installation may be inhibited if new reg­ would almost reach new Zealand’s ndC. But the increase in
ulations require lithium­ion batteries to be installed in separate renewable generation required to achieve this would be about
enclosures outside homes for fire safety reasons. 130%. Thus, the question is what sources could be used to
deliver that level of renewable generation.
The Future The sheer quantum leap of new generation required will
The ea’s statutory objective is “to promote competition in, inevitably imply a major conflict between global environ­
reliable supply by, and the efficient operation of, the elec­ mental concerns and localized environmental antagonism to
tricity industry for the long­term benefit of consumers.” hydro or wind development, at least. But there are also three
Consistent with this, the agency’s current priorities include specific problems to be addressed.
encouraging more retail competition in the market, improv­ First, the short­term variability of renewable generation
ing information flows, finalizing prices closer to real time, sources will be a particular problem in the new Zealand
and enabling access to retail data, such as smart metering system, because it is relatively small and unable to import or
data. it is also reviewing distribution pricing and exploring export energy or achieve the diversity typical of continental
options to encourage greater efficiency and competition by power systems. new Zealand has so far incorporated 800 Mw
opening access to distribution networks, developing alter­ of wind generation (about 9% of installed capacity) with no
natives to traditional electricity distribution, diversifying adverse effects on power system reliability, primarily because
supply sources, and better utilizing demand response. flexible (predominantly hydro) generation has thus far been
some electricity distribution businesses are evolving from able to manage the variations in wind generation supply. But
low­voltage network owners into mini system operators, as significant additions of flexible hydro capacity seem unlikely,
they seek to integrate the numerous new devices connecting and the flexibility of existing operations is gradually being
to the network and make economic tradeoffs with the new ser­ reduced by environmental opposition to varying both flow and
vices to manage system peaks and reduce the need to continu­ storage levels.
ally upgrade their networks. Challenges abound for low­volt­ There has also been significant pushback over the im­
age networks in optimizing the use of storage batteries, smart pact of wind farms on landscape values. still, with about
electric vehicles, and increased demand­response, especially 3,000 Mw already approved for development, wind can be
where this requires integration with price signals emanating expected to play a major role in achieving the 100% renew­
from the wholesale market. Presently, the trend toward distri­ able target, along with geothermal, of which there is about
bution system operators is occurring within existing network 300 Mw endorsed for installation. studies by the green
owners; it remains to be seen whether the separation between grid project have investigated the technical impact on the
asset ownership and system operation, which has been largely power system of adding up to 4,000 Mw more of wind gen­
adopted for the high­voltage grid market, will also eventuate eration (about 50% of 2018’s installed capacity). The results
for distribution­level markets. show an increased need for frequency regulation, instanta­
at a macro level, while the renewable generation share is neous reserves to deal with the reduction in inertia, and droop
currently around 85%, a government goal to reach 100% renew­ response. ancillary service prices will eventually have to
able generation in a normal hydrological year by 2035 means rise to a level at which it becomes economical for investors
that the market now faces a very significant developmental to provide these services, either from partially dispatched

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 51


geothermal generation, demand­side involvement, or battery­ general public. Those perceptions may ultimately determine
based ancillary services. the durability of the regime.
second, new Zealand’s highest demand occurs during win­ Perhaps the ea’s current approach will endure if the sec­
ter evenings, when there is no solar and the prospect of cold, tor continues to be dominated by substantial vertically inte­
windless conditions. Thus, for the near future, flexible hydro grated firms, with strong incentives to stay in business for the
will need to be supplemented by thermal peaking plants, albeit long term. But that may change if the sector evolves toward
operating at low load factors. in the longer term, though, the a purer version of the competitive market paradigm, with a
storage capacity of hydro and demand­side heating/cooling large number of less­substantial firms relying on supply from
systems will probably need to be supplemented by storage bat­ and to a highly volatile spot market.
teries, including distributed battery capacity in PV solar instal­ The situation in new Zealand is quite different from that
lations and electric vehicles. in, e.g., australia, where both investors and the general pub­
Third, new Zealand already faces a significant mismatch lic expect a fairly predictable number of short, sharp spikes
between seasonal demand and supply patterns that will not on hot days every summer. in new Zealand, a future genera­
be reduced by the renewable development options discussed tion of consumers. having experienced maybe 20 years of
here. it must also cope with major wet/dry­year fluctuations, low renewable energy prices, may find it quite hard to accept
which may well be exacerbated by climate change. indeed, that the accumulated cost of backup generation must be paid
changing precipitation patterns may well change the effec­ for in a single dry winter of extremely high prices. Presented
tive storage capacity of existing hydro. arguably, these with such an event, a future government may also find it hard
factors could be mitigated by building much more hydro res­ not to respond by intervening, either changing the market
ervoir storage capacity, but that seems unlikely to happen. if design, overruling the regulator, or perhaps even reversing
burning stored fossil fuels is unacceptable, the only alter­ privatization. risk­averse investors are likely to commit to
natives would seem to be burning stored biofuels, extreme significantly less than the optimal capacity requirement
overbuilding of other renewable energy systems, or demand­ on the basis of such an irregular and unpredictable income
side management. in particular, electricity­intensive indus­ stream and even less if they believe the regime itself may
tries, such as smelting, could be developed further, provided be changed so as to specifically prevent them from collect­
those industries maintained the flexibility to substantially ing the revenue required to pay for that capacity when a
reduce consumption in dry years. effectively, varying the really dry year finally occurs. Thus, arguments about the
net export of, say, smelted aluminum would be equivalent need for an explicit capacity market mechanism seem only
to varying the net export of electricity, as would occur if likely to increase.
new Zealand were connected to a larger international power
grid. There would obviously be an economic cost to building For Further Reading
demand­side capacity to be idle in the occasional dry year. T. alvey, d. goodwin, X. Ma, d. streiffert, and d. sun, “a
But that cost may be significantly less than that of build­ security­constrained bid­clearing system for the new Zea­
ing substantial excess hydro/wind/solar capacity to be idle land wholesale electricity market,” IEEE Trans. Power Syst.,
in every other year. The same is likely to be true of many vol. 13, no. 2, pp. 340–346, 1998.
islanded power systems. J. g. Culy, e. g. read, and B. wright, “structure and
Finally, increasing renewable contributions will also regulation of the new Zealand electricity sector,” in Inter-
increase the proportion of time that plants with near­zero national Comparison of Electricity Regulation, r. gilbert
marginal cost are on the margin. offering more genera­ and e. Kahn, eds. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge Univ. Press,
tion from these plants to the wholesale market will depress 1996, p. 312–365.
the market clearing price, providing lower market returns a. Miller, s. Mcnab, s. lemon, and a. wood, “The eco­
for most generation most of the time. To recover generators’ nomics and potential uptake of PV solar power by region and
fixed costs in an energy­only market will then require more PV system cost,” in Proc. Electricity Engineers Association
periods with higher scarcity prices. arguably, this trend Conf. Exhibition, wellington, new Zealand, 2016.
may be so extreme as to pose an existential challenge to the
whole market design and its governance arrangements. it Biographies
is possible to calculate the average annual level of scarcity Andy Philpott is with the University of auckland, new
prices required to incentivize a reasonable level of capac­ Zealand.
ity investment. in theory, we may argue that there is little Grant Read is with the University of Canterbury, Christ­
difference between suppliers collecting this revenue during church, new Zealand.
occasional price spikes and the government collecting it via Stephen Batstone is with whiteboard energy and sapere
capacity charges, as was done when new Zealand last had a research group, Queenstown, new Zealand.
100% renewable power system before 1958. But there may Allan Miller is with the University of Canterbury, Christ­
be very significant differences in the way those two regimes church, new Zealand.
p&e
are perceived by risk­averse investors, the regulator, and the

52 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


A Change
Is Coming

©istockphoto.com/kamisoka

B
How Regulation and Based on current policy targets, projec-
tions, and expectations, electricity is set to play a cen-
Innovation Are Reshaping tral role in the european union’s (eu’s) economy. the
ambitious goals of decarbonization and energy-efficient
the European Union’s actions include decreasing greenhouse gas emissions
by 40% in 2030 and 95% in 2050 down to below 1990
Electricity Markets levels, increasing the renewable energy share to at least
27% of final energy consumption in 2030, and attain-
ing 27% energy savings by 2030 as compared to busi-
ness-as-usual rates of growth. correlated electrification,
decentralization, and digitalization trends suggest that the
By Gianluca Fulli, share of electricity in final energy consumption can grow
Marcelo Masera, from above 30% in 2030 to nearly 40% in 2050. decen-
tralized generation capacity could account for more than
Amanda Spisto, and 30% of all generation capacity in 2030 and could eas-
ily exceed half of installed generation capacity by 2050.
Silvia Vitiello intelligent inverters can double the distribution grid’s
capacity to the host photovoltaic systems. smart meters
Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/MPE.2018.2872303
are scheduled to reach nearly half of the eu’s citizens
Date of publication: 7 January 2019 by 2020, whereas internet-of-things (iot) devices (with

january/february 2019 1540-7977/19©2019IEEE ieee power & energy magazine 53


The role of wholesale, day-ahead electricity markets in steering not
only as short-term, efficient resource allocations, but also medium-
to-long-term investments, is currently being debated.

embedded functions that interact with the grid) could serve a full ownership-unbundled tso; 2) an independent system
the majority of the eu’s population by 2030. operator managing, but not owning, the transmission network
in such a rapidly shifting context, electricity system stake- assets; or 3) an independent tso legally separated but still
holders are striving to keep up with the pace of innovation and embedded in a larger energy company (Figure 1). in europe,
anticipate the infrastructure and market arrangements neces- 43 tsos and roughly 2,400 distribution system operators
sary for future electricity delivery and services. legislators (dsos), acting as regulated independent actors, comprise the
and regulators are confronted with the challenging task of cre- link between the system physics and the market transactions
ating the most effective actions to steer the electricity sector by interacting with several electricity system players.
transition for the customers’ benefit. the eu’s energy union another main regulatory intervention addresses electric-
strategy issued in 2015 and the ensuing clean energy package ity markets. today, electricity is traded in the eu either via
proposal (cep) put forward by the european commission in long-term bilateral contracts (which represent two-thirds of
2016 are examples of the efforts of eu institutions to under- the electricity transactions concluded in the major markets
take those policy and regulatory issues. in 2015) or via the four segments of the wholesale power
against this backdrop, we describe some of the main exchanges, i.e., the forward and derivatives markets (weeks
regulatory challenges underpinning the restructuring of elec- to years in advance), the day-ahead markets (daMs), the
tricity markets in the eu. We first analyze how policy deci- intraday markets (iMs) (operating for an hour or fractions of
sions have contributed to developing the present eu electric- an hour), and the balancing markets (operating in real time).
ity system and markets. then, we illustrate new policy and the 2015 yearly trading volumes reached a few hundred ter-
regulatory initiatives that aim to redesign the eu markets. awatthours in the major european spot markets, including
in conclusion, we share some thoughts on the interplay of the italian power market exchange (ipeX), the centre-north
regulatory and technical advances and their impact on future european power market exchange epeX, and the scandina-
power systems. vian nordpool. at the retail market level, roughly 3,100 local
suppliers offer electricity to consumers that is acquired from
Current EU Electricity either generators or the wholesale market.
Markets’ Regulations the role of wholesale, day-ahead electricity markets in
steering not only as short-term, efficient resource allocations,
Background and General Features but also medium-to-long-term investments, is currently being
the demand for electricity within europe’s internal market debated. as low-carbon technologies penetrate the system,
prompted the introduction of a radical project that triggered average spot-market energy prices tend to drop while price
significant challenges following the passage of the single volatility (if not constrained by rules) grows. the anticipated
european act of 1986, a piece of legislation that advocated an decrease in wholesale, day-ahead energy prices does not seem
eu internal electricity market by 1992. three subsequent eu consistent with guiding long-term investments in electric-
energy packages, introduced in 1996, 2003, and 2009, have ity generation and infrastructure. the widespread incentives
created a single, competitive european market. national verti- available for specific technologies triggered by supply secu-
cally integrated undertakings, which, in the past, controlled the rity, sustainability, or social inclusion policies may discourage
whole electricity value chain, are now divided into four blocks: market-driven investments in some power system areas. in
generation and retail companies that compete in their respec- particular, a large portion of public support in the electricity
tive domains and (natural) transmission and (local) distribution sector, which increased from €36 billion to €63 billion during
monopolies. at the same time, the power system has progres- the period 2008–2012, went to low-carbon solutions. the costs
sively moved from a scheme with centralized and predict- related to redispatching and balancing capacity procurement
able generation, which met a rather inelastic demand, toward and capacity mechanisms have grown in recent years. the
one with higher shares of renewable and distributed energy tendency to increase the nonenergy component of the electric-
resources that meets a more flexible expectation. ity retail prices acts to reduce the amount of competition in
the european regulatory approach concerning monopolies end-user markets. the interactions among the different poli-
was implemented by the third energy package that, among cies affecting the market price signals are being scrutinized
other things, called for the unbundling of transmission system to help understand the consequences on the level of competi-
operators (tsos) according to one of the following options: 1) tion and business opportunities for the investors. the goal of

54 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


such revisited policies is to remodulate public-support schemes Electricity End-User and Retail Market Status
while making low-carbon technologies cost-effective. the distribution system is the electricity value chain’s crucial
a third, significant eu regulatory effort focuses on research sector, incubating most of the innovation. the dsos facili-
and innovation (r&i) (also financed by private investors) tate the retail market’s functions by connecting parties to
to determine how smart and digital energy systems, which the distribution grid, enabling supplier switching, provid-
embed sizable amounts of distributed energy resources, could ing metering data from customers, and delivering allocation
be deployed on a large scale. in the past 15 years, €5 billion and reconciliation services. Fewer than 10% of the dsos are
has been invested in roughly 1,000 r&i projects, testing novel partially (i.e., functionally or legally) unbundled, while the
smarter electricity systems on the ground (Figure 2). invest- smaller distributors, serving fewer than 100,000 customers
ment in smart energy system r&i have steadily increased in the or isolated systems, are exempt from any unbundling. new
eu, growing from approximately one-fifth in 2010 to approxi- and emerging actors, often power system business outsiders
mately one-quarter of the total expenditure (€27  billion) in the (including municipalities, house corporations, telecommuni-
energy union-related r&i priorities in 2014. cations, high-tech/security companies, or social media), are

Unbundling Model Ownership


Full Ownership Unbundling FS Fully State Owned

Independent System Operator MS Mostly State Owned

Independent Transmission Operator MP Mostly Privately Owned


Mix FP Fully Privately Owned
Not Applicable

The

figure 1. A transmission operation unbundling status.

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 55


moving into the distribution, retail, and end-user spheres as and taxes and levies on the other, make up the remaining two-
a result of the various socioeconomic drivers. thirds. the recent wholesale price drop only slightly reduced
the rising penetration of distributed generation brings the retail price energy component, which, through 2015,
more voltage stability and congestion-management issues to resulted in escalating prices for consumers due to mounting
dso operations. today, flexible distribution resources rarely nonenergy components (2016 was the first year in a decade in
participate in the tso-governed ancillary services markets which retail prices declined). recently, liberalized countries
(asMs) and rarely intervene to solve local network prob- (generally in southeastern europe) have exhibited more non-
lems; fragmented products and rules are used across mem- price related features (i.e., linked to renewable/environmental
ber states (Mss). aspects) in their electricity retail offers and lower consumer
in europe, the customers’ price is considered “the sum of switch rates to alternative suppliers compared to that of coun-
the following three main components: the energy and supply tries with more mature wholesale market competition (gener-
component, the network component (transmission and distri- ally in northwestern europe, as shown in Figure 3).
bution), and the component comprising taxes, levies, fees, and the eu pursues deregulation actions on final electricity
charges” [cf. art. 2 of annex to the proposal directive of the prices to foster market entry, innovation, and competition.
european parliament and of the council on common rules Household retail prices consistently followed the wholesale
for the internal Market in electricity (recast)]. the wholesale dynamics in the few cases where more competitive/dynamic
market’s dynamics are transferred to the retail level mostly retail market schemes were in place, whereas fixed, regulated
through the energy component of the retail prices, and they prices are still used in nearly half of the Mss. specific con-
make up just one-third of average eu retail electricity prices. sumer categories indicate a preference for fixed-price contracts
the nonenergy components, i.e., network costs on one side over a financial reward for modulating consumption.

20° 10° 0° 20°


Budget Applications
European Finland 10
Commission
100
Joint Research Center 2017,
Directorate C Energy, Transport Detail for
and Climate, Gangale, F., Vasijevska
J., Covrig, F., Mengolini, A., Fulli, Norway Estonia € Million <€10 Million
G., Smart grid projects outlook 2017:
facts, figures and trends in Europe.
Latvia 0
EUR 28614 EN, doi: 10276015583 Other
Sweden Integration of Large-Scale
Denmark Renewable Energy Sources
United Kingdom Lithuania E-Mobility
Integration of DG and Storage
Ireland
50° DSM
The Netherlands Smart Network Management
Belgium Germany Poland

Czech Republic
Luxembourg
Slovakia
Austria
Switzerland Hungary
Slovenia
Croatia Romania

France

40° Bulgaria
Italy

Portugal
Greece

Spain
Cyprus
0 250 500
km Malta 20° 20°
figure 2. The smart grid research and innovation projects—a geographical distribution of investment by domain. DG:
distributed generation. [From the Joint Research Centre (authors’ elaboration).] E-Mobility: electric mobility; DSM: demand
side management.

56 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


approximately 25% of european household consumers consumer protection and empowerment rights are incor-
are already equipped with electricity smart meters. only porated into national and regional legislation. With the goal of
roughly half of those devices, however, embed the ten func- protecting and engaging consumers, some eu Mss have begun
tionalities (including more frequent readings and support to 1) provide more information on price changes, bills, actual
for advanced tariff schemes) recommended by the ec. this consumption, and costs; 2) introduce single contact points and
makes dynamic pricing mechanisms, demand response, and energy consumer checklists; and 3) simplify the supplier switch-
energy-saving strategies difficult to implement on a large ing processes. the benefits are not clear regarding the accumu-
scale. demand response and dynamic pricing promise to lated information offers provided and process improvements,
bring new flexibility resources to power system balancing; and their impact on consumer responsiveness remain unclear.
however, the debate continues regarding the real value as consumer rights vary greatly across europe, with some
well as the costs and the benefits for all of the perspective consumers having little or no choice of supplier. energy
actors in the current market settings. poverty and vulnerability are unresolved problems; it is

Percentage of
Total Consumers
0/No Data
0.1–5
5–10

10–15
15–20
20–25
> 25

The

0 250 500 km

figure 3. The percentage of final electricity consumers by EU country changing suppliers. (Data courtesy of the Agency for
the Cooperation of European Energy Regulators, 2016.)

