You are on page 1of 23

Theft, Gift-Giving, and Trustworthiness: Honesty Is Its Own

Reward in Rural Paraguay

By Laura Schechter*

In developing countries lacking legal enforcement, villagers may use implicit con-
tracts to minimize crime. I construct a dynamic limited-commitment model, in which
a thief cannot commit to forego stealing, but is induced to steal less by the promise of
future gifts. Combining survey data on production, theft, gifts, and trust with experi-
ments measuring trustworthiness, I provide supporting evidence. Farmers living near
more relatives or with plots that are difficult to steal from give fewer gifts and trust
more, and those living near more relatives also experience less theft. Giving increases
when trust is lower and the threat of theft is greater. (JEL D86, K42, O17, Z13)

Due to a lack of legal enforcement in rural giving gifts to a person they believe to be a thief
areas around the world, theft between farmers in the hopes that this untrustworthy person will
is a common occurrence. Fifty percent of sur- limit the amount he steals from them. Thus, hon-
vey respondents in rural Paraguay reported that est people may receive few gifts, while untrust-
some item was stolen from them in the past year. worthy people benefit.
Among those from whom something was stolen, Gary S. Becker (1968) models a rational anon-
median theft accounted for a loss of 2 percent ymous thief who weighs the benefits of stealing
of annual income. Not only is theft large, it against the costs of possible punishment. This
also affects investment decisions, as 42 percent one-period model predicts there will be more
of respondents said there was at least one crop theft when the potential gains are greater and
they didn’t plant because of fear of theft. More the probability of punishment is smaller. A large
­unusually, 42 percent of households admit to literature on anonymous property crime (Eric
D. Gould, Bruce A. Weinberg, and David B
Mustard 2002; Steven D. Levitt 2004) has grown
* Department of Agricultural and Applied Economics,
Uni­ver­sity of Wisconsin at Madison, 417 Taylor Hall, 427 from this seminal research. Becker’s model can
Lorch St., Madison, WI 53706 (e-mail: lschechter@wisc. explain why some crops are more vulnerable to
edu). This research was funded by the Social Science theft. But, only in a multiperiod model in which
Research Center (SSRC), the Russell Sage Foundation nonanonymous individuals interact repeatedly
(RSF), Berkeley’s Institute of Business and Economic can gift-giving play a role in theft prevention.
Research (IBER), Berkeley’s Center for International
and Development Economics Research (CIDER), and the Farmers in rural areas have extensive knowl-
Giannini Foundation. I am grateful to José Molinas and edge of each other’s actions, interact with each
Instituto Desarrollo for their support in Paraguay. I’d like other on a daily basis, and use formal and infor-
to thank George Akerlof, Michael Carter, Anke Kessler, mal contracts in many aspects of their lives
Ted Miguel, Krishna Pendakur, Matthew Rabin, Heather
Royer, Elisabeth Sadoulet, Perry Shapiro, three anony- (Jean-Philippe Platteau and Jeffrey Nugent 1992;
mous referees, and seminar participants at Brandeis Uni­ Christopher Udry 1994). Given the lack of ano-
versity, Carnegie Mellon University, Harvard Univer­sity, nymity and the long-term nature of relationships
Middlebury Col­lege, North Carolina State Univer­sity, that characterize life in rural Paraguay, villagers
Simon Fraser University, UC Berkeley, UC Irvine, Univer­ should be able to use informal contracts with
sity of Maryland, University of Wisconsin at Madison, and
Williams College for comments. I am indebted to Ethan one another to prevent excessive theft as well.
Ligon for his invaluable advice and patience. I construct a dynamic limited-commitment

Anthropologists have discussed theft between fellow model in which the formal judicial system is
villagers in the context of Italy (Edward C. Banfield 1958),
Mexico (George M. Foster 1965), Vietnam (Jeffrey Paige
1975), and Malaysia (James C. Scott 1978).
 
The survey covered 223 households in rural Paraguay Informal contracts refer to the unwritten system of
in 2002. sanctions and rewards.
1560
VOL. 97 NO. 5 schechter: theft, gift-giving, and trustworthiness in paraguay 1561

ineffective. An agent cannot credibly commit to nature of gifts in “primitive societies,” “which
refrain from stealing from another agent, and so are in theory voluntary, disinterested and sponta-
must be induced to limit his theft by the ­promise neous, but are in fact obligatory and interested’’
of future gifts. The model presented here is (Mauss 1967, 1). In this case, gifts are similar to
novel in the economics literature on crime, as loans which must be repaid in the future.
most other papers do not consider interactions Using data from rural Paraguay, I test for
between thieves and their victims. evidence of contracting between thieves and
Economists often think of gift-giving as their victims. Researchers in Paraguay and at
something one does on the holidays, a symbolic the University of Wisconsin collected panel
gesture, a form of charity, a means of trade, or data from over 200 households in 16 randomly
a means of reciprocal exchange. The dynamic selected villages of rural Paraguay at three points
limited-commitment model shows gifts can also in time throughout the 1990s (Michael R. Carter
be given to potential thieves to deter theft. This and Pedro Olinto 2003). I conducted a fourth
model yields predictions contrary to those from round of data collection in 2002, adding detailed
fairness models in which agents reward actors questions on theft experienced by a household,
with good intentions (Matthew Rabin 1993) or gifts they gave, and survey data on their level of
give gifts to reduce inequality (Ernst Fehr and trust to the original, more standard, questions
Klaus M. Schmidt 1999), as well as mutual on production. I also ran a series of economic
insurance models in which households give experiments measuring trust, trustworthiness,
gifts to those households with whom they have and risk aversion with the same households that
fewer enforcement problems (Stephen Coate and responded to the survey. While the main limita-
Martin Ravallion 1993). Of course, households tion of the dataset is the relatively small sample
give gifts for a myriad of reasons, among them, size, the advantage is that it combines real-world
a preference for fairness, a form of mutual insur- decisions made by the household, survey mea-
ance, and a desire to appease potential thieves. sures of trust, and experimental data on risk
This last reason for gift-giving, while not the aversion and trustworthiness.
only reason, has been generally ignored in the To test the predictions of the model empiri-
economics literature. cally, I estimate a system of three equations with
Colin F. Camerer (1988) and H. Lorne theft experienced, gifts given, and trust as the
Carmichael and W. Bentley MacLeod (1997) left-hand side variables. Evidence is provided
explain the use of gifts (and particularly imprac- that farmers do contract with each other to limit
tical gifts) in modern society as signals repre- theft. Households whose fields are less vulner-
senting willingness to enter into a relationship. able to theft experience less theft, give fewer
This is different from the transfers described in gifts, and have a greater level of trust (relative
this paper, which are between villagers who are to other farmers within their village) in their fel-
forced into relationships with one another due to low villagers. Households that live in the same
geographic proximity. Marcel Mauss (1967) and village with more of their close family mem-
Richard A. Posner (1981) emphasize the exchange bers give fewer gifts. At first this result seems
surprising, given findings that relatives in rural
areas of developing countries transfer more to

Economists have modeled thieves interacting with each other than other households (Yoram Ben-
other thieves, teaching each other methods, or exerting peer Porath 1980; Posner 1981; Andrew D. Foster
pressure (Edward L. Glaeser, Bruce Sacerdote, and José A. and Mark R. Rosenzweig 2001). However, these
Scheinkman 1996), or victims interacting in neighborhood results are in accord with the predictions of the
watch programs (Steffen Huck and Michael Kosfeld 2007). limited-commitment model if family members
However, there are few models in which victims interact
with thieves, and there are no empirical papers that I know are either more trustworthy when acting with
of on the topic. In the theoretical paper by Vai-Lam Mui one another or if they monitor each other’s fields
(1995), one farmer sabotages a second farmer out of envy, more. This shows the importance of gift-giving
and the second farmer can limit this sabotage by giving to limit theft.
gifts. The act of sabotage gives no monetary benefits, only
serving to reduce the saboteur’s envy. In the envy model, Although gift-giving may be a form of char-
thieves must be poorer than their victims, and gift-giving ity or of progressive taxation, the results suggest
will occur even in a one-shot game. this is not the main underlying cause. A social
1562 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2007

p­ lanner would prefer that the richest people items include crops, small animals, and small
redistributed wealth to the poorest, while a tools. Large items include large animals and
model of charitable giving would suggest that large tools. Of those items for which the
altruistic farmers give more. Instead, I find that thief’s identity was known, 70 percent of
farmers who live in the same village with more smaller items were stolen by a neighbor or a
close family members give fewer gifts, and that relative, while only 18 percent of larger items
farmers with fields that no one passes give fewer were stolen by a neighbor (and none by rela-
gifts and experience less theft. This suggests tives). Sixty-six percent of the known thieves
that it is not necessarily the richest nor the most of small items were given gifts, lent money,
altruistic who are giving, but rather the most or hired by the victim before the theft, while
vulnerable to theft. In addition, farmers with only 36 percent of the known thieves of
more trustworthy neighbors plant more steal- large items were given these transfers. Only
able crops. This suggests it is not necessarily 4 percent of known thieves of small items
the poorest who are receiving, but rather the less were reported to the police, but 64 percent
trustworthy. of thieves of large items were reported. The
The remainder of this paper is organized as word theft in the rest of this paper refers only
follows. Section I lists eight facts about theft to the theft of smaller items.
in rural Paraguay. In Section II, I lay out the
dynamic limited-commitment model and its 2. Theft is common and economically impor-
implications. Section III describes the survey tant. Forty-three percent of households had
data and experiments, while Section IV uses some small item stolen from them in the
the data to test the implications of the model. past year. The median value stolen from the
Section V concludes. households that experienced theft was around
$17, which is a 1 percent loss of median house-
I.  Stylized Facts about Theft hold income.

