You are on page 1of 9

Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 56 (2016) 563–571

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews


journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/rser

How capacity mechanisms drive technology choice in power


generation: The case of Colombia
Yris Olaya a, Santiago Arango-Aramburo a, Erik R. Larsen b,n
a
Decision Science Group, Universidad Nacional de Colombia, Colombia
b
Università della Svizzera italiana, Switzerland

art ic l e i nf o a b s t r a c t

Article history: Colombia enacted its first legal framework for promoting alternative energies in 2001 and a second
Received 12 May 2015 framework in 2014. Since the generation technology mix has not changed since 2000, there is a need to
Received in revised form understand how regulation and market structure affect the adoption of technologies. In this paper we
30 October 2015
address the question of what has been the impact of the capacity mechanisms adopted during the 2000s
Accepted 22 November 2015
on technology choices for power generation in Colombia. Our approach is to analyze the evolution of
Available online 17 December 2015
market structure and regulation. We found that regulatory uncertainty and low prices drove a surge of
Keywords: small hydro plants during the 2000s. During the 2010s, the new regulatory focus on reliability of supply
Power generation mix has resulted in increased coal-fueled generation and large hydro. This increased reliance on hydro power
Capacity mechanisms
can further delay the entry of renewable technologies and the diversification of the Colombian portfolio.
Renewable energy
& 2015 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
Colombia

Contents

1. Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 563
2. Overview of the Colombian power system. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 564
2.1. From central planning to deregulation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 565
3. Effect of capacity mechanisms in the Colombian power sector . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 565
3.1. Before deregulation (Before 1994) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 565
3.2. Market system and capacity charge (1994–2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 566
3.3. Reliability charge or forward firm energy market (After 2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 567
4. From big to small hydro . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 568
4.1. Role of (other) renewables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 568
5. Discussion and conclusion . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 569
References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 570

1. Introduction countries a desire to move away from nuclear generation [1–3].


Some of these changes are motivated by environmental concerns,
Technology choices for power generation determine to a large by technological uncertainty, economic changes, and perceived risk
extent the structure of energy supply and have lasting impacts on of nuclear power as well as ideological views, all of which play a
the environment. During the last three decades, we have witnessed role in establishing policy priorities.
a shift away from coal to gas-fueled power generation, the intro- The creation of power markets worldwide is the result of a
duction of renewable energy technologies, and recently in many broader energy policy aimed at increasing efficiency and attracting
private investments – with the goal of satisfying a growing
n
demand for electricity, particularly in the developing world [4]. In
Correspondence to: Via Buffi 13, CH-6904 Lugano, Switzerland.
E-mail addresses: yolayam@unal.edu.co (Y. Olaya), the early years of market reforms, increasing competition and
saarango@unal.edu.co (S. Arango-Aramburo), erik.larsen@usi.ch (E.R. Larsen). efficiency in generation were the main issues by regulators and

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.rser.2015.11.065
1364-0321/& 2015 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
564 Y. Olaya et al. / Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 56 (2016) 563–571

researchers. Bringing competition to the power market meant compared to other industries, making it more difficult to ensure
often unbundling utilities, breaking monopolies up, and creating that the right incentives are in place to achieve the right mix of
commodity-like markets for electricity. Two decades later, future technologies.
reliability is one of the main concerns in liberalized markets [5–9]. The aim of this paper is to illustrate how different regulatory
In fact, the International Energy Agency (IEA) and European Union regimes affect technology choices, using Colombia as a case study.
(EU) estimate that EU countries need to invest Euro 1 trillion from Colombia is an interesting case as the incentives for adding
2012 to 2020 and a further Euro 3 trillion to 2050 to ensure ade- capacity have been modified twice since deregulation, in an effort
quate electricity capacity [8], despite some disagreements with to adapt the regulation to shifting economic and market condi-
these estimates [10]. Ensuring that such new investments are tions. The first incentives (1996–2006) aimed at reducing the
made in a timely manner is a challenge for power markets and it electricity system's vulnerability during dry periods. These
might be an opportunity for introducing alternative generation incentives were modified in 2006 in order to provide signals for
technologies. expansions of the system. While regulation has succeeded in
In theory, a competitive market setting should give the right securing supply during dry periods, the technology mix has
signals at the right time for investors to choose the best technology remained basically unchanged since 2000. Furthermore, with the
for expanding generating capacity. Power markets, however, are not exception of small hydro plants, penetration of other renewable
perfectly competitive [11], future returns are highly uncertain [12] technologies is almost zero. In the next sections we examine how
and investment decisions are constrained by environmental con- capacity mechanisms and the structure of the market have influ-
cerns, availability of appropriate generation technologies and the enced technology choices for power generation in Colombia.
general future economic outlook [13]. As a result of the high This paper is organized as follows: Section 2 makes a brief
uncertainty and the long lead times for new projects, it is common description of the Colombian power system, including the capacity
for power markets to observe cycles of over- and under-capacity before deregulation and explains the events that led to deregula-
margin [14]. Such fluctuations increase supply risk, and thus the tion. Section 3 describes and discusses the resource adequacy
objective of regulation is to reduce them. Achieving a long-term mechanisms used in Colombia, and their impact on the generation
security of supply (resource adequacy) at a low cost is particularly mix, including capacity mechanisms’ implications for renewable
challenging for developing countries that face increasing demand energy. Section 4 presents the main insights and conclusions from
and need to expand access to energy [5–9,15]. the previous analysis.
While markets in different jurisdictions have different price-
setting mechanisms, the most common mechanism is prices based
on marginal costs. Marginal cost-pricing, however, does not offer 2. Overview of the Colombian power system
sufficient incentives for adding new capacity and increasing long-
term security of supply [16], a phenomenon known as the “miss- Seasonal variations of power demand in Colombia are relatively
ing money problem” [17]. Most markets solve it by using a sepa- small, and high capacity margins are maintained as a reliability
rate, often complex, set of rules for calculating and allocating strategy. Because the share of hydro generating capacity is larger
payments for capacity availability – known as capacity payments. than 65%, the Colombian power system is vulnerable to weather
The idea behind capacity payments is to recover capital costs that changes such as the prolonged and intense droughts caused by the
are not part of the market price, thus keeping enough capacity to macroclimatic phenomena of “El Niño South Oscillation” (ENSO).
satisfy demand at a given reliability level. Nowadays, there is a The interconnected power system provides electricity to 94.6% of
debate on whether capacity payments are needed, instead of the population [19], with high quality standards. Table 1 sum-
relying on an energy-only market that rewards generating plants marizes the main indicators of Colombia's macroeconomic con-
with scarcity rents [15,17,18]. Suppliers in an energy-only market dition and power system. Hydro power dominates the technology
bid prices instead of bidding their marginal cost. Price bids should
include the capacity cost and they also increase during peak Table 1
demand periods, when capacity is scarce. Many electricity markets Macro-economic and electricity industry indicators in Colombia.
use capacity payments or a related mechanism to increase the
Demographic and economic indicators Electricity prices ($US/kW h)
revenues of the generators and to incentivize their investment in
2012a
new capacity. That is the case of Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Population (est. Jan. 2015)b 47,965,803 Residential 0.2
Perú, Spain, and the UK [15]. Alternatively, Australia, Alberta, GDP (ppp) Billions US$ 526.5 Industrial 0.22
ERCOT, and New Zealand have complete commodities markets for (est. 2013)c
electricity and have implemented energy-only markets that have GDP per capita (ppp) 2013 11,100 Commercial 0.16
est.c
been successful so far [17].
Market structure Bid based
The contribution of new capacity to the system's reliability
Installed generation capacity (MW), Dec. Electricity demand profile
depends on the size and timing of investments and varies widely
31 2013d (2012)e
across technologies. Wind technologies, for instance, have name- Hydro 9875 Industry 31%
plate capacities that are between 60 and 70 percent higher than Thermal 4598 Transport 0%
their annual output, and they only increase capacity margins when Wind 20 Residential 41%
wind is available. In fact, a proper mix of technologies increases Co-generation 66 Commerce and public 24%
Total 14559 Agricultural/Forestry/ 4%
the reliability of supply. Therefore, regulators need to understand
fishing
the logic of investment decisions and tailor the resource-adequacy
Energy intensitye Electricity demand growthe
mechanisms to each particular case.
TPES/pop (toe/capita) 0.66 Average 2004–2008 3.0%
To a great extent, the incentives and rules set by regulators TPES/GDP (toe/000 2005 0.16 Average 2008–2012 4.5%
drive technology choices by investors in a particular area, and the USD)
pace of the investment. The consequences of investment decisions
a
are complex as new capacity takes from some months (e.g. Photo [24].
b
[22].
Voltaic (PV)), several years (e.g. Combined Cycle Gas Turbines c
[21].
(CCGT)) to a decade (e.g. big hydro) to come on-stream. Moreover, d
[20].
capacity is often added in large chunks and has a long life-time e
[23].
Y. Olaya et al. / Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 56 (2016) 563–571 565