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 57


The first example of a regionally integrated generation adequacy
assessment carried out in collaboration with the seven European
TSOs was published in 2015 by the Pentalateral Energy Forum.

estimated that one in five european household energy consum- as significantly as in other world economies (Figure 4). nev-
ers is classified as “vulnerable.” poorer households, as com- ertheless, current levels of electricity prices in the wholesale
pared to wealthier ones, have energy expenditures that claim markets in europe vary significantly across Mss (Figure 5),
a higher share of their income. in some Mss, suppliers of last- indicating that the goal of long-term price convergence for
resort mechanisms, who seek to replace failing suppliers and electricity remains distant.
protect inactive or poor consumers, cover more expenditures part of the difficulties with the implementation of the fully
than is necessary for consumers, thus hampering their proactive integrated european electricity market comes from the two
involvement in the retail market’s dynamics. waves of “disruptive innovations” that occurred in the power
system in the last decades, e.g., the widespread use of renew-
Electricity Wholesale Market Status able energy sources (ress) (in 2015, 27.5% of electricity in
the ultimate goals of the eu energy legislation are electricity the eu was generated from renewables, a 12.6% increase from
market integration (which features convergent prices across the 2005) as well as the use of smart energy system interactions to
eu), improved investments in low-carbon technologies and decentralize the consumption–production loop. some exam-
flexible solutions, and more focused market-based governmen- ples of the role of regulation in adaptating to unforeseen devel-
tal support. despite the progress of energy-sector regulation in opments and coordinating between european and national
the past 20 years, many improvements are necessary to address policies can be seen at both the european and national levels.
several issues. these include low liquidity and low prices for one of the main obstacles to an integrated european whole-
transmission rights that forward markets continue to offer as sale market is the lack of coordination in addressing power sys-
well as the iMs and balancing markets that are underdeveloped tem adequacy (or reliability), i.e., the ability of the power sys-
and only offer a portion of the short-term adjustments needed tem to meet electricity demand 99% of the time, as mandated
for greater penetration of variable renewable energy. by the european system operation network code. currently,
electricity wholesale prices in europe have been subject the official reports on generation adequacy assessment are pro-
to considerable volatility over the last decade, although not duced by each Ms (with complete autonomy) with respect to

200
Japan EU-Platts PEP
180
United States Australia
160

140

120
(€/MWh)

100

80

60

40

20

1 3 5 7 9 11 1 3 5 7 9 11 1 3 5 7 9 11 1 3 5 7 9 11 1 3 5 7 9 11 1 3 5 7 9 11 1 3 5 7
2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016
Source: PJM and ERCOT Markets in the United States, Platts in the EU, Japanese Power Market Exchange (Japan),
and AEMO (Australia)

figure 4. The wholesale electricity prices in Europe, United States, Japan, and Australia. [Adapted from the European
Commission staff working document “Energy Prices and Costs in Europe,” (COM 2016) 769 final.]

58 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


the methodology, data sets, scenarios, and time frames for the (dark-shaded area). the last column on the right reports the dif-
analysis. the first example of a regionally integrated genera- ference between the two cases.
tion adequacy assessment carried out in collaboration with the the costs (in millions of euros) associated with the lole
seven european tsos was published in 2015 by the pentalateral level (h) for each Ms are assessed using the methodology pro-
energy Forum (pleF). the study compares the levels of loss of posed by Wu et al., who run a stochastic long-term (ten years),
load expectation (lole) from 1 october 2015 to 30 september security-constrained, unit commitment model and assess the
2016 for two different cases (table 1). in the first case, the reli- costs associated with the four levels of reliability that are set
ability assessment is undertaken in a noncoordinated way by as constraints in the model, i.e., 24 h, 120 h, 240 h, and 360 h.
each individual country, i.e., reducing the net transfer capacity the cost of lole in each european country is computed by
along all of the borders (light-shaded area). in the other case, multiplying the number of hours of lole resulting from the
countries carry out the assessment in a coordinated manner pleF’s adequacy study by the associated cost range calculated

Euro/MWh
0/No Data

0.1–35
35–40

40–45
45–50
> 50

The

0 250 500 km

figure 5. The average annual wholesale electricity prices per country in 2017. (Data courtesy of the European Commis-
sion, “Directorate General for Energy, Data, and Methodology” adapted from the “Quarterly Report on European Electricity
Markets” report.)

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 59


according to the methodology in Wu et al., divided by ten (i.e., european national regulatory authorities approved the proposal
the number of years of optimization). this cost is then adjusted under the commission’s capacity allocation and congestion
to the 2016 dollar-to-euro exchange rate. Management (cacM) regulation, (eu) 2015/1222, that was
there are several benefits of a coordinated approach. introduced by the 17 nominated electricity Market operators
the first is that the results of the reliability indicators can (neMos) committee. the agreement seeks to establish a
be compared across countries. Moreover, the reliability european market coupling operator to further integrate daM
indicators for each Ms are more accurate because they are and iM functions across europe, a strategy referred to as the
calculated using data from neighboring countries, i.e., the MCO plan. the plan’s goals are to increase liquidity by orga-
available capacity for generation and transmission as well as nizing trade between zones and establish clear and detailed
hydrological data, which is provided homogeneously by the rules among the neMos.
tsos or other collaborating national bodies. the coordinated national regulation, on the other hand, serves as a bridge for
approach produces a more realistic estimation of the costs the implementation of european policies and plays a funda-
of each level of reliability. these costs are generally lower mental role as a bottom-up driver the transition of national
than for the uncoordinated case because, when countries can power markets toward an integrated system. power exchanges
rely on the available generation capacity of their neighbors, are the operational bodies of the national regulators and tasked
investments in such capacity can be more efficient. with implementing technical market rules. an example of a
the widespread implementation of market coupling-solu- structured market is the italian power market exchange (ipeX),
tions for cross-border congestion management in europe is which is managed by gestore dei Mercati energetici and orga-
another example of regional coordination contributing to the nized in a multisession structure from the day ahead to the day
realization of the internal electricity market. at the moment, of delivery (Figure 7), where it simultaneously (i.e., implicitly)
22 european countries (including the united Kingdom) are manages both energy and transmission capacity. during each
coupled in different combinations for the daM (Figure 6) market session, operators can change their bids/offers to new
with the goal of improving market liquidity, investment allo- and more refined demand and renewable generation forecasts.
cation management, and price signals. coupled markets use this structure adds flexibility to the system and creates business
a common algorithm for settling market transactions, taking opportunities for market operators to provide system services.
into account the constraints of the interconnectors linking the
countries. therefore, we can conclude that the coordination of Forthcoming Policy and
national energy systems across the eu is beneficial from the Regulatory Challenges
standpoints of coordinating generation capacity investment and
coupling energy markets. Overarching Challenges and Trends
there is ongoing discussion on the benefits of a euro- regulators must properly allocate risks associated with low-
pean market coupling for cross-border iMs. in june 2017, all carbon innovation investments and guarantee cost recovery
through market prices. the invest-
table 1. A comparison of reliability performances ment volume from now until 2030
in the isolated and coordinated cases. is estimated at €90 billion yearly,
which comprises power generation
Single-Country Coordinated Benefits of
Assessment Assessment Coordinated (55%) and grids (45%). policy deci-
Isolated Case Interconnected Case Assessment sion makers must intervene to revise
Average Cost of LOLE Average Cost of LOLE
prices and regulate charges for elec-
Countries LOLE (h) (€ Million) LOLE (h) (€ Million) (€ Million) tricity delivery and related services
so that there is a level playing field
Belgium 177 48.06 0 0 48.06
for all resources. at the same time,
France 217 58.21 14 4 54.21 they must promote new public–pri-
Austria 0 0 0 vate coordination mechanisms and
generation- or demand-side public
Switzerland 1,251 330.11 0 330.11
support for low-carbon solutions that
Germany 0 0 0 are not competitive.
The Netherlands 0 0 0 to improve individual storage
and electric vehicle (eV) solutions
Luxembourg 8,760 2,311.53 0 2,311.53
(possibly combined with generation),
Total 2,747.9 4 2,743.9 tailored remuneration schemes and
[Adapted from the Joint Research Centre, “The Pentalateral Energy Forum Support Group ownership structures may be needed
2 Generation Adequacy Assessment,” (authors’ elaboration) and on the basis of the for these technologies. r&i proj-
methodology developed in Wu et al., “Costs of reliability analysis based on stochastic unit ects are analyzing the participation
commitment,” IEEE Transactions on Power Systems, vol. 23, no. 3, 2008.]
of storage in the balancing market

60 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


(e.g., netfficient) and proposing a cloud-based flexibility man- storage and implementation of market-based energy-effi-
agement system with eVs and batteries (e.g., inVade). cient measures.
the cep proposal for integrating electricity grids provides the cep also promotes changes in the markets along
the dso–tso cooperation rules that manage supply- and the following:
demand-side flexibilities during different time scales. clarifi- ✔ the local spatial dimension, which allows the participa-
cation is needed on the dsos’ tasks and challenges related tion of innovative service providers on a cross-national
to procuring services from resources (not necessarily owned scale to extend market coupling and spatial optimiza-
by them), such as distributed generation, demand response, or tion of investments

Trilateral Market Market Coupling of Europe


Coupling Market Coupling of Spain
and Portugal

(a) (b)

Market Coupling of Europe Market Coupling of Europe


4M Market Coupling 4M Market Coupling
Market Coupling “Italian Borders”

(c) (d)

figure 6. Maps of market coupling in European power markets for (a) 2006, (b) 2010, (c) 2014, and (d) 2015. The “Italian-
borders” coupling considers the whole energy market of bordering countries to define the actual allocation of energy and
capacity for each border. 4M: four markets (Czech, Slovak, Hungarian, and Romanian).

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 61


✔ the time dimensions (from long

injections and withdrawals from the grid in real time. The ASM consists of the ex-ante ASM and the balancing market. B: balancing market; IM: intraday market; R: results of
previous ex-ante ASM sessions. In the balancing market, the TSO accepts energy demand bids and supply offers to provide secondary control services and balance energy
00:00 a.m.
term to real time) for the renewable in-
tegration and optimization of market
11:00 p.m.

figure 7. The IPEX market sessions’ 2016 scheme. In B1 (Terna), the Italian TSO takes into consideration the valid bids/asks that the participants have submitted in the
10:00 p.m.
transactions and network operations.

In the balancing market, the TSO accepts energy demand bids and supply offers to provide secondary control services and balance energy injections and withdrawals
9:45 p.m.

8:00 p.m. With respect to digitization, cyberse-


7:00 p.m.
curity, and privacy (including elements

C*
such as distributed ledgers and artificial

R13-6
6:15 p.m.

5:00 p.m. intelligence), the cep advocates that all


4:45 p.m.
R7
consumers (as deemed necessary) should
3:00 p.m.
be equipped with modern smart meters

C*
that diligently protect their rights con-
R12-5
Day of Delivery

2:15 p.m.

1:00 p.m. cerning the processing and free movement


of personal data. this requires a careful
R6

11:45 a.m.

assessment of the costs and benefits.

In B1, the TSO takes into consideration the valid bids/asks that the participants have submitted in the previous ex-ante ASM session.
11:00 a.m.
C*

data protection and security, which in-


R11-4

10:15 a.m.

9:00 a.m. volve the technological, procedural, archi-


tectural, and behavioral aspects of custom-
R5

8:15 a.m.

ers’ personal and consumption information,


C*

7:00 a.m.

are receiving increased attention courtesy of


R10-3

6:15 a.m.

5:00 a.m. the eu’s general data protection regulation.


in this context, a few Mss linked their smart
R4

4:15 a.m.

metering roll-out plans to data protection


C*

3:00 a.m.

compliance. to secure smart grid opera-


R9-2

2:15 a.m.

1:00 a.m.
each market session. [From the GME (authors’ elaboration).] GME: Gestore dei Mercati Energetici. tions, several r&i projects have proposed
novel decision-support systems (sesaMe)
R3

00:15 a.m.

11:00 p.m. and innovative risk assessment and manage-


ment solutions (sparKs and segrid).
B2
B3
B4
B5
B6

10:30 p.m.

Various data-management models with


10:00 p.m.
R8-1

numerous ratios of traditional actors (par-


B1

9:45 p.m.

8:00 p.m.
ticularly tsos and dsos) and covering
different nonenergy systems and services
7:00 p.m.

are emerging across the eu. neutral data


6:00 p.m.
IM3
IM4
IM5
IM6
IM7

5:30 p.m.
brokers might arise as independent parties
R2

5:00 p.m.
Ex-ante ASM (Six Sessions)

4:30 p.m. feeding all players with the data required to


pursue their business. the cep clarifies the
One Day Before the Delivery

R1

3:30 p.m.

role of the parties responsible for data man-


The ASM consists of ex-ante ASM and balancing market.

3:00 p.m.

2:00 p.m. agement by introducing a common euro-


1:00 p.m. pean data format (some stakeholders suggest
making the existing national data models
IM1
IM2

12:55 p.m.
R1

12:00 Noon simply compatible rather than harmonized).


11:00 a.m. these new trends call for measures that tar-
10:00 a.m. get the data-management solutions’ scal-
9:00 a.m.
ability issues as they relate to iot and big
data applications.
8:00 a.m.
into/from the grid in real time.

several r&i projects, which often


7:00 a.m.

rely on the expanded common infor-


6:00 a.m.

5:00 a.m.

4:00 a.m.
mation model, study new digitization
3:00 a.m. solutions, including improved distribu-
2:00 a.m. tion grid observability and control solu-
1:00 a.m. tions (upgrid); a nondiscriminatory,
00:00 data-sharing platform for cross-eu data
exchange (FleXiciency); and a neutral
Nine Days

11:59 p.m.
Delivery

Note:
Before

market hub and common data platform for


DAM

8:00 a.m.
islanded energy management (upgrid
and netFFicient).

62 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


Flexibility may become the glue between the wholesale a significant influence on the design and management of the
and retail markets, and the overall benefits may grow when the electrical system. For this reason, strategies should be devel-
balancing and congestion-management tasks (for the most part oped between the different sectors to stimulate joint invest-
currently under the tsos’ control) are shared with the dsos ments and coherence in regulatory frameworks.
or other regulated and nonregulated market parties. demand several r&i projects include multiple electricity, gas,
response is one of these flexibility resources, and attention to water, heating and cooling systems, and different end-use
this technology is increasing in europe, although its deploy- sectors. some projects try to optimize heterogeneous energy
ment is scattered across the Mss. systems, including storage and renewable energy (smiles),
several r&i projects (see Figure 8 for the demand-side man- while others test integrated management platforms acting on
agement investments within the smart grid projects) investigate different energy carriers (pentagon).
new market schemes, including a third-party market operator
(sMartnet), the interplay of demand response with other Electricity End-User
flexibility resources (ecogrid and interFleX) and novel and Retail Market Challenges
prosumer’s flexibility concepts (FleX4grid). dynamic pricing entails passing a portion of the wholesale
the cep streamlines the procedure for expanding net- volatility to retail consumers. the cep entitles every cus-
work codes (and guidelines) from the transmission/wholesale tomer to a dynamic electricity price contract, which reflects
level down to the transmission/distribution interfaces and the “wholesale prices at intervals at least equal to the market
distribution/retail system. the standards for the future power settlement frequency.” dynamic pricing will only work if
grids are being developed based on the smart grids archi- wholesale markets become more efficient, detailed metered
tecture Model framework. data (ideally referring to each individual customer) are avail-
standardization and interoperability requirements are able, pricing intervals are small enough, and pricing options
tested in r&i projects on virtual power plant participation are carefully designed.
with wholesale/intraday markets (smartereMc2) and neigh- some players suggest not only intervening on the energy
borhood involvement in energy/flexibility markets (cooper- and supply component but also on the other two components
ate), whereas other projects (internet ppp and Finesce) (the network component and the component comprising taxes,
are demonstrating the value of open-source cloud platforms for levies, fees, and charges), which are not energy related, to make
the development of smart applications in multiple sectors. them more variable with the wholesale market dynamics.
necessary interactions between wider energy systems (such several r&i projects are studying how time-varying prices
as gas, heating, and cooling subsystems) and sectors (such as can shift consumption patterns in intelligently automated
information and communications technologies, transportation, households (linear) or how dynamic pricing can reduce
home automation, water, health, finances, and food) will have congestion problems and curtailment needs (goFleX).

250
Total
200 Private
206.9
Investment (€ Million)

150
158.1

144.3
140.4

137.2

133.2

100
106.7

37.3
85

82.2

31.1
78.9

26.8

25.5
73.8

73.2

50
70.6

15.1

14.2

14.8
13.8
24

12.4
54.2
42.1

48.8
43.5

6.8

7.1
28

0
Distribution System
Operator
ICT Company and
Telecom

University

Technology
Manufacturer

Consultancy

Research Center

Retail Company

Public Institution

Utility

Emerging Stakeholder

Other

Generation Company

Industry Association

Transmission System
Operator
Engineering Services

figure 8. The demand-side management investment in smart grid projects, per organizational type. ICT: information and
communications technology. (From the European Commission Joint Research Centre.)

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 63


During times of constrained economic development, vulnerable
consumers—as opposed to the average household consumers—
end up being the most affected by price spikes.

the cep fosters a fair and cost-reflective consumer interac- consumers) need to be carefully assessed. several r&i proj-
tion with the energy markets via improved billing information, ects address socioregulatory aspects by testing the consumer
certified price-comparison tools, an easier choice of suppliers/ response to information on renewable energy availability (e.g.,
aggregators, the possibility to self-generate, the entitlement to nicegrid) and adopt social comparison strategies for individual
a dynamic price contract, and the installation of a smart meter. user engagement (e.g., intrepid and 3e-Houses).
consumer protection also entails defining clear conditions of ter- local energy communities that manage distribution
mination, duration, price, and the conditions of switching suppli- resources, infrastructure, and services are defined by the
ers. decision makers will need to strike a balance between avoid- cep and open the door to many services and business oppor-
ing situations in which simple consumers pay for the benefits of tunities. they differ from profit-driven energy companies in
the prosumers and that of rewarding active consumers/inves- their value-creation motivation and are entitled to own, estab-
tors who deliver local/systemic benefits to the energy system lish, or lease community networks and autonomously man-
(i.e., via their flexibility potentials). age them. they are expected to access all organized markets,
social acceptance issues as well as the perception of lim- either directly or through aggregators or suppliers.
ited savings out of demand response practices may persist. the regulatory challenge is to reconcile the development of
consumers must be protected from both current actors large energy communities with the reliable and secure opera-
and emerging aggregators, and the benefits/risks linked to tion of the power system. to this end, roles and responsibilities
price volatility with dynamic pricing schemes need to of existing and emerging actors need to be clarified and recon-
be properly explained. Fair and cost-reflective network ciled in a number of areas, including micro-grid management,
charges shall also be applied to users who do not support/ service quality, and flexibility services. How does one ensure
belong to the local energy community but are connected that all of the parties will bear a proportionate cost compared
to the grid operated by such a community. aspects to be to the benefits? an issue for debate involves the payment of
clarified include the definition of cost reflectiveness as well imbalance-induced compensation by the aggregators to the
as the calculation methodologies used for consumer net- suppliers, thus balancing all responsible parties or generators.
work charges and the supplier’s economic loss caused by How small should those payments be to encourage the market
customers switching suppliers, the reward models used for participation of demand response also through the aggrega-
the active participation of citizens/communities in retail tors? How big should they be to ensure that balancing costs
markets, the consumption and generation of measurement and benefits induced by the aggregators are fairly assigned to
modalities, and the merits used for revisiting net-metering/ market participants?
billing practices. examples of r&i pilot studies include market-based energy
the cep reviews the “duly justified exceptions,” which are services and technological solutions for local energy commu-
typically linked to energy, poverty, and vulnerability, and allows nities and smart houses (eMpoWer and smartHouse/smart-
regulators to deviate from market-based retail prices. it also grid), schemes to help dsos operate their grid with higher
makes the public service obligations that Mss may impose on penetration of renewables, and interaction with commer-
energy undertakings more transparent and nondiscriminatory. cial aggregators (Wisegrid and ide4l).
during times of constrained economic development, vul-
nerable consumers—as opposed to the average household Electricity Wholesale Market Challenges
consumers—end up being the most affected by price spikes. the challenges that lie ahead for the european power sys-
consistent definitions of energy poverty and vulnerability are tem, as addressed in the cep, have the wholesale electricity
still absent. eu Mss identify vulnerable consumers by several market at the core of all the main policy objectives, such as
characteristics that may overlap or extend well beyond their decarbonizing the eu energy system, taking stock of tech-
relationships with the power system, including income, age, nology innovations, and further integrating the eu national/
health, social protection, and security. at times, this renders regional energy markets while ensuring competition and
consumer eligibility difficulty to ascertain. cooperation across borders at every relevant timescale.
solutions shall be implemented that enable consumers who While much progress has been made on power transmission
are vulnerable or experience energy poverty to participate in local and the role of the tsos courtesy of the third energy pack-
energy communities. Moreover, the effects of dynamic pricing age, completing the internal energy market remains one of
on certain household categories (i.e., large families or vulnerable the top political priorities of the ec’s current agenda.