Anthropologists discuss different reasons for 3. Victims know who is stealing from them.
sharing, including trade, altruism, reciprocity, Forty-seven percent of those who experi-
and “tolerated theft.” Tolerated theft occurs enced theft knew or suspected the identity of
when, due to diminishing marginal returns, the thief of at least one of the items stolen
it does not pay the owner of a stock of food to from them in the past year.
defend it against a hungry village-mate who
will be willing to fight harder for it (Nicholas 4. It is believed that some people receive less
G. Blurton-Jones 1987; Kristen Hawkes 1993; psychic disutility from thieving than others.
Rebecca L. Bliege-Bird and Douglas Bird 1997). Seventy percent of the victims who knew or
Food taken under the guise of tolerated theft suspected the identity of the thief said the
may be taken through force, or it may be pas- thief committed the crime because of pov-
sively transferred in an attempt to avoid force. erty, 2 percent blamed revenge, and 4 per-
James C. Scott (1985) proposes another view cent blamed envy. Twenty-five percent added
of theft as an “everyday form of peasant resis- in their own option of either habit or “no
tance.” In Malaysia, the victims of theft tended
to be the peasants who had mechanized their
farms rather than employing poorer peasants to 
In the Encuesta Integrada de Hogares carried out by
do the same work. The threat of theft was used the national statistical bureau of Paraguay (DGEEC), 8.3
percent of rural households claimed to have experienced
to ensure a continued stream of work. some theft in 2000. In my sample, 50.2 percent of house-
Below, I list stylized facts about theft in rural holds experienced some theft, while only 14.4 percent expe-
Paraguay and give supporting evidence from the rienced the theft of a large item. Given that respondents to
data. the national survey may mention only larger items stolen
and not petty theft, and that there may be more under-
reporting in a large national survey, these numbers seem
1. The people who steal “smaller” items have quite comparable.
a different relationship with their victims 
Theft of large and small items is 2 percent of median
than people who steal “larger” items. Small household income.
VOL. 97 NO. 5 schechter: theft, gift-giving, and trustworthiness in paraguay 1563

shame” (sin vergüenza). One might think that fields at night or planting more desirable crops
even more victims would have chosen “no further from footpaths. One option was: “If
shame” if it had been an option on the list. In you know someone is a thief, do you give him
Malaysia, farmers “think they know who is to gifts to avoid getting stolen from?” Forty-two
blame for most thefts. Three names are most percent of households answered yes.
frequently mentioned” and those three people
are “members of the ‘undeserving,’ ‘disrepu- In general, victims are on friendly terms with
table’ poor” (Scott 1995, 270–71). Casual thieves. Sixty-six percent of the suspected
conversation suggests that, in Paraguay as thieves received gifts, work, or loans from
well, each village has only a few thieves. their victim before the theft, while 82 percent
were from the same village as the victim. In
5. Victims do not report thieves to the police fact, the thieves are often close neighbors
or punish them physically. Only 14 percent (54 percent) or relatives (16 percent) of the
of households that suspected or knew the victim.
identity of the thief yelled at him, 29 percent
stopped drinking terere (a tea drunk socially 8. Investment decisions are distorted due to
in Paraguay) with him, and only 4 percent the potential of theft. The survey asked each
reported him to the authorities. Perhaps vic- household if there was a crop they wanted
tims in the survey punish thieves so lightly to plant but didn’t because of fear of theft.
due to a prohibitive social cost to physically Forty-two percent of respondents said there
harming a neighbor who has lived nearby for was a crop, and 8 percent said there was an
generations. animal, they were discouraged from planting
or raising because of fear of theft.
6. Some plots of land are more vulnerable to
theft than others. More of a crop is stolen The giving this paper focuses on does not
when it is planted on a plot along a footpath. include Christmas or birthday presents, only the
I compare crops (red, white, and fresh corn, giving of agricultural products or livestock. Thus
yucca, banana, melon, and watermelon) this gift, or transfer, refers literally to something
planted on plots which no nonhousehold that is given, and is not a present as we may
member and one or more nonhousehold think of it. Casual conversation suggests that
member walks past per week. For each crop, the three most common ways this giving takes
more is stolen from fields which more people place are: (a) a household decides to give some
walk past. Fifty-six percent of households of a crop to another household and so sends one
claimed to avoid planting more desirable of its younger members to take the gift to the
crops in plots adjoining popular footpaths, receiving household; (b) a villager goes to visit
although only households that cultivate at another household after work or on the week-
least one such plot can use this strategy. end and, although the visitor did not request
anything, the household sends him home with
7. Households give transfers to thieving house- a bit of produce; and (c) a villager goes to visit
holds to avoid being stolen from. Households another household with the express purpose of
were given a list of actions they might under- requesting a bit of some crop output.
take to avoid theft, such as monitoring their
II.  Dynamic Limited-Commitment Model

From anecdotal evidence, even if a farmer catches a The stylized facts above suggest that both
thief red-handed, he does not physically harm him, although
he does reclaim the stolen object. gift-giving and theft occur in equilibrium, while

This question was asked toward the beginning of the current gift-giving and the promise of future
survey in the land tenure section, before the questions on
theft. People were encouraged to think about whether peo-

ple walked past their field on the way to the bus stop, the There is anecdotal evidence that, if a farmer stops giv-
school, or their work. They should not be thinking yet about ing transfers to the thief, he may begin stealing larger quan-
theft and about people who might walk to their field for the tities of “small items” from the farmer although he will not
express purpose of stealing. steal “large items” such as cows.
1564 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2007

gift-giving is used to limit theft. I construct a As we have seen in the previous section, both
dynamic model in which potential thieves can- theft and gift-giving persist in equilibrium. This
not commit to refrain from stealing but can means that there must be something preventing
be convinced not to steal more than some tol- the farmer from fully compensating the thief
erated amount by strategic gift-giving.10 The for refraining from stealing. Agatha Christie
model is similar to those designed by Narayana claimed criminals must have means, motive,
R. Kocherlakota (1996), Kenneth M. Kletzer and opportunity. The model sketched thus far is
and Brian D. Wright (2000), and Ethan Ligon, missing that last item.
Jonathan P. Thomas, and Tim Worrall (2002). Opportunity changes in each period, and
The dynamic limited­-commitment model is I incorporate that by stating that the cost of
commonly used as a basis for empirical work stealing (to the thief) is different in each state
on informal contracts in developing coun- of nature. Before each period, there is uncer-
tries, between villagers who know each other tainty as to what that cost will be. For example,
well and interact repeatedly, but do not have a farmer may be home eating a snack or wait-
access to many formal institutions (Foster and ing out a rain storm when a potential thief walks
Rosenzweig 2001; Pedro Albarran and Orazio past his field. If that is the case, the thief can
P. Attanasio 2003; Pierre Dubois, Bruno Jullien, more easily pick a few watermelons as he walks
and Thierry Magnac 2006). by. On the other hand, the farmer may be work-
ing in the field when the potential thief walks
A. Layout of Model past, and then it will be quite difficult to steal.
When the farmer decides on the size of the gift,
The farmer can give two types of transfers he is uncertain as to the state of nature and so
to the thief: gifts and prescribed theft (the level he cannot fully compensate the thief. When the
of theft the farmer is willing to put up with). state is realized, if it is one in which the cost of
The timing of the model is as follows. First, stealing is low, then the farmer will expect the
the farmer sets the level of prescribed theft and thief to steal more than he would have if the cost
the size of the gift he will give at the end of the of stealing were higher.
period. Second, the thief decides how much Putting this sketch of a model into equations,
to steal (and steals that amount). Third, the the farmer and thief have sure income y1 and y2.
farmer observes how much the thief stole and If income were risky, theft would serve as insur-
decides whether to give him the gift. Backward ance, but here I assume no output uncertainty.12
induction shows that in the one-shot version of The farmer transfers a “gift” of v to the thief and
this game the farmer will never give the gift. prescribes a permissible 1 p 2 amount of theft (or
Knowing this, the thief will steal the amount robbery) rsp, which may differ depending on how
that maximizes his momentary utility (and is in difficult it is to steal in each state 1s 2 of nature.
general greater than the prescribed amount). The farmer’s momentary utility from consump-
In the infinitely repeated game, gift-giving tion is v 1y1 2 v 2 rsp 2 and that of the thief is
can be used to prevent stealing. In such a game, u 1y2 1 v 1 rsp 2. The Inada conditions hold, with
if theft is costly, while giving is not, there will lim yS0 u91y 2 5 `, lim yS` u91y 2 5 0, u91·2 , $ 0,
not be any theft in equilibrium. The farmer will and u0 1·2 , , 0 (and likewise for v 1·2 2. In addi-
give a gift just large enough to prevent all theft.11 tion to consumption utility, the thief also suffers
Thus, in the simple finite horizon game, there the cost of stealing, c 1s, rs 2 , which is different
will be theft but no gift-giving. On the other in each state of nature s. This cost increases in
hand, in the simple infinite horizon game, there the amount stolen at a nondecreasing rate, i.e.,
will be gift-giving but no theft. c91s, ·2 . 0 and c0 1s, ·2 $ 0 for all s.

10
Udry (1994) finds that, in rural Nigeria, the inability
12
to commit is more important than informational constraints Marcel Fafchamps and Bart Minten (2006) show that
in determining contracts. crop theft does increase with transitory poverty. On the
11
If neither theft nor giving is costly, then there may be other hand, in results not shown here, I find that households
both theft and gift-giving in equilibrium. In this case, the that experienced more illness in the past year experience
size of the two will be defined only up to their sum. more theft, not less.
VOL. 97 NO. 5 schechter: theft, gift-giving, and trustworthiness in paraguay 1565

