You are on page 1of 4

VIEWPOINT

Viewpoint

Equity and health sector reforms: can low-income countries escape


the medical poverty trap?

Margaret Whitehead, Göran Dahlgren, Timothy Evans

In the past two decades, powerful international trends in care costs fall more directly on the sick (who are most likely
market-oriented health-sector reforms have been sweeping to be poor, children, or elderly), than on healthy
around the world, generally spreading from the northern to individuals. The World Bank’s counter-argument was that
the southern, and from the western to the eastern revenues from user fees could be used to subsidise those
hemispheres. Global blueprints have been advocated by least able to afford care.7 Exemption schemes were
agencies such as the World Bank to promote privatisation proposed to get round the difficulty of poor people not
of health-service providers, and to increase private being able to afford essential services. During the 1990s,
financing—via user fees—of public providers. Furthermore, the World Bank predicted that in one sweep, this user-fee
commercial interests are increasingly promoted by the policy would improve poorer groups’ access to and use of
World Trade Organisation, which has striven to open up essential health services.7 Why then is there widespread
public services to foreign investors and markets.1–3 This dissatisfaction with this policy in developing countries? The
policy could pave the way for public funding of private answer lies in the actual, rather than the predicted, effects
operators in health and education sectors,2 especially in experienced by families and communities.
wealthy, industrial countries in the northern hemisphere.
Although such attempts to undermine public services Out-of-pocket expenses for private services
pose an obvious threat to equity in the well established A second trend reinforcing the effect of user charges in the
social-welfare systems of Europe and Canada, other public sector, is the increase in private medical practices,
developments pose more immediate threats to the fragile and an explosive growth in private pharmacies.8 In
systems in middle-income and low-income countries. Two developing countries, pharmaceutical drugs now account
of these trends—the introduction of user fees for public for 30 to 50% of total health-care expenditure, compared
services, and the growth of out-of-pocket expenses for with less than 15% in established market economies.9
private services—can, if combined, constitute a major Private drug vendors, especially in Asia and parts of Africa,
poverty trap. tend to cater for poor people who cannot afford to use
professional services. These vendors, who are often
Private finance for public services unqualified, frequently do not follow prescribing
Introduction of user fees for public services has become regulations. In parts of China and India, drug vendors can
entrenched in many developing countries since publication be found on nearly every street corner.10 Limited access to
of the World Bank policy document of 1987.4 This strategy professional health services, and aggressive marketing of
was part of a health-policy package, which in turn was drugs on an unregulated market have not only generated an
one component of common macroeconomic structural- unhealthy and irrational use of medicines, but also wasted
adjustment programmes for countries facing debt.5 The scarce financial resources—especially, among poor people.
World Bank strategy has been powerfully reinforced by the
practice of making user fees a condition of loans and aid Medical poverty trap
from international donors, for example, in Kenya and The positive assumptions on which these strategies have
Uganda. been based are not borne out by the evidence. Results of
Private financing of public health services has also empirical studies on the effects of these policies point to
increased in countries with high and stable economic severe negative consequences.11,12 Rises in out-of-pocket
growth rates, such as China and Vietnam. Privatisation is costs for public and private health-care services are driving
claimed to increase the public’s appreciation of health many families into poverty, and are increasing the poverty
services and prevent overuse.4 Fees are assumed to offer of those who are already poor. The magnitude of this
financial possibilities to health providers for improvement situation—known as “the medical poverty trap”—has been
of quality of services.6 shown by national household surveys and participatory
Such privatisation policies in health care, however, are poverty alleviation studies.11,13–16 The main effects fall into
highly regressive, because pooling of risk is reduced and four categories.