64 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


a nondistortive electricity market will be crucial not only an open-minded approach in its cep package, which allows
to guarantee the fair treatment of european consumers, pro- the combination of both tools. nevertheless, given the unclear
ducers and prosumers but also to provide clear investment organization of the future internal energy market, especially
signals, i.e., to install adequate generation capacity to meet for near real-time markets (i.e., intraday, balancing, reserves,
future demand and enough network capacity to ensure there and ancillary services), in which a large variety of models cur-
is sufficient transmission capacity to reduce price discrepan- rently exist across the eu, it is important to assess the interplay
cies across all regions. in fact, the eu has chosen a “regional” among various tools and schemes in each specific situation.
approach to european energy policies, i.e., most of the elec- the transition toward a single, integrated european mar-
tricity system and market aspects are addressed via aggrega- ket (ieM) will surely help as well by allowing more and
tions of bordering countries, named regions. an appropriate more cross-border exchanges of balancing services. to guar-
and coherent governance of the interplay between regions, antee nondiscrimination, all of these mechanisms should be
control areas under the tsos’ responsibility, and scheduling applied regardless of the country in which a generator is
areas is needed to ensure coordination. located by considering its contribution to regional or conti-
as mentioned previously, the impact of policy challenges nental power system stability.
on the reliability of power systems is not yet clear since the an appropriate market design is likely to be the most
policy that encourages typically intermittent and decentral- important factor in achieving a single european power mar-
ized ress also increases the complexity of guaranteeing ket in the future. the first logical steps are improving the
system stability. additionally, specific markets that remuner- existing framework guidelines of the cacM regulation. the
ate reliability services (e.g., asMs, balancing, and reserves) cacM regulation represents a key moment for europe’s integra-
remain fairly underdeveloped in europe. tion of electricity markets; however, the capacity calculation
to guarantee adequacy throughout europe, the cep has and allocation principles described within it represent only the
introduced new tools such as scarcity pricing and capacity- first step and do not provide a univocal solution to europe’s
remuneration mechanisms. scarcity pricing refers to the mecha- capacity-calculation problem.
nism used for price formation in electricity markets, especially one of the most important features of capacity calcula-
those closest to real time (e.g., balancing, reserves, and ancil- tions in europe is the choice of a zonal model. Zones can
lary services provisions). indeed, it might seem like a redundant be effective nodes (similar to those in italy) or countries.
definition, since, in perfectly competitive markets, price-forma- redispatching/countertrading is carried out by tsos at the
tion mechanisms are exclusively driven by demand and supply; national level at a considerable cost, especially for eu coun-
therefore, prices reflect conditions of scarcity of supply. tries that chose the one-zone/one-country solution.
Forward markets and daMs are those in which the bulk capacity calculation is strongly intertwined with energy
of electricity is traded, so the remuneration of investments for trading. the alternative locational marginal pricing for
many generators depends on the prices determined in these energy, which also takes into account the available transmis-
market segments. as non-res generators will be less remu- sion capacity from/to each node, has been put on hold in favor
nerated in the daMs due to the market price decline (i.e., the of an intermediate solution, such as zones. there are three
missing money problem), and as the share of ress in genera- main reasons for using zones.
tion increase, the adequacy issue is expected to worsen. 1) nodal pricing is computationally burdensome; there-
the cep marks a mind-set shift in regarding temporary fore, it would be impossible to calculate the market
price spikes in the future that may not be due to mere specu- equilibrium for all of europe at the same time. this ar-
lation but, rather, due to scarcity pricing, i.e., a way to remu- gument is refuted by the existence of nodal pricing in
nerate the provision of electricity when the balance between large markets, such as the pjM in the united states. so,
demand and supply is tight so that the investors who have in the future, it will certainly be possible to run a nodal
built plants that play a key role in “keeping the lights on” are european market that manages all of the high-voltage
compensated enough to stay in the market. nodes in the grid.
as mentioned by the scholars who have addressed the 2) nodal pricing and zonal pricing with small zones hinder
topic, continuous market monitoring must be ensured and is competition; therefore, generators have access to all of
provided for in the eu courtesy of the regulation on whole- the nodes/zones, but their electricity is “weighted” by the
sale energy market integrity and transparency. scarcity pric- network costs necessary to deliver it to each node. nodal
ing is not enough to address the adequacy problem, however, pricing will likely increase competitiveness by providing
which is why the cep also provides for capacity remunera- optimal investment signals in the medium/long term.
tion mechanisms, i.e., state subsidies to generators who play 3) optimal bidding zones are substantially equivalent to
a key role in keeping the power system running. nodal pricing. unfortunately, optimal bidding zones
state subsidies tackle the longer-term perspective of ade- do not exist and cannot be drawn beforehand. efficient
quacy, but scarcity pricing in the short/medium term might market zones must be time variant and rely only on
help in correcting unwanted distortions arising from capac- the pure physics of the transmission grid because the
ity remuneration mechanisms. in this sense, the eu has taken power flow varies over time.

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 65


an appropriate capacity calculation that is consistent with a major regulatory challenge is to reconcile the stability
the features of the european transmission grid will allow the of the legal framework with the rapidity to react to the
expected benefits of transnational infrastructure projects— pace of innovation. in future scenarios, predictably flexible
e.g., the projects of common interest—to be assessed in a truly regulations should enable market players to assess the prof-
impartial way. itability of investments through meaningful prices. Flexibil-
Market liquidity is crucial to delivering electricity efficiently; ity and resilience, as much as in the power system, surface
if generators, consumers, and prosumers do not take part in the as must-have attributes in legislators’ quest for social wel-
market, the price formation in that market will not reflect the real fare maximization.
conditions of the energy system. Because liquidity in eu power
markets is still relatively low, regulatory initiatives that ensure suf- Acknowledgments
ficient participation in organized markets (versus over-the-counter the authors are thankful to joint research centre colleagues
contracts) are fundamental to allowing power markets to deliver. alexis Meletiou and Mircea ardelean for their comments
another missing piece of regulatory action that would help and map production.
achieve a fully efficient ieM concerns coordinating differ-
ent markets during different time frames. For the allocation For Further Reading
(market-based auctions for forward and daMs, continuous european commission. Market legislation. accessed on nov.
trading for iMs) and entitlement methods to occur in markets 13, 2018. [online]. available: https://ec.europa.eu/energy/en/
closer to real time, an effort toward substantial harmoniza- topics/markets-and-consumers/market-legislation
tion may prove useful. such a lack of harmonization may give agency for the cooperation of energy regulators. Mar-
rise to market manipulation by the most important operators, ket monitoring. accessed on nov. 13, 2018. [online]. avail-
which would optimize their profit arbitraging between mar- able: http://www.acer.europa.eu/en/electricity/market%20
kets, i.e., the relatively important generators may decide to monitoring/pages/default.aspx
withdraw capacity from the daM to bid only on the more european commission. (2016). clean energy for all eu-
lucrative, closer-to-real-time balancing and iM markets. ropeans proposal. [online]. available: https://ec.europa.eu/
energy/en/news/commission-proposes-new-rules-consumer-
Regulation and Innovation centred-clean-energy-transition
Interplay in Future Markets g. Fulli, M. Masera, c. F. covrig, F. profumo, e. Bom-
if energy markets are to remain the instruments that enable pard, and t. Huang, “the eu electricity security decision-
long-term policy and innovation initiatives, new regulatory analytic framework: status and perspective developments,
arrangements are needed to reconcile the security and com- energies,” Energies, vol. 10, no. 4, p. 425, Mar. 2017. doi:
petitiveness of sustainable solutions. promising reforms are 10.3390/en10040425.
outlined (e.g., in the electricity market time and spatial scales), e. Bompard, g. Fulli, M. ardelean, M. Masera, “it’s a bird,
with the objective of properly distributing costs and benefits it’s a plane, it’s a…supergrid!” IEEE Power Energy Mag., vol.
among current and emerging actors. However, several aspects 12, no. 2, pp. 40–50, Mar.–apr. 2014.
and interfaces must be properly understood to govern the evo- F. gangale, j. Vasiljevska, c. F. covrig, a. Mengolini, g.
lution of the electricity delivery options and services. legisla- Fulli, “smart grid projects outlook,” european commission,
tors and regulators must address a series of pressing questions. luxembourg: publications office of the european union, 2017.
1) How are business cases across interlinked energy and doi: 10.2760/701587.
nonenergy system configurations identified? j.-M. glachant and s. ruester, “the eu internal electric-
2) How is the balance between technology push and mar- ity market: done forever?” Utilities Policy, vol. 30, pp. 1–7,
ket pull toward a fair energy transition designed? sept. 2014. doi: 10.1016/j.jup.2014.05.003.
3) How can private investors convert publicly supported l. Wu, M. shahidehpour, and t. li, “cost of reliability
innovation into marketable products? analysis based on stochastic unit commitment,” IEEE Trans.
4) to what extent can emerging sociopolitical and tech- Power Syst., vol. 23, no. 8, pp. 1364–1374, 2008.
nological trends subvert the wholesale transmission
and retail distribution boundaries and equilibria? Biographies
With this in mind, the eu and national decision makers are Gianluca Fulli is with the european commission joint re-
making efforts to combine energy and climate change policy search centre, ispra, italy.
actions with other proposals linked to, among others, digital Marcelo Masera is with the european commission joint
markets, circular economy innovation agendas, and capital research centre, petten, the netherlands.
market/investment plans. large-scale and multidisci- Amanda Spisto is with the european commission joint
plinary pilots that target integrated architectures, interoper- research centre, petten, the netherlands.
able applications, and harmonized standards are still needed Silvia Vitiello is with the european commission joint
to test the merits and challenges of those potentially converg- research centre, ispra, italy.
p&e
ing initiatives.

66 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


By Emma Nicholson and Arnie Quinn

I
In thIs artIcle, we gIve
our view of how the U.s. Federal
energy regulatory commission
(Ferc) typically approaches mar-
ket design issues in jurisdictional
wholesale electricity markets in
the United states and identify
three challenges that lie ahead for
these markets. the first challenge
is declining prices in wholesale
electric energy markets, which
can lead to revenue adequacy
issues for some resources. the
second challenge is to ensure that
wholesale electricity markets give
investors the proper incentives to
invest in resources that have the
operational flexibility needed to

©istockphoto.com/nazarkru

Wholesale Identifying Future


Challenges Facing

Electricity
Commercial Energy

Markets in the
United States
Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/MPE.2018.2872304
Date of publication: 7 January 2019

january/february 2019 1540-7977/19©2019IEEE ieee power & energy magazine 67


One key advantage of RTO/ISO markets is the transparency
of market outcomes and the operational decisions that
drive those outcomes.

serve more variable net loads in the future. the third chal- issued a rule to more effectively integrate electric storage
lenge is the interdependence between the natural gas and elec- resources into rtO/IsO markets.
tric industries, which has implications for reliability. as former federal regulators, we are cognizant that
actions by Ferc to require market design changes will result
FERC Background in changes to rtO/IsO priorities. a Ferc-mandated change
Ferc has many responsibilities as a federal regulator, but the can crowd out or delay other market design changes. that
most pertinent to this article is its role as the regulator of the said, some market design changes require Ferc leadership
interstate transmission and sale of wholesale electricity for to be appropriately prioritized. For instance, market design
resale. this role involves reviewing and approving the market changes that have the potential to create clear winners and
rules of six jurisdictional wholesale electricity markets in the losers (e.g., cost allocation issues) may not be amenable to
United states and ensuring that the resulting wholesale rates a stakeholder-driven process typically used to advise rtO/
in those markets are just and reasonable. Many areas related IsO-sponsored market design changes. Ferc can play a role
to electricity service in the United states lie outside of Ferc’s in ensuring that such market design changes are adopted if
jurisdiction and within the purview of state public utility com- the status quo results in unjust or unreasonable rates.
missions; this includes, but is not limited to, the regulation of a variety of factors are relevant when deciding where and
retail electric and natural gas rates, the approval of the con- how to act. at the highest level, a market design ideally creates
struction of electric generation facilities, and overseeing reli- incentives for resources to meet system needs during the oper-
ability issues related to electric distribution systems. ating horizon and invest in enhanced performance during the
the six Ferc jurisdictional wholesale electricity mar- planning horizon. Furthermore, one key advantage of rtO/
kets in the United states are IsO markets is the transparency of market outcomes and the
✔ california Independent system Operator corporation operational decisions that drive those outcomes. Ideally, mar-
(caIsO) ket design changes enhance rather than introduce regulatory
✔ Midconti nent Independent system Operator, Inc. certainty and remain robust under a variety of future condi-
(MIsO) tions. this can mean initiating action when a trend is emerg-
✔ IsO new england, Inc. (IsO-ne) ing but before it has a material impact on market outcomes in
✔ new York Independent system Operator, Inc. (nYIsO) rtOs/IsOs. Finally, one needs to consider the complexity of
✔ PJM Interconnection, llc (PJM) any proposed market design. rtO/IsO markets are inherently
✔ southwest Power Pool, Inc. (sPP). complex, which has the potential to make it more difficult for
these markets are operated by regional transmission orga- market participants to understand market outcomes and asso-
nizations (rtOs) and independent system operators (IsOs). ciated value propositions. It can also make it more difficult for
Ferc approves the rules of the markets operated by the six rtOs/IsOs, regulators, and stakeholders to evaluate how well
jurisdictional rtOs/IsOs, which include markets for energy, a particular market design is functioning.
ancillary services, capacity, and financial transmission rights. On the basis of our experience, generic actions directed
all six operate energy, ancillary services, and financial trans- by Ferc are based on a methodical and evidence-based
mission rights markets, but only four (IsO-ne, MIsO, nYIsO, approach to address rtO/IsO market design issues. we view
and PJM) operate centralized capacity markets. this as a three-step approach:
Ferc has historically promoted market-based outcomes 1) define a problem
for wholesale electricity on the grounds that competition is 2) develop and analyze record evidence
a means to create just and reasonable rates. For example, in 3) identify a just and reasonable solution.
1996, Ferc issued Order 888, which promoted competition Ferc often uses this approach when it proposes new rule-
through open-access nondiscriminatory transmission ser- making, which may result in a final rule, and when it investi-
vices. In 1999, Ferc issued Order 2000, which advanced the gates market design issues in other proceedings.
formation of rtOs/IsOs and codified their minimum char- the problem definition step is critical because it lays the
acteristics and functions. Ferc is also in a unique position foundation for the inquiry that occurs in step two and the sub-
to identify market design issues across rtOs/IsOs, such as sequent solution in step three. the second step is to develop
barriers and inefficiencies that may arise with new resource a record of evidence that the commission will rely upon in
or technology types. For example, in February 2018, Ferc its decision making. rtO/IsO stakeholders (e.g., rtO/IsO

68 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


management and staff, state governments, load-serving enti- fast-start resources, commitments to manage multiple contin-
ties, resource owners, transmission owners, public power gencies, look-ahead modeling, uplift allocation, and transpar-
systems, power marketers, consumer advocates, advocacy ency. rtO/IsO stakeholders were also invited to comment on
groups, and trade associations) contribute to this record, often these rtO/IsO reports. Ferc relied on the record developed
based on targeted questions from Ferc and/or through par- in the price formation proceeding to issue four proposed rules.
ticipation in technical conferences. the initial stages of the two of these rules have since become final (settlement inter-
record development process are designed to keep it focused vals and shortage pricing and offer caps). Both of the final rules
on the identified problem and identify potential solutions and required uniform changes across the rtOs/IsOs while allow-
their associated tradeoffs. the analysis of the record devel- ing for some regional flexibility on implementation so that
oped in the initial stages of a proceeding is intended to deter- changes were consistent with other marker design elements.
mine whether the problem results in unjust and unreasonable Ferc decided not to finalize a proposed rule on fast-start pric-
rates and, if so, to weigh the merits of the potential solutions ing, choosing instead to permit regional variation. Ferc has
and select a proposed just and reasonable solution based on yet to act on the fourth proposed rule (uplift and transparency).
the record evidence. It is important to note that Ferc must
follow an administrative process after identifying a proposed Our View of the Market Design
solution to provide notice of a potential change. this admin- Challenges Ahead for RTOs/ISOs
istrative process serves to gather additional record evidence the first challenge rtOs/IsOs in the United states will face in
that will support any final action to adopt the proposed solu- the future is declining revenues in energy and ancillary services
tion. we believe this approach helps leverage the expertise of markets because of low natural gas prices, a higher penetration
market participants and other stakeholders to develop rtO/ of resources that have low or zero marginal cost, and demand-
IsO market rules that produce just and reasonable rates and side investments to reduce peak load in response to high prices.
change or refine those rules if the record evidence suggest given these trends, locational marginal prices (lMPs) in some
that changes are warranted. rtOs/IsOs are at historic lows when viewed on an average
One consideration when evaluating a potential solution is annual basis. Figure 1, prepared by the U.s. Department of
the degree to which that solution should be generic or provide energy, plots electricity prices in both rtOs/IsOs and non-
for regional flexibility. Ferc has long held that there can be rtO/IsO regions and shows the extent to which these prices
a variety of just and reasonable rtO/IsO market designs. have fallen in recent years. It also compares those prices to the
Furthermore, various regions have different resource mixes, natural gas price at henry hub (an important national bench-
state regulatory structures, and institutional history that may mark for the U.s. natural gas market).
affect the need for a market design change and regional flex- low wholesale energy prices are good for the U.s. econ-
ibility in developing potential solutions. while regional flex- omy, and rtO/IsO markets have been successful in translating
ibility is often warranted, several factors can suggest when these energy market trends into savings for electricity custom-
more uniform market designs are appropriate, such as when ers in their respective footprints. however, these trends are
regional flexibility could create or exacerbate seams between likely to change the way that some resources recover their
rtOs/IsOs or between an rtO/IsO and a non-rtO/IsO costs because, in the past, many resources recovered a por-
region. In addition, uniform market designs have an advan- tion of their costs through inframarginal rents in rtO/IsO
tage relative to regional flexibility when one considers that energy markets. these inframarginal rents have declined over
participants have to understand a variety of market designs time as lMPs have declined. Other revenue streams—such as
when regional flexibility is permitted. ancillary services and capacity market revenues—may need
Ferc’s price formation effort is a recent example of this to play a larger role in ensuring that the resources needed to
three-step approach (Docket aD14-14-000). In the price for- provide reliable electric service to load have the proper incen-
mation effort, the commission examined price formation in tives to provide this service. a challenge in addressing this
rtO/IsO energy and ancillary services markets in four areas: issue is differentiating between market fundamentals and
1) the use of uplift payments underlying concerns with rtO/IsO market designs in a low
2) offer price mitigation and offer price caps lMP environment.
3) scarcity and shortage pricing It is often instructive to examine rtO/IsO market design
4) operator actions that affect price. issues in a mechanism design framework, which requires a clear
as part of this effort, in 2014, Ferc staff wrote four techni- objective and a set of payments and penalties designed to maxi-
cal papers and held three technical conferences to discuss mize that objective in light of market participant incentives. For
these price formation issues. example, in IsO-ne, MIsO, nYIsO, and PJM, capacity mar-
to better define potential price formation problems in ket revenues are designed to recover the going-forward costs
rtO/IsO energy and ancillary services markets, Ferc issued of the resources needed to provide resource adequacy net of
a request for comments after the technical conferences that energy and ancillary services revenues. accordingly, if lMPs
asked several detailed questions. Ferc also issued an order decline, capacity prices in these rtOs/IsOs are generally
directing rtOs/IsOs to submit reports about the pricing of expected to increase. however, a fixed annual payment in the

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 69


capacity market may mute the incentives resources have to per- dispatchable range), or having a low or zero minimum operat-
form during the delivery period (typically one calendar year). It ing level. a single resource need not possess each dimension
may be appropriate to revise resource compensation, add new of flexibility. In the future, rtOs/IsOs will need to design
performance requirements, or develop new rtO/IsO products markets to ensure that sufficient investments occurs and that
to enhance the performance signal. they yield the rtO/IsO’s desired levels of flexibility.
a second challenge rtOs/IsOs in the United states will some rtOs/IsOs have market designs that explicitly
face is the need to replace installed generation capacity that procure and value resource flexibility. For example, the flex-
retires with new generation assets with the flexible operat- ible resource adequacy requirement in caIsO, which is
ing characteristics needed to serve net load (i.e., load minus necessitated by the california Public Utilities commission’s
distributed resource output) at least cost. this turnover could resource adequacy program, specifies that some capacity
be quite considerable in rtOs/IsOs that have a significant resources have flexible capability. additionally, both caIsO
amount of capacity at or near retirement age. and MIsO explicitly value flexibility within their energy
net load is expected to be more volatile in the future as markets; MIsO has a ramp capability product, and caIsO
rtOs/IsOs integrate more distributed energy resources and has a flexible ramping product. these products are designed
loads invest in equipment that enables them to be more price to procure ramp capability based on the system’s expected
responsive to wholesale electricity prices. the resulting net needs in future intervals. without a ramping product, rtOs/
load profiles will likely change the optimal mix of resources IsOs may need to take out-of-market actions to posture
that rtOs/IsOs will need to meet their respective reserve resources available to provide ramping capability in future
requirements and balance the system in real time. For exam- periods. the creation of a ramping product is one way to
ple, as shown in Figure 2, wind resources were the marginal move out-of-market actions into the market and reflect the
resource, and thus set the energy price, in the sPP about 10% system need in prices.
of the time, on average. a future challenge will be determining which market
while lower load growth and more price-responsive (energy, ancillary services, or capacity, or some combina-
loads are likely to reduce expected peak load, which will tion thereof) should provide the incentives for and compen-
reduce the capacity needed for resource adequacy planning sate the resource attributes that will be needed in the future.
purposes, new generation assets will be needed, and some an important consideration is whether short-term compen-
of that capacity will have to be more flexible. resource flex- sation for flexibility will be sufficient to drive long-term
ibility can be measured in several dimensions, including the investments that enhance a resource’s flexibility. If multiple
ability to start up quickly (e.g., a fast-start unit that can start markets are needed, market design changes may be needed
up within 10 min), the ability to get offline quickly (i.e., short to improve coordination in such markets to avoid over-
minimum run time), a quick ramp rate (having a fairly wide or undercompensation.