of the electricity sector's budget was allocated to pay back the


loans, and to cover past deficits [29].
During the 1980s, GDP grew on average less than 4% annually
[30]. The low economic growth continued through the 1990s, and
between 1985 and 1996 per capita electricity consumption in
Colombia was one of the lowest in Latin America [31]. Never-
theless, construction delays in new power plants and a strong El
Niño in 1991–992, led to major blackouts from March of 1992 to
April of 1993 [32]. The severe financial problems of the utilities,
their lack of efficiency and inability to make timely investments
explain why, by the end of the 1980s, there was a general agree-
ment on the need for a reform of the power sector, to improve its
technical and administrative efficiency.
The power industry's reform began with the new constitution
in 1991, and was completed in 1994 by laws 142 [33] and 143 [34].
Law 143 (Electricity Law) aims at increasing the efficiency and
Fig. 1. Contribution of public utilities (electricity, gas, and water) to the Colombian quality of the electricity supply through market mechanisms,
external debt between 1970 and 1998, [28]. whereas Law 142 establishes the role of the government as a
regulator. Enactment of these laws was the first step towards
mix for generation, as it represents 65% of the 8525 MW of deregulation. Law 142 created regulatory, planning, and oversight
installed capacity [20]. bodies for electricity and gas. To foster competition, reforms
Since the reforms of the power sector in 1994, Colombia has separated transmission from distribution and generation, and
had a market-oriented system, including regulatory and oversight achieved partial unbundling of generation and distribution. An
bodies [25]. Following deregulation, the power market has sup- independent system operator in charge of coordinating transmis-
plied energy with virtually no interruptions; power companies are sion and dispatch was created, and open access to the grid was
today in a good financial position, as evidenced by their ability to guaranteed. Monopolies in transmission and distribution were
enter new markets in Chile, Brazil, Perú, and Guatemala, among regulated, while generation and the unregulated retail market
others [26]. Nevertheless, as we discuss next, the process to were opened for competition.
improve the system's performance was not smooth and it has A pool-based market was created to increase competition in
required major structural and regulatory challenges. power generation. In this market, price is set in a day-ahead
The issues before the reforms are illustrated by the fact that market in which all generators must participate, regardless of their
public utilities were responsible for more than 35% of the contracts. Bids are freely placed in the market. Thermal generators'
Colombian external debt (see Fig. 1). Some companies had diffi- bids are to be based on variable operating costs (fuel) while hydro
culties financing expansions and mismanagement was widespread generators' bids represent the value of water. One of the main
[27], which led to a series of costly blackouts in the early nineties. motivations for the reform was the need to attract investment in
These major blackouts made reforms easier to pass because they the generation needed to keep pace with the (forecasted) growth
exposed the weaknesses of the existing monopolistic system. in demand, [4,25,35]. For this reason, from the beginning, there
The Colombian power sector has gone through several struc- were separate payments for energy and for capacity. Capacity
tural reforms, in which the regulator has adapted the strategy to payments have been modified three times since 1994, reflecting
achieve resource adequacy, as we show in the following sections. policy shifts, and these changes have produced distinct responses
These changes provide us with valuable data and insights on the in capacity expansion that we examine next.
impact of regulation on technology choices, as well as on the
effects of the initial technology mix on regulatory decisions. We
discuss these issues in further detail in the following section, in 3. Effect of capacity mechanisms in the Colombian power
which we give a short account of the events that shaped the sector
present power system in Colombia.
In this section we discuss the effect of capacity mechanisms on
2.1. From central planning to deregulation generation-technology choices in Colombia. Fig. 2 shows the
additions of generating capacity to the Colombian system from
In the early 1960s, the Colombian government began planning 1960 to 2010 and the approved additions to enter between 2011
for the interconnection of the largest regional, vertically- and 2019. As discussed above, between 1960 and 2014 the elec-
integrated public utilities. ISA, the national grid company, was tricity sector went through major structural changes. We divide
our analysis into three periods: the period before the sector reform
created in 1967 and was responsible for the system operation and
in 1994, the first regulatory period focusing on resource adequacy
expansion planning. Between 1970 and 1980 the public utilities,
where the mechanism was capacity payments, and a second reg-
along with ISA, installed more than 1200 MW of generating
ulatory period beginning in 2006, corresponding to reliability
capacity,1 to satisfy the growing demand. Because of this expan-
payments (see Fig. 2).
sion, utilities (including ISA) were having trouble financing pro-
jects and there were problems with completing projects on
3.1. Before deregulation (Before 1994)
schedule; such delays led to power cuts in 1981 [27]. To avoid
power shortages, the government focused on financing new gen-
Before 1994, ISA, the national transmission company, coordi-
erating plants which led to a 28% increase in Colombia's external
nated the expansion of generating capacity. Expansion projects
debt between 1970 and 1980. By 1985, the external debt origi-
were selected using an optimization program that minimized
nating from public utilities was 35% [28]. At this point, nearly 40%
capital and operating costs while satisfying expected demand and
transmission constraints, among other conditions. During this
1
ISA informes de operación 1970–1998. period, hydro power was the preferred technology for expanding
566 Y. Olaya et al. / Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 56 (2016) 563–571