Lancet 2001; 358: 833–36 Untreated morbidity


The most severe effects are felt by those who are denied
Department of Public Health, University of Liverpool, Liverpool, UK services because they cannot afford them and whose
(Prof M Whitehead PhD); Swedish National Institute of Public Health, sickness goes untreated. Such people are at risk of further
Stockholm, Sweden (Prof Göran Dahlgren MA); and Health Equity suffering and deterioration in health. In the Caribbean,
Division, The Rockefeller Foundation, New York, NY, USA between 14 and 20% of people who reported illness
(Timothy Evans MD) indicated that they did not seek care because of lack of
Correspondence to: Prof Margaret Whitehead, Department of Public funds for treatment or transport.17 In the Kyrgyz Republic,
Health, University of Liverpool, Whelan Building, The Quadrangle, more than half the patients referred to hospital were not
Liverpool L69 3GB, UK admitted, because they could not afford hospital costs.15 In
(e-mail: mmw@liverpool.ac.uk) some Indian rural areas, 17% of people who reported

THE LANCET • Vol 358 • September 8, 2001 833

For personal use. Only reproduce with permission from The Lancet Publishing Group.
VIEWPOINT

illness did not seek care, of whom more than a quarter cited the Asiatic republics of the former USSR.15 Poor
financial reasons.18 households reporting illness in a rural area in northern
Untreated sickness among poor people is recorded not Vietnam, spent an average 22% of their household budget
only in countries with serious economic difficulties, but also on health-care costs, whereas rich households spent 8%.14
in those with high and stable economic growth. For Moreover, poor people tended to pay more than rich
example, access to essential health services in rural China people at a health centre, and poor communes charged
was renowned, but has been drastically reduced despite a more than rich communes.24 In Thailand, poor people also
yearly economic growth rate of almost 10% in the past two pay proportionally more for health care than rich people.25
decades. In household surveys in rural China, 35–40% of So-called free maternity services in Dhaka, Bangladesh,
people who reported that they had had an illness did not have hidden and unofficial payments that necessitate more
seek health care, with financial difficulties cited by poor than a fifth of families spending the equivalent of 50–100%
people as the main reason.13,19 Additionally, 60% of those of their monthly income on maternity care.16 In Vietnam,
referred to hospital by a doctor never contacted the hospital the average cost of hospital admission is the equivalent of
because they knew they could not afford to pay the high 2 months’ wages,14 and in rural China, hospital care costs
user charges.13 Costs to individuals and society from up to seven times the net monthly income of a poor
untreated morbidity are potentially devastating. household.26
Loans and debt are common consequences of such
Reduced access to care expenses. In rural North Vietnam, 60% of poor households
Introduction of high user fees has typically caused an were in debt, with a third citing payment for health care as
indiscriminate reduction in access to care. The United the main reason.24 Similar patterns of debt occur in parts of
Nations Research Institute for Social Development has Africa, China, and Cambodia. In Phnom Pen, Cambodia,
recently summarised the experiences of user fees: “Of all 20% of patients who had obtained money for treatment
measures proposed for raising revenue from local people costs had taken out loans from private lenders, and were
this [user fees] is probably the most ill advised. One study paying extortionate interest of 20–30% per month. 10% of
of 39 developing countries found that the introduction of these patients cut down on food to offset the cost of
user fees had increased revenues only slightly, while borrowing. In two rural districts of Uganda, between 20%
significantly reducing the access of low-income people to and 40% of patients raised money for health-care bills not
basic social services. Other studies have shown that fees only by borrowing, but also by working for others, or selling