New
England

Midwest New York


140 14 West
Mid-Atlantic
CAISO+ Central
120 12
Natural Gas Price (US$/MMBtu)
Electricity Prices (US$/MWh)

Southeast
100 10
ERCOT

80 8

60 6 New England (ISO-NE Mass Hub)


New York (NYISO NYC Zone J)
40 4 Mid-Atlantic (PJM Western Hub)
Midwest (MISO Indiana Hub)
20 2 Central (SPP South Hub)
ERCOT (ERCOT North Hub)
0 0 CAISO+ (CAISO SP15)
2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 2014 2016 Northwest (Mid-Columbia)
Henry Hub Natural Gas Price

figure 1. The average wholesale electric costs between 2002 and 2016. (Source: U.S. Department of Energy, “Staff
Report to the Secretary on Electricity Markets and Reliability,” Figure 6.2.)

70 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


100

80
Intervals on the Margin (%)

60

40

20

0
Dec. Jan. Feb. Mar. Apr. May June July Aug. Sept. Oct. Nov. Dec. Jan. Feb. 2016 2017 2018
2016 2017 2017 2017 2017 2017 2017 2017 2017 2017 2017 2017 2017 2018 2018 Winter

Other Gas, Simple Cycle Gas, Combined Cycle Coal Wind

figure 2. The SPP generation technology on the margin in the real-time electricity market. (Source: SPP Market Monitor-
ing Unit, “Winter 2018 State of the Market Report,” Figure 3-7, used with permission.)

a third challenge facing U.s. rtO/IsO markets today and


in the future is coordinating the operation of the interstate 1,600
natural gas pipeline system with the needs of natural gas- 1,400
Terawatt Hours (TWh)

fired generators, known as gas-electric coordination. this 1,200


issue will become increasingly important as the generation 1,000
fleet in rtOs/IsOs shifts toward natural gas-fired generation
800
resources. Figure 3 plots the U.s. energy Information admin-
600
istration’s reference case forecast of net generation from coal,
400
natural gas, nuclear, and renewable generation resources. nat- Coal Natural Gas
200 Nuclear Renewable
ural gas generation is expected to increase significantly.
Poor gas-electric coordination can place stress on certain 0
16
19
22
25
28
31
34
37
40
43
46
rtO/IsO markets in the northeastern United states, particu- 49
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20
20

larly during extreme cold winter weather. natural gas gen-


erators in rtOs/IsOs often rely on interruptible natural gas figure 3. The U.S. Energy Information Administration’s 2018
transportation delivery contracts as opposed to firm delivery annual energy outlook reference case forecast of net genera-
ones because sufficient capacity is typically available to serve tion from coal, natural gas, nuclear, and renewable resourc-
the needs of both a firm and the interruptible customers on es. (Source: U.S. Department of Energy, “Energy Information
interstate pipelines. however, during the winter months, when Administration, 2018 Annual Energy Outlook, Reference
natural gas supplies are needed to serve both thermal heating Case Electricity Supply, Disposition, Prices, and Emissions.”)
loads and natural gas generators, the interstate natural pipeline
system can become constrained and unable to meet demand
beyond firm commitments, which can threaten an rtO/IsO processes on interstate natural gas pipelines and public utilities
market’s ability to provide reliable electric service. as shown (Docket rM14-2-000). to some extent, gas-electric coordina-
in Figure 4, the north american electric reliability corpora- tion presents many of the same issues as resource flexibility.
tion identified clusters of natural gas generators that would be when concerns about the availability of natural gas are most
susceptible to a natural gas supply disruption. acute, rtOs/IsOs may take out-of-market action to be pre-
Ferc has been investigating gas-electric coordination issues pared to respond if natural gas-fired resources are not avail-
since 2012 when Ferc held a technical conference on the mat- able. Ideally, these out-of-market actions would be moved into
ter (Docket aD12-12-000). after examining the record devel- the market, for instance through performance penalties or new
oped in the gas-electric coordination proceeding, Ferc issued reserve products. like flexibility, an important consideration is
Order 809 in april 2015 that better coordinated the scheduling what form of compensation will be sufficient to drive long-term

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 71


Northwest New England
25 GW, 2016 11 GW, 2016
4 GW, Planned 5 GW, Planned

Mid-Atlantic
≤50 MW 96 GW, 2016
>50 MW 50 GW, Planned
>100 MW
>200 MW
>400 MW

South CA-AZ East TX-OK-LA Southeast Florida


60 GW, 2016 60 GW, 2016 55 GW, 2016 38 GW, 2016
17 GW, Planned 17 GW, Planned 7 GW, Planned 5 GW, Planned

figure 4. The North American Electric Reliability Corporation-identified natural gas generation clusters of at least 2 GW
that are vulnerable to a natural gas supply disruption. (Source: North American Electric Reliability Corporation, “Special
Reliability Assessment: Potential Bulk Power System Impacts due to Severe Disruptions on the Natural Gas System,”
Figure 5.1. This information from the North American Electric Reliability Corporation’s website is the property of the
North American Electric Reliability Corporation.)

investments that match the value consumers place on avoiding energy, washington, D.c., aug. 2017. [Online]. avail-
the operational or cost concerns associated with the lack of natu- able: https://www.energy.gov/sites/prod/files/2017/08/f36/
ral gas-fired generation. resolving this issue will also require staff%20report%20on%20electricity%20Markets%20
Ferc, rtOs/IsOs, and other stakeholders to develop solutions and%20reliability_0.pdf
that both preserve reliability while at the same time minimizing energy Information administration, “2018 annual energy
the costs to consumers in rtOs/IsOs. outlook,” U.s. Department of energy, washington, D.c., Feb.
2018. [Online]. available: http://www.eia.gov/outlooks/aeo
Acknowledgments north american electric reliability corporation, “spe-
the opinions and views offered here are those of the authors, cial reliability assessment: Potential bulk power system im-
and not necessarily those of the United states, the Federal pacts due to severe disruptions on the natural gas system,”
energy regulatory commission, the individual commis- north american electric reliability corporation, atlanta,
sioners, or members of the commission staff. ga, nov. 2017. [Online]. available: httpps://www.nerc.com/
pa/raPa/ra/reliability%20assessments%20Dl/nerc_
For Further Reading sPOD_11142017_Final.pdf
Federal energy regulatory commission, “electric storage par-
ticipation in markets operated by regional transmission organiza- Biographies
tions and independent system operators,” Federal energy regu- Emma Nicholson is with the concentric energy advisors,
latory commission, washington, D.c., Order 841, Feb. 15, 2018. Inc., washington, D.c.
U.s. Department of energy, “staff report to the secretary Arnie Quinn is with vistra energy, washington, D.c.
p&e
on electricity markets and reliability,” U.s. Department of

72 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


Demand-Side,
Renewable,
Economic and Distributed
Efficiency and Resources
Debunking Incremental
the Natural Improvements
Monopoly Myth

By Benjamin F. Hobbs
and Shmuel S. Oren
©istockphoto.com/siberianart

Three Waves of
U.S. Reforms
N
New geNeratioN, storage, demaNd maNagemeNt, aNd smart
Following grid technologies have the potential to make the grid of 2050 very different from
today’s power system. Can market designers keep up, and what do they need
the Path of to pay attention to now? Before offering a few answers to these questions, we first
give some historical perspective on the creation of markets for electric power and
Wholesale how those markets have been adapted to new needs.
the power industry is now undergoing dramatic changes, following many
Electricity transitions that we have already experienced. in the 1960s, nearly all power was
provided by vertically integrated utilities. they confidently planned ever-larger
Market coal and nuclear generators (including floating nuclear plants), whose prudently
incurred costs would be guaranteed by ratepayers. at least one industry group
Restructuring concluded that its greatest environmental challenge was the ugliness of overhead
distribution lines; climate change meant global cooling and was irrelevant to plan-
ners and regulators.
all of that has now changed beyond recognition in most (but not all) of the
world. Future changes in the industry will differ in type but not in magnitude
Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/MPE.2018.2873952
from those past changes. if market designs adhere to the principles of open access,
Date of publication: 7 January 2019 technology neutrality, recognition of network realities, and financial rewards for

january/february 2019 1540-7977/19©2019IEEE ieee power & energy magazine 73


providing what the system really needs when and where it the right amount, type, and place of generation capacity and
needs it, then the power system will be well placed to adapt even transmission (schweppe et al., 1988). a great irony is that
to whatever technology and social changes are coming. schweppe first proposed that this be used to motivate consum-
ers to modify their behavior; only later was this idea extended
The First Wave of Reforms: to supply. the irony is that, in today’s markets, the demand
Unbundling and Debunking the side of the market remains largely insulated from prices that
Natural Monopoly Myth reflect actual system conditions in time and space. mean-
the first introduction of competition into the electric power while, schweppe’s mit colleagues Paul Joskow and richard
sector of the U.s. economy is often attributed to the 1978 schmalensee (1983) described how institutions could be
Public Utilities regulatory Policy act (PUrPa). that act defined to promote competition in distribution, transmission,
required electric utilities, which were most commonly verti- and especially generation.
cally integrated monopolies within their service territories, to But it was not the earlier examples of competition or the
buy power produced by small (lower than 50 mw) and renew- intellectual frameworks proposed by schweppe et al. that
able power sources. were chiefly responsible for spurring the U.s. restructuring
PUrPa came about at a time when washington, d.C., was efforts of the 1990s. instead, the large and obvious decline
abuzz about deregulation. economist Fred Kahn of Cornell, in the cost of rail shipments, natural gas, telephone calls,
who was President Jimmy Carter’s chief economic advisor, and air travel was a major inspiration. another driver was
is largely credited with first promoting the liberalization of that large customers chafed under rising electric rates occur-
markets away from heavily regulated or publicly owned firms. ring in some jurisdictions due to generation construction cost
the basic idea was that freer markets could spur companies to overruns; they demanded access to the cheaper power being
offer a wider range of products and lower costs. Policy makers sold in other areas or produced by efficient and quickly built
deregulated and restructured railroads, telecommunications, plants burning now-cheap natural gas. rates in neighboring
air travel, shipping, securities markets, and gas and water utili- states sometimes differed by a factor of two. in some areas,
ties. in the 1990s, policy makers, consumers, traders, and aca- the difference between the low marginal costs of producing
demics sought to bring the same revolution to electric power. power by gas and the high embedded cost rates of vertically
However, PUrPa and the subsequent reforms of the integrated supply created a strong incentive for consumers to
1990s were not the first time that competition was intro- access cheaper power.
duced to power provision. Britain’s Central electricity Board the 1990s witnessed the debunking of a long-standing
created an auction in the 1930s in which power was con- myth that the electricity industry is a natural monopoly, with
tracted from the providers who could offer it most efficiently, competition being introduced in many jurisdictions in two
contributing to a halving of heat rates in that decade. in the forms. one was PUrPa-style competition among indepen-
United states, despite samuel insull’s success in promoting dent generators to sell to utilities at a regulated avoided cost-
the regulatory compact between monopoly power providers based price. to the extent that these avoided costs accurately
and states that agreed to regulate them, distribution-level reflected the cost of utility-based supply, this type of compe-
competition was not completely eliminated. in some cities, tition reduced the cost of supply. However, regulators often
rival distribution companies ran lines in parallel to poach overestimated avoided costs, which sometimes resulted in
each other’s customers; there is some evidence that lower overpayment and expansion of uneconomical supply, which,
rates resulted where there was such competition. although in turn, inflated electric rates. this increased pressure for a
post–world war ii nationalization displaced Britain’s com- second type of competition: access by consumers to cheaper
petitive market and distribution-level competition eventually generation, facilitated by marketers.
disappeared in the United states, these examples were an at first, this access was through wheeling arrangements.
inspiration to U.s. reformers in the 1990s. But to spread widely the benefits of access, many states turned
Prior to the 1990s, free-market ideology in the United King- to a restructuring framework in which distribution, transmis-
dom and Chile led to the first wholesale restructurings of the sion, and generation were unbundled. generation assets
power sector, unburdened by any felt need for careful analy- were then to be spun off to independent supply companies that
sis of benefits and costs. in British Prime minister margaret would then compete to sell power to consumers, using the grid
thatcher’s view, there was simply “no other alternative,” given, as a common carrier. this second type of competition also did
e.g., how the nationalized industry failed to keep the lights on not necessarily decrease the overall societal costs of power.
during the coal strikes earlier in the 1970s. at the same time, in it has been argued that it was primarily an effort by some
the United states, academics were establishing the intellectual customers to shift the fixed costs of stranded assets (such as
underpinnings for restructuring. Fred schweppe of the massa- uneconomical PUrPa contracts or utility generation whose
chusetts institute of technology (mit) and his students math- construction costs were underestimated) either to other cus-
ematically described how prices could vary over time and from tomers or investors (Borenstein and Bushnell, 2015). today,
bus to bus based on the instantaneous marginal cost of deliver- similar efforts by consumers to shift costs to other parties
ing power and how such spot prices could incentivize building by avoiding average cost–based rates are continuing to drive

74 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


Today, similar efforts by consumers to shift costs to other parties by
avoiding average cost–based rates are continuing to drive radical
changes in the industry.

radical changes in the industry—but in a very different way, the states facilitated through their unbundling and divestment
as we explain later. actions. in december 1999, FerC issued order 2000, which
explicitly encourages the establishment of regional transmis-
Genesis of the Second Wave sion organizations (rtos) to facilitate markets and further the
in the 1990s, the enthusiasm of many states for restructuring goals of order 888. some of those rtos have since become
was fed by overestimated savings from competition; opti- full-fledged independent system operators (isos) that oper-
mistic projections of the competitiveness of new, cleaner ate day-ahead and real-time electricity spot markets, although
technology; and the prospect that the some of the benefits many parts of the country honor order 888 simply by com-
of competition could be tapped for popular programs sub- plying with rules requiring nondiscriminatory access to their
sidizing energy efficiency and renewable technology. the transmission facilities.
belief that restructuring was a cornucopia to benefit every-
one was epitomized by the unanimous vote of the Califor- The First Wave Disappoints:
nia assembly in favor of assembly Bill 1890 in 1996, the Genesis of the Second Wave
electricity restructuring act. other states quickly followed
suit. within the next few years, nearly half of the states had The California Crisis
passed laws or instituted regulations to restructure the power the 2000–2001 California crisis, however, stopped state
industry. many of those states intended to allow retail access restructuring efforts in their tracks. the causes of the crisis
for all customers, optimistically anticipating wide participa- have been chronicled and debated extensively in this maga-
tion and dramatic cost savings. these state actions were fol- zine. we believe that the problems arose, first, from an exer-
lowed in many cases, most notably in California, by wide- cise of market power right out of an economics 101 class—
spread voluntary or forced divestment of generation assets the withdrawal of supply to push up prices. this exercise was
by the former monopoly utilities. facilitated by supply problems, such as drought, a natural gas
Unfortunately, if such a dramatic change to an industry compressor explosion, and kelp sucked into a nuclear station’s
is favored by everyone, at least some people must be overly cooling system and was also enabled by state regulators who
optimistic about the benefits they will receive. any such actively discouraged forward contracting.
change, even if it improves efficiency and lowers prices, will second, the market design also disregarded important phys-
inevitably produce some losers as well as winners, which, in ical characteristics of electricity. these naïve designs included
fact, became apparent later. Furthermore, as many industry the definition of uniform pricing zones in the day-ahead market
writers warned at the time, the technical intricacies of power that ignored local transmission congestion. as a result, opera-
systems meant that creating a market for power would not tors had to scramble to resolve congestion in real time, endan-
be nearly as easy as for much simpler systems. the inspira- gering reliability and exacerbating local market power.
tion provided by the successful creation or restructuring of another issue was the creation of isolated day-ahead and
markets for simple commodities, such as the 1990 Clean real-time markets for energy and operating reserves that over-
air act’s continent-scale pollution-trading scheme, was, in looked their strong interconnections. enron and other mar-
part, misleading. ket parties resorted to disguising actions or outright lying to
at the same time that states were acting, the Federal arbitrage between those markets. such arbitrage is, in fact, an
energy regulatory Commission (FerC) also moved the essential function in all other markets and arguably improved
restructuring agenda forward. in april 1996, it adopted order rather than harmed power market functioning at the time.
888, which was intended to “remove impediments to competi- there was also the failure to promote forward contract-
tion in the wholesale bulk power marketplace and to bring more ing, which enabled any exercise of market power to immedi-
efficient, lower cost power to the Nation’s electricity consum- ately benefit the whole portfolio of a company’s generators.
ers.” all public utilities that owned assets transmitting electric- the consequences of poor market designs and market power
ity in interstate commerce had to allow market parties to use were unambiguous: rolling blackouts, a threefold increase in
their facilities on a nondiscriminatory basis, based on published wholesale power costs, and loss of public confidence in the
transmission tariffs. making the high-voltage grid available ability of restructuring to deliver lower costs. since the cri-
to all comers would, it was hoped, facilitate the states’ retail sis, no additional states have joined the original 23 to allow
markets and give access to the independent generators that for retail choice in their electricity markets, and, of those 23,