The thief cannot commit to steal only the equilibria can be found using the worst perfect
prescribed quantity. If he deviates, stealing an equilibria for each player as punishment when
amount rsd greater than the prescribed amount, that player deviates. If the thief deviates, his
rsp, he experiences psychic trustworthiness disu- punishment is reversion to the Nash equilibrium
tility akin to his feeling of guilt or pride.13 This of the one-shot game with continuation utility
trustworthiness disutility is by no means neces- D 2. If the farmer deviates, a punishment strat-
sary for the coherence of the model, but it does egy 1with continuation utility D 12 would be for
lead to testable predictions. It is the sense of the thief to steal more than he would optimally
guilt a person is born with and does not change in the one-shot game for a few periods. After
depending on his experiences. The more disutil- that, he steals the amount he would have in the
ity an agent gets from stealing, the more “trust- one-shot game, in addition to receiving a gift
worthy” he is. This disutility from stealing is from the farmer. If the farmer doesn’t give this
t 1rsd 2 and it increases in the amount stolen at a gift, he is punished again by the extra-high level
nondecreasing rate 1i.e., t91·2 . 0 and t0 1·2 $ 02. of theft. I assume that after deviating the thief
Note that all theft is costly 1denoted c 1s, rs 2 2 , but receives trustworthiness disutility for whatever
only theft when deviating yields psychic disutil- he steals.
ity 1t 1rsd 2 2.
The thief prefers his transfer as a gift so as not B. Finding the Constrained-Efficient Frontier
to incur the costs of theft. The farmer thus also
prefers giving the transfer as a gift, because he The farmer’s maximization problem is
can transfer less while maintaining the thief’s
utility level. If the gift were allowed to be state- V1U2 5  maxp a ps 3v 1y1 2 v 2 r sp 2 1 bV1Us 24,
contingent, and the farmer could give a larger v, 5U , r 6 s s s s
gift when the cost of stealing was lower, theft
would be eliminated in equilibrium. Given that subject to the following constraints:
we see theft in equilibrium, the assumption that
(1)  a ps 3u 1y 2 1 v 1 r sp 2 2 c 1s, r sp 2 1 bUs 4 $ U;
gifts not be state-contingent is necessary. One
can imagine a similar but more complex model s
in which gifts can be given only in certain peri-
ods (on weekends or after work), while theft can (2)  u 1y2 1 v 1 r sp 2 2 c 1s, r sp 2 1 bUs
occur at any time. In this case, even if the gift
could be state-contingent, a risk-averse thief    $ u 1y2 1 r sd 2 2 c 1s, r sd 2 2 t 1rsd 2 1 bD2
would steal based on the cost of stealing at each
moment. The gift given after a series of such for all s, rsd;
moments would not directly depend on the state
at any given moment. The model used here, in
which theft is state-contingent while the gift is (3)  v 1y1 2 v 2 r sp 2 1 bV1Us 2
not, is a simplification of the model in which
theft can take place at any time while gifts can    $ v 1y1 2 r sp 2 1 bD1  for all s;
be given only occasionally.
In this infinitely repeated game, an equi-
librium with no stealing above the prescribed (4)  r sp $ 0  for all s;
amount is enforceable with the threat of punish-
ment. Dilip Abreu (1988) proves that all perfect
(5)  v $ 0,
13
James Andreoni and John Miller (2002) and Fehr
and Simon Gächter (2000) used experiments to show that where the value function for the continuation
individuals have heterogeneous preferences, some being utility of the farmer is V1·2 , and U represents the
selfish and others altruistic or reciprocating. Posner (1998)
uses “moral pride” as an explanation for non-self-interested thief’s continuation utility. The probability of
behavior (i.e., some people do not like to think of them- each state of nature is ps, and b is the discount
selves as thieves). factor. The farmer must decide the size of the
1566 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2007

gift 1v 2 , the level of tolerated theft given each fsps on the theft nonnegativity constraints (4).
state of nature 1r sp 2 , and the future continuation The envelope theorem implies
utility he will promise the thief in each state of
nature 1Us 2. (7)  V91U2 5 2l.
The first constraint (1) is the promise-­keeping
constraint which ensures that the thief’s expected The first-order condition with respect to r sp is
utility does not go below some level. This means
that the farmer cannot rescind the promise to (8) 
maintain the farmer’s continuation utility at U,
which he made in the previous period. The next vr 1 y1 2 v 2 r ps 2
two are the thief’s and farmer’s incentive-com- ur 1 y2 1 v 1 r ps 2 2 cr 1 s, r ps 2
patibility (IC) constraints, which ensure that the
agents are at least indifferent between the equi-
1 fs 1 nsv r 1 y 1 2 r ps 2 2
librium strategy and deviating. In constraint (2),    2
we see that the thief must be at least as happy 1 1 1 ns 2 1 ur 1 y 2 1 v 1 r ps 2 2 cr 1 s, r ps 2 2
stealing the prescribed amount 1r sp 2 and receiv-
ing the continuation utility promised by the l 1 ms
farmer 1Us 2 as he would be stealing a larger devi-   5  .
1 1 ns
ation amount 1r sd  2 , receiving psychic disutility
from doing so 1t 1r sd  2 2 , and receiving the level of
deviation continuation utility in the future 1D22. These equations show that l equals the ratio
Constraint (3) shows that the farmer must be at of marginal utilities of the two individuals in
least as happy giving the gift today as he would the current period and in the previous period if
be refraining from giving the gift and being pun- neither agent’s constraint binds, and prescribed
ished thereafter. Constraints (4) and (5) are the theft is positive. It is possible to prove a proposi-
nonnegativity constraints on theft and the gift. tion similar to one found in Ligon, Thomas, and
If the thief deviates, he steals the amount r sd Worrall (2002).
so that u91y2 1 r sd  2 , c91s, r sd 2 1 t91r sd 2. Thus,
both less trustworthy, as well as poorer, individ- Proposition 1: Let the history of states ht
uals will be more likely to steal and will steal 5 1 s1, s2, … , st 2 be given and let s be the state
more. Interestingly, households for which u91y22 which occurs at time t. Any constrained-effi-
, c91s, 02 1 t9102 for every possible state s have cient contract can be characterized as follows:

such high trustworthiness disutility that they there exist S state-dependent intervals 3l –s, ls 4
will never steal more than prescribed. Thus, the such that l 1 ht 2 evolves according to the follow-
farmer will have no reason to prescribe a posi- ing rule:
tive level of theft to such a household. Stylized
fact 4 suggested that there are only a few thieves –s
l if l 1ht212 , l
–s
in each village. The fact that, in the model and

perhaps in reality, there are households with (9) l 1ht 2 5 µ l 1ht212 if l 1ht212 [ 3l
–s, ls 4 ,
such high trustworthiness disutility that they
– –
never steal is good motivation for focusing on ls if l 1ht212 . ls
two agents, one who is a potential thief and one
who is not.
– –
The first-order condition for Us simplifies to where l –s 5 2V91U – s 2 , and ls 5 2V91Us 2. I define
U
– s as the lowest sustainable continuation payoff
that the thief could receive in state s so as
l 1 ms – to just
(6)  V91Us 2 5 2   , satisfy his IC constraint (2). Likewise, Us is the
1 1 ns highest sustainable continuation payoff that the
thief could receive in state s so as to just satisfy
where l is the multiplier on the promise-keeping the farmer’s IC constraint (3). This completely
constraint (1), msps on the thief’s IC constraints characterizes the contract once an initial value
(2), nsps on the farmer’s IC constraints (3), and for l 1ht212 is given.
VOL. 97 NO. 5 schechter: theft, gift-giving, and trustworthiness in paraguay 1567

Thus, if possible, the transfers are fixed so as trusts him less. This corresponds with Hardin’s
to keep the ratio of marginal utilities (v91y1 2 definition of trust, in that, as the thief’s utility
v 2 r sp 2/ 3u91y2 1 v 1 r sp 2 2 c91s, r sp 24) constant after deviating increases, he cares less about
over time and over states. If some constraint is the continuation of the gift-giving relationship
binding, the ratio will be changed by the mini- with the farmer. He then becomes more costly to
mum possible to satisfy the constraints. I move convince not to steal and the farmer trusts him
forward by deriving comparative statics which less.
can be tested empirically in a reduced-form Looking at equations (6) and (8), one finds
estimation. that when fs 5 0 (prescribed theft is greater than
zero) and ns 5 0 (the farmer’s IC constraint does
C. Comparative Statics not bind), then Us (the thief’s continuation util-
ity) is a nondecreasing function of v 1 r sp (the
I derive comparative statics for the effects of transfer from the farmer to the thief in the cur-
changes in exogenous features such as: (a) the rent period). If the thief’s IC constraint is bind-
cost of stealing 1c 1s, rs 2 2; (b) trustworthiness ing, then as his trustworthiness decreases (i.e.,
1t 1rs 2 2; and (c) risk aversion on endogenous vari- as t 1·2 falls for all theft levels) he must have both
ables such as (i) gifts given (v); (ii) prescribed higher consumption and higher continuation
theft 1r sp 2; and (iii) trust. I consider trust an utility. Thus, contrary to what one might expect,
endogenous variable (while trustworthiness is ceteris paribus, more trustworthy agents con-
exogenous).14, 15 Russell Hardin (2002) empha- sume less and have lower utility.16 Because this
sizes that trust is relational, i.e., two people’s less trustworthy agent has a higher continuation
levels of trust depend on their ongoing interac- utility 1Us 2 , his utility must be higher in the next
tion. He defines trust as “encapsulated interest.’’ period as well. As theft is costly while gifts are
One agent (the farmer) trusts a second agent (the not, most of this higher consumption will come
thief) because he knows the thief values the con- in the form of a higher gift. When a farmer has a
tinuation of the relationship, and so he will take less trustworthy neighbor, his trust decreases as
the interests of the farmer into account. Levi well. Because V91Us 2 5 21l 1 ms 2/ 11 1 ns 2 , the
(2001) claims that distrust raises the “transac- higher U obtained by a less trustworthy agent
tion costs” of cooperation. when his IC constraint binds (and the farmer’s
In accord with those definitions, I measure does not, so that ns 5 0) implies that ms is higher
(lack of) trust as the sum of the multipliers on as well. Thus, a less trustworthy thief causes the
the thief’s IC constraints (2) 1o s ps ms 2 , given farmer to be less trusting.17
some reference utility U for the thief. This mea- The effects of a change in the cost structure
sures how the farmer’s expected utility reacts to of stealing are similar to the effects of a change
a slight relaxation of the thief’s IC constraints. If in trustworthiness. If the thief’s IC constraint
the thief’s IC constraints never bind, so that he binds and the marginal cost of theft in that state
would never steal more than prescribed, then the decreases, both sides of the thief’s IC constraint
multiplier equals zero and the farmer has com- will increase, although the right-hand side will
plete trust in the thief. As the thief becomes more increase more than the left. Thus, the thief’s util-
willing to steal and more costly to convince not ity in equilibrium (on the left-hand side) must
to steal, the multiplier increases and the farmer be increased to compensate and so the transfer
1v 1 r sp 2 and continuation utility 1Us 2 must both
14
Some literature assumes trust is endogenous (Alberto
16
Alesina and Eliana LaFerrara 2002) or determined by cul- I assume that villagers know each other’s levels of
ture (Francis Fukuyama 1995), while other work assumes trustworthiness, so a thief cannot misrepresent himself as
trust is exogenous and looks at its effects (Stephen Knack being untrustworthy in order to receive more gifts.
17
and Philip Keefer 1997; Deepa Narayan and Lant Pritchett The comparative statics would not change if the
1999). Raymond Fisman and Tarun Khanna (1999) summa- farmer could impose some punishment on the thief (such
rize the literature making those different assumptions. as social sanctions or physical punishment) in addition to
15
One could argue that trustworthiness is endogenous cutting him off from future gifts, though the level of gift-
in the long run as norms are set. I assume these norms are giving would be lower. This externally imposed punish-
fixed for relatively long periods of time, and it is beyond the ment would function in a similar manner to the internal
scope of this paper to model that process. trustworthiness disutility suffered by the thief.
1568 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2007