Fig. 2. Annual additions to generating capacity in Colombia from 1960 to 2010 and approved additions from 2011 to 2019. Data from ISA's annual operation reports 1980–
2005, and from UPME, [36].

power generating capacity at low cost. In fact, 86% of the 1240 MW weather conditions, making them less competitive. The electricity
added during the 1960s was hydro. market began operating in 1995, and it became clear that thermal
In the 1970s, new generating capacity doubled the previous output sold at peak prices during dry seasons would not generate
decade's capacity and the share of thermal generating capacity enough revenue to justify investments in thermal capacity. The
increased to 40% of the total, as more than 5 GW were added. response from regulators was to create a capacity charge [39,40],
Despite this surge in capacity, power generation could not keep up which rewarded the contribution of each generator to securing
with increases in demand as some projects were delayed, which supply during dry periods, in particular for an extreme El Niño
led to a blackout in 1983. By 1990, total generating capacity was event. Such charges had previously been applied in the UK, Chile,
8312 MW with 78% hydro and 22% thermal. Capacity, however, and Argentina [15].
continued to grow at a slower pace than demand, creating the Capacity payments were proportional to the fixed costs of a
conditions for the pivotal 1992 blackouts. thermal generation plant (capacity charge). The reference value for
The year of 1991 had the lowest rainfall recorded to date and estimating capacity charges was the cost of installing 1 kW of an
water reservoir levels dropped from 57% in September of 1991 to open-cycle gas generator (5.25 US$/kW). Charges were collected
17% in March of 1992 [37]. Furthermore, thermal plants had been from the energy pool and were a lower cap for the electricity price
poorly maintained, and of the 2100 MW of installed thermal [4]. Each month, the capacity payments for each plant were cal-
capacity, only 1137 MW (62%) were operating [38,32]. Power culated as the product of the capacity charge multiplied by the
shortages began in March of 1992 and lasted over a year. More fraction of demand that each plant could supply in a critical
than 2400 GW h were rationed and it is estimated that these
hydrology scenario. To calculate the availability of plants in a dry
programmed power cuts cost about one percentage point of the
year, the regulator used cost and critical hydrology data to run a
GDP over the period [38].
model of the market [41].
During the blackouts, the government invested in refurbishing
After some adjustments, capacity payments were applied from
generating units and accelerated the construction of backup
1996 to 2005. As shown in Fig. 3, the average share of capacity
plants, adding 400 MW of capacity. When the blackouts ended, an
payments awarded to thermal and hydro technologies is similar to
investment strategy was devised to accelerate capacity expansion,
the thermal/hydro share of the system (approximately 30%/70%).
thereby improving the power system's robustness by adding
The thermal capacity expansion from 1996 to 2000 can be
1950 MW of generating capacity between 1995 and 1999 [32].
explained, at least partially, by the capacity payments mechanism
Thermal plants accounted for more than 60% of the new capacity,
and to a less degree by the government's push for a higher share of
comprising: 750 MW of gas fired plants, 450 MW of coal-fired
thermal generation. The investments of this period changed the
plants, and 750 MW of new hydro capacity.
technology mix from 87% hydro in 1995 to below 70% in 2000,
In 1993, estimated costs for the 1995–2000 expansion strategy
were 1.88 billion US dollars [32]. The hydropower projects had which corresponds to an increase in thermal capacity of 2514 MW.
already been financed by multilateral bank credits and the public The new thermal capacity included 1230 MW from the govern-
utilities' own resources. However, there was particular interest in ment's emergency plan of 1993; the only hydro plant to come on
securing financing for thermal projects that would decrease the stream in this period (340 MW) was also initiated by the emer-
vulnerability of the system to extremely dry seasons. The scheme gency plan. The increase in thermal generating capacity achieved
proposed to finance the thermal projects consisted of long-term its purpose as it made the system more reliable. In fact, the 97–98
power purchase agreements (PPA), guaranteed by the government. El Niño, which was stronger than the 91–92 El Niño, caused no
This scheme pays for the energy from, as well as for capacity of, blackouts, although spot prices were about four times higher than
the new plants. The same long-term PPA-with-guarantees scheme in previous dry seasons.
was suggested for promoting private investment [32]. By the late 1990s, Colombia faced an economic crisis with GDP
falling by 4.2% in 1999, and growing at rates below 5% until 2003
3.2. Market system and capacity charge (1994–2006) [30]. The economic recovery was slow, electricity demand growth
stalled, and capacity margins increased to above 50%, which kept
The blackouts of 1992 led to the construction of thermal prices low making the return on investments less attractive. As a
capacity, and the pressure for increasing reliability provided by result, only 1050 MW were added to generating capacity between
thermal generation continued after the power sector was 2000 and 2005, of which 95% was hydro. This included about
reformed in 1994. However, while thermal plants provide relia- 200 MW of small hydro, and a 400 MW hydro plant commissioned
bility, their operating costs are higher than hydro under normal before 1994 (see Fig. 2). Another factor contributing to the delay of
Y. Olaya et al. / Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 56 (2016) 563–571 567