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 75


eight have suspended such choice. of the states that origi- consumers’ stranded benefits (earned through depreciation
nally encouraged retail markets, only texas has a vibrant payments embedded in the regulated rates) through vesting
and active retail markets for all consumers: industrial, com- call options (imposing bid caps) on divested plants. such vest-
mercial, and residential. ing contracts were imposed, e.g., in the earlier U.K. divesti-
despite the crisis, FerC gamely pressed on. after an unsuc- ture. the managers of future restructuring, which may even-
cessful attempt to develop a standard market design to impose tually come to the northwestern and southeastern parts of the
on all restructured wholesale markets, a voluntary wholesale United states that have resisted it, should consider smoothing
market “platform” was promoted, with elements that FerC the transition through such contracts.
believed would prevent California-style problems from occur- another lesson was the need for consumers to forward-
ring in the future. these included location-specific (nodal) contract for supply to prevent the exercise of market power.
prices that reflected consideration of the network’s actual con- the California regulators discouraged long-term contracting
straints, before-the-market identification and mitigation of between generators and load-serving entities, believing that
bids that appear to attempt to exercise market power, forward clearing all electricity in the day-ahead spot market would
financial contracts and resource-adequacy markets, financial eliminate the need for regulatory intervention in price setting.
transmission rights (Ftrs), cooptimized spot energy and after the crisis, California regulators reversed course and
operating reserves markets, financial arbitrage between day- instead mandated month- and year-ahead forward contract-
ahead and real-time markets, and a hybrid market that oper- ing and showings of adequate physical resources. FerC, in
ates like a so-called power pool company (PooLCo) but also turn, has encouraged, but not mandated, so-called resource-
facilitates bilateral transactions. adequacy mechanisms in part to give more assurance that
a PooLCo in a particular region is defined as a single enough supply and demand resources would be available to
market operator that would run an auction to buy power from prevent shortages. after the crisis, these mechanisms helped
generators and then resell it to consumers or load-serving assure nervous regulators that another California blowup
entities. PooLCos can also enable bilateral deals to be made would not happen and provided a source for missing money
between generators and consumers or load-serving entities for resource investors who would not earn adequate returns
by moving the power from the former to the latter and charg- from price-capped energy markets alone.
ing for the short-term use of the network based on the differ- the adopted approaches, however, differ in different
ences in the energy spot prices it calculates at the locations areas. PJm and iso New england have capacity markets in
of sellers and buyers. this allows trading to take place, while which the isos procure forward capacity (subject to specific
accounting for all of the physical constraints in the network must-offer obligations) through annual auctions that allow
that must be satisfied. participation by existing and planned capacity as well as
demand-side resources willing to curtail load. texas, how-
Lessons Learned from the First Wave ever, has opted for an energy-only market, with spot prices
to summarize, the first wave of restructuring was driven by a allowed to reach Us$9,000/mwh. it has also complemented
global move toward privatization of infrastructure industries, the raising of price caps with an administrative operating
vertical and horizontal unbundling, and implementation of reserve demand curve that imposes a price adder on energy
competitive wholesale markets as means for achieving eco- to reflect reserve depletion, so that energy prices better reflect
nomic efficiency in investment, production, and consump- scarcity rents in times of shortage.
tion. we now describe several of the lessons learned from the a third lesson was learned when both state regulators and
first wave of restructuring and the California crisis, lessons FerC underestimated the market power and other abuses
that are, more or less, embodied in FerC’s platform and in that could take advantage of inconsistencies between the
the market redesigns actively promoted in PJm interconnec- commercial model (e.g., uniform price zones and separate
tion, California, and the other U.s. isos. energy and ancillary service markets) and the technical real-
one lesson concerned how to unbundle and then distribute ity. FerC authorization of market-based wholesale rates
the resulting economic benefits and costs. Not everyone auto- was based on standard department of Justice criteria—
matically becomes better off. the initial main challenges e.g., the Herfindahl–Hirschman concentration index—that
were the divestiture of assets and recovery of the stranded proved to be inadequate for the electric power industry. the
costs resulting from the regulatory compact. some thought commercial models initially implemented in California and
that electricity under deregulation would be much cheaper, texas emphasized trading simplicity, as is still the case in
which would, therefore, significantly depreciate the value of europe. the California crisis and widespread gaming (par-
the divested assets. in California, the Competitive transition ticularly the so-called “dec game”) in PJm, California, and
Charge mechanism was designed to make the shareholders texas demonstrated the need for consistency between the
of the investor-owned utilities whole. But the arrangement commercial and technical models, which eventually led to
was asymmetric and did not protect customers against wind- further reforms of these markets, such as California’s mar-
fall profits for the asset buyers due to unexpected events and ket restructuring and technical upgrade and the texas nodal
the exercise of market power. No one thought of protecting market. (in the dec game, a generator in a location with

76 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


excess power would schedule a power sale into a zonal day- where most energy is traded hourly for the next 24 h with
ahead market at a regional high price that disregards conges- financially binding quantities and prices determined by a
tion and then buy the power back in real time at a lower price security-constrained, bid-based economic dispatch, imple-
that reflects local congestion.) mented through unit commitment optimization employing
in particular, nodal markets, whose locational marginal mixed-integer programming.
prices would be determined through uniform price-clearing deviations from the day-ahead hourly commitments are
auctions, were instituted in both the day-ahead and real-time reoptimized every 5 min based on rebidding every 15 min. Vir-
markets. initially, real-time markets were hourly, but to address tual bidding allows arbitrage by both energy traders and spec-
the need for greater flexibility in response to renewable output ulators and results in a closer convergence of day-ahead and
variations, FerC order 764 reduced the settlement intervals to real-time prices. it also eliminates the incentive to disguise arbi-
15-min markets, with reoptimization of dispatch every 5 min. trage through implicit virtual bidding, in which physical energy
Contrary to fears that having separate prices at each bus would offers or bids to buy are deferred until real time to manipulate
increase the ability to manipulate prices, the markets diminished day-ahead prices. Both the supply and demand sides engaged
opportunities to exercise market power by making constraints in implicit virtual bidding during the California crisis. Figure 1
transparent and managing congestion day ahead. However, illustrates a typical day-ahead and real-time dispatch versus the
these measures are not enough to eliminate market power in hourly day-ahead load forecast and actual load.
load pockets with limited supply and transmission bottlenecks.
From the California crisis, we learned that there was a The Second Wave:
need for active market monitoring together with automated Focus on Economic Efficiency
detection and mitigation of inflated supply bids that attempt and Incremental Improvements
to exercise market power in local markets. trading energy at what was learned in the decade after the California crisis is
nodal prices has provided accurate price signals reflecting con- that market design is not a destination but a journey. as sup-
gestion that facilitate efficiency in production, consumption, ply and demand technologies improve, computational capa-
and investment. However, it quickly became apparent that the bilities are enhanced, and more is learned about the func-
variability and uncertainty of such locational prices exposes tioning and needs of markets, further changes are proposed
market participants to high risks. thus, another lesson was and implemented. in recent years, these changes have been
that there was a need for financial hedges for these risks. Bill primarily incremental in nature (which we call the second
Hogan of Harvard complemented schweppe’s vision of nodal wave), but as we will discuss in the next section, more dra-
energy markets with a proposal that isos create hedging and matic reforms may lie ahead in response to the smart grid,
property rights instruments in the form of Ftrs. these are renewable energy, and distributed resources revolutions.
financial instruments that entitle their holders to the net gain
resulting from nodal price difference between two specific
nodes. they allow energy market participants and transmis-
sion owners to hedge the locational price risk associated with 27,500
energy trading and provide means for monetizing some of the 26,500
property rights resulting from the ownership of transmission 25,500
assets that restrict power flows. markets for Ftrs, with peri-
24,500
odic auctions, are managed by all isos as a complement to the
Power (MW)

23,500
model energy markets (Hogan, 1992).
everyone also learned from the California debacle that 22,500
markets should not be arbitrarily isolated and that arbitrage 21,500
is important for improving efficiency, providing informa- 20,500
tion, and making it harder to exercise market power. one 19,500
response is to design markets so that energy and ancillary 18,500
service interdependencies are recognized; this is now done 17,500
by cooptimizing those markets, committing resources to
0:00

6:00

12:00

18:00

24:00

provide whichever commodity is most valuable to the sys-


tem and paying in a way that also makes that schedule the Time of Day
most profitable course for individual suppliers. another Day-Ahead Generation Schedule
response is the two-settlement energy market design, with Day-Ahead Load Forecast
virtual bidding, which is now standard in U.s. organized Hour-Ahead Load Forecast
markets. thus, most energy trading is contracted in forward Actual Load
bilateral and over-the-counter markets, complemented by
long-run financial contracts. the isos settle day-ahead and figure 1. A typical two-settlement dispatch, from 8 Janu-
spot energy transactions through a two-settlement approach ary 2018. (Data from California ISO.)

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 77


one fundamental challenge is the divergence between another trend made possible by computational software
the economist’s ideal of a convex, smooth supply cost func- and hardware improvements is the explicit consideration of
tion and the reality of lumpy commitments, minimum output postcontingency corrective actions in market software. Pre-
constraints, and nonconvex heat rate curves. the U.s. mar- viously, such risks were handled in the markets by preventive
ket designs allow generation resources to provide economic prepositioning of supply, through zonal operating reserve
offers in the day-ahead and real-time markets in the form of requirements, N-1 constraints on dispatch, or minimum
various combinations of an energy supply function, start-up online constraints. the hope was that this excess supply
cost, and no-load cost. such offers are cleared using unit com- would be sufficient to allow the system to securely manage
mitment optimization mixed-integer programming software. unexpected equipment outages or fluctuations in net loads.
alternatively, generation resources can submit physical bilat- For some time, academics have pointed out that if postcon-
eral transactions that are scheduled outside the optimization tingency redispatch could be modeled and optimized, then
as price-taking transactions. the cost of prepositioning the generation could be reduced.
one of the consequences of the nonconvex cost structure this is because the software would automatically fine-tune
of generation is that generation units may not cover their the location and quantity of reserves that are acquired.
lumpy costs through energy payments they receive over a the California iso is implementing corrective action
24-h period. But because of another widely adopted market optimization for certain contingencies by explicitly representing
feature, generators who participate in the market by submit- how dispatches and commitments could be adjusted optimally
ting economic offers receive make-whole payments, covered after an event. similar approaches could be used to optimize
by an uplift known as bid cost recovery (BCR) payments that reserves to cover, e.g., ramp events, avoiding the need for
ensure no losses over each 24-h period. the BCr payments highly conservative and blunt zonal or system requirements
provide an incentive for generators to submit economic offers for flexible ramping products. Ultimately, this could lead to full-
rather than self-schedule. blown stochastic optimization for unit commitment, in which a
the rules for bidding and paying for lumpy costs have large number of possible contingency, load, and supply scenarios
remained an important item on the market reform agenda, could be considered when optimizing which units to put online
with ongoing dissatisfaction over the basic BCr model. to and which fast-start units to hold in reserve.
minimize uplifts and recover as much of the cost as possible the incremental improvements associated with the second
through energy charges, an approach known variously as wave have resulted in or will soon yield significant operat-
extended locational marginal pricing and convex hull pric- ing cost savings. Not all parties, however, are happy with this
ing has been partially implemented at the mid-Continent trend toward making market software more complex. some
iso and is being considered by other isos. complain that price drivers are not transparent and perhaps
another area of incremental improvement has been have contributed to decreases in trading activity. an evolu-
the geographic expansion of markets to take advantage of tion toward stochastic market clearing could accelerate that
complementary fuel mixes in neighboring regions and short- trend. some observers call for a reversal of this trend, e.g.,
term diversity in load and, increasingly, renewable output. toward simplifying supply offers by eliminating lumpy cost
PJm’s expansion westward to Chicago immediately resulted and minimum output bidding. But this discussion has received
in increased west-to-east power flows and in fuel cost sav- far less attention than other looming issues that the industry in
ings of over Us$100 million per year. the integration of the general and market operations in particular are facing.
day-ahead markets in europe has achieved similar results.
more recently, the desire for more efficiency in real-time The Third Wave:
balancing in western North america has led to the rapid Making Way for Demand-Side,
expansion of the California iso’s energy imbalance market Renewable, and Distributed Resources
(eim) involving eight U.s. states and even the Canadian the third wave of market and industry reform, which is largely
province of British Columbia. a large motivator is the nega- still a work in progress, is associated with the rapid penetra-
tive real-time prices that often occur midday in the Califor- tion of renewables and distributed energy resources (ders)
nia market, which means that neighboring states would be into the electricity generation mix and the deployment of smart
paid to take California’s surplus. the eim eliminates the grid technologies, such as smart metering, phasor measure-
hurdle rate of transmission access and other charges that ment units, and storage (sioshansi, 2016). also important are
hinder trade between neighboring balancing areas. Unfortu- changes in consumption patterns due to demand response, the
nately, governance issues have prevented the California iso electrification of the transportation sector, and increased cus-
from expanding this model to the day-ahead market. sensing tomer participation in electricity production (so-called prosum-
an opportunity, the southwest Power Pool/mountain west age). as we discussed earlier, the first two waves were largely
partnership is competing to enlist balancing areas that have motivated by the move toward vertical and horizontal unbun-
not yet joined the eim. it also seeks to expand day-ahead dling and privatization of the electricity infrastructure and
markets, perhaps including closer coordination of the east- by increased efficiency of investment and operation through
ern and western interconnections through expanded dc links. competition. in contrast, the third wave is largely driven by

78 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


an environmental agenda for the decarbonization of electric- contract for PV solar power at Us$0.057/kwh, while in Chile’s
ity generation to reduce global warming, a social movement atacama desert, contracts for PV solar at Us$0.033/kwh were
toward more exercise of customer choice and democratization recently signed. such supply for renewable energy would eas-
of the energy supply, and rapid technological innovation in sup- ily compete in current electricity markets without the need for
ply, storage, metering, and control in the energy area. perverse incentives inducing inefficient rent chasing, espe-
Political forces advocating for these trends have cham- cially if a carbon tax or a cap-and-trade policy is implemented.
pioned policies that subsidize technological innovation on wind power is another major renewable energy source that
ideological grounds rather than economic efficiency. this could be competitive without targeted subsidies if appropri-
tilting of the playing field is counter to the fundamental prin- ate carbon pricing were introduced. Unfortunately, in many
ciples of market design. the result is perverse incentives and systems, wind power has been implicitly subsidized through
rent-seeking behavior on the supply and demand sides alike feed-in tariffs and must-take policies imposed on system oper-
and proposals for increasingly complicated market mecha- ators. such policies are often supported by the false premises
nisms that attempt to mitigate the technical challenges and that renewable energy is free, is valuable for its own sake, and
economic distortions resulting from those incentives. should not be spilled except for emergencies or overgeneration
in the rest of this article, we consider some of the impli- situations. these suppositions do not account for many of the
cations for the third wave of market design of the accelerat- complexities associated with providing reliable power consid-
ing penetration of renewable and distributed sources. For ered in security-constrained, economical dispatch. it can be
example, policies such as net metering have become pervasive easily demonstrated that the strategic curtailment of the renew-
in the United states and abroad. these policies compensate ables supply (which is technically feasible) enables the more
rooftop photovoltaic (PV) solar production at the retail rate, efficient and even less polluting dispatch of conventional slow-
even when household production of solar energy exceeds con- ramping resources. Hence, in some systems, such as the Cali-
sumption. to illustrate, in California, net metering payments fornia iso, negative bids (down to −Us$150/mwh), and thus
under Pacific gas and electric’s retail tariff e6 can reach prices, have been incorporated into the market design to negate
Us$0.45/kwh at peak hours, while the wholesale energy cost some of the perverse production subsidies. Further incentives
may be as low as Us$0.04/Kwh. such rates fail to recognize for the curtailment or withholding of renewable energy can
that the high volumetric retail rates were designed to distribute be used to correct the distortions resulting from suboptimal
the infrastructure cost among retail customers in an equitable deployment of conventional standby resources.
manner so that consumers that use more energy pay a markup in europe, and particularly in germany, the rapid pen-
reflecting a higher share of the infrastructure cost. Under the etration of wind generation and solar power through perverse
net metering paradigm, however, such high-end consum- economic incentives has resulted in the virtual collapse of the
ers can offset their payments by installing solar panels and wholesale energy market. as shown in Figure 2, such a col-
shifting their share of the infrastructure cost to low-end con- lapse in wholesale energy prices resulted in a missing money
sumers. the distortion created by net metering has resulted phenomenon that has motivated the capacity remuneration
in rapid expansion of rooftop PV systems in states such as of conventional power plants. ironically, the abundance of
California, Nevada, and Hawaii, even though their costs are renewable power has also resulted in a sharp drop in carbon
roughly twice that of grid-scale solar. prices and led to the increased use of lignite, which negates
this expansion, in turn, has led to a legislative rebellion much of the environmental benefit provided by renewables.
that discontinued the original net metering policy in Nevada From a market design perspective, the rapid penetration of
and Hawaii and produced a close three to two vote in the Cali- renewables and ders has created several major challenges.
fornia Public Utility Commission that revised net metering
practices and rates. Hawaii has opted for a major reduction
in payments for the excess production of rooftop PV systems
70
above customers’ self-use and an increase in fixed connection
Cost of Energy (€/MWh)

60
charges for new rooftop solar installations. Nevada went even
further along that path by retroactively changing the terms 50
originally offered to customers with rooftop solar installa- 40
tions. these moves were fought in the political arena by the 30
rooftop solar power industry. 20
while net metering may distort economic incentives in
10
favor of rooftop solar installations, it should be noted that cen-
0
tralized PV solar power is becoming increasingly competitive, 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016 2017
and the U.s. department of energy has recently announced Year
that centralized PV solar installations have reached long-term
costs of Us$0.06/kwh. Consistent with that, in israel, the figure 2. The collapse of the German wholesale market.
Public Utility authority has recently signed a 20-year supply (Data from energy-charts.de.)

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 79


the inherent systematic variability and uncertainty of renew- reward capacity that is available precisely when needed and
able resources results in extreme ramping and a need for flex- can ramp up quickly when prices spike and then disappear
ibility. the famous California duck curve, shown in Figure 3, when they collapse.
illustrates the impact of high solar penetration on the need for But reforming energy and ancillary services markets to
fast-ramping resources in the early morning and late afternoon provide more appropriate rewards for flexibility is not neces-
and the overgeneration potential that would require curtailing sarily simple either. Flexibility of energy resources is essen-
renewable resources. to address these problems, the California tial for the integration of renewables and ders at various
Public Utility Commission has modified its resource adequacy time scales, and hence such flexibility must be priced in the
(ra) mechanism to require about a third of the capacity that various market horizons so that it provides the appropri-
load-serving entities must show for achieving their obligation ate price signals for investment and operation of resources.
needs to meet flexibility criteria. Flexible resources must be this is accomplished by creating revenue streams and
economically dispatchable and able to be ramped continuously market products that enable the remuneration of resources
over a 3-h period. Unlike regular ra resources, which must that provide flexibility. such flexibility can be mobilized
offer obligations by being dispatched or available for dispatch, through shorter settlement intervals, demand-side manage-
flexible ra must be offered at a price that enables the iso to ment, the flexible use of transmission assets (e.g., trans-
dispatch them economically. mission switching and dynamic ratings of thermal limits),
For several reasons, however, the ra mechanism is a and flexible ramping products. the value/cost of flexibility
blunt tool to encourage flexibility. First, is it 3-h, 1-h, or 5-min must be reflected in the payments to renewable and distrib-
ramps that must be managed? different resources are best uted resources that impose such costs on the system, and
for each. it also matters whether the ramps are predictable resources that help resolve issues associated with flexibility
or uncertain. second, how does one compare, for instance, should be remunerated.
the flexibility contributed by combustion turbines that are For example, California iso has introduced a new flexible
limited to one start a day, storage with 15 min of energy, ramping product (sometimes called flexiramp) that enables
demand response that can be called upon only a handful of remuneration of resources that are being held in reserve
times per month, and plants with different ramp rates? this out of merit order instead of being dispatched to produce
suggests that, rather than develop a generic definition of flex- energy which they offer below the market clearing price.
ible capacity, it would be better to reform energy markets to such reserves differ from regulation-type reserves, which

30

25 Distributed Solar
Utility-Scale Solar
Energy (GWh)

20
Imports
15 Other Renewables
Thermal
10
Nuclear
5 Hydroelectric
0
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24
Hour of the Day
(a)
Cost of Energy ($/MWh)

60
40 Real-Time
Average
20
Hourly
0 Price
–20
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 20 22 24
Hour of the Day
(b)

figure 3. An illustration of (a) the California ISO net generation duck curve and (b) negative wholesale prices, both for 11
March 2017. (Note: Distributed solar generation is estimated based on December 2016 installed net-metered capacity as
reported in form EIA-826, Monthly Electric Utility Sales and Revenue Report with State Distributions, U.S. Energy Informa-
tion Administration.)