reinforce gender inequality.20 Poor people delay seeking off assets such as land or cattle. Withdrawal of children
care until an emergency situation arises, because of from school is another common coping strategy—to save
financial constraints.11 This delay often forces them on school fees and so that children can help out on the farm
eventually to seek care at a more expensive level, typically at while parents seek temporary jobs to pay off loans for
a hospital, rather than at a health centre. The negative hospital bills.11 In traditional economic analyses, poorer
effects of user fees are therefore two-fold: poorer health and groups’ payment for health care is typically used as
increased medical expenditure. High user fees are thus evidence of willingness to pay. However, it is increasingly
inefficient and inequitable. clear that payment is not the same as ability to pay. Many
However, advocates of private finance argue that negative poor people cannot afford to pay, but still do so, at great
effects of user fees are not inevitable. Efficient and fair long-term cost to themselves and their families.
systems for waiving user fees could be established, and
thereby secure access to public health-care services for Irrational use of drugs
those not able to pay.7 In practice, establishment of well Irrational prescribing and drug resistance make an
functioning systems for waiving fees has proved very important, but overlooked, contribution to the inequities of
difficult.21 A major difficulty is to identify very poor people the medical poverty trap. For example, in India, 52% of
in a population in which poverty is rife. Another difficulty is out-of-pocket health expenditure went towards medicines
that no public funds are set aside to compensate local and fees, as did 71% of in-patient expenditure.18 People in
providers for reduction or elimination of fees for some of parts of rural China spend between two and five times the
their poorer patients. Public health-care providers, who average daily-per-capita income on a typical prescription.27
depend on revenue from fees, are likely to start to give In a growing number of low-income countries, profits from
priority to patients who can pay. In many countries, this sales of drugs have become an important part of health-
trend is reinforced because revenue from fees is directly related workers’ incomes, and an incentive for workers to
linked to health staff payments and salaries.22 In such a increase sales to their maximum.28
financial climate, public hospitals tend to favour rich Increasingly, in developing countries, sale of drugs
people, who generally gain greater shares of public funds without prescription by unqualified people, who have
than poor people. financial incentives to overprescribe, leads to unnecessary
and irrational use of medicines. In rural areas and poor
Long-term impoverishment quarters of cities in India, indiscriminate prescription of
People buy care even if it costs them their long-term injections and drips is rife. For example, in an analysis of
livelihood, because medical expenses are often forced prescriptions in the Indian district of Satara in
payments. Their difficulty is not in allocation of scarce Maharashtra,29 19% of prescriptions were thought
resources, but rather whether or not they can find money irrational, 47% were unnecessary, and 11% were
for urgent treatment such as surgery. The negative social hazardous. Unnecessary injections were given in 24% of
effects of direct user fees for health care are also greater cases. Up to 70% of all expenditure on drugs in India is
than most other fees, because these expenses are thought unnecessary.18
unexpected and total cost is often not known until after In a national household survey in Vietnam, 67% of all
treatment. those who reported illness in the previous 4 weeks had
The economic effect of ill health has long been a cause of obtained medicines without consultation with a medical
bankruptcies in the USA,23 but in the 1990s, ill health practitioner.30 Furthermore, rural commune health-workers
became a leading cause of household impoverishment in frequently prescribed oral antibiotics, gentamicin
transitional economies, such as rural China,13 and some of injections, potent steroids, and oral and intravenous