100%
90%
CC Thermo CC Hydro
80%
70%

60%
50%

40%

30%
20%
10%

0%
Apr-97

Apr-98

Apr-99

Apr-00

Apr-01

Apr-02

Apr-03
Jul-97

Jul-98

Jul-99

Jul-00

Jul-01

Jul-02

Jul-03
Jan-97

Jan-98

Jan-99

Jan-00

Jan-01

Jan-02

Jan-03

Jan-04
Oct-97

Oct-98

Oct-99

Oct-00

Oct-01

Oct-02

Oct-03
Fig. 3. Share of capacity payments awarded to thermal and hydro technologies in Colombia between 1997 and 2004. Data from NEON (www.xm.com.co).

investment decisions was general economic uncertainty, as well as because less energy is traded at volatile spot prices [47]. The
the expectation for a new regulation period beginning in 2005 [25]. downside for the buyers is that they will have to pay more for the
By the year 2000, capacity payments were contested by both energy during periods where prices otherwise would have been
thermal and hydro generators. In fact, the regulatory commission low. To some extent, this mechanism shares some of the char-
was studying alternatives for increasing capacity adequacy. It was acteristics of mothballing, a controversial practice in which buyers
argued that these payments did not send clear signals for expan- also pay for having less volatility [48].
sion, that they favored hydro generators, and that the technology The period 2006–2009 was designated as a transition period by
used as a reference (GT) had low capital costs [42]. Most of the the regulator [45]. During this period, a centralized mechanism
critiques from generators were about the model's validity and was used for assigning and pricing capacity. A total of 138 MW of
assumptions. In particular, generators argued that the optimization new generation capacity was added during this period. The
model used by the regulatory commission was not adequate for the expansion consisted of 57 MW of thermal and the rest of small
reformed market because its parameters did not represent the hydro-power plants. The first auction took place in 2008, awarded
system's characteristics. It was also argued that capacity charges contracts for 3420.8 MW of new generating capacity that will
were only a source of revenue and that reliability was not guaran- come on stream between 2013 and 2019, where about 90% of this
teed [43,4]. These problems led the regulator to introduce the capacity is hydro.
reliability payments, which we discuss in the following section. The large share of hydro generation is explained by the
mechanism for estimating contributions to firm energy. For hydro-
3.3. Reliability charge or forward firm energy market (After 2006) power plants, the estimation of firm energy is based on an opti-
mization model that considers critical hydrology. By contrast, firm
In 2006, the regulator changed the mechanism for securing energy offered by thermal power plants must be backed by a long-
generation adequacy in the Colombian system. The previous term fuel contract [49]. Such long-term fuel contracts are not
scheme (capacity charge) had worked well on thermal-based available at competitive prices, in particular for natural gas con-
systems, such as the UK, but as discussed above, it was argued tracts. Before markets for natural gas were established around the
that paying for firm energy instead of capacity would be more world, the typical gas contract was a 20-year take-or-pay contract.
appropriate for a hydro-based system such as the Colombian Although take-or-pay contracts help to pay for dedicated
system [44]. The new mechanism is called the reliability charge, assets, during the 2000s, concerns about security of gas supply,
and it is based on a forward market for firm energy, where firm changes in natural gas regulation, and noncompetitive behavior
energy is the capacity to deliver energy in a dry year. The regulator from sellers have resulted in a lower offer of firm gas contracts in
auctions off sufficient obligations to supply firm energy (OEFs) to Colombia [50]. As a result, gas-fired power generators have been
satisfy the system's forecasted demand, three years ahead. OEFs required to have other fuel backups. Since fuel prices and supply
can be seen as a call option, backed by physical capacity. A gen- are highly uncertain, we argue that the mechanism for estimating
erator receiving an OEF must supply a given quantity of energy if firm energy favors hydro power. This is indeed supported by the
the spot price is above a previously defined scarcity price [45]. A choice of generation technology observed in the past firm-energy
generator that supplies more than its share during scarcity periods auctions. It also provides another example of how gas and elec-
receives the spot price, while a generator that supplies less is tricity markets are becoming increasingly interdependent and, in
penalized. Therefore, there is an incentive for the generator to be this case, what is “bad” for gas would be “good” for electricity.
able to deliver the agreed quantity as long as the penalty for not For the last 20 years, power demand in Colombia grew at a
being able to deliver is severe enough [44]. Contract length for yearly average rate above 2%. This, along with the potential for
new plants is currently 20 years. Simulation analysis indicates that hydro power, made mid- to large-size hydro plants the most effi-
the reliability mechanisms attract investment [46], lower market cient option to satisfy a growing demand, both under central
risk, and improve coordination in investment [47]. This latter planning and market rules (see [51]). Thermal plants are built to run
feature is desirable, since lack of coordination in investment has during dry seasons or to supply zones that have transmission
been related to undesired long-term cycles of over- and under- constraints. However, given the “bias” in the firm energy mechan-
capacity [14]. ism, there might not be enough thermal capacity available for a dry
Similar auction schemes are being used in Brazil, Chile, Peru, season. Other technologies, in particular renewables, have capital
and Panama [15]. The auctions of long-term supply contracts costs higher than hydro and there have been few opportunities to
provide stable revenue and more certainty for the investors in new develop them. As we discuss next, small hydro (less than 20 MW) is
generation capacity so that adequate resources are provided when the only renewable technology that has a noticeable share of
they are needed. Moreover, forward markets lower risk for buyers capacity and that is profitable in the market.
568 Y. Olaya et al. / Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 56 (2016) 563–571