80 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


are a capacity-based ancillary service product used for load competition and taking advantage of diversity of load and
following within each 5-min interval. in contrast, flexiramp generation patterns across large regions. ironically, while
serves to assure the availability of energy and regulation in the scale of markets has greatly increased, at the same time
future intervals. Hence, these flexiramp reserves are remu- the scale of who can compete has become much smaller, so
nerated for lost opportunity costs, which is the profit that is that household-scale technologies are now revolutionizing
forgone when capacity is held back out of merit rather than the market.
dispatched (i.e., opportunity cost = clearing price − bid). market designs have not kept up with these changes.
Besides the growth of renewables, the other dramatic this means that we have not realized the full economic and
change in the industry is the proliferation of many small environmental benefits of new technologies. Present chal-
ders on both the demand and supply sides. this reflects a lenges for market designers include further expansion of the
general trend toward diverse participation in the produc- geographic scope of markets; reconciling the wildly incon-
tion of energy and the above-described need to address the sistent price signals in retail and wholesale power prices;
many new challenges posed by the introduction of renew- incentivizing an optimal mix, location, and scale of flexible
ables. such proliferation is largely enabled by innovation in generation, storage, and demand-side resources to firm up
the smart grid technologies area. there are many ways to renewable generation; and avoiding confusing means for
integrate such resources and organize market platforms that ends by keeping a firm eye on the goals we want to accom-
will facilitate the procurement of ders, enable peer-to-peer plish with renewable and other policies. it is lower system
transactions at the distribution level, and create new products. costs, greater reliability, and lower pollution we want, not
these changes will redefine the role of future utilities to sup- particular technologies; the best means to achieve those
port their ability to assure retail supply reliability in a world goals are likely to surprise us. therefore, markets must be
where their volumetric revenue base is shrinking because of designed to allow the best solutions to emerge and succeed
increased self-supply of energy behind the meter. without policy makers imposing their prejudices about what
one market design choice is whether to make the market they should look like.
iso-centric, where ders are integrated into the system through
distribution system operators and third-party aggregators who For Further Reading
participate in the iso wholesale market. alternatively, the mar- s. Borenstein and J. Bushnell, “the Us electricity industry
ket organization could be distribution-level–centric, with the after 20 years of restructuring,” Annu. Rev. Economics, vol.
iso performing limited coordination functions among distri- 7, no. 1, pp. 437–463, 2015.
bution system operators that accomplish most of the der inte- w. w. Hogan, “Contract markets for electric power trans-
gration through local distribution system market platforms. the mission,” J. Regulatory Econ., vol. 4, no. 3, pp. 211–242, 1992.
California iso and PJm have opted for the first through-market P. L. Joskow and r. schmalensee, Markets for Power: An
initiatives that carve a role for der aggregators (in California) Analysis of Electric Utility Deregulation. Cambridge, ma:
and curtailment service providers (PJm) that behave as virtual mit Press, 1983.
power plants that can participate as regular plants in the iso e. t. mansur and m. w. white. (2012, Jan. 13). market
wholesale market. such participation broadens the scope of the organization and efficiency in electricity markets. dart-
conventional isos and adapts them to the brave new world of mouth College, Hanover, NH. [online]. available: www
renewables and distributed resources. New York state, on the .dartmouth.edu/~mansur/papers/mansur_white_pjmaep.pdf
other hand, has been promoting its reform the energy Vision F. C. schweppe, m. C. Caramanis, r. d. tabors, and r.
initiative, which emphasizes customer choice and active partici- e. Bohn, Spot Pricing of Electricity. Norwell, ma: Kluwer,
pation by ders. 1988.
F. P. sioshansi, ed., Future of Utilities, Utilities of the Fu-
Conclusions ture: How Technological Innovations in Distributed Energy
From thomas edison’s Pearl street station (and his earlier Resources Will Reshape the Electric Power Sector. New
Holborn Viaduct plant in London) to samuel insull’s regu- York: academic, 2016.
lated utility and the vertically integrated monopolies of the s. stoft, “economic feedback: working with the insa-
late 1900s, the power industry saw tremendous innovation tiable profit motive,” IEEE Power Energy Mag., vol. 99, no.
in technology and institutions during its first century. the 3, pp. 14–16, 2003.
last three decades have seen further tremendous changes,
with environmental concerns coming to the fore and renew- Biographies
able generation now dominating new capacity additions. Benjamin F. Hobbs is with Johns Hopkins University, Bal-
New computation and communications technologies have timore, maryland.
facilitated a revolution in markets, allowing much bigger Shmuel S. Oren is with the University of California,
geographic coverage and efficiently coordinating an array Berkeley.
of energy, ancillary service, and transmission products. this
p&e
growth in the scope of markets lowers costs by increasing

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 81


PV-Battery
Systems
for Critical
Loads During
Emergencies
By Chanaka Keerthisinghe, Mareldi Ahumada-Paras,
Lilo D. Pozzo, Daniel S. Kirschen, Hugo Pontes,
Wesley K. Tatum, and Marvi A. Matos

photos courtesy of: university of Washington

Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/MPE.2018.2877896


Date of publication: 7 January 2019

82 ieee power & energy magazine 1540-7977/19©2019IEEE january/february 2019


H
Hurricane Maria struck Puerto rico on 20 sePteMber
2017 and left large parts of the island without electricity for months. as
Figure 1 shows, restoration in remote mountainous regions took consider-
ably longer.
Long-term power outages can be lethal to individuals who rely on
electrically powered medical devices or require medicines that must
be refrigerated. although the initial death toll of Hurricane Maria was
64, one study concluded that actual number of deaths caused by the
hurricane is closer to 2,975 due to the lack of utilities, such as electric-
ity. researchers calculated this number by comparing the total medi-
cal-related deaths during 2017 with the average numbers in the past four
years. another study esti-
mated the death toll at 4,645.
it is likely that remote areas were
more severely affected because dam-
A Case Study from
aged roads not only prevented access to med-
ical facilities but also hampered the regular delivery of medical supplies
Puerto Rico After
and fuel for portable generators. communities were deprived of electric-
ity and water, hospitals and clinics were inoperable, and communication
Hurricane Maria
and transportation were unavailable for months; 200 days after the hur-
ricane, 160,000 people still lacked electricity. the devastating destruction
from the hurricane is highlighted in Figure 2.
small systems combining photovoltaic (PV) generation and battery energy
storage could be deployed during such emergencies to help affected indi-
viduals cope until grid-supplied power is restored. However, very little
reliable data are available on how such systems would actually
be used to meet critical medical needs and, thus, on what
their design requirements should be. to gather data on
how emergency systems would actually work and pro-
vide some relief to a severely affected community,
our group from the university of Washington in
seattle made three field trips to Jayuya, a remote
small town in the mountainous center of Puerto
rico, to collect preliminary information about
medical needs, install PV battery systems,
and gather the data collected by these sys-
tems after several months of use. Figure 3
shows some photos highlighting the work.

Field Results
Figure 4 outlines the time line and pur-
poses of the three field trips to Puerto rico.

First Field Trip:


Preliminary Needs Assessment
the goal of the first trip was to identify, based
on interviews with patients and their families,
the critical medical needs that require electric
power at the household level and carry out a pre-
liminary assessment of the power and energy require-
ments associated with these needs. the critical medical
conditions and associated electrical devices that were iden-
tified during these interviews were
✔ feeding machines and electrical bedding for patients with
percutaneous endoscopic gastrostomy (PeG)

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 83


✔ nebulizers or oxygen concentrators for patients with ✔ refrigeration for medicines, such as insulin for dia-
asthma and/or chronic obstructive pulmonary disease betic patients, and food for patients with special di-
(coPD) etary requirements.
✔ continuous positive airway pressure (cPaP) machines Dialysis and treatments for other acute medical needs were
for patients with sleep apnea not included in this assessment because they are usually not
carried out at home and patients with critical needs are fre-
quently evacuated before or after emergencies. interviews also
revealed how individuals coped with the lack of electricity.
100
PeG patients used gravity feeding instead of powered peri-
Customers with Power (%)

Entire Puerto Rico


80 San Juan (Capital) staltic pumps, which resulted in substantially faster feeding.
Caguas (Mountainous) Many diabetic patients kept their insulin cool either by using
60 water and ice or moving their refrigerators to nearby busi-
nesses that had emergency generators; however, some stopped
40 18–23 March
19–24 November 2018 (Trip 2) taking insulin out of fear that it had degraded. the local clinic
20 2017 (Trip 1) was without power until a backup generator arrived, and they
lost medicine requiring refrigeration as well as all vaccines.
0 other loads common to all households were perceived
0 20 40 60 80 100 120 140 160 180 200
Time (Days) as important but less critical: refrigeration for regular food,
fans, lighting, tV, and washing machines (particularly
figure 1. The restoration of power to customers in Puerto important in households with bedridden patients). cooking
Rico after Hurricane Maria, beginning on 20 September appliances do not appear on this list because most house-
2017. Note the significant difference between the San Juan holds in this part of Puerto rico use gas for cooking.
urban area and the mountainous and directly hit region basic information about the critical loads was also gath-
of Caguas. ered by reading manufacturers’ labels and asking families

figure 2. The devastation caused by Hurricane Maria in Puerto Rico. (Photos courtesy of the University of Washington,
used with permission.)

84 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


how often each appliance was used and for how long. table 1 Diesel generators are commonly used in emergencies but
summarizes time-of-use and duration data. because there were perceived as having the following drawbacks:
was no electricity during the first field trip, it was not pos- ✔ our interviews revealed that the condition of some asth-
sible to measure actual demands or load profiles, so the mea- ma and coPD patients had worsened because of the
sured power values in table 1 were obtained during the third exhaust gases (such as carbon monoxide) or the aero-
trip. the maximum power drawn by the devices was used solized soot particles produced by the diesel engines.
for sizing the inverter, whereas the entire load profile was ✔ because of the noise, generators cannot be used at night
required to size the PV and battery systems. to power the cPaP machines of sleep apnea patients.

figure 3. Some of the PV-battery systems installed in Puerto Rico by researchers at the University of Washington in
Seattle. (Photos courtesy of the University of Washington, used with permission.)

Trip 1: Trip 2: Trip 3:


19–24 November 18–23 March 2018 2–5 July 2018
Hurricane 2017
Maria Hit
Puerto Rico on
20 September Identify Critical Donate Extract Data
2017 Loads and Value PV-Battery (i.e., Electrical
of a PV-Battery Systems Load Profiles)
System

figure 4. The time line and purposes of the field trips.

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 85


table 1. The maximum and average measured power, time of use, and duration of critical electrical loads.
Device Name Duration, Time of Use Average Power Maximum Power
PEG feeding machine 30 min, four times <10 W 120 W (manufacturer)
Electrically actuated bed 30 s, ten times 18 W 53–65 W
Inflatable mattress 8–24 h Lower than 10 W <10 W
Nebulizers 5–25 min, two–four times 23–52 W 23–66 W
Oxygen concentrators Up to 24 h 350 W 428 W
CPAP 9 h, 10 p.m.–7 a.m. 34 W 47 W
Refrigerator 8–24 h 136–352 W 140–392 W
Refrigerator (small) 8–24 h 20 W 97 W
TV 2–4 h, 3–9 p.m. 28–292 W 31–392 W

table 2. A summary of the various systems installed.


Number of
PV Size (W) Battery MPPT Inverter (kW) Installations
Type A 260 160 Ah (lead acid) Yes 1 Six
Type B 100–200 80–100 Ah (lead acid) No 1 Six
Type C 400 1.1 kWh (lithium ion) Yes 1.1 Five
Type D 100 100 Ah (lead acid) No dc system Four

✔ Maintaining a generator (e.g., changing the oil) is


challenging for some users because it requires time,
knowledge, and money.

Second Field Trip: PV-Battery


Systems Deployment
To PV Panels the goal of the second field trip was to install 17 stand-alone
PV-battery systems of four different types and power ratings
in households with individuals relying on electrically powered
medical devices or medically related refrigeration needs. a
MPPT Charge
Controller summary of the installed systems is given in table 2; four sys-
Inverter Monitor tems had been installed in the first trip. because systems were
not available for all households with critical medical needs,
figure 5. The top view of a PV-battery system designed priority was given to those who lacked the resources to buy
at the University of Washington. The batteries, data logger, or obtain another source of electricity and those living in the
and majority of the cables are inside the box.
more remote mountain areas.
Figure 5 shows a top view of a type a system, which
✔ reliable access to a supply of diesel fuel during an consists of an inverter, a maximum power point tracking
emergency can be difficult or impossible, particularly (MPPt) solar-charge controller, a display monitor, lead-acid
in a remote area. batteries, and data loggers to record the electrical load pro-
✔ using a generator can cost up to us$10 per day. over files, PV output, battery state of charge (soc), and tempera-
an extended period of time, this can be excessive for ture. system types a, b, and D were designed at the univer-
low-income households. sity of Washington, and system type c was a commercially
✔ emergency diesel generators are often not designed for con- available system.
tinuous use. individuals would have to use them for periods because of budget and time restrictions, the systems were
of 2–6 h. For example, some households ran diesel genera- limited in capacity. nevertheless, we anticipated that they
tors up to 8 h per day (4 h in the morning and 4 h in the would be able to meet at least some of the critical loads of indi-
evening) to keep medicines cool. there were also many in- vidual households, either fully on their own or in tandem with
stances in which generators had broken because of overuse. diesel generators, if households were already using a generator.

86 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


Long-term power outages can be lethal to individuals
who rely on electrically powered medical devices
or require medicines that must be refrigerated.

because these systems were sized from inaccurate load pro- Analysis of Field Data
files based on the limited information collected during the We choose to analyze the six households that received type
first field trip, some of them were undersized. although we a PV-battery systems because they were the only systems
encouraged the users to try not to discharge the batteries below equipped with data loggers that could record all of the nec-
recommended safety limits to maximize battery life, some bat- essary data. systems in five other households recorded only
teries degraded prematurely because of excessive depth of the load profiles.
discharge (DoD).
Energy Consumption and Generation
Third Field Trip: Data Collection and Analysis Figure 6 shows the total daily energy consumption and PV
the purpose of the third trip was to obtain the data col- generation over 47 days for six households where type a PV-
lected by the data loggers in the installed PV-battery sys- battery systems were installed. the energy-use pattern for
tems. satisfaction surveys were also administered to gauge household 6 is similar to the PV generation pattern, which
user experience and perceptions of solar energy as a form shows that users managed to consume the PV generation on
of emergency energy supply. these quantitative and quali- the same day. this energy-consumption pattern contributed to
tative data are analyzed in the next section. keeping the battery in good condition. another important

2 2
1.5 1.5
1 1
0.5 0.5
0 0
5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45
Days Days Stopped Using the Load
(a) (b) Logger but Continued to
Use the System
Electrical Energy (kWh)

Electrical Energy (kWh)

2 2
1.5 1.5
Got Electricity Back,
1 1 So Stopped Using the
0.5 0.5 System and Load Logger
0 0
5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45
Days Days
(c) (d)
2 2
1.5 Got Electricity Back 1.5
1 Started Using Stopped Using 1
the Load the Load Logger
0.5 Logger Late 0.5
0 0
5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45
Days Days
(e) (f)
PV Output Load

figure 6. The total daily load and PV output for six households over 47 days. Households (a) 1, (b) 2, (c) 3, (d) 4, (e) 5, and
(f) 6. The load was measured after the inverter.

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 87


The local clinic was without power until a backup generator
arrived, and they lost medicine requiring refrigeration as
well as all vaccines.

finding is that households 4 and 5 stopped using the systems load measured corresponds to different devices specific to
after they regained grid power within one month after instal- each household connected at each moment. For example,
lation, whereas the other users continued to use the systems household 1 used the system to power a refrigerator (~150 W)
throughout the whole period. from 7 a.m. to 3 p.m., an entertainment system (~375 W)
for periods of an hour at a time, and a nebulizer (23–52 W)
Load Profiles a few times a day for 45 min. Households 1–6 used most of
Figure 7 illustrates the load profiles for the days with the their devices during the day when there was sun to maxi-
highest energy consumption for eight households. the mize battery life. nevertheless, they used the battery when

600 200
Entertainment System Refrigerator
150
400
TV
Refrigerator 100
Nebulizer
200 50
0 0
4 8 12 16 20 24 4 8 12 16 20 24
Time Time
(a) (b)
600 600
400 Refrigerator 400 Refrigerator
200 200
Electrical Power (W)

Electrical Power (W)

0 0
4 8 12 16 20 24 4 8 12 16 20 24
Time Time
(c) (d)
400 200
300 150
Nebulizer
200 Refrigerator 100
100 50
0 0
4 8 12 16 20 24 4 8 12 16 20 24
Time Time
(e) (f)
100 8
Small Refrigerator PEG Patient
6
50 4
2
Feeding Machine Electrical Bed
0 0
4 8 12 16 20 24 4 8 12 16 20 24
Time Time
(g) (h)

Day 1 Day 2 Day 3

figure 7. The electrical load profiles of eight different households over one to three days. Households (a) 1, (b) 2, (c) 3, (d)
4, (e) 5, (f) 6, (g) 7, and (h) 8. The load profiles consist of all of the critical devices; however, we were able to identify some
of these devices through interviews, as noted in the figure.

88 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


Because battery use in emergency situations is likely to be poorly
controlled, it is important to collect data about charge/discharge cycles
so that information can inform the design of longer-life systems.

consumption was greater than PV generation, thereby be inevitable, because critical needs might not occur during the
increasing battery degradation. the PV systems given to daylight hours when PV generation is sufficient. We were able
households 1–6 are rated at only 260 W. to confirm during the third field trip that the lead-acid battery of
the days with the highest consumption from Figure 7 household 6 was still in excellent condition, but the residents of
are used to construct the critical load percentages shown household 2 said that their battery was not performing as well as
in table 3. For households 1 and 2, the critical loads repre- it did originally.
sent 17.2 and 15.4%, respectively, of the average daily load because a battery’s temperature also affects its useful life, the
before the hurricane. this information was obtained from data loggers recorded battery temperature. as Figure 8(b) shows,
electricity bills dated before the hurricane. unfortunately, even though Puerto rico has a tropical climate, the battery
it was not possible to obtain the loads before the hurri- temperatures generally remained within the expected limit of
cane for some households. these percentages can be used 20−25 °c, with the exception of the battery of household 5, where
to create critical load profiles for other households in the the temperature increased up to 30 °c. a possible explanation
future when designing microgrid systems for resilience. is that the household 5 is at a lower elevation than the others.