increase. A decrease in the marginal cost of In a world with no theft, it might be the case
stealing in all states will cause an increase in the that the more stealable crop would be more
size of the gift, similar to the case of a decrease profitable. If fear of theft discourages a farmer
in trustworthiness. An increase in the variance from planting a more profitable crop, there will
of the marginal cost of stealing, on the other be a decrease in efficiency due to the lack of
hand, will cause an increase in theft in the states enforcement.
in which theft is easiest. As the marginal cost In this modified model, the farmer would
in a state decreases, Us increases, causing ms to choose the level of the gift and prescribed theft
increase, which means that the farmer’s level of he would tolerate for each of the two crops. He
trust is lower when it is easier to steal. would use backward induction to decide which
As the farmer’s risk aversion increases, his crop to plant given the profitability of the two
utility from deviating decreases. This is because crops on his land and the size of the trans-
his consumption varies more when deviating fers he would have to give for each of the two
than it does in equilibrium. As this relaxes his crops. Conditional on crop choice, the compara-
IC constraint, the total transfer he gives will tive statics derived thus far will still hold. For
increase. Because he is more risk averse and example, as a thief becomes less trustworthy, he
because theft is costly, he must give a higher will be transferred a higher gift, as long as the
(state-independent) gift. This relaxes the thief’s farmer continues to plant the same crop. If the
IC constraint, which means that future pre- thief becomes so untrustworthy that the farmer
scribed theft will be lowered to compensate. switches to planting a less stealable crop, then
I have assumed perfect information about a less trustworthy thief will actually receive a
the identity of the thief, the amount stolen, and lower-value gift.
the state of nature. Stylized fact 3 showed that Consider two farmers who are similar in
although almost half of the time the victim every respect (the trustworthiness of their neigh-
claims to know who stole how much, half of the bors, the cost of stealing from them, etc.) except
time he does not. In a game of moral hazard, that one farmer’s land is better suited to planting
complete information is essentially equivalent the more stealable crop. The farmer who plants
to receiving complete information with positive the more stealable crop will have to give more
probability (Bengt Holmström 1979). A similar gifts than the farmer who plants the less steal-
argument shows that if the farmer has complete able crop in order to discourage the thief from
information with positive probability, then the stealing. The comparative static for the effect of
contract would be quite similar to that with per- crop choice on trust depends on how we define
fect information. The thief could be induced to trust. If it is measured using the multipliers on
report accurately, knowing that there is a ran- the thief’s IC constraints for the crop the farmer
dom chance that the farmer will find out. The chose to plant, then the farmer who plants the
resulting equilibrium and comparative statics more stealable crop will end up trusting less. If
would not change qualitatively.18 one uses the multipliers over both crops weighted
equally, then the farmer who trusts more will
D. An Extension with Crop Choice plant the more stealable crop.20

Now imagine modifying the model so that a


farmer chooses between planting a more “steal-
able” crop (e.g., watermelon) with a higher value
per handful but a lower quantity output, and a a farmer, irrespective of the crop. The stealability of a crop
refers to how valuable a crop is to a thief. Crops that are
less “stealable” crop (e.g., cotton) with a lower more valuable per handful and can be used immediately,
value per handful but a higher quantity output.19 rather than being sold in bulk (like cotton) or dried for
hours (like peanuts), are more stealable.
20
A farmer who chooses to plant the more stealable
18
The model would get quite a bit more complicated if crop might trust more originally (weighting all multipliers
one incorporated costly monitoring as a choice made by the equally), but as his experience with the crop he has chosen
farmer. becomes more salient, he may weight the multipliers for the
19
The stealability of a crop differs from the cost of crop he has chosen more heavily, and thus he may begin
stealing. The latter measures the difficulty of stealing from to trust less.
VOL. 97 NO. 5 schechter: theft, gift-giving, and trustworthiness in paraguay 1569

E. Model Synthesis p­ roduced. Then they were asked how much of that
was sold, consumed within the household, fed to
The limited-commitment model predicts that animals, given away, stolen, and still in storage.
as the cost of stealing goes up, a farmer will give A similar procedure was used for livestock, their
a lower total value of gifts and trust more. As the derivates (e.g., eggs and milk), and extractives
variance of the cost of stealing goes down, he (e.g., firewood and coal). Households were also
will experience less theft. As the farmer becomes asked what tools were stolen from them in the
more risk averse, he will give more gifts and last year, and to list any other items stolen from
experience less theft. A farmer with less trust- them. Summary statistics can be found in Table 1.
worthy neighbors will give more gifts and trust Note that gifts given are approximately three
less. In addition, all else equal, if a farmer plants times the size of theft (of small items) experi-
more stealable crops he will give more gifts. enced. In the limited-commitment model on the
equilibrium path, it would be efficient for gifts
III.  Data to be larger than theft. In addition, the measure
of gifts includes both gifts given to limit theft
In 2002, I collected data in rural Paraguay and those given for other reasons.
combining traditional survey data on produc- I measure trust with the World Values Survey
tion with nonstandard questions measuring question, “What share of your fellow villag-
economic variables such as theft experienced ers would try to take advantage of you if they
and agricultural giving. Respondents were also had the opportunity?” The answers are 1–all,
asked their level of trust. To complement the 2–more than half, 3–half, 4–less than half, and
survey data, I ran experiments measuring the 5–none.22 In this setting, the survey measure of
trust, trustworthiness, and risk aversion of the trust is more appropriate than the experimental
respondents. measure. This is because the survey question
In 1991, the Land Tenure Center at the Uni­ measures the respondent’s trust in his fellow
ver­sity of Wisconsin in Madison and the Centro villagers given the system of rewards and sanc-
Paraguayo de Estudios Sociológicos in Asunción tions he can impose. Trust as measured by the
worked together in the design and implementation experiment is anonymous when no rewards or
of the original survey of 300 rural Paraguayan sanctions are possible.
households in 16 villages in 3 departments (com- In each period, the equilibrium level of gift-
parable to states) across the country. This was giving, theft in every state, and the continuation
a random sample, stratified by landholdings. utility in every state are all functions of one
The original survey was followed by subse- another as well as of the exogenous variables.
quent rounds of data collection in 1994, 1999, The level of trust, the negative of the Lagrange
and, most recently, I collected the last round in multiplier on the thief’s IC constraint, depends
2002. All rounds include detailed information on the equilibrium values of all the choice vari-
on production and income, and in 2002 I added ables as well. If the level of the gift went down
questions on theft, trust, and gifts. Although the slightly, the level of theft in at least one state of
dataset is rather small, with only 223 households nature would have to go up to compensate the
interviewed in 2002, it is quite detailed, reducing thief. As discussed in Section IIA, relying on
potential omitted variable problems.21 theft rather than on gifts to make transfers to
Theft experienced and gifts given were mea- the thief is more costly for the farmer, and so his
sured as defined by the respondents themselves. level of trust will be lower. Likewise, if the level
For every crop the household planted in the last of theft went up in all states, the gift would go
year, they were asked the total amount they down to compensate.
The data collected measure total theft experi-
enced and gifts given over the course of a year,
21
Comparing this dataset with the national census, I find
that my sample is slightly older, which makes sense given
it was randomly chosen 11 years earlier. The households in
22
this survey are also slightly more educated and wealthier The correct cardinality is probably 1, 0.75, 0.50, 0.25,
than the average rural household, probably due to the over- and 0. As this is just a linear transformation of the 1–5
sampling of households with larger landholdings. scale, I have left the variable in its original form.
1570 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2007

Table 1—Summary Statistics for September 2001–September 2002

Variable Mean 1Std. dev.2


Annual theft experienced 1 in $2 23 1702
Log of annual theft experienced 1 in 1,000s of guaranies 2 2.04 12.482
Annual gifts given 1 in $2 64 11092
Log of annual gifts given 1 in 1,000s of guaranies 2 4.07 12.442
Annual income 1 in $2 5,903 115,0302
Median annual income 1 in $2 1,885
Wealth 1 in $2 50,395 1166,2902
Log of wealth 1 in 1,000s of guaranies 2 10.12 12.002
Median wealth 1 in $2 4,771
Trust from the surveya 3.11 11.152
No one passes field 0.44
No. of households in 250-meter radius 5.8 16.52
Family size 5.6 12.42
Close relatives in village 1# of households2 3.2 13.02
Kilometers to police station 4.06 12.662
Years in village 39 1202
Japanese village 0.04
Didn’t participate in games 0.15
Bet in risk game 1 in guaranies, 188 observations2 3,400 2,000
Trustworthiness (share returned in trust game, 188 observations2 0.44 0.20
Neighbor trustworthinessc 0.28 0.16
No. of stealable cropsb 2.3 11.12
No. of stealable crops in 1999 2.1 10.92
Altitude 1 in meters2 196 1812
Potential evapotranspiration 1 in millimeters2 465 1612
Observations 223
a
“What share of your fellow villagers would try to take advantage of you if they had the
opportunity?” 1–all, 2–more than half, 3–half, 4–less than half, and 5–none.
b
The number of the following crops planted in the previous year: watermelon, melon,
banana, corn, and yucca.
c
Share returned in the trust game by the least “trustworthy” of the household’s three clos-
est neighbors who participated in the games.

the equivalent of multiple periods in the model. v­ ariable that affected gifts but not theft, and at
Total theft experienced is a function of the exog- least one variable that affected theft but not gifts.
enous variables (neighbor trustworthiness, the It is difficult even to conceptualize what such a
cost of stealing, etc.) and total gifts given. The variable might be. Due to the lack of such vari-
same can be said for the total gifts given. The ables, I will focus instead on testing the com-
ceteris paribus arguments made above suggest parative statics derived from the model. These
that one might want to estimate a more structural comparative statics do not state, for example,
model. One would include the level of theft in that conditional on the level of theft, as a farmer
the gift regression, the level of giving in the theft becomes more risk averse he will give more
regression, and both theft and gifts in the trust gifts. They state that, as he becomes more risk
regression (in addition to the other exogenous averse, he will both give more gifts and experi-
variables in all three). All else equal, we would ence less theft.
expect a negative correlation between theft and Nevertheless, the correlation coefficients
gift-giving, a positive correlation between gift- among the three endogenous variables under
giving and trust, and a negative correlation consideration are of interest. These three vari-
between theft and trust. ables are measured as the log of one plus the
In order to estimate such a structural model, value of theft experienced, the log of one plus
one would need to have data on at least one the value of gifts given, and the answer to the
VOL. 97 NO. 5 schechter: theft, gift-giving, and trustworthiness in paraguay 1571

Table 2—Correlation Coefficients


(Pearson correlations above the diagonal and Spearman correlations below)

Log (theft) Log (giving) Trust


Log (theft) 1.0000 0.1507** –0.1225*
Log (giving) 0.1405** 1.0000 –0.0657
Trust –0.1364** –0.1050 1.0000
  *–10 percent, **–5 percent, and ***–1 percent significance.