80 compared to conventional technologies [60]. As summarized in


70 Table 2, the provisions for RETs in Colombia's interconnected
system are limited to tax exemptions and other alternatives used
Capacity additions, MW

60
Small Hydro Plants

in other countries, such as feed-in-tariffs, and obligations [61] are


50 not considered [62]. The consequence of this structure is that
renewables other than small hydro play a minor role in the
40
Colombian electricity supply.
30 The institutional design has not taken RETs into account, which
20 means they must compete against conventional generation tech-
nologies whose environmental and social costs are not fully
10
internalized [63,64]. In general, the mechanisms for integrating
0 RETs with the interconnected system are not clearly defined. This
1971

1995
1960
1963
1966
1968

1973
1975
1977
1979
1981
1983
1985
1987
1991
1993

1997
1999
2001
2003
2005
2007
2009
2011
2013
is a problem for wind and other power sources, because the lack of
a methodology and rules for calculating their contribution to firm
Fig. 4. Small-hydro generating plants built between 1960 and 2011 and connected
to the power grid. Additions in 2000 include previously built plants that were
energy means that these sources cannot compete for reliability
rehabilitated. payments in the firm energy auctions [65]. As discussed, high
Source www.xm.com.co. investment costs are one of the barriers for large scale generation
with RETs. While costs of wind and PV have decreased in recent
4. From big to small hydro years [61], their decrease has not yet facilitated their adoption in
Colombia, as, e.g. in the residential sector, the benefits of PV do not
Large hydro-power plants are frequently perceived as envir- outweigh their costs [66]. The outlook for the future of renewables
onmentally unfriendly because they disrupt ecosystems and live- in Colombia is uncertain, but several steps have been taken that
lihoods of communities [52–54], even though they have low could influence the future adoption of RETs making them more
emissions. Furthermore, mid to large-sized hydro plants have attractive as a generation technology.
higher capital requirements and longer lead times than thermal In May 13th, 2014, a new Law (1715/2014) was issued in order
plants, which increases uncertainty for the investors. In Colombia, to integrate non-conventional energy into the national power
they attracted no private investment during the first years of system. This law provides a new legal framework to promote
deregulation; in fact, no private firm was willing to make the investment, research, development, and use of non-conventional
necessary financial commitment over the long time horizon in a energy sources including: wind, geothermal, PV, and biomass. The
system where nobody knew how the market might evolve. law creates tax incentives for developing renewable generation
Instead, a surge in small hydro-power projects was observed projects beyond the reliability framework of the OEF. The exact
during the 2000s, as shown in Fig. 4. The large base of hydro mechanism is still not fully agreed, so currently we cannot foresee
capacity means that electricity prices in Colombia are low for most the effect it will have on the future generation mix. Considering
of the year, i.e. outside the dry seasons, and competitive genera- this uncertainty, the best signal is given by the Colombian Energy
tion technologies must have low operating costs. In Colombia, and Planning Unit, (UPME) in its 2015 generation and expansion
hydropower plants with less than 20 MW capacity are classified as plan. The plan is not mandatory, and thus provides only an indi-
small hydro, and under the current regulation, these plants are cation of possible future scenarios. According to the scenarios,
always scheduled for dispatch at the spot price. RETs' share in the 2028 generation matrix might be between 6%
Colombia's potential for generating power with small hydro and 15% of installed capacity [36]. As Fig. 5 shows, proposed wind
centrals is estimated to be between 8000 and 25000 MW [55]. projects (scenarios 9 and 10) could substitute between 24% and
There are currently 95 small hydro plants in the interconnected 86% of the 1050 MW of coal capacity required in the base high-
system, with a combined capacity of 643 MW [20]. More than 50% demand scenario (5).
of this capacity (387 MW) came on stream between 2001 and The results in Fig. 5 are consistent with previous research on
2010 (Fig. 2). the competitiveness of wind power in the Colombian wholesale
The reforms to the power sector have had a positive effect on market [64,65]. From a reliability point of view, increasing the
small hydro deployment; this can be inferred not only for the new share of renewable technologies that do not depend on water
capacity being installed but also from the rehabilitation of more might help during dry seasons [51,59,67]. Furthermore, develop-
than 20 MW of small hydro plants installed before 1960. Since ing wind resources in the Guajira region could relieve some of the
small hydro plants have low operating costs and their capital costs current transmission constraints [67]. Generation from sugar cane
are lower than solar and wind, they are profitable at the Colom- and African palm biomass is currently competitive [64,36], and
bian spot market price, while solar and wind plants are not further developing this technology would diversify energy supply,
[51,56]. We turn now to discuss renewables, in particular solar although at a smaller scale than wind power.
and wind. Spot prices are expected to decrease with a higher share of
renewables, which would particularly affect thermal generation,
4.1. Role of (other) renewables implying that an increase in renewables will make future thermal
expansions harder. Finally, expansion of renewables is expected to
Currently, the Colombian generation technology mix relies be facilitated by the development of smart grid technologies.
almost exclusively on hydro resources and thermal power. Since Smart grids in Colombia are envisioned as support for energizing
hydro plants generate most of the electricity in Colombia, power isolated rural areas using renewable generation [68], for inte-
generation contributes only 8.5% of the total CO2 emissions in grating renewables to the national energy system [69], and for
Colombia [57], a low value compared to the 2012 world average of developing an electric car sector [67]. The challenge for regulators
42% emissions from power generation and heating [58]. Colombia is to integrate smart grids with the wholesale market. To date,
has focused its incentives for renewables on the electrification of most smart grid projects have been demonstration projects.
rural off-grid zones, as emissions from the power sector are low InterAmerican Development Bank, IADB, is developing a roadmap
[59], and the costs of renewable technologies (RETs) are high for the promotion of smart grids but results are not yet available.
Y. Olaya et al. / Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 56 (2016) 563–571 569

Table 2
State and incentives for renewables in Colombia until 2014.