834 THE LANCET • Vol 358 • September 8, 2001

For personal use. Only reproduce with permission from The Lancet Publishing Group.
VIEWPOINT

vitamin preparations inappropriately.31 Vietnam’s high households of low, middle, and high income? How
frequency of antibiotic resistance is a clear indication of the affordable are the results of different policy options for
adverse health effects of inappropriate drug sales and families? How do reforms affect the ability of different
irrational consumption.32 In a poor region of Mexico, 74% population groups to secure health services according to
of health-care visits resulted in inadequate treatment or need? In such an approach, questions would also be asked
advice, especially from traditional healers or retail drug about why an increasing number of households do not use
sellers.33 On average, the equivalent of 13 days minimum available public health services, but treat themselves at
wage was spent unnecessarily per patient, in 1 month, home. Qualitative studies are needed to fully understand all
because of inadequate prescribing.33 the factors involved in these decisions. The fact that many
Poor people receive ineffective, or even dangerous people pay for health care has for too long been taken as
treatment, including inappropriate or inadequate synonymous with willingness and ability to pay, but with no
antituberculosis treatment regimens,34 and contraindicated assessment of how much of a burden payment is on the
drugs for women in pregnancy.35 If people can afford only a household budget.41 Affordability should have a more
part course of drugs (eg, for tuberculosis or malaria), these important place in investigation of health reform. The
drugs are not only ineffective, but also create drug potential to do this type of household-focused research is
resistance that can threaten whole communities.36 The increasing, because many low-income countries are
same situation occurs with widespread overprescription (or undertaking national standard-of-living household surveys
self-medication) of antibiotics for straightforward cases of and various participatory poverty assessment studies.
diarrhoea, for which oral-rehydration therapy would be How could the medical poverty trap be prevented? What
most appropriate.37 For example, in a periurban community are the policy options for prevention of medical poverty
in Mexico, antibiotics were used in 37% of diarrhoeal traps in different countries? The answer to these questions
episodes, although this therapy was indicated in only 5% of will be crucial in the next few years, and will need to
episodes.38 In six other Latin American countries, a quarter encompass not only health-systems policy, but also broad
of drugs bought over the counter should have been development issues to alleviate poverty.
dispensed on a prescription, because they needed medical Furthermore, the weaknesses in public health services
follow-up.39 need to be acknowledged and tackled. Cultural access is an
especial problem that encompasses: lack of responsiveness;
What can be done about the medical poverty disrespect shown towards disadvantaged groups of people;
trap? and widespread use of informal so-called under-the-table
The actual outcomes of previous and current market- payments, which all contribute to underuse of public
oriented reforms have often been contrary to stated services in some low-income countries. This underuse is
objectives, as economic access for poor people has declined also caused partly by chronic under-resourcing, partly by
and total costs increased. These gaps between stated the ways staff treat patients, and partly by indirect costs of
objectives and outcomes have shown lack of, and need for, service use, such as transport and loss of income.22,42
a firmer evidence base for health-sector policies. The Furthermore, public hospital services are mainly used by
overall view is clouded by rhetoric and unsupported better-off people, who can afford high direct costs. This
assumptions about the merits of policies that are widely tendency to crowd out less-privileged people is reinforced
advocated. There is a need for policy research to assess the in times of economic recession, when rich people find
validity of assumptions that underly market-oriented paying the market price for private health-care services
reforms, and the options for, and constraints on, difficult to afford. The way forward is certainly country
development of efficient and equitable health-care systems. specific, but policy-oriented research is needed to assess the
The need to be vigilant and to ascertain what is really most promising options.
happening in low-income countries, rather than to rely on Such options include strategies for public finance that
assumptions, is vividly illustrated by policy on user fees. encompass tax polices and tax evasion, to ensure effective
Some commentators accept that the World Bank has pooling of risks across the whole population. Also needed is
ceased pushing user fees as a strategy in low-income gradual change from direct payments to social health-
countries, and therefore, that this strategy is a thing of the insurance systems, in which healthy, high-income groups
past and no longer a problem. Unfortunately, this subsidise care for low-income groups. These insurance
discredited policy is still alive and well, and causes immense systems would include community-based health insurance
distress in many countries of the southern hemisphere. subsidised by public funds, which could also cover costs for
Noting the persistence of this policy, the US House of essential drugs. Efforts should be intensified to reduce, and
Representatives approved a measure in July, 2000, to even eliminate, informal payments for public health-
pressure the World Bank to stop requiring impoverished services. Ways of strengthening the regulatory role of
countries to charge “user fees” for basic health services and governments should be investigated, to empower
primary education. This opens up an opportunity to governments to develop and implement essential drug
influence the user-fee policy of the Bank, by use of the best programmes and systematic assessments of medical
evidence available, although that evidence has yet to be technologies. This shift in power could ensure the highest
fully marshalled. possible value for money spent on health services and drugs
Apart from the user-fee issue, other aspects of reforms in terms of improved health, minimum negative side-
are proving pernicious to poor people, and require a much effects, and reductions in inequities in access to care.
more active approach to monitor trends in the health At the international level, financial institutions should
sector; one such approach, termed an equity gauge, is focus on how to tax rich rather than poor people—for
already underway and provides a model for how this might example, by promotion of a tax on funds hidden in tax-free
be done.40 In this context, the potential of an essential drugs offshore accounts. If these off-shore deposits (estimated by
watch is being assessed, which would monitor equity and International Monetary Fund to be around US$8 trillion)
quality of countries’ drug policies, raise awareness of health earned income of around 5% per year, which was taxed at
issues, and inform health policies. 40%, about US$160 billion per year would be raised—
Effects of reform efforts need to be assessed from a estimated to be more than the cost of providing basic social
household perspective. What do health reforms mean for services for developing countries.20

THE LANCET • Vol 358 • September 8, 2001 835

For personal use. Only reproduce with permission from The Lancet Publishing Group.
VIEWPOINT