World Values Survey question above. These thirds of one day’s wages) and chose how much
correlations can be found in Table 2. (if any) to invest. The experimenter then rolled a
As Table 2 does not control for any explana- die to determine the payoffs. After that, I ran the
tory variables, I cannot rely on ceteris paribus trust game originally described in Joyce Berg,
arguments. A farmer who lives near a thief will John Dickhaut, and Kevin McCabe (1995).25
give more gifts, experience more theft, and The trustor was given a sum of money. In the
trust less than a farmer whose neighbors are all first move, the trustor decided how much, if any,
completely trustworthy. This suggests a positive to send to an anonymous trustee.26 Any money
correlation between theft and gift-giving (rather sent to the trustee was tripled. The trustee made
than the negative correlation suggested by the the second move, deciding how much money
ceteris paribus analysis), and a negative corre- to return to the trustor. Money sent by the trus-
lation between trust and theft, as well as trust tor is commonly used to measure his trust that
and gift-giving.23 The correlations in Table 2 the anonymous trustee will return his money.
are in line with these hypotheses. Although the Money returned by the trustee is used to mea-
correlation between trust and giving is not sig- sure his trustworthiness.
nificant, the fact that it is negative yields more To measure trustworthiness for every house-
suggestive evidence that transfers are not solely hold, I had each player play the role of trustor
given as a form of reciprocal exchange, but that first and then the role of trustee. Stephen V.
they are also used to limit theft. Burks, Jeffrey P. Carpenter, and Eric Verhoogen
In order to measure the exogenous variables, (2003) find that playing both roles decreases
I carried out two economic experiments, one the amount sent and the share returned. They
measuring trust and trustworthiness, and the hypothesize that playing both roles reduces the
other measuring risk aversion. A more detailed player’s sense of responsibility for the well-being
description of the games can be found in of his partner. If this is the case, playing both
Schechter (2007), but I will describe them briefly roles decreases correlation between the measure
here. After surveying each village, the enumera- of trustworthiness and altruism, allowing trust-
tors invited a player from each household that worthiness to be measured more purely.
had participated in the survey to play the games.
Of the 223 families surveyed, 188 sent a family IV.  Empirics
member to participate in the experiments.24 The
players won an average of two days’ wages. Because of the difficulties involved in iden-
The risk game was played first. The investor tifying the structural equations that arise in the
was given a sum of money (equivalent to two- model, I must estimate reduced-form equations.

23 25
There is the second-order consideration that a farmer As is common with games played in rural villages,
who is more risk averse will give more gifts and experi- the games were not double blind (Abigail Barr 2003; Dean
ence less theft than a less risk-averse farmer. This suggests S. Karlan 2005). This is due to the importance of making
a negative correlation between theft and trust, although one sure players understand the games and difficulties in run-
would suspect this effect is of smaller magnitude than that ning experiments in a village setting.
26
predicting a positive correlation, as discussed above. As the villagers all played together, they knew the
24
Households that did not send players were wealthier pool from which their partner was drawn, although they
and had younger household heads. did not know with whom they were paired.
1572 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2007

In this section, I test the comparative statics that footpaths are easier to steal from. I also include
hold in equilibrium. the number of households within 250 meters of
the surveyed household, so that the indicator for
A. Estimation before Controlling for no one walking past the field is not just proxy-
Crop Choice ing for a household having few neighbors, but
actually represents a characteristic of the plot in
In Section IIC of this paper I derived com- which crops are planted.
parative statics for the three endogenous vari- In the model, the cost of stealing differs in
ables: gifts given, theft experienced, and trust, each state while the variables above do not.
with regards to exogenous changes in the cost of Household size and whether or not people walk
stealing, the risk aversion of the farmer, and the past the field affect the probability that a poten-
trustworthiness of his neighbors. I estimate the tial thief finds himself in a state in which the
system of equations cost of stealing is low. Thus, these variables
proxy for the distribution of the cost of stealing.
y1 5 xb1 1 u1 ; I also include variables representing the
trustworthiness of neighbors. I have GPS data
y2 5 xb2 1 u2 ; on each household in the survey (latitude, lon-
gitude, and elevation) and the measure of trust-
y3 5 xb3 1 u3 , worthiness from the experiment. I combine
these, measuring neighbor trustworthiness as
where y1 is theft experienced, y2 is gifts given, the level of trustworthiness of the least trustwor-
and y3 is trust. Before controlling for crop thy of the household’s three closest neighbors.
choice, the regressors are all exogenous. As the I focus on the level of trustworthiness of the
xs do not differ across equations, the analysis least trustworthy neighbor because the model
simplifies to equation by equation OLS. This predicts that it is the least trustworthy persons
will no longer be the case in Section IVB after who must be contracted with to reduce theft. I
controlling for crop choice. focus on close neighbors because the evidence
The exogenous regressors common to all presented in stylized fact 7 suggested that close
three equations include variables representing neighbors are often the culprits. As the experi-
risk aversion, the cost of stealing, and the trust- ment is anonymous, trustees should not decide
worthiness of neighbors. The amount the house- how much to return based on past experiences
hold bets in the risk experiment is included as a with the other players. I assume play by the
measure of (lack of) risk aversion, as the more trustees is exogenous and determined by their
they bet, the less risk averse they are. For those innate sense of moral pride.27
households that did not participate in the experi- A last proxy for trustworthiness is the number
ments, the value of the bet is set to zero, and of households in the village with members who
an indicator variable for households that did not are close relatives of the surveyed household.
participate in the experiments is included. Thus, Close relatives include parents, children, or sib-
the sample size remains 223, although only 188 lings of the household head and his wife. They
households participated in the experiments. do not include cousins or other extended fam-
Household size (in adult equivalents) is ily members. A potential thief may experience
included to represent the cost of stealing. It may a larger trustworthiness disutility when stealing
be more difficult to steal from a larger household, from his own relative. Note that if close family
as some household member will be in the fields
more often. I include a variable indicating if any
nonhousehold member walks past the family’s 27
Note that for the endogenous measure of trust I use
main plot in any given week, which affects the the answer to the survey question, while for the exogenous
cost of stealing as well. If no nonhousehold mem- measure of trustworthiness I use play by the trustee in the
ber walks past a field, then people do not know experiment. This is because I want a proxy for trustwor-
thiness measuring intrinsic trustworthiness in anonymous
what crop is in the field or when it will be ripe, situations, while I want to measure trust in nonanonymous
and will look more out of place if they are seen situations given the system of rewards and sanctions in the
walking past the field. Fields on ­commonly used village.
VOL. 97 NO. 5 schechter: theft, gift-giving, and trustworthiness in paraguay 1573

members monitor each other’s fields, then liv- by certain households having fewer neighbors,
ing near more close family members could also but is directly related to the number of people
make it more difficult for thieves to approach. walking past the field. In terms of plots located
Thus, this variable could affect both the cost of on popular footpaths, the limited-commitment
stealing and trustworthiness. model is supported, as both gifts given and theft
The log of household wealth, the number of experienced increase when the cost of stealing
years the household has lived in the village, goes down.
the distance between the house and the nearest At first glance, the results on trustworthiness
police station, and a dummy for the Japanese do not show evidence that gift-giving is used to
village are also included as controls. limit theft. As his least trustworthy neighbor
becomes more trustworthy, a farmer gives more
Implementation.—When not controlling for gifts (and there is no effect on theft or trust). The
crop choice, I estimate the system of equations limited-commitment model predicted farmers
using equation by equation OLS.28 I do not con- with more trustworthy neighbors would trust
trol for village fixed effects in the analysis in the more and give fewer gifts.
main text to preserve precious degrees of free- However, a different measure of trustworthi-
dom, though I have accounted for clustering in ness, the number of close family members living
the standard errors.29 Given the omission of crop in the same village, shows effects consistent with
choice, the results in Table 3 may be biased but the limited-commitment model. Households
they give an interesting overview. with more close family members give signifi-
Larger households do not experience any less cantly fewer gifts. For every additional family
theft, and they actually give more gifts. If it is member living in their village, a household gives
more difficult to steal from larger households, approximately 10 percent fewer gifts. This is
then this result is in contradiction with the pre- contrary to the expectation that households with
dictions of the model. Keep in mind that I have more close family members give more gifts, not
not yet controlled for crop choice. less. This result fits directly with the limited-
“No one passes field” represents an increase commitment model’s predictions that, as trust-
in the cost of stealing. Households with fields worthiness increases, gifts given decrease and
which nonhousehold members do not walk past trust increases (although, in this regression, the
give a significantly lower total value of gifts effect on trust is not significant).
and experience significantly less theft. In fact, The coefficients on risk aversion are all
a household that does not possess a plot that no insignificant, perhaps because risk aversion
one walks past experiences approximately 60 was measured for one member of the household
percent more theft and gives 82 percent more and not for the family as a whole. Households
gifts than a household that has such a plot. One of Japanese heritage experience less theft,
might think that the reason households with give fewer gifts, and trust more. This result
fields that no one walks past give fewer gifts should not hastily be used to conclude that the
and experience less theft is that people who live Japanese are more trustworthy, as I have not yet
on the outskirts of town have no neighbors to controlled for crop choice, and Japanese farm-
whom to give gifts. But this result holds even ers plant quite different crops than do farmers
when including the number of households in a of South American heritage.30 Wealthier house-
250-meter radius of that household as an explan- holds give significantly more gifts but do not
atory variable. Thus, this result is not caused experience more theft than poorer households.
This effect is not as large economically as one
28 might expect. A household that is 10 percent
As many households experience no theft or give no
gifts, I have also tried estimating those equations using a wealthier gives less than 3 percent more gifts.
tobit regression. The qualitative results are the same either This implies that, although wealthier house-
way, so I use linear regression techniques to facilitate com- holds do give a higher total value of gifts, they
parisons with Section IVB in which I estimate the three
equations as a linear system.
29
The standard errors are robust to heteroskedastic-
30
ity and allow for intra-village correlation, which differs Results when excluding the Japanese altogether are
between villages but is the same within each village. quite similar.
1574 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2007