2014 installed capacity (MW) FIT Electric utility quota/obligation Tax exemptions Surplus energy and energy sales

Wind 20a No No Yes


Biomass – Cogeneration 206a No No Yes At market price
Biomass – Other 26b No No Yes At market price
Geothermal 0 No No Yes At market price
PV 9–11c No No Yes Regulated prices

a
Interconnected capacity.
b
Data for 2010 [55].
c
Isolated capacity. Sources: [55,36].

Fig. 5. Alternatives for capacity expansions 2019–2028 in a high-demand scenario. RETs: geothermal, solar (PV) and Wind.
Source: elaborated from [36].

5. Discussion and conclusion countries suggest that renewable technologies require non-market
incentives such as feed-in-tariffs, but there are proposals for
Large hydropower plants dominate the portfolio for power supporting these technologies with capacity payments similar to
generation in Colombia. The expansion in thermal capacity the reliability charges [65,70].
observed between 1995 and 1999 resulted from government plan- The power market created in the 1990s has greatly improved
ning and market intervention rather than from market rationality. the financial position of companies in the Colombian power sector.
With the advantage of hindsight, the need for thermal power was There is evidence of the ability of the power system to satisfy
overestimated, as evidenced by the low share of production by demand with efficiency. Capacity payments, such as the ones
thermal plants, and by the number of units retired during the 2000s applied in Colombia, have been effective in the sense that they
(more than 400 MW). Electricity demand is expected to continue have added generating capacity, thereby avoiding black outs.
growing as the country develops, and adding hydropower capacity The goal of diversifying the technology mix for generation in
keeps carbon emissions and electricity prices low – provided that order to make the Colombian power system less vulnerable to
the market behaves competitively. The hydropower plants expected changing weather has not been achieved by the process of dereg-
to enter between 2014 and 2019 are supported by the new capacity ulation. Although technology diversification can be attained in
mechanism, known as reliability charge or firm energy. Although competitive markets, the high uncertainty in costs, demand and
the mechanism allows the installation of any technology that technologies, and the imperfections of power markets may cause
increases resource adequacy, the conditions in Colombia: uncer- actual choices to differ from optimal choices. Regulators are
tainty in gas markets and a large base of hydro, favor large hydro- expected to set up clear and stable rules for investing in new gen-
power plants. Along with the new large hydropower plants, a boom eration capacity. Regulators often intervene in the market with
of small hydro plants has been observed during the 2000s. These incentives that are intended to move the system towards what is, at
small plants take advantage of their low capital cost, low environ- that moment, seen as the desirable state. Many interventions,
mental impacts and the fact that all power plants under 20 MW are however, lead to unintended consequences [71] as the market
always dispatched in the market (guarantee of generation). might not always respond in the foreseen way, e.g. in the case of
The additions of hydro power that were awarded long-term Colombia, we can actually observe that twenty years after dereg-
capacity contracts in 2008 displace thermal generation to the right ulation the system has less thermal generation than in the initial
of the supply curve, increase resource adequacy, and make eco- period. It is also important that the regulator does not constantly
nomic sense. However, hydropower has environmental costs that intervene in the system as this creates additional uncertainty and
are not fully accounted for, such as the impacts on communities risk for long-term investments. This is important because, as the
and the local environment, and it is also vulnerable to weather Colombian case evidences, investors respond to regulatory uncer-
changes. A more diverse mix of generation technologies could tainty by delaying decisions until new information is available.
make the power system more reliable, for example, by using the The impact of the different periods of regulation in Colombia
increase of winds during dry seasons to offset the decrease in shows that the power system has improved, the debt levels are far
hydro power [70]. Adding intermittent technologies such as wind from what we observed before the deregulation, the companies are
or solar power to the interconnected system is one of the chal- relatively healthy today and, so far, there is enough capacity to satisfy
lenges for the next regulation periods. The experiences in other demand. From this point of view we conclude that the changes in
570 Y. Olaya et al. / Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 56 (2016) 563–571