Battery Degradation Survey


repeatedly discharging lead-acid batteries below a recommend- as shown in table 4, all 15 households interviewed said that
ed soc progressively degrades their energy capacity. because they would prefer a solar system over a diesel or gas genera-
battery use in emergency situations is likely to be poorly con- tor for their energy needs. among those, 14 said that they are
trolled, it is important to collect data
about charge/discharge cycles so
table 3. Critical and normal energy consumption for six households.
that information can inform the
design of longer-life systems. all Load Before Cost of
recipients of PV-battery systems Critical Load Hurricane Critical Load Generator
Household (kWh/day) (kWh/day) Percentage (%) Fuel (US$/day)
were instructed to operate the battery
within safe limits. as Figure 8(a) 1 1.5 8.67 17.2 10
shows, households 5 and 6 used the 2 1.2 7.77 15.4 7
systems such that the DoD of the 3 1.2 — — 10
battery rarely exceeded 50%. on the 4 1.1 — — —
other hand, most of the discharge
5 0.7 7.5 9.2 —
cycles of the batteries in households
6 1 — — —
1–3 exceeded a 50% DoD. this may

200 32
Battery Temperature (°C)

Above 50% DoD 30


150 Below 50% DoD 28
Battery Cycles

26
100 24
22
50 Households: 1 2 3
20
4 5 6
0 18
1 2 3 4 5 6 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
Households Days
(a) (b)

figure 8. The battery operation for six households over 105 days: (a) the number of battery cycles above and below 50%
DoD and (b) the average daily battery temperature.

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 89


TV was critical to most families because it was a distraction
from their current difficulties, was a source of entertainment,
and provided information crucial to their well-being.

more comfortable using a PV-battery system. the household batteries are assumed to last 200 cycles when the DoD is
that answered “same” is household 4, in which electricity was above 50% and 500 cycles when the DoD is below 50%.
restored within 18 days (Figure 6). eleven households had used table 5 summarizes the operation of different combina-
a generator before, and nine of the 11 that were actively using tions of battery and PV ratings for each case. in particular, it
or had previously used a diesel/gas generator mentioned that shows how much energy would be produced and consumed
the PV-battery system improved their health. one household and how many charge/discharge cycles the battery would
was unfortunately provided with a defective commercial solar undergo in one, three, five, and ten years. the last four col-
generator system that quickly broke down. they were given a umns indicate the cost of each PV battery combination (capi-
replacement for use in future emergencies, but they gave our tal cost), including battery replacement costs (maintenance
survey a low rating based on their experience. cost), for a lifetime of one, three, five, and ten years. the cost
of a system depends more on the number of battery replace-
Simulation Results and Discussion ments needed than on duration of the system. in some cases,
a linear optimization method was used to minimize PV-bat- the cost is the same for initial installations of larger batteries
tery system costs that are able to supply critical loads for a year versus smaller ones that need replacing because of more fre-
considering PV and demand variations. battery degradation cost quent, deeper DoD operations.
over the lifetime of these systems was considered when choosing the systems designed for cases a, b, and c provide
the optimal design. We consider the following scenarios: some guidelines regarding the sizing of PV-battery sys-
✔ case a involves household 1’s critical load profile as illus- tems for emergencies. Figure 9(a) shows how the optimal
trated in Figure 7(a) and includes an efficiently managed battery capacity decreases as the PV rating increases for
refrigerator, a nebulizer, and an entertainment system. case a’s system. because we are interested only in the
✔ case b represents a household with a PeG patient and minimum battery capacity required to provide continuous
a small refrigerator. the critical load profile is a com- power to critical loads, extra PV generation is curtailed
bination of Figure 7(g) and (h). to avoid having to increase the battery size. Figure 9(b) shows
✔ case c is a household with a sleep apnea patient. the that, because the unit cost of batteries (us$192/kWh for
critical loads include the cPaP machine, a refrigera- lead-acid batteries and us$800/kWh for lithium-ion bat-
tor, and a small tV. the critical load profile for this teries) is much higher than the per-unit cost of PV gen-
scenario was created using the data in table 1. eration (us$1.5/W), the cost of the system decreases with
✔ case D has the largest critical load, which consists of decreasing battery size, even though the required PV rat-
a continuously running oxygen concentrator, a refrig- ing increases.
erator, and a large tV. using lead-acid batteries leads to the lowest cost systems for
an interesting finding was that tV was critical to most fami- cases a, b, and c for up to a three-year system life because,
lies because it was a distraction from their current difficulties, although lithium-ion batteries can be discharged completely and
was a source of entertainment, and provided information cru- therefore have a smaller rating, their cost is still much higher. in
cial to their well-being. particular, a system that lets lead-acid batteries discharge com-
PV output data for the optimizations are from the national pletely to meet critical loads is the least expensive solution
renewable energy Laboratory’s PVwatts calculator. Lead-acid for a one-year system life because such a system is effectively
sized to minimize the number of
table 4. A summary of survey results. battery cycles. When the expected
system lifetime increases, limit-
Solar Generator Same
ing the lead-acid battery to 50%
Do you prefer solar or generator? 100% (15) 0% 0% DoD is more economical because
Which are you most comfortable using? 93% (14) 0% 6.7% (one) it reduces the required number of
Yes No bat tery replacements.
on the other hand, case D re-
Did you have a generator before? 11 Four —
quires such a large system that it
If yes, did solar improve your health? 82% (nine) 9% (one) 9% (one)
would probably be economically

90 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


table 5. A comparison of various PV battery system designs.
Total Total
PV Load Battery Cycles (n) Cost (US$)
Battery PV (kWh), (kWh),
Battery Type Size (Ah) Size One One One Three Five Ten One Three Five Ten
and DoD at 12 V (Wp) Year Year Year Years Years Years Year Years Years Years
Case A: Refrigerator, nebulizer, and TV
Lithium ion 100 800 1,291 484 78 235 392 783 2,150, 2,150, 2,150, 2,150,
(100% DoD) r=0 r=0 r=0 r=0
Lead acid 170 600 968 63 188 313 626 1,291, 1,291, 1,682, 2,464,
(100% DoD) r=0 r=0 r=1 r=3
Lead acid 260 700 1,130 36 107 178 356 1,648, 1,648, 1,648, 1,648,
(50% DoD) r=0 r=0 r=0 r=0
Case B: PEG patient and small refrigerator
Lithium ion 60 300 484 197 166 497 828 1,655 1,020, 1,020, 1,020, 1,020,
(100% DoD) r=0 r=0 r=0 r=0
Lead acid 120 200 323 92 275 458 916 576, 852, 1,128, 1,680,
(100% DoD) r=0 r=1 r=2 r=4
Lead acid 120 300 484 88 263 438 876 726, 726, 726, 1,002,
(50% DoD) r=0 r=0 r=0 r=1
Case C: CPAP, refrigerator, and small TV
Lithium ion 120 700 1,130 459 245 735 1,225 2,450 2,190, 2,190, 2,190, 2,190,
(100% DoD) r=0 r=0 r=0 r=0
Lead acid 270 500 807 117 351 585 1,170 1,371, 1,992, 2,613, 4,476,
(100% DoD) r=0 r=1 r=2 r=5
Lead acid 290 700 1,130 108 324 540 1,080 1,717, 1,717, 2,384, 3,051,
(50% DoD) r=0 r=0 r=1 r=2
Case D: Oxygen concentrator, refrigerator, and TV
Lithium ion 950 4,900 7,907 3,594 219 656 1,093 2,185 5,900, 5,900, 5,900, 5,900,
(100% DoD) r=0 r=0 r=0 r=0
Lead acid 2,070 3,800 6,132 108 324 540 1,080 r=0 r=1 r=2 r=5
(100% DoD)
Lead acid 1,980 5,500 8,875 110 331 552 1,103 r=0 r=0 r=1 r=2
(50% DoD)
The cost consists of only the PV and batteries, and r is the number of battery replacements. Wp is the nameplate value, which is a measure of
watts at peak production.

12 4k
Battery Capacity (kWh)

Case A
10
3k
8
Cost (US$)

6 2k
4
1k
2
0 0
0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8 2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8 2
PV System Size (kWp) PV System Size (kWp)
(a) (b)

Lithium Ion (100% DoD) Lead Acid (100% DoD) Lead Acid (50% DoD)

figure 9. (a) The minimum battery capacity required to power critical loads over a year for case A as a function of the PV
rating. (b) The total system cost as a function of the PV rating.

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 91


also would like to thank Dennis r. Wise from the university of
2,500 Washington for some of the photographs.
PV-Battery System Day 65–66
2,000 Diesel Generator For Further Reading
Slope Is the clean energy institute. (2018). Puerto rico: clean energy so-
Cost (US$)

1,500 Fuel, Oil


Change, and lutions for public health. clean energy institute, university
1,000 Depreciation of Washington. [online]. available: https://www.cei.washington
Slope Is the Total Costs Per Day
Per-Day Cost of .edu/education/global-engagement/puerto-rico/
500 Battery Cycle and PV u.s. Department of energy, office of cybersecurity,
Capital and Electronic
Costs Depreciation energy security, and emergency response. (2018, apr.)
0
10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 Hurricanes nate, Maria, irma, and Harvey situation reports.
Days [online]. available: https://www.energy.gov/ceser/downloads/
hurricanes-nate-maria-irma-and-harvey-situation-reports
figure 10. A comparison of the cost of using a diesel genera- k. anderson, k. burman, t. simpkins, e. Helson, and L.
tor versus a PV battery system during an emergency for case A. Lisell. (2016, June). new York solar smart DG hub-resilient
solar project: economic and resiliency impact of PV and stor-
age on new York critical infrastructure. national renewable
beneficial to install a grid-connected system and operate it energy Laboratory (nreL) and city university of new York
for nonemergencies as well. in this case, lithium-ion batteries (cunY). [online]. available: https://www.nrel.gov/docs/
would be less expensive because their cost is lower at larger rat- fy16osti/66617.pdf
ings. the cost of the system in case D is based on a us$0.75/W L. santiago, c. e. shoichet and J. kravarik. (2018, aug.)
for PV and us$195/kWh for lithium-ion batteries. although Puerto rico’s new Hurricane Maria death toll is 46 times
lithium-ion batteries are currently more expensive than lead- higher than the government’s previous count. cnn. [online].
acid ones, they are more convenient because they are smaller available: https://www.cnn.com/2018/08/28/health/puerto-
and lighter. they are easier for a user to move around the house rico-gw-report-excess-deaths/index.html
to connect to various critical loads and also easier to deploy n. kishore, D. Marqués, a. Mahmud, M. V. kiang, i. ro-
after a natural disaster. driguez, a. Fuller, P. ebner, c. sorensen, F. racy, J. Lemery,
Figure 10 compares the total cost of using a diesel gen- L. Maas, J. Leaning, r. a. irizarry, s. balsari, and c. o.
erator and PV-battery system as a function of the duration buckee, “Mortality in Puerto rico after Hurricane Maria,”
of a power outage for case a (i.e., household 1). the capital New Eng. J. Med., vol. 379, no. 2, pp. 162–170, 2018. doi:
cost of a generator is lower than for a PV-battery system. 10.1056/neJMsa1803972.
However, the ongoing costs of fuel, oil changes, and depre- c. keerthisinghe, M. ahumada-Paras, L. D. Pozzo, D. s.
ciation rise rapidly. on the other hand, the ongoing cost kirschen, H. Pontes, W. k. tatum, and M. a. Matos, “PV-
of running a PV-battery system largely depends on battery battery systems for critical loads during emergencies: case
degradation because the PV panels and the other elec- study from Puerto rico after Hurricane Maria,” 2019. [on-
tronics are expected to last ten–15 years. these results sug- line]. available: https://www.researchgate.net/project/PV-
gest that any place likely to experience more than 66 days battery-systems-for-critical-Loads-during-emergencies-case-
of power outages (cumulative over multiple events) would study-from-Puerto-rico-after-Hurricane-Maria
benefit from a PV-battery system. Longer usage loads (e.g.,
cPaP, air mattress, or oxygen concentrator) may inevita- Biographies
bly need PV-battery systems or, at the very least, batteries Chanaka Keerthisinghe is with the university of Washing-
that can be charged with a generator during its use because ton, seattle.
small diesel/gas generators are noisy when used at night and Mareldi Ahumada-Paras is with the university of
are often not designed for continuous use. Washington, seattle.
Lilo D. Pozzo is with the university of Washington,
Acknowledgments seattle.
the authors would like to thank the university of Washington’s Daniel S. Kirschen is with the university of Washington,
clean energy institute and office of Global affairs’ Global seattle.
innovation Fund for providing travel funds. the solar-powered Hugo Pontes is with the university of Washington,
battery devices installed in March 2018 were purchased thanks seattle.
to generous support from the clean energy Group through its Wesley K. Tatum is with the university of Washington,
resilient Power Project and from gifts from numerous donors. seattle.
the group would like to thank all of the participants in the Marvi A. Matos is with blue origin, kent, Washington.
study and the community organizers in Jayuya, Puerto rico,
p&e
who helped organize and identify participants. the authors

92 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/MPE.2018.2885101
society news
M.J. Stryjewski

2018 General Meeting


reimagining the electric grid

M
MeMbers of the Ieee Power the week’s events kicked off at the
& energy society (Pes) and other in- oregon Museum of science and Indus-
dustry enthusiasts came together for the try (oMsI) with a delicious cat ere d
Pes General Meeting 5–9 August 2018. welcome reception, where friends old
More than 3,200 attendees converged and new were united. the oMsI had
on Portland, oregon, for new insights, many interesting exhibits that captured
innovative ideas, and answers to some the imaginations of attendees. As luck
of the most intriguing and important would have it, the premier attraction
questions facing the power industry today. was the robot revolution, a display that
During the course of the week, members demonstrated how, in the near future,
were able to attend informational, techni- robots will become our companions and
cal, and tutorial sessions; committee and colleagues—changing the way we play,
working group meetings; poster sessions; live, and work together.
a job fair; networking events; tours of tech- the following morning, the all-im-
nical facilities; and companion activities. portant Members’ Meeting featured an
As they say, “You can, in Portland,” and update on society activities from Pes
we certainly did! whether it was enjoying President saifur rahman, including a
Portland’s eclectic visual arts scene, great new interactive portion where attend-
meals from hundreds of food carts, or fan- ees were able to respond to questions in
tastic tax-free vintage shopping, Portland real time and help drive the conversa-
provided a truly unique environment for tion toward their interests.
this year’s conference. At the Plenary session, hosted by
richard Goddard of the host utility Port- PES President Saifur Rahman explains
Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/MPE.2018.2877915
land General electric, attendees were the new interactive portion of the
Date of publication: 7 January 2019 officially welcomed to Portland and opening session.

The plenary session panel discussed shifting trends in the electric industry.

94 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


In Memoriam: Prabha Shankar Kundur
On 9 October 2018, Prabha Shankar Kundur passed away previously served as president and CEO of Powertech
unexpectedly at the age of 79. A true technical leader in the Labs Inc., and, before that, he worked for nearly 25 years
electric power industry, Prabha chaired numerous commit- at Ontario Hydro, where he held senior positions involv-
tees and working groups of the IEEE Power & Energy Soci- ing advanced power system planning and design. Much
ety (PES), and he was elected as a Fellow of his work focused on modeling and
of the IEEE in 1985 “for contributions to measurement tools, analysis methods,
modeling techniques in power system and control techniques that enhance
control and stability analysis and their power system stability.
applications.” He served as the chair of Prabha was elected as a fellow of
the IEEE Power System Dynamic Perfor- the Canadian Academy of Engineering
mance Committee from 2002 to 2004. in 2003 and a foreign member of the
From 2006 to 2010, he was a member of U.S. National Academy of Engineering
the IEEE PES Governing Board as the vice in 2011. He was awarded two honorary
president for Education. He received sev- degrees: doctor honoris causa by the
eral IEEE awards, including the 1997 IEEE Politehnica University of Bucharest, Ro-
Nikola Tesla Award, the 2005 IEEE PES mania, in 2003 and doctor of engineer-
Charles Concordia Power System Engi- ing, honoris causa, by the University of
neering Award, and the 2010 IEEE Medal Waterloo, Canada, in 2004.
in Power Engineering. Prabha Shankar Kundur After earning his Ph.D. degree in
Prabha was also active in CIGRE for 1967 in electrical engineering from the
many years. He first served on Study Committee (SC) 38 as University of Toronto, Prabha returned to India to teach at
the Canadian representative and, later, as chair of Adviso- Bangalore University before accepting a position as analyti-
ry Group 2. During the restructuring of CIGRE in 2002, he cal engineer at Ontario Hydro in 1969. He also served as an
served as the first chair of SC C4 on System Technical Per- adjunct professor at the University of Toronto from 1979 to
formance from 2002 to 2006 and, subsequently, as a mem- 2017 and the University of British Columbia from 1994 to
ber of the Administrative Council from 2006 to 2010. He re- 2006. He authored Power System Stability and Control (Mc-
ceived the CIGRE Technical Committee Award in 1999, the Graw-Hill, 1994), a comprehensive book used worldwide by
CIGRE Honorary Member Award in 2006, and the CIGRE industry practitioners and students alike.
Medal in 2014. To recognize his technical leadership, the IEEE PES Prab-
A s president of Kundur Power System Solutions ha S. Kundur Power System Dynamics and Control Award
I n c . , Prabha performed international consulting and was established in his honor in 2012 to acknowledge out-
delivered advanced-level technical courses for utilities, standing contributions to the understanding and control of
manufacturers, and universities around the world. He the dynamics of the interconnected bulk power system.
Prabha is survived by his wife of 55 years, Geetha, his
Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/MPE.2018.2877874
Date of publication: 7 January 2019 daughter, Deepa, and his two grandchildren.

shifting trends in the electric industry ✔ Larry bekkedahl, vice president, timely and emerging topics were ex-
were discussed as well as strategy im- transmission and Distribution, plored in various session formats during
plications. six speakers from an interna- Portland General electric the week, including the highly attended
tional cross section of organizations deal- ✔ Peter Jørgensen, vice president, super sessions, where topics closely fol-
ing with diverse aspects of technology and Associated Activities, energinet lowed this year’s theme of reimagining
energy integration provided insight into ✔ Mark Ahlstrom, vice president, the electric grid:
initiatives that are currently underway renewable energy Policy, Nextera ✔ data science and data quality as
and their visions of the future. the excit- ✔ heather rosentrater, vice president, applied to power systems
ing lineup of participants included energy Delivery, Avista Corp. ✔ lower inertia and weaker grids
✔ Maria Pope, president and chief ✔ David Danner, chair, washing- ✔ new application of technology in
executive officer, Portland Gen- ton Utilities and transporta- the power industry
eral electric tion Commission. ✔ emergency response.

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 95


Long-time and new friends enjoyed the reception at the OMSI.

The poster sessions stimulated interesting discussions.