Conclusion 16 Nahar S, Costello A. The hidden cost of “free” maternity care in Dhaka,
An evidence-based approach to secure efficient, equity- Bangladesh. Health Policy Plan 1998; 13: 417–22.
oriented health-sector reforms is long overdue, but would 17 Theodore K. Health sector reform and equity in Jamaica: report to the
Pan-American Health Organisation. Washington : PAHO, 1999.
require policy makers to refocus their efforts on many 18 Iyer A, Sen G. Health sector changes and health equity in the 1990s in
fronts.43 The research community has an important part to India. In: Roghuram S, ed. Health and equity: technical report series
play in distinguishing myths from realities, and making 1.8. Bangalore: HIVOS, 2000.
explicit the underlying values of proposed policies.44 People 19 Hao Y, Suhua C, Lucas H. Equity in the utilization of medical services:
studying health systems should widen their perspective to a survey in poor rural China. IDS Bull 1997: 28.
20 United Nations Research Institute for Social Development (UNRISD).
include links with poverty-alleviation strategies, and vice Visible hands—taking responsibility for social development. Geneva:
versa. Above all, a shift in perspective is needed to give UNRISD, 2000.
greater emphasis to equity when assessing the effects of any 21 Russell S, Gilson L. User fee policies to promote health service access
proposed policy changes on health and social wellbeing of for the poor: a wolf in sheep’s clothing? Int J Health Services 1997; 27:
families. In particular, changes need to be reviewed with 359–79.
22 McPake B, Asiimwe D, Mwesigye F, et al. Informal economic activities
poorer, more vulnerable sections of society in mind, to of public health workers in Uganda: implications for quality and
ensure that these groups are winners and not losers in accessibility of care. Soc Sci Med 1999; 49: 849–65.
global health-policy reform. 23 Gottlieb S. Medical bills account for 40% of bankruptcies. BMJ 2000;
320: 1295.
Contributors 24 Ensor T, Pham S. Access and payment for health care. The poor of
Margartet Whitehead, Göran Dahlgren, and Timothy Evans generated the Northern Vietnam. Int J Health Plann Manage, 1996; 11: 69-83.
original idea, developed the approach, appraised the evidence, agreed on the 25 Pannarunothai S, Mills A. The poor pay more: health-related inequality
structure, and contributed to the writing of the paper. All three authors read in Thailand. Soc Sci Med 1997; 44: 1781–90.
and approved the final manuscript. 26 Yu H, Cao S, Lucas H. Equity in the utilisation of medical services: a
survey in poor rural China. IDS Bull 1997; 28: 16–23.
Acknowledgments 27 Zhan S, Tang S, Guo Y. Drug prescribing in rural health facilities in
We thank all participants of the expert consultation at Rockefeller China. IDS Bull 1997; 28: 66–70.
Foundation Study Centre, Bellagio, Italy, July, 2000, for their insight in 28 Wolffers I. The role of pharmaceuticals in the privatization process in
discussions on equity and health-sector reforms: Celia Almeida, Vietnam. Soc Sci Med 1995; 41: 1325–32.
Lincoln Chen, Andrew Creese, Davidson Gwatkin, Benjamin Nganda, 29 Phadke A. The quality of prescribing in an Indian district. Natl Med
Di McIntyre, Martin McKee, Harry Minas, Myrtle Perera, Malcolm Segall, J India 1996; 9: 60–65.
Gita Sen, Karl Theodore, and Meg Wirth. Margaret Whitehead and 30 Prescott N. Poverty, social services and safety nets in Vietnam: World
Göran Dahlgren were funded by Rockefeller Foundation planning grant Bank discussion paper no 376. Washington: World Bank, 1997.
number RG 99037 number 4 to develop an international programme of 31 Tipping G, Truong V, Nguyen T, Segall M. Quality of public heath
research on equity and health-sector reforms. services and household health care decisions in rural communes of
Vietnam. IDS report no 27. University of Sussex: Institute of
Development Studies, 1994.
32 Törnqvist N, Wenngren B, Nguyen TKC, et al. Antibiotic resistance in
References
Vietnam: an epidemiological indicator of inefficient and inequitable use
1 Price D, Pollock AM, Shaoul J. How the World Trade Organisation is of health resources. In: Hung PM, Minas IH, Liu Y, Dahlgren G,
shaping domestic policies in health care. Lancet, 1999; 354: 1889–92. Hsiao WC, eds. Efficient equity-oriented strategies for health:
2 Pollock A, Price D. Rewriting the regulations: how the World Trade international perspectives—focus on Vietnam. CIMH: University of
Organisation could accelerate privatisation in health-care systems. Melbourne, 2000.
Lancet, 2000; 356: 1995–2000. 33 Briggs J. The economic consequences of inadequate prescribing on
3 Anon. Trading public health for private wealth. Lancet 2000; 356: 1941. health care users and providers: a case study in San Cristobel, Mexico.
4 Akin J, Birdsall N, Ferranti D. Financing health services in developing Liverpool: Liverpool School of Tropical Medicine, 2000.
countries: an agenda for reform. Washington: World Bank, 1987. 34 Uplekar M, Shepard D. Treatment of TB by private GPs in India. Tuber
5 Sen K, Koivusalo M. Health care reforms and developing countries—a Lung Dis 1991; 72: 284–90.
critical overview. Int J Health Plann Manage 1998; 13: 199–215. 35 Krause G, Borchert M, Benzler J, et al. Rationality of drug prescriptions
6 Griffin D. Welfare gains from user charges for government health in rural health centres in Burkina Faso. Health Policy Plan 1999; 14:
services. Health Policy Plan 1992; 7: 177–80. 291–98.
7 Shaw P, Griffin C. Financing health care in sub-Saharan Africa through 36 Farmer P, Reichman L, Iseman M, eds. The global impact of drug
user fees and insurance: directions in development. Washington: World resistant tuberculosis. Boston: Harvard Medical School/Open Society
Bank, 1995. Institute, 1999.
8 Paphassarang C, Tomson G, Choprapawon C, Weerasuriya K. The Lao 37 Le Grand A, Hogerzeil H, Haaijer-Ruskamp F. Intervention research in
national drug policy: lessons along the journey. Lancet 1995; rational use of drugs: a review. Health Policy Plan, 1999; 14:
345: 433–35. 89–102.
9 Velásquez G, Madrid Y, Quick J. Health reform and drug financing: 38 Bojalil R, Calva J. Antibiotic misuse in diarrhea: a household survey in a
selected topic—health economics and drugs DAP Series No 6. Mexican community. J Clin Epidemiol 1994; 47: 147–56.
WHO/DAP/98.3, action programme on essential drugs. Geneva: World 39 Drug utilization research group, Latin America. Multicenter study on
Health Organisation, 1998. self-medication and self-prescription in six Latin American countries.
10 Kamat V, Nichter M. Pharmacies, self-medication and pharmaceutical Clin Pharmacol Ther, 1997; 61: 488–93.
marketing in Bombay, India. Soc Sci Med 1998; 47: 779–94. 40 Health Systems Trust. Equity gauge: an approach to monitoring equity
11 Tipping G. The social impact of user fees for health care on poor in health and in health care in developing countries. Report of an
households: commissioned report to the Ministry of Health, Hanoi, international meeting 17–20 Aug, 2000. Durban: Health Systems Trust,
Vietnam; 2000. 2000.
12 Creese A, Kutzin J. Lessons from cost-recovery in health. Discussion 41 Evans TG. Socioeconomic consequences of blinding onchocerciasis in
Paper No 2. Forum for Health Sector Reform. Geneva: World Health West Africa. Bull World Health Organ 1995; 73: 495–506.
Organization, 1995. 42 Bloom G, McIntyre D. Towards equity in health in an unequal society.
13 Fu W. Health care for China’s rural poor, international policy Soc Sci Med 1998; 47: 1529–38.
programme. Washington: World Bank, 1999. 43 Whitehead M, Dahlgren G, Gilson L. Developing the policy response to
14 Segall M, Tipping G, Lucas H, et al. Health care seeking by the poor in inequities in health: a global perspective. In: Evans T, Whitehead M,
transitional economies; the case of Vietnam: research report no 43. Diderichsen F, Bhuiya A, Wirth M. Challenging inequities in health:
Sussex: Institute of Development Studies, 2000. from ethics to action. New York: Oxford University Press, 2001.
15 World Bank. The Kyrgyz Republic: participatory poverty assessment, 44 Segall M. From co-operation to competition in national health
prepared for the global synthesis workshop poverty programme. systems—and back? Impact on professional ethics and quality of care.
Washington: World Bank, 1999. Int J Health Plan Manage 2000; 15: 61–79.

836 THE LANCET • Vol 358 • September 8, 2001

For personal use. Only reproduce with permission from The Lancet Publishing Group.

You might also like