regulatory regimes have had at least some desirable effects, in that [27] Sandoval AM. Monografía del sector de electricidad y gas colombiano: con-
the last change prompted a further round of investments. However, diciones actuales y retos futuros. Archivos de Economía, Doc. 272, 1-121
(Bogotá), 2004.
from the reliability perspective there might still be a number of [28] Banco de la República de Colombia. Deuda Publica Externa de Mediano y
uncertainties, as the change in regulation has not created the desired Largo Plazo. Banco La República Colomb Finanz Públicas, 〈http://www.banrep.
gov.co/series-estadisticas/see_finanzas_publi.htm〉; 2011.
change in the capacity mix. There is always a tradeoff between the [29] Ochoa Franco FJ. Incidencia de los problemas financieros en los raciona-
reserve margin, cost, and reliability, e.g. if Colombia has a significant mientos de energía eléctrica. Lect Econ 1986;19:33–96.
[30] Banco de la República de Colombia. PIB, producción, salarios y empleo; 1998.
reserve margin mainly based on hydro then reliability might not be
[31] Garay LJ, Quintero LF, Villamil JA, Tovar J, Fatat A, Gómez S, et al. Colombia:
an issue; however, the consumers will have to pay for this excessive estructura industrial e internacionalización 1967–1996. Bogotá, D.C.: Bib-
reserve margin. On the other hand, if the regulator manages to lioteca Virtual del Banco de la República; 1998. p. 2004.
[32] ISA. Plan de Expansión de Referencia Generación-Transmisión 1993 Revisión.
increase the thermal generation capacity through capacity or relia- Medellín: UPME ;1993.
bility payments, this might also increase the cost. The tradeoff [33] Congreso de la República. Ley 142 de 1994. Por la cual se establce el régimen
de los servicios públicos domiciliarios y se dictan otras disposiciones.
between these two options has to be carefully weighed to decide
Colombia: Diario Oficial no 41.433; 1994.
which is the most cost-efficient for the same reliability. [34] Congreso de la República. Ley 143 de 1994. Por la cual se establece el régimen
para la generación, interconexión, transmisión, distribución y comercialización de
electricidad en el territorio nacional, se conceden una autorizaciones y se dictan
otras disposiciones en materia energ. Colombia: Diario Oficial no 41.342; 1994.
[35] Bacon RW, Besant-Jones J. Global electric power reform: privatization and liber-
References alization of the electric power industry in developing countries. Annu Rev Energy
Environ 2001;26:331–59. http://dx.doi.org/10.1146/annurev.energy.26.1.331.
[36] UPME. Plan de Expansión de Referencia Generación-Transmisión 2014–2028; 2015.
[1] Sioshansi FP, Pfaffenberger W. Why restructure electricity markets? In: Sioshansi [37] Caicedo E. El fenómeno del Niño y su posible impacto en Colombia. Bogotá, D.C.;
FP, Pfaffenberger W, editors. Electricity market reform: an international perspec- 2007.
tive. 1st ed.. Amsterdam: Elsevier Science; 2006. p. 35–48 978-0-08045-030-8. [38] Mejía Mazuera J. APAGÓN VALE $ 342.000 MILLONES. El Tiempo; 1992.
[2] Chick M. Electricity and energy policy in Britain, France and the United States [39] CREG. Resolución 116 de 1996. Colombia: Comisión de Regulación de Energía y
since 1945. 1st ed.. . Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing; http://dx.doi. Gas; 1996.
org/10.4337/9781847206893. [40] CREG. Resolucion 113 de 1998. Colombia: Comisión de Regulación de Energía y
[3] OECD, IEA, NEA. Technology roadmap: nuclear energy. Paris: 2015.
Gas; 1998.
doi:10.1007/SpringerReference_7300. [41] CREG. Resolución 111 de 2000. Colombia: Comisión de Regulación de Energía
[4] Arango S, Dyner I, Larsen ER. Lessons from deregulation: understanding
y Gas; 2000.
electricity markets in South America. Util Policy 2006;14:196–207. http://dx.
[42] Rivier M, Vásquez C, Enamorado JC, Pérez Arriaga JI. Documento Final Estudio
doi.org/10.1016/j.jup.2006.02.001.
Cargo por Capacidad realizado por la U. Bogotá: Comillas de Madrid; 2000.
[5] Roques FA. Market design for generation adequacy: healing causes rather than
[43] TERA. Escisión del SIC-Bolsa de Energía Eléctrica de las Actividades Comer-
symptoms. Util Policy 2008;16:171–83. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jup.2008.01.008.
ciales de Interconexión Eléctrica S.A. E.S.P y definición del Esquema Institu-
[6] Roques FA, Newbery DM, Nuttall WJ. Investment incentives and electricity
cional para las demás funciones del Actual Centro Nacional de Despacho.
market design: the British experience. Rev Netw Econ 2005;4:93–128.
Bogotá, D.C.; 2001.
[7] OECD/IEA. Power generation investment in electricity markets. Paris; 2003.
[44] Cramton P, Stoft S. Colombia firm energy market. In: Proceedings of the 40th
[8] OECD/IEA. Tackling investment challenges in power generation in IEA countries.
Annual Hawaii International Conference on System Science. HICSS 2007. IEEE;
Paris; 2007. doi:10.1787/9789264030084-en.
2007. p. 124. doi:10.1109/HICSS.2007.133.
[9] Olsina F, Garcés F, Haubrich H-J. Modeling long-term dynamics of electricity mar-
[45] CREG. Resolución 071 de 2006. Colombia: Comisión de Regulación de Energía
kets. Energy Policy 2006;34:1411–33. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2004.11.003.
y Gas; 2006.
[10] Euroelectric. Powering investments: challenges for the liberalised electricity
[46] Restrepo EMI, Arango S, Vélez ALG. La confiabilidad en los Sistemas Eléctricos
sector; 2012.
Competitivos y el Moelo Colombiano de Cargo por Confiabilidad. Cuad Econ
[11] Sweeney James L. The california electricity crisis. 1st ed.. Stanford, California:
2012;31:199–222.
Hoover Institution Press Publication; 2002.
[47] Ausubel LM, Cramton P. Using forward markets to improve electricity market
[12] Dyner I, Larsen ER. From planning to strategy in the electricity industry. Energy
Policy 2001;29:1145–54. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0301-4215(01)00040-4. design. Util Policy 2010;18:195–200. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jup.2010.05.004.
[13] Stoft S. Power system economics. New York: Wiley-IEEE Press; 2002. [48] Arango S, Castañeda J a, Larsen ER. Mothballing in power markets: an experi-
[14] Arango S, Larsen E. Cycles in deregulated electricity markets: empirical evi- mental study. Energy Econ 2013;36:125–34. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.
dence from two decades. Energy Policy 2011;39:2457–66. http://dx.doi.org/ eneco.2012.11.027.
10.1016/j.enpol.2011.02.010. [49] CREG. Análisis de Asignación de OEF 2014–2015. Bogotá, D.C.; 2010.
[15] Moreno R, Barroso L a, Rudnick H, Mocarquer S, Bezerra B. Auction approaches [50] Frontier Economics. Diagnóstico fallas del mercado de gas natural de Colom-
of long-term contracts to ensure generation investment in electricity markets: bia. Bogotá, D.C.; 2010.
lessons from the Brazilian and Chilean experiences. Energy Policy [51] García H, Corredor A, Calderón L, Gómez M. Análisis costo beneficio de ener-
2010;38:5758–69. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2010.05.026. gías renovables no convencionales en Colombia; 2013.
[16] Hunt S. Making competition work in electricity. 1st ed.. New York: Wiley; 2002. [52] Klimpt JÉ, Rivero C, Puranen H, Koch F. Recommendations for sustainable
[17] Adib P, Schubert E, Oren S. Resource adequacy: alternate perspectives and hydroelectric development. Energy Policy 2002;30:1305–12. http://dx.doi.
divergent paths. In: Sioshansi Fereidoon, editor. Competitive electricity mar- org/10.1016/S0301-4215(02)00092-7.
kets. Design, implementation, performance. 1st ed.. Oxford: Elsevier Science; [53] Caetano de Souza AC. Assessment and statistics of Brazilian hydroelectric
2008. p. 327–62. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/B978-008047172-3.50013-1. power plants: dam areas versus installed and firm power. Renew Sustain
[18] Cramton P, Stoft S. A capacity market that makes sense. Electron J 2005;18:43– Energy Rev 2008;12:1843–63. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.rser.2007.04.005.
54. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.tej.2005.07.003. [54] Sternberg R. Hydropower: dimensions of social and environmental coex-
[19] UPME. Cobertura de Energía Eléctrica a 2014; 2015. istence. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 2008;12:1588–621. http://dx.doi.org/
[20] XM. Descripción del sistema eléctrico Colombiano. Informacion 10.1016/j.rser.2007.01.027.
operativa y comercial, /http://www.xm.com.co/Pages/DescripciondelSiste [55] CORPOEMA. Formulacion de un Plan de Desarrrollo para las Fuentes no
maElectricoColombiano.aspxS; 2015 [accessed 23.01.15]. Convencionales de Energía en Colombia, PDFNCE. Volumen 2, Diagnóstico. vol.
[21] CIA. The World Factbook. World Factb, 〈https://www.cia.gov/library/publica 2. Bogotá, D.C.; 2010.
tions/resources/the-world-factbook/index.html〉; 2014 [accessed 20.10.14]. [56] Arango S, Larsen ER. The environmental paradox in generation: how South
[22] DANE. Estimaciones de población 1985–2020 y proyecciones de población America is gradually becoming more dependent on thermal generation.
2005–2020 total municipal por área, 〈http://www.dane.gov.co/index.php/ Renew Sustain Energy Rev 2010;14:2956–65. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.
poblacion-y-demografia/proyecciones-de-poblacion〉; 2015. rser.2010.07.049.
[23] IEA. Colombia: electricity and heat for 2012, 〈http://www.iea.org/statistics/sta [57] IDEAM. Segunda Comunicación Nacional ante la Convención Marco de las
tisticssearch/report/?country¼Colombia&product¼electricityandheat〉; 2015. Naciones Unidas sobre Cambio Climático. Colombia; 2007.
[24] OLADE. Precios Promedio Anual, Sistema de Información Económica Energética, [58] International Energy Agency (IEA). CO2 Emissions from fuel combustion
〈http://sier.olade.org/consultas/visor_reportes_d3.aspx? highlights. Paris; 2014.
oc¼ 360&or¼640&ss¼2〉; 2015. [59] UPME. Integración de las energías renovables no convencionales en Colombia
[25] Larsen ER, Dyner I, Bedoya L, Franco CJ. Lessons from deregulation in Colombia: Integración de las energías en Colombia; 2014.
successes, failures and the way ahead. Energy Policy 2004;32:1767–80. http: [60] GEA Writing Team. Global energy assessment. toward a sustainable future. 1st
//dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0301-4215(03)00167-8. ed.. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press; http://dx.doi.org/10.1017/
[26] Industria y banca. líderes de la inversión nacional en el exterior. El Tiempo 2014 CBO9780511793677.
/http://m.eltiempo.com/economia/sectores/industria-y-banca-lideres-de-la- [61] Foley T, Thornton K, Hinrichs-rahlwes R, Sawyer S, Sander M, Taylor R, et al.
inversion-nacional-en-el-exterior/14288059/2S. Renewables 2015. Global Status Report. Paris: REN21; 2015.
Y. Olaya et al. / Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews 56 (2016) 563–571 571