Many attendees congratulated award winners at the dinner.


before the week was done, more than
500 tutorials, technical sessions, pa-
t he annual Pes
Awards Gala once again
The creativity Although it seems
that the 2018 General
per sessions, poster sessions, commit- recognized our peers and pioneering Meeting just happened,
tee meetings, working group meetings, by applauding their we are hard at work on
and task force meetings were held, vision, leadership, and technological the 2019 General Meet-
propagating the latest technical infor-
mation and developing leading prac-
innovations. the cre-
ativity and pioneering
excellence ing, which will be held
4–8 August in Atlanta,
tices and standards for the power and technological excel- of the award Georgia. the steering
energy industry. lence of the award win- and Local organizing
the annual student/Industry/faculty ners was celebrated by winners was Committies plan to raise
Luncheon was a hit with students and
employers alike, who dined together
a smooth jazz band and
a delicious meal. we
celebrated by the bar again as we ex-
plore the theme expect
and then participated in a well-attended hope you’ll consider a smooth jazz Uncertainty/Prepare
job fair. this, along with the scholar- nominating a colleague to Adapt. we hope to
ship Plus reception and student poster in this upcoming year band and a see you in Atlanta in
session, highlighted a compelling stu-
dent Program.
and attend the 2019
Awards Gala.
delicious meal. August 2019!
p&e

january/february 2019 ieee power & energy magazine 97


calendar

PES meetings
for more information, www.ieee-pes.org

T
T H E I E E E P ow E r & E n E rg y May 2019 IEEE Electric Ship Technologies
Society’s (PES’s) website (http://www IEEE International Con ference Symposium (ESTS 2019), 13–16 Au-
.ieee-pes.org) features a meetings sec- on Electrical Machines and Drives gust, washington, D.C., United States,
tion, which includes calls for papers (IEMDC 2019), 11–15 May, San Di- contact Scott Sudhoff, sudhoff@purdue
and additional information about each ego, California, United States, contact .edu, https://ests19.mit.edu/
of the PES-sponsored meetings. Avoki omekanda, avoki.omekanda@
ieee.org, http://iemdc.org/ September 2019
January 2019 IEEE PES Innovative Smart Grid
IEEE PES 201 Joint Technical Com- IEEE PES Innovative Smart Grid Technologies Latin America (ISGT LA
mittee Meeting (JTCM 2019), 13–17 Technologies Asia (ISGT Asia 2019), 2019), 15–18 September, gramado, Bra-
January, orange County, California, 21–24 May, Chengdu, China, contact zil, contact gabriel Arguello, garguello@
United States, contact Solveig ward, Qi Huang, hwong@uestc.edu.cn, http:// cenace.org.ec, http://ieee-isgt-latam.org/
sward@quanta-technology.com, www sites.ieee.org/isgt-asia-2019/
.pestechnical.org I EEE PE S Innovative Smart Grid
June 2019 Technologies Europe (ISGT Europe
February 2019 14th International Conference on 2019), 29 September–2 october, Bu-
IEEE PES Innovative Smart Grid Transmission and Distribution Con- charest, romania, contact george Cris-
Technologies (ISGT 2019), 18–21 struction, Operation and Live-Line tian Lazaroiu, cristian.lazaroiu@upb.ro,
February, washington, D.C., United Maintenance (ESMO 2019), 24–27 http://sites.ieee.org/isgt-europe-2019/
States, contact 2019ISgT@ieee.org, June, Columbus, ohio, United States,
http://ieee-isgt.org/ contact Eriks Surmanis, e.surmanis@ December 2019
pdc-cables.com, http://ieee-esmo.com/ IEEE PES Asia-Pacific Power and
March 2019 Energy Engineering Conference
IEEE PES GTD Grand Internation- IEEE PowerTech Milan (PowerTech (APPEEC 2019), 1–4 December, Macao,
al Conference and Exposition Asia 2019), 23–27 June, Milan, Italy, contact China, contact Man-Chung wong,
2019 (GTD Asia 2019), 20–23 March, Federica Foiadelli, federica.foiadelli@ cmwong@umac.mo
Bangkok, Thailand, contact nopbhorn polimi.it, http://ieee-powertech.org/
Leeprechanon, nopbhorn@engr.tu.ac
.th, http://www.ieeegt-d.org/ August 2019
IEEE PES General Meeting (GM 2019),
4–8 August, Atlanta, georgia, United States,
Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/MPE.2018.2873954
contact Matt Stryjewski, matthew.stry
p&e
Date of publication: 7 January 2019 jewski@ieee.org, http://pes-gm.org/2019/

98 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/MPE.2018.2885104
in my view (continued from p. 104)

problem and the search for alternatives, run operating costs, will be replaced by is fully utilized, the price rises to limit
usually some form of long-term capac- capital-intensive but low or zero-vari- demand. In these periods, the short-run
ity payment, to restore the economics of able-cost resources. Distributed demand price is entirely determined by the scar-
investment. These alternative approaches participation will be evermore impor- city value. But in all other respects, the
typically postulated some traditional tant in managing overall system balance analysis of basic principles is the same
generating-capacity type to serve as the and security. The result will be a much as it is for the Figure 1. The dispatch
benchmark for the cost of new entry to less important role for spot markets and quantity changes over time, but the spot
identify and pay the missing money. the associated spot locational marginal price is always equal to the short-run
The early and growing penetration prices. So the argument goes that new variable cost, including the marginal
of renewables has been driven by man- revenue models will be required, and cost of scarcity. Efficient spot prices are
dates and subsidies. At some point, the the fundamentals of the basic electricity part of the solution derived from basic
likely importance of these top-down ap- market will have to change. principles. And with greater reliance
proaches will diminish for at least one Despite the appeal of this logic, it de- on zero-variable-cost resources that can
of two reasons. The cost of the subsidies pends on implicit assumptions that are change availability over short horizons,
and mandates will be too great, and the incorrect and point in the wrong direc- the scarcity component of spot pricing
political economy will shift away from tion for market reform. One implicit as- becomes even more important. In the
this approach. Or the cost of renewables sumption is that the basic analysis cannot extreme case, scarcity pricing is the only
will decline to the point where they are accommodate a world with a large frac- short-run incentive that matters.
fully economic without the mandates and tion of energy supplied by zero-variable- Another implicit assumption of the
subsidies, which will then atrophy and cost renewable energy. The argument is flawed argument is that demand partici-
disappear. The interesting questions that zero-variable-cost supply will pro- pation can be managed without efficient
are how can economically efficient re- duce low spot prices that could never pricing mechanisms. Under the current
newables alter the fundamentals and how support efficient investment. supply configuration with large thermal
will this dictate changes in the basics of The flaw in the argument is revealed generators, it is possible to imagine cen-
efficient electricity market design? by looking again at the implied spot tralized control without the benefits of
Going forward, the increasing role market. Consider the extreme case in spot prices. But even for the present case,
of intermittent renewables and the tech- Figure 2. The short-run supply curve, it is commonplace for system operators
nological potential of distributed energy or dispatch stack, is now replaced with to observe how much better the system
resources, especially including demand a green supply that is completely zero- works when locational prices provide the
participation, might seem to turn over variable-cost renewables. In most hours, right incentives and reinforce the choic-
the assumptions of 30 years ago and the implied efficient price is zero, and es of economic dispatch. Moving to a
call for an entirely new approach. From demand participation would expand to greater reliance on distributed resources
this perspective, large-scale thermal take advantage of the free energy. In (many and small) and demand participa-
generation, with relatively high short- some hours, when the available capacity tors (many and small) leads inexorably
to a greater need to have real-time spot
prices that send the right price signals.
Short-Run Electricity Market The central control of distributed re-
with Zero Marginal Cost Renewables
sources would not be feasible, and prices
Short-Run must provide the needed incentives. Fail-
Marginal ure to provide the right price signals will
Price at Cost
lead to distributed decisions that would
Energy Price (¢/kWh)

7–7:30 p.m.
undermine efficient operations.
Hence, the increased arrival of renew-
ables and a greater reliance on distributed
Scarcity Price

Demand resources both point to fundamentals that


7–7:30 p.m. reinforce rather than invalidate the fun-
Demand damental logic of electricity spot-market
Price at
9–9:30 a.m.
9–9:30 a.m. operation and pricing. This overview
Demand
Price at reveals that the problem lies not in the
2–2:30 a.m.
2–2:30 a.m. fundamentals of market design but rather
Q1 Q2 Qmax
(MW) in the flaws of implementation that have
led to the distracting focus on capacity
figure 2. The renewable-only spot market. markets and other ad hoc approaches for

100 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


2019

10 Years of ISGT!
Innovation for a Flexible and Resilient Grid
REGISTER NOW
2019 Innovative Smart Grid Technologies (ISGT 2019)
18-21 February 2019 | Grand Hyatt Washington, Washington DC

Join experts from around the world as we gather at the ISGT North America Conference to
share experiences and lessons learned, and to raise awareness and understanding of the latest
concepts, applications, and technologies.

ISGT 2019 provides a forum to discuss the latest issues, trends, and emerging and innovative
technologies for grid modernization in the face of challenges of a rapidly changing environment
resulting from the dramatic increase in deployments of renewable and Distributed Energy
Resources (DERs) and the emergence of new business and operating concepts and services.
The topics discovered include prosumers, microgrids, aggregators, distribution markets, and
platforms for the generation, commercialization, and management of electricity.

The conference is organized along three tracks:


• Transmission and distribution systems planning and analysis
• Technology applications and supporting tools for transmission and
distribution system operations
• Market and policy considerations in facilitating innovation and enabling
a flexible and resilient grid

For more information visit: ieee-isgt.org

Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/MPE.2018.2885103


correcting the defects of the spot-market the range of the ramping constraints, spot against the real-time spot price. The value
implementation. There are small and prices in all periods can reflect the value of these prominent best-practice features
large changes in spot-market implemen- of ramping flexibility and provide market in existing electricity markets has been
tation that have been long needed, and rewards for the generators and demand well established in actual implementation.
these reforms will be even more impor- participants that can and do respond, with- Reconsidering of these best practices in
tant for the future electricity system. out the need to discriminate by creating light of the increase in intermittent gener-
The first reform is better scarcity pric- special categories of dispatch resources. ation and distributed resources reinforces
ing. The example of the Electric Reli- One of the simplifying assumptions the importance of the fundamentals.
ability Council of Texas market stands of the basic spot-market model is that The problem is not the underlying
out as guiding the way. Embedded in everything is so flexible that there are no structure of the theory of electricity spot
the original spot-market analysis, an as- start-up costs, no minimum run times, markets. The basic model works in the-
sumption was that demand participation and so on. Some markets are premised ory and performs well in practice. But
would handle the needed scarcity pric- on the assumption that these real-world the practical implementations have used
ing. But there is a chicken-and-egg prob- complications are so minor that they can certain shortcuts, or averted eyes from
lem: without scarcity pricing, there is not be ignored. But ignoring these complica- the basics, and created imperfect market
enough incentive for demand participa- tions becomes more important in a system implementations that seem to be incom-
tion. A missing element is in the pricing where the remaining thermal resources are patible with the needs of the electricity
of operating reserves, i.e., the short-term transformed from base-load facilities that markets of the immediate future.
capacity set aside to deal with unexpected are always running to dispatched resourc- The argument here is that the funda-
changes over the next dispatch intervals. es that keep changing output to meet the mentals continue to point in the same
This necessarily administrative construct system requirements. In this model of the direction. The defects in practical short-
can be addressed with the operating re- future, the costs of startup and minimum term markets are not minor issues that can
serve demand curve, based on the value load complicate the pricing analysis and be ignored. But a comprehensive rethink-
of lost load and the probability that load lead to the requirement for uplift payments ing of the market design is not required.
will be curtailed. As in Texas, this cre- to ensure participation in the dispatch. A The importance of the fundamentals and
ates the right incentives for generation to natural extension of the basic analysis of the need to continue to improve on the
be available and, through the associated efficient spot prices is found under the market designs already in place must be
energy price, sends the virtuous signal heading of extended locational marginal recognized. The expansion of intermit-
to demand participation and distributed prices (ELMPs) that preserve, as much as tent and distributed resources makes this
resources to respond to the needs of ef- possible, the basic pricing arguments and more urgent, but it would be a good idea
ficient dispatch. This separates scarcity minimize the need for uplift payments. in any event. The big mistake would be to
pricing from the exercise of market power, Although approximations of this pricing continue to create new products and sub-
adjusts the implied scarcity price over all reform have been in use for many years, sidies in the futile attempt to replace mar-
hours, and provides good incentives with- the more general application is receiving ket incentives with central procurement
out requiring the system operator to de- increased attention with the increased pen- directives. The proper challenge is to take
clare an emergency, and an alternative to etration of intermittent resources. Further- the fundamentals seriously, and follow
the administrative determination of long- more, implementing the ELMPs in spot where they lead: get the prices right.
term capacity payments. markets interacts in a natural way with the
A second reform would be to give need for multiperiod dispatch and pricing, For Further Reading
greater attention to multiperiod dispatch so the reforms can proceed together. ERCOT. (2014). About the operating re-
and pricing. In particular, ramping con- The central role of the real-time spot- serve demand curve and wholesale electric
straints can and do limit the ability to market design is one of the key findings in prices. [Online]. Available: http://www
respond to short-term changes in net de- the analysis of the fundamentals of elec- .ercot.com/content/news/presentations/
mand that will be of increasing importance tricity markets. The associated locational 2014/ORDCUpdate-FINAL.pdf
with the expansion of intermittent resourc- pricing model resolved the longstanding PJM Interconnection. (2017). Pro-
es. This sometimes goes under the head- dilemma of how to charge for the op- posed enhancements to energy price for-
ing of flexibility requirements. In practice, portunity costs of transmission, provides mation. [Online]. Available: http://www
much of the problem relates to actual the foundations for financial transmission .pjm.com/-/media/library/reports-notices/
dispatch models using something close to rights (FTRs), and creates the benchmark special-reports/20171115-proposed-enhance
a single-period formulation with the as- for the design of day-ahead markets that ments-to-energy-price-formation.ashx
sociated prices. This inherently ignores must be compatible with real-time pric- F. C. Schweppe, M. C. Caramanis,
the value of ramping. The computational ing. The forward markets allow for a R. D. Tabors, and R. E. Bohn, Spot Pric-
problems of a multiperiod dispatch are reconfiguration of FTRs and the intro- ing of Electricity. Norwell, MA: Kluwer
relevant but should not be determinative. duction of virtual bidding for day-ahead Academic, 1988.
p&e
With a multiperiod dispatch longer than financial contracts that will be settled

102 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


advertisers index
The Advertisers Index contained in this issue is compiled as a service to our readers and advertisers: the
publisher is not liable for errors or omissions although every effort is made to ensure its accuracy. Be sure
to let our advertisers know you found them through IEEE Power & Energy Magazine.

Company page# URL Phone


ASPEN, Inc. CVR4 www.aspeninc.com +1 650 347 3997
Bigwood Systems, Inc. 6 www.bigwood-systems.com +1 607 257 0915
CYME CVR 2 www.eaton.com/cyme +1 800 361 3627
Delta Star 96 deltastar.com
DIgSILENT GmbH 3 www.digsilent.de
EasyPower LLC 17 www.EasyPower.com/1584
Electrical Studies, Corp. 97 www.electrical-studies.com
ETAP 15 etap.com/arcflash +1 949 900 1000
Manitoba Hydro International Ltd. 7 www.pscad.com
Massachusetts Water Resources Authority 96 https://mwra.applicantpro.com/jobs +1 617 242 6000
NR Electric Co., Ltd 12 www.nrec.com +86 25 8717 8888
P & R Technologies 19 www.pr-tech.com +1 800 722 8078
Powertech Labs, Inc. 11 www.dsatools.com
PowerWorld Corporation 8 www.powerworld.com +1 217 384 6330
RTDS Technologies, Inc. 9 www.rtds.com
Siemens Power Technologies International CVR 3 siemens.com/electrical-digital-twin
SKM Systems Analysis, Inc. 5 www.skm.com +1 800 500 4SKM

445 Hoes Lane, Piscataway, NJ 08854

IEEE power & energy magazine representative


Erik Henson
Naylor Association Solutions
+1 352 333 3443, fax: +1 352 331 3525
ehenson@naylor.com

Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/MPE.2018.2884804

Reach Decision Makers in the Power & Energy Market With


IEEE PES Support Opportunities!

Advertise in the Following Publications:


Power and Energy Magazine
- The global source of information for power and energy professionals

PES Monthly eNews Update


- Build your brand with high-impact digital ads on our eNewsletter and website,
reaching more than 38,000 subscribers monthly

IEEE Electrification Magazine


- A publication for industry practitioners focused on advanced concepts, technologies,
and practices associated with all aspects of electrification

Support Upcoming Conferences:


IEEE PES General Meeting 2019
- August 4-8, 2019 in Atlanta, GA. Raise the profile of your organization among more IEEE PES
GENERAL MEETING

than 3500 electric energy professionals who are your current and potential customers. 4-8 AUGUST
ATLANTA, GA USA

For more information contact: Erik Henson | Media Director | (352) 333-3443
Naylor Association Solutions | ehenson@naylor.com
Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/MPE.2018.2885098
in my view
William W. Hogan

market design practices


which ones are best?

O
ORGANIzED WHOLESALE ELEC-
Short-Run Electricity Market
tricity markets in the United States fol-
low the principles of bid-based, securi- Short-Run
ty-constrained, economic dispatch with Marginal
Price at Cost
locational marginal prices. The basic
7–7:30 p.m.
Energy Price (¢/kWh)

elements build on analyses done when


large thermal generators dominated
the structure of the electricity market in Demand
most countries. Notable exceptions were 7–7:30 p.m.
Price at
countries like Brazil that utilized large- 9–9:30 a.m.
scale pondage hydro systems. For such
systems, the critical problem centered on Price at Demand
2–2:30 a.m. 9–9:30 a.m.
managing a multiyear inventory of stored
Demand
water. But for most developed electric- 2–2:30 a.m.
ity systems, the dominance of thermal
Q1 Q2 Qmax
generation implied that the major inter-
(MW)
actions in unit commitment decisions
would be measured in hours to days, and figure 1. The spot market.
the interactions in operating decisions
would occur over minutes to hours. As a than dispatch costs, would provide the the importance of the basic principles and
result, single-period economic dispatch contribution for covering the cost of good market design. Not every electricity
became the dominant model for analyz- investment. With the accompanying market in the world has made this transi-
ing the underlying basic principles. simplifying assumptions, this efficient tion. However, it is clear that if open ac-
The structure of this analysis inte- dispatch and pricing model would have cess and nondiscrimination principles set
grated the terminology of economics been all that was be needed to support the constraints, there is only one market
and engineering. As shown in Figure 1, operating and investment decisions. design that meets the test, and the critical
the increasing short-run marginal cost More than 30 years ago, Schweppe et al. elements of this efficient market design
of generation defined the dispatch stack showed how this basic efficient market have been adopted by every organized
or supply curve. Thermal efficiencies could be expanded to include the effects wholesale market in the United States.
and fuel costs were the primary sources of transmission and the associated loca- The practical application of the ba-
of short-run generation cost differences. tional prices. In principle, extending this sic principles has been highly successful
The introduction of markets added the model to include multipart bids, look- but not always perfect. A major problem
demand perspective, where lower prices ahead, and multiperiod optimization occurred with implementation details that
induced higher loads. As demand shift- presented no major challenges. tended to depress the spot energy price,
ed over the day, prices would rise and The road to success with this market particularly during periods of constrained
fall. The rents earned by generators, in design was littered with prominent failed capacity. The defect of the twin absences
the periods when prices were higher attempts to avoid the basic analysis and of demand participation and explicit
dismiss the special characteristics of scarcity pricing created the missing-money
Digital Object Identifier 10.1109/MPE.2018.2871736
security-constrained economic dispatch.
Date of publication: 7 January 2019 Eventually, the expensive failures showed (continued on p. 100)

104 ieee power & energy magazine january/february 2019


Streamlined renewable
integration analysis
Leverage existing GIS data to optimize
processes and planning studies

The grid is becoming increasingly connected at the distribution level


due to the growing penetration of Distributed Energy Resources
(DERs). Power distribution planners are experiencing more
interconnection requests – causing longer queues and additional
manual efforts to perform studies. Future ready utilities need a
solution to help reduce efforts, automate processes, and maximize
ROI. With the Siemens Electrical Digital Twin solution, distribution
planners can streamline interconnection processes and leverage
data from existing GIS systems for more accurate planning studies.

siemens.com/electrical-digital-twin
ASPEN
OneLiner
Short circuit and relay coordination program
trusted by utilities worldwide

ASPEN OneLiner ™
Powerful, fast, intuitive and easy to use

Applications Advanced features


PRC compliance Simulates breaker-failure conditions
Fault location Models wind and solar plants and VSC converters
Circuit breaker rating Time-distance diagram
Relay setting and testing Vendor-specific distance relay models
System-wide coordination studies Relay coordination checking with stepped events

ASPEN 49 N. San Mateo Dr., San Mateo, CA 94401 USA


650-347-3997 info@aspeninc.com www.aspeninc.com

You might also like