give a smaller proportion of their wealth than do equations as a system. The system of equations
poorer households. The relatively small coeffi- estimated is
cient on wealth suggests that models in which
gifts are given out of altruism or inequality y1 5 xb1 1 vg1 1 u1 ;
aversion, or in order to mitigate envy, are not
driving the results.31, 32 y2 5 xb2 1 vg2 1 u2 ;
Table 3 as well as the other tables in the main
text do not control for village fixed effects. The
y3 5 xb3 1 vg3 1 u3 ,
Appendix shows the corresponding results,
including village fixed effects. As can be seen
in the Appendix, the main results do not change where x are the exogenous regressors and v is
much. One interesting change is that the coef- crop choice. The instrument set z includes all
ficients in the trust regression on “no one passes the elements of x, as well as instruments for
field” and “close relatives in village” are both crop choice. The moment conditions require
significant after controlling for village fixed that E 1z9ug 25 0 for every equation g.
effects, while not before. This suggests that Define the matrix of regressors,
these farmers, who are more difficult to steal
from or have more relatives as neighbors, trust
xi1 0 0
more than other farmers within their village.
Xi 5 ± 0 xi2 0 ≤ ,
B. Estimation Controlling for
Crop Choice
0 0 xi3
Crop choice is an endogenous decision made
by the farmer, so in this section I use an instru- for each individual i so that xi1 includes all of the
mental variables approach. Instead of using regressors in the first equation (including both
OLS, I now estimate the system of equations x and v), xi2 includes all of the regressors in the
using generalized method of moments (GMM). second equation, etc. The matrix X is obtained
In the implementation, I will use more instru- by stacking the matrices Xi for all individuals.
ments than endogenous variables, which means The matrix of instruments Z has a similar struc-
that the equations are overidentified. Thus, there ture. The matrix Y is obtained by stacking the
is now an efficiency gain to estimating the three individual vectors

yi1
31
I conduct a robustness test including income rather
than wealth as a regressor. Although income is endogenous, Yi 5 ± yi2 ≤ .
as both crop choice and theft experienced affect income,
most of the results remain the same. The main difference
is that the coefficient on “# close relatives in village” in the yi3
giving regression remains negative but loses significance.
This could be because villagers who live in the same vil-
lage with many relatives experience slightly less theft and I estimate the coefficients by first estimating
so have slightly higher income. Thus, the effect of living an initial consistent estimator of b which I call
near close relatives on giving could be picked up by the b̂ˆ . For this step, I use the 2SLS estimator b̂ˆ  5
endogenous income variable, lowering the coefficient on 3X9Z1Z9Z2 21 Z9X4 21 X9Z1Z9Z2 21 Z9Y. From this,
relatives. one obtains the residual vectors ûˆ i 5 yi 2 Xi b̂ˆ .

Ŵ5 1N 21 g i51Zi9V̂Zi 2 21, where V̂ is an estimate


32
As another robustness check, I use the answer to the
question, “If you know someone is a thief, do you give him Then, I estimate the optimal weighting matrix
N
gifts to avoid getting stolen from?” rather than the value of
gifts given as the left-hand-side variable. This is the only of uiu9i. This estimate uses the residuals ûˆ i found
variable I have that hints at the motivation behind the gift- above and allows for heteroskedasticity and intra-
giving. The main results still hold, with households living
in the same village with more of their close relatives, or village correlation differing between villages but
with fields that no one passes, being less likely to claim to the same within each village (both between equa-
give gifts to prevent theft. tions and within equations). Using this weighting
VOL. 97 NO. 5 schechter: theft, gift-giving, and trustworthiness in paraguay 1575

Table 3—Correlates of Gift Giving, Theft Experienced, and Trust before


Controlling for Crop Choice Using OLS

Log 1 theft2 Log 1giving2 Trust


Bet 0.053 –0.024 0.005
10.0962 10.0782 10.0392
Didn’t play games 0.736 –0.003 –0.502*
10.6442 10.6482 10.3052
No one passes field –0.602* –0.824*** 0.231
10.3402 10.3162 10.1492
No. of households in 250 m radius 0.026 –0.068*** –0.002
10.0252 10.0222 10.0132
Family size –0.044 0.206*** –0.000
10.1022 10.0792 10.0422
No. of close relatives in village –0.054 –0.109** 0.031
10.0542 10.0542 10.0292
Neighbor trustworthiness 1.350 1.718* 0.591
11.1572 11.0152 10.6002
Kilometers to police –0.071 0.063 –0.003
10.0582 10.0672 10.0272
Log 1wealth 2 0.075 0.257*** –0.025
10.1022 10.0892 10.0492
Years in village 0.016** 0.022** 0.009**
10.0082 10.0092 10.0042
Japanese village –1.685** –4.428*** 0.699**
10.6872 10.5942 10.3172
R2 0.077 0.244 0.066
Observations 223 223 223
Note: Clustered heteroskedasticity-consistent standard errors in parentheses.
*–10 percent, **–5 percent, and ***–1 percent significance.

matrix, one can obtain the ­optimal linear GMM watermelons, and not how many to plant, which
estimator b̂ 5 3X9ZŴZ9X4 21 X9ZŴ Z9Y. affects theft, i.e., if whether a farmer plants 200
watermelons or 1,000, the thief steals the same
Implementation.—Some crops are more valu- amount.33
able to thieves than others. Crops such as cotton, While including only the total number of
wheat, and soy, which are usually sold in bulk, stealable crops planted as an explanatory vari-
are not very desirable to thieves, nor are crops able conserves degrees of freedom in comparison
such as peanuts, which must be dried in the sun with including a dummy for each crop, using the
for a day or two before eating. The crops about number of crops planted imposes linearity on the
which farmers most often claim to worry are effect of crop choice. I have also tried using the
watermelons, melons, bananas, corn, and yucca. square and the log of the number of commonly
The dynamic limited-commitment model pre- stolen crops planted, as well as ­ converting the
dicts that a household planting these crops will
give more gifts and trust less. Crop choice is 33
A farmer who plants two stealable crops, which make
included as an explanatory variable indicating up 10 percent of his output, plants more stealable crops
how many of the crops listed above the house- than a farmer who covers half of his farm with one steal-
hold planted. Note that crop choice is measured able crop. This is because a thief whose neighbor plants
as the number of stealable crops planted, rather both watermelon and corn may want some of both, while if
his neighbor plants only watermelon, he will only want the
than the total value planted in these crops. watermelon. Since these thieves are not stealing for resale,
The number of stealable crops planted is the there is only so much watermelon they will desire to steal
apprpriate measure if it is the decision to plant and consume.
1576 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2007

count data into an indicator variable for planting Table 4—“First-Stage” Regression of Crop Choice
three or more of those crops, and the results are on the Exogenous Variables Using OLS with and
without Including Instruments
not substantially different.34
I instrument for crop choice with the altitude No. of stealable crops
of the household’s main plot and potential evapo- Bet 0.005 0.013
transpiration. Elevation was measured for each 10.0362 10.0372
household with the GPS unit. Plots at different Didn’t play games 0.097 0.089
elevations belong to different micro-climates 10.3182 10.2922
with different soil characteristics. Elevation No one passes field –0.097 –0.095
varies from 91 to 449 meters above sea level 10.1392 10.1382
and varies substantially even within villages.35 No. of HHs in 250 m radius –0.030*** –0.026***
10.0092 10.0082
Households at higher elevations are more likely
Family size 0.144*** 0.112**
to plant soy, wheat, and rice, while households 10.0492 10.0452
at lower elevations are more likely to plant No. of close relatives in village –0.021 –0.020
yucca, cotton, bananas, beans, and watermelon. 10.0232 10.0212
Evapotranspiration is the combination of water Neighbor trustworthiness 0.884** 0.948**
lost from the soil by evaporation and from plants 10.4152 10.3952
by transpiration, while potential evapotranspi- Kilometers to police station 0.020 0.052
ration is the water requirement of a reference 10.0412 10.0372
crop. This variable does not vary within villages. Log 1wealth 2 0.018 0.016
10.0492 10.0482
Households in villages with higher evapotranspi-
Years in village 0.001 –0.003
ration are less likely to plant crops of any kind.36 10.0052 10.0052
Elevation and potential evapotranspiration Japanese village –2.005*** –1.962***
are both exogenous predetermined characteris- 10.3132 10.2762
tics. Still, one might worry that they were cor- Altitude 1 in dekameters2 –0.024**
related with the error terms, which would be the 10.0102
case if, for example, there were more roads at Potential evapotranspiration –0.004***
low altitudes, making farmers at low altitudes 10.0012
more susceptible to theft. Looking at the data, R2 0.222 0.271
there are (insignificantly) more roads and bus Wald test for 43.285
crossings at higher altitudes, not lower, while   instrument significance 1p 5 0.002
households at lower altitudes plant more of the F test for instrument 6.972
more stealable crops. This shows that altitude   significance 1p 5 0.002
captures microclimate rather than transporta- Observations 223 223
tion. It is difficult to think of a similar argument Note: Clustered heteroskedasticity-consistent standard
as to why potential evapotranspiration might errors in parentheses.
be correlated with the error terms. Since these   *–10 percent, **–5 percent, and ***–1 percent significance.
variables are shown to be correlated with crop
choice and believed to be uncorrelated with the
error term, they are valid instruments.
When estimating a system of equations using However, I include Table 4 with the regression
GMM, there is no real first stage as in 2SLS. of crop choice on all of the explanatory vari-
ables, similar to a “first-stage” regression, to
34
give an idea of the correlates of crop choice. I
If I include the share of total output, in terms of value, show results both including and excluding the
dedicated to stealable crops as a regressor, rather than the
number of stealable crops, the qualitative results do not instruments. The F-statistic and the heteroske-
change. dasticity consistent Wald-statistic testing the
35
The differences within each village between the joint significance of the two instruments show
household at the highest elevation and the household at the
lowest elevation are between 25 and 150 meters.
36
Data on evapotranspiration is from the Latin America
Maize Research Atlas by D. P. Hodson, E. Martínez- the International Maize and Wheat Improvement Center
Romero, J. W. White, J. D. Corbett, and M. Bänziger at (CIMMYT).
VOL. 97 NO. 5 schechter: theft, gift-giving, and trustworthiness in paraguay 1577