[62] Zuluaga MM, Dyner I. Incentives for renewable energy in reformed Latin- [68] Gaona EE, Trujillo CL, Guacaneme J a. Rural microgrids and its potential
American electricity markets: the Colombian case. J Clean Prod 2007;15:153– application in Colombia. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 2015;51:125–37. http:
62. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2005.12.014. //dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.rser.2015.04.176.
[63] Ruiz B, Rodríguez-Padilla V. Renewable energy sources in the Colombian [69] Naranjo C, Alzate JD, Salazar J. Future scenarios of smart grids in Colombia and
energy policy, analysis and perspectives. Energy Policy 2006;34:3684–90. their impact on climate change. In: Proceedings of the 2011 IEEE PES Con-
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.enpol.2005.08.007. ference on Innovative Smart Grid Technologies (ISGT Latin America). IEEE;
[64] Caspary G. Gauging the future competitiveness of renewable energy in 2011. p. 1–8 (UNFCC: United Nation Framework for Climate Change).
Colombia. Energy Econ 2009;31:443–9. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j. doi:10.1109/ISGT-LA.2011.6083200.
eneco.2008.12.007. [70] Vergara W, Deeb A, Toba N, Cramton P, Leino I. Wind energy in Colombia. A
[65] Botero BS, Isaza CF, Valencia A. Evaluation of methodologies for remunerating framework for market entry. Washington, D.C.; 2010. doi:10.1596/978-0-8213-
wind power's reliability in Colombia. Renew Sustain Energy Rev 8504-3.
2010;14:2049–58. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.rser.2010.02.005. [71] Sioshansi FP. Electricity market reform-progress and remaining challenges.
[66] Radomes A a, Arango S. Renewable energy technology diffusion: an analysis of Competitive electricity markets. Design, implementation, performance, vol.
photovoltaic-system support schemes in Medellín, Colombia. J Clean Prod 1987. Oxford: Elsevier Ltd.; 2008. p. 1–23. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/
2015;92:152–61. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.jclepro.2014.12.090. B978-008047172-3.50004-0.
[67] UPME. Plan Energético Nacional Colombia: Ideario Energético 2015. Bogotá,
D.C.; 2015.

You might also like