that the instruments are jointly significant at the no one passes still give fewer gifts and experi-
1 percent level. ence less theft, while those living in the same
Farmers of Japanese heritage plant fewer steal- village with more close family members continue
able crops. These farmers are larger-scale farm- to give fewer gifts as well. Large households and
ers and tend to plant soy and wheat for export. households with more trustworthy neighbors no
Farmers with more trustworthy neighbors and longer give significantly more gifts than other
larger households plant more stealable crops, households, after controlling for the higher
perhaps because they worry less about theft. quantity of stealable crops they plant. As there
In the previous subsection, we saw that larger are many reasons people give gifts, only one of
households and households with more trustwor- which is the desire to limit theft, the fact that the
thy neighbors actually give more gifts. The rea- number of close relatives in the village and the
son they give more gifts may be to compensate number of people passing the field are significant
for the many stealable crops they are planting. in predicting gift-giving is quite convincing.
The fact that farmers with more trustworthy The two variables constructed from the exper-
neighbors plant more stealable crops suggests imental data—the player’s bet in the risk game
that the trustworthiness disutility included in and the trustee’s play in the trust game—are
the model does have an effect. Thieves do not not often significant in the regressions. I do not
steal only due to poverty, but also because of take this to mean that risk aversion and neighbor
their level of trustworthiness. trustworthiness are unimportant, but rather that
Table 5 shows the GMM results. The first the measures delivered by the experiments may
three columns estimate the system using all not capture them properly.
explanatory variables, while the last three col- Researchers who wish to combine survey and
umns use fewer regressors due to concerns of experimental data may learn from this experi-
degrees of freedom. Hansen’s J-statistic tests ence. Experimental data do tend to be correlated
whether the instrument set is uncorrelated with with real-world decisions. Karlan (2005) found
the errors. The J-statistics for the two sets of that play by individuals in the trust game has
explanatory variables have p-values of 0.22 and strong predictive power for default rates and
0.98. Although this test may behave strangely savings rates of those same individuals in their
with small datasets, I cannot reject the exogene- microfinance loans. In the current paper, risk
ity of the instruments. aversion is measured for one representative of
Households planting more stealable crops give the household, while the gift/theft equilibrium
significantly more gifts, although there is no is decided by the family as a whole. Future
effect on theft or trust.37 A household ­ planting work should strongly encourage the person who
one stealable crop gives a bit more than double makes the economic decision of relevance in
the value of gifts that a household planting no the survey to participate in the experiment as
stealable crops gives. A one-period model would well.38, 39 I use play by the trustees to derive a
predict that a farmer who plants more stealable measure of neighbor trustworthiness. Not only
crops will experience more theft. As gift-giving is the trust game played by only one individual
cannot discourage theft in a one-period model, in the household, it is also not played with all
there would be no correlation between gift-giving households in the village, but rather a random
and crop choice. Thus, the results are in accord sample. Researchers who want to use experi-
with the limited-commitment model but con- ments to measure group-level characteristics
trary to what a one-period model would suggest. should make sure to include as many members
The main results that held before controlling of the group as possible.
for crop choice still hold. Households with fields
38
There is a trade-off between allowing household
37
If farmers base their level of trust on the crop they members who are not instrumental in the decision of inter-
choose, then farmers who plant more stealable crops would est to participate and forbidding them, leading to missing
trust less. If they base their level of trust on both crops data and selection issues.
39
equally, then people who plant more stealable crops trust Excluding bets in the risk game made by women, the
more. If they weight the chosen crop more heavily, the coefficients are closer to significant and are in the predicted
effect will be indeterminate. direction.
1578 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2007

Table 5—Correlates of Gift Giving, Theft Experienced, and Trust Controlling for Crop Choice Using GMM

Panel A Panel B
Log 1 theft2 Log 1giving2 Trust Log 1 theft2 Log 1giving2 Trust
Bet 0.064 –0.070 0.021
10.0922 10.0642 10.0402
Didn’t play games 0.927 –0.245 –0.480
10.6272 10.5052 10.3062
No one passes field –0.568* –0.599** 0.178 –0.911*** –0.983*** 0.055
10.3282 10.2872 10.1532 10.3152 10.2762 10.1622
No. of HHs w/in 250 meters 0.035 –0.031 –0.008
10.0312 10.0222 10.0142
Family size –0.086 –0.003 0.043 –0.161 0.018 0.011
10.1272 10.0822 10.0482 10.1302 10.0872 10.0442
No. of close relatives in village –0.038 –0.095** 0.033 –0.013 –0.075* 0.029
10.0532 10.0442 10.0312 10.0482 10.0452 10.0292
Neighbor trustworthiness 1.572 0.984 1.143* 1.759 0.960 0.455
11.2382 10.9752 10.6092 1 1.2262 10.8132 10.5152
Km to police station –0.078 0.034 –0.006
10.0602 10.0362 10.0252
Log 1wealth 2 0.098 0.282*** –0.030 0.075 0.088 –0.057
10.1012 10.0712 10.0482 10.0712 10.0662 10.0362
Years in village 0.015** 0.024*** 0.011***
10.0072 10.0062 10.0042
Japanese village –1.296 –2.216*** 0.289
11.4042 10.8182 10.4922
No. of stealable crops 0.162 1.332*** –0.243 0.377 1.214*** –0.189
10.5622 10.3522 10.1722 10.5092 10.3372 10.1642
Overidentification 1J2 test 4.440 0.178
1 p 5 0.222 1 p 50.982
Observations 223 223 223 223 223 223
Note: Clustered heteroskedasticity-consistent standard errors in parentheses.
  *–10 percent, **–5 percent, and ***–1 percent significance.

V.  Conclusion Using a new dataset from rural Paraguay, I


test the predictions of the model. The dataset
Rural theft in Paraguay is not carried out by includes information on theft experienced, gifts
anonymous agents. Farmers claim to know who given, and survey measures of trust, as well as
is stealing from them, and have designed a sys- GPS data on location and elevation. In addition,
tem of informal sanctions and rewards to limit it includes measures of trustworthiness and risk
the amount of theft they experience. I have laid aversion from a set of economic experiments.
out a dynamic limited-commitment model in This experimental data provide novel controls
which a potential thief cannot commit to refrain that allow me to partially overcome omitted
from stealing. A farmer will thus give him gifts, variable bias.
and promise him continued gifts in the future, if The predictions of the limited-commitment
he limits his level of theft. This model yields pre- model are supported. Households with more
dictions that contrast with those of many models close relatives living in the same village give
of fairness and gift exchange in which increased fewer gifts, contrary to what one might expect.
trust is associated with more gift-giving rather These households may give fewer gifts because
than less. In this model, honest people who they know that their family members are less
would never steal will not receive gifts, while likely to steal from them and more likely to help
those who are untrustworthy are rewarded. monitor their fields, and so they do not need
VOL. 97 NO. 5 schechter: theft, gift-giving, and trustworthiness in paraguay 1579

Table A1—Correlates of Gift Giving, Theft Experienced, and Trust Using OLS with
Village Fixed Effects

Log (theft) Log (giving) Trust


Bet 0.067 –0.026 –0.003
(0.094) (0.085) (0.039)
Didn’t play games 0.528 –0.369 –0.459
(0.653) (0.622) (0.324)
No one passes field –0.604* –0.959*** 0.249
(0.353) (0.304) (0.156)
No. of households in 250 m radius 0.037 –0.058** –0.002
(0.027) (0.023) (0.012)
Family size –0.110 0.098 0.025
(0.105) (0.080) (0.046)
No. of close relatives in village –0.048 –0.094* 0.058**
(0.065) (0.053) (0.028)
Neighbor trustworthiness 1.659 1.793 0.648
(1.446) (1.282) (0.613)
Kilometers to police station –0.261* 0.045 –0.016
(0.149) (0.112) (0.050)
Log (wealth) 0.185* 0.329*** –0.067
(0.111) (0.103) (0.053)
Years in village –0.000 0.009 0.014**
(0.012) (0.011) (0.006)
Japanese village –4.072** –5.318*** 0.867*
(1.712) (1.191) (0.464)
R2 0.180 0.317 0.174
Observations 223 223 223
Note: Clustered heteroskedasticity-consistent standard errors in parentheses.
  *–10 percent, **–5 percent, and **–1 percent significance.

to entice them away from theft by giving them Appendix: Using Village Fixed Effects
gifts. Households from which it is more difficult
to steal give fewer gifts and experience less theft. In the analysis thus far, village fixed effects
In addition, households living in the same vil- were excluded, but it is of interest to see if the
lage with more close family members and with results change when including them. In this
fields no one passes trust more relative to other appendix, I carry out the same analysis as in
farmers in their village. I conclude that farmers the text but include village fixed effects. Before
in Paraguay do use giving, and the promise of controlling for crop choice, I include the same
future giving, as a means of limiting theft. explanatory variable as in Table 3. When con-
Throughout the paper, I assume the only way trolling for crop choice and including village
a farmer can avoid theft is through crop choice fixed effects, I can no longer use evapotranspi-
and strategic gift-giving. Much economic litera- ration as an instrument since it does not vary
ture on crime has focused on other forms of self- within a village. As altitude alone is not a strong
protection victims may employ (Isaac Ehrlich instrument, I use both altitude and past crop
and Gary S. Becker 1972). Farmers may choose choice as instruments, and I include the same
to monitor their fields, giving potential thieves explanatory variables as in the right-hand-side
less opportunity to steal. A useful avenue for columns of Table 5.
further research would be to incorporate the fact The results in Table A1, which do not control
that farmers can choose actions that affect the for crop choice, and those in Table A2, which do
cost of stealing for the potential thief. control for crop choice, are similar to those in
1580 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2007

Table A2—Correlates of Gift Giving, Theft Experienced, and Trust Using GMM
with Village Fixed Effects Controlling for Crop Choice

Log 1 theft2 Log 1giving2 Trust


No one passes field –0.335 –1.119*** 0.365**
10.3712 10.3702 10.1782
Family size –0.220* –0.048 0.017
10.1232 10.1112 10.0482
No. of close relatives in village –0.065 –0.045 0.084**
10.0642 10.0692 10.0332
Neighbor trustworthiness 2.183 –0.419 1.282
11.7962 11.7412 10.7842
Log 1wealth 2 –0.012 0.173 –0.057
10.1222 10.1102 10.0752
No. of stealable crops 0.390 2.058*** –0.004
10.8072 10.7072 10.3802
Overidentification 1J2 Test 6.252
1 p 5 0.102
Observations 177 177 177
Note: Clustered heteroskedasticity-consistent standard errors in parentheses.
  *–10 percent, **–5 percent, and ***–1 percent significance.

the main text. The results are a bit weaker than References
before. As there are 16 villages, this uses up 15
degrees of freedom in Table A1 and 45 valuable Abreu, Dilip. 1988. “On the Theory of Infinitely
degrees of freedom in Table A2 when the equa- Repeated Games with Discounting.” Econo-
tions are estimated as a system. This is a lot for metrica, 56(2): 383–96.
such a small dataset. Albarran, Pedro, and Orazio P. Attanasio. 2003.
Even after including village fixed effects, “Limited Commitment and Crowding Out
households with fields off of main footpaths of Private Transfers: Evidence from a Ran-
experience significantly less theft and give sig- domized Experiment.” Economic Journal,
nificantly fewer gifts; households with more 113(486): 77–85.
close relatives living in their village give sig- Alesina, Alberto, and Eliana La Ferrara. 2002.
nificantly fewer gifts; and households planting “Who Trusts Others?” Journal of Public Eco-
more easily stealable crops give significantly nomics, 85(2): 207–34.
more gifts. This is reassuring evidence that the Andreoni, James, and John Miller. 2002. “Giving
findings in the main text of this paper are not According to GARP: An Experimental Test of
due to unobserved village effects. the Consistency of Preferences for Altruism.”
After controlling for crop choice and village Econometrica, 70(2): 737–53.
fixed effects, larger households experience less Banfield, Edward C. 1958. The Moral Basis of a
theft. In addition, after controlling for village Backward Society. Glencoe and Chicago, IL:
fixed effects, two new results regarding trust Free Press.
arise. Farmers with fields that no one passes Barr, Abigail. 2003. “Trust and Expected Trust-
and who live in the same village with more of worthiness: Experimental Evidence from
their close relatives trust significantly more. Zimbabwean Villages.” Economic Journal,
These results were predicted by the model, but 113(489): 614–30.
were not found before controlling for village Becker, Gary S. 1968. “Crime and Punishment:
fixed effects. This suggests these farmers trust An Economic Approach.” The Journal of
more relative to other farmers within their vil- Political Economy, 76(2): 169–217.
lage, but not relative to farmers throughout the Ben-Porath, Yoram. 1980. “The F-Connection:
country. Families, Friends, and Firms and the Organi-
VOL. 97 NO. 5 schechter: theft, gift-giving, and trustworthiness in paraguay 1581

zation of Exchange.” Population and Develop- ity.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(3):
ment Review, 6(1): 1–30. 159–81.
Berg, Joyce, John W. Dickhaut, and Kevin A. Fehr, Ernst, and Klaus M. Schmidt. 1999. “A
McCabe. 1995. “Trust, Reciprocity, and Social Theory of Fairness, Competition, and Coop-
History.” Games and Economic Behavior, eration.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114
10(1): 122–42. (3): 817–68.
Bliege-Bird, Rebecca L., and Douglas W. Bird. Fisman, Raymond, and Tarun Khanna. 1999.
1997. “Delayed Reciprocity and Tolerated “Is Trust a Historical Residue? Information
Theft: The Behavioral Ecology of Food-Shar- Flows and Trust Levels.” Journal of Economic
ing Strategies.” Current Anthropology, 38(1): Behavior and Organization, 38(1): 79–92.
49–78. Foster, Andrew D., and Mark R. Rosenzweig.
Blurton-Jones, Nicholas G. 1987. “Tolerated 2001. “Imperfect Commitment, Altruism, and
Theft: Suggestions about the Ecology and Evo- the Family: Evidence from Transfer Behavior
lution of Sharing, Hoarding, and Scrounging.” in Low-Income Rural Areas.” Review of Eco-
Social Science Information, 26(1): 31–54. nomics and Statistics, 83(3): 389–407.
Burks, Stephen V., Jeffrey P. Carpenter, and Eric Foster, George M. 1965. “Peasant Society and the
Verhoogen. 2003. “Playing Both Roles in the Image of Limited Good.” American Anthro-
Trust Game.” Journal of Economic Behavior pologist, 67(2): 293–315.
and Organization, 51(2): 195–216. Fukuyama, Francis. 1995. Trust: The Social
Camerer, Colin. 1988. “Gifts as Economic Sig- Virtues and the Creation of Prosperity. New
nals and Social Symbols.” American Journal York: Free Press.
of Sociology, 94: 180–214. Glaeser, Edward L., Bruce Sacerdote, and José A.
Carmichael, H. Lorne, and W. Bentley MacLeod. Scheinkman. 1996. “Crime and Social Inter-
1997. “Gift Giving and the Evolution of Coop- actions.” Quarterly Journal of Economics,
eration.” International Economic Review, 111(2): 507–48.
38(3): 485–509. Gould, Eric D., Bruce A. Weinberg, and David B.
Carter, Michael R., and Pedro Olinto. 2003. “Get- Mustard. 2002. “Crime Rates and Local Labor
ting Institutions ‘Right’ for Whom? Credit Market Opportunities in the United States:
Constraints and the Impact of Property Rights 1979–1997.” Review of Economics and Statis-
on the Quantity and Composition of Invest- tics, 84(1): 45–61.
ment.” American Journal of Agricultural Eco- Hardin, Russell. 2002. Trust and Trustworthi-
nomics, 85(1): 173–86. ness, Vol. 4. New York: Russell Sage Founda-
Coate, Stephen, and Martin Ravallion. 1993. tion.
“Reciprocity without Commitment: Charac- Hawkes, Kristen. 1993. “On Why Male Foragers
terization and Performance of Informal Insur- Hunt and Share Food: Reply to K. Hill and H.
ance Arrangements.” Journal of Development Kaplan.” Current Anthropology, 34(5): 701–9.
Economics, 40(1): 1–24. Hölmstrom, Bengt. 1979. “Moral Hazard and
Dubois, Pierre, Bruno Jullien, and Thierry Observability.” Bell Journal of Economics,
­Magnac. 2006. “Formal and Informal Risk 10(1): 74–91.
Sharing in LDCs: Theory and Empirical Evi- Huck, Steffen, and Michael Kosfeld. 2007. “The
dence.” Institut National de la Recherche Agro­ Dynamics of Neighbourhood Watch and Norm
nomique Working Paper 2006–08. Enforcement.” Economic Journal, 117(516):
Ehrlich, Isaac, and Gary S. Becker. 1972. “Mar- 270–86.
ket Insurance, Self-Insurance, and Self-Pro- Karlan, Dean S. 2005. “Using Experimental Eco-
tection.” Journal of Political Economy, 80(4): nomics to Measure Social Capital and Predict
623–48. Financial Decisions.” American Economic
Fafchamps, Marcel, and Bart Minten. 2006. Review, 95(5): 1688–99.
“Crime, Transitory Poverty, and Isolation: Evi- Kletzer, Kenneth M., and Brian D. Wright. 2000.
dence from Madagascar.” Economic Develop- “Sovereign Debt as Intertemporal Barter.”
ment and Cultural Change, 54(3): 579–603. American Economic Review, 90(3): 621–39.
Fehr, Ernst, and Simon Gächter. 2000. “Fairness Knack, Stephen, and Philip Keefer. 1997. “Does
and Retaliation: The Economics of Reciproc- Social Capital have an Economic Payoff? A
1582 THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW DECEMBER 2007

Cross-Country Investigation.” Quarterly Jour- opment and Cultural Change, 47(4): 871–97.
nal of Economics, 112(4): 1251–88. Paige, Jeffery M. 1975. Agrarian Revolution:
Kocherlakota, Narayana R. 1996. “Implications Social Movements and Export Agriculture in
of Efficient Risk Sharing without Commit- the Underdeveloped World. New York: The
ment.” Review of Economic Studies, 63(4): Free Press.
595–609. Platteau, John Philippe, and Jeffrey Nugent. 1992.
Levi, Margaret. 2001. “When Good Defenses “Share Contracts and Their Rationale: Lessons
Make Good Neighbors: A Transaction Cost from Marine Fishing.” Journal of Develop-
Approach to Trust and Distrust.” In Institu- ment Studies, 28(3): 386–422.
tions, Contracts, and Organizations: Perspec- Posner, Richard A. 1981. The Economics of Jus-
tives from New Institutional Economics, ed. tice. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Claude Menard, 137–57. Cheltenham, UK: Press.
Edward Elgar. Posner, Richard A. 1998. “Social Norms, Social
Levitt, Steven D. 2004. “Understanding Why Crime Meaning, and Economic Analysis of Law: A
Fell in the 1990s: Four Factors That Explain the Comment.” Journal of Legal Studies, 27(2):
Decline and Six That Do Not.” Journal of Eco- 553–65.
nomic Perspectives, 18(1): 163–90. Rabin, Matthew. 1993. “Incorporating Fairness
Ligon, Ethan, Jonathan P. Thomas, and Tim Wor- into Game Theory and Economics.” American
rall. 2002. “Informal Insurance Arrangements Economic Review, 83(5): 1281–1302.
with Limited Commitment: Theory and Evi- Schechter, Laura. 2007. “Traditional Trust
dence from Village Economies.” Review of Measurement and the Risk Confound: An
Economic Studies, 69(1): 209–44. Experiment in Rural Paraguay.” Journal of
Mauss, Marcel. 1967. The Gift: Forms and Func- Economic Behavior and Organization, 62(2):
tions of Exchange in Archaic Societies. New 272–92.
York: Norton. Scott, James C. 1985. Weapons of the Weak:
Mui, Vai-Lam. 1995. “The Economics of Envy.” Everyday Forms of Peasant Resistance. New
Journal of Economic Behavior and Organiza- Haven: Yale University Press.
tion, 26(3): 311–36. Udry, Christopher. 1994. “Risk and Insurance in
Narayan, Deepa, and Lant Pritchett. 1999. “Cents a Rural Credit Market: An Empirical Investi-
and Sociability: Household Income and Social gation in Northern Nigeria.” Review of Eco-
Capital in Rural Tanzania.” Economic Devel- nomic Studies, 61(3): 495–526.

You might also like