You are on page 1of 80

Trials of the Left: Do Leftist Governments Spell Economic Disaster for Latin America?

A thesis presented

by

Auren Evan Kaplan

The Department of Political Science


in partial fulfillment of the requirements
for the degree with honors
of Bachelor of Arts
The University of Michigan
March 2009

1
Acknowledgements

For their guidance and direction in the process of creating this thesis, I offer my most
profound thanks to Professors Mika Lavaque-Manty, Robert Mickey, and William Clark.

For inspiring within me a deep-seated intellectual interest in the topic of economic


development and a predilection for the region of Latin America, I extend my sincere
gratitude to Professors John Jackson, Ashutosh Varshney, and Mary Corridore.

And for their unwavering support and unconditional love during many late-night phone
calls and discussions, and throughout my college career, I deeply thank my parents,
Frances Goldstein and Gerald Kaplan.

2
Trials of the Left: Do Leftist Governments Spell Economic Disaster for
Latin America?

TABLE OF CONTENTS

CHAPTER 1: Introduction.................................................................................................4
CHAPTER 2: Economic Development Strategies in Latin America...............................12
CHAPTER 3: Partisanship & Economic Performance in OECD Countries....................28
CHAPTER 4: Data and Empirical Analysis.....................................................................43
Introduction.........................................................................................................................................43

Variables..............................................................................................................................................44

Data.....................................................................................................................................................47

Model..................................................................................................................................................48

Table 1: Left’s Effects on Budget Surplus; No Interaction with Personal Vote........................51

Table 2: Left’s Effects on Growth; No Interaction with Personal Vote......................................53

Table 3: Left’s Effects on Inflation; No Interaction with Personal Vote....................................56

Table 5: Left’s Effects on Budget Surplus When Interacting with Personal Vote....................59

Table 6: Linear Combination Test Showing Personal Vote Interaction Effects in the Model
with Budget Surplus.........................................................................................................................61

Table 7: Left’s Effects on Growth When Interacting with Personal Vote..................................62

Table 8: Linear Combination Test Showing Personal Vote Interaction Effects in the Model
With GDP Growth............................................................................................................................65

Table 9: Left’s Effects on Inflation When Interacting with Personal Vote................................66

Table 10: Linear Combination Test Showing Personal Vote Interaction Effects in the Model
with Inflation.....................................................................................................................................68

Summary of Findings..........................................................................................................................68

CHAPTER 5: Concluding Remarks.................................................................................71


BIBLIOGRAPHY..............................................................................................................78

3
4
CHAPTER 1: Introduction

The problem of development is one of great relevance to economists, who

frequently focus on the specific policy structures best suited to grow economies and

effectively develop societies. In this sub-discipline called development economics, these

economists may focus on macroeconomic goals such as increased Gross Domestic

Product (GDP) growth, or on interstate policy issues of tariffs and the negative growth

consequences they may have for the economies of developing countries, or on

microeconomic questions regarding the ability of the poor to generate enough income to

subsist with adequate nutrition. Their work is necessary and to be commended, for the

pursuit of improved development outcomes is a noble one. Indeed, if one were to

synthesize a discussion on development into its purest form, what would result is a focus

on materially improving the quality and scope of people’s lives – increasing literacy rates

or years of education, or focusing on increasing life expectancy while decreasing infant

mortality. For all the studies completed and books written on the economics of

development, common themes have emerged that are accepted across the literature as

central to the quest for improved development outcomes, whether through focus on

education, or improved infrastructure, or access to healthcare, or through steady

economic growth with minimal inflation and controlled unemployment. In short, the

theoretical body of knowledge on how to successfully improve development outcomes is

vast. While discrepancies still exist over details and new trends emerge as time passes,

the basic concepts regarding successful development are agreed upon. The answers are

out there.

5
Yet it takes but a fleeting glance at the current state of world affairs to realize that

for all the knowledge and theory on development economics in the world, the reality is

one in which differences in development measures across countries and regions remain

vast. While the most developed countries in the world boast life expectancies near or

above 80 years (Japan, 82 years; France 81 years; United States 78 years), the poorest of

countries – most located in Africa – have life expectancies barely half that of their fully

developed counterparts (South Africa, 49 years; Nigeria, 47 years; Zimbabwe, 44 years). 1

Even so-called ‘emerging market’ developing countries, while far more developed than

their African counterparts, are literally years behind (and in some cases decades behind)

first-world countries in terms of life expectancy (Brazil, 72 years; Bolivia, 67 years;

Russia, 66 years).2 With this vast difference in mind, it is evident that knowledge of

proper development policies is not sufficient. The implementation of those policies

requires action by government, which at least in cases of democratic governance is on

some level accountable to its citizens. Knowledge of good policies is fine, but it is

through the action (or inaction) of government that these policies either are or are not

implemented. It will be through an examination of political differences within

government, and the implications those differences will have for development, where my

thesis finds its focus. I will explain further in a moment.

The impetus for this thesis stems from my travels in South America after studying

abroad in Santiago, Chile during the spring and summer of 2007. Chile is a nation often

described as among the most developed in Latin America, indeed perhaps approaching

1
Central Intelligence Agency World Factbook. Rank Order – life expectancy at birth.
https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/rankorder/2102rank.html (access
January 17, 2009)
2
Ibid.

6
“first-world status.”3 Yet even upon first arriving to the sprawling megalopolis of

Santiago, I noted a poverty that was simply more pervasive than to what one is

accustomed in a developed country like the United States. And in smaller, poorer

sections of the country such as the Atacama Desert in the north, it was common to see

homes constructed of mud-bricks, unpaved roads, and large numbers of people earning

their living as vendors selling the most basic of items. Like most Americans, I had heard

stories regarding poverty and sub-first-world conditions elsewhere in the world, and I had

seen pictures of the substandard conditions with which the impoverished lived outside of

our borders. But my experience seeing this poverty first-hand led me to question on a far

deeper level exactly why situations such as these occurred outside of our borders.

Yet for the stark differences in wealth I witnessed between the first-world Chilean

middle class and the many remaining in an impoverished underclass, nothing could

prepare me for the absolutely abject poverty I would come across when traveling through

Peru and Bolivia. I would see poor children on the street with decaying teeth, unpaved

one-lane dangerous mountainous roads, and old ladies selling coca leaves on the streets

of La Paz for $0.02 a bag. The differences in development between these countries and

that of Chile were practically unfathomable, let alone in comparison with the United

States. I will never forget taking a horse-back riding tour in Tupiza, Bolivia, where I

learned that our 17-year old guide made just $20 every 2 weeks for his eight-hour

workdays. When asked where the money would go, he responded that he gave it to his

mother to help feed the family. Faced with a poverty as pervasive and deep as this, one

that a first-world American of any economic level simply could not understand without
3
Walter, Matthew. Chile, Seeking First-World Status, Tackles Santiago River Mess.
Bloomberg.com, May 17, 2007 (accessed February 17, 2009
http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=20601087&sid=aXT9fzUY3Ti0&refer=home)

7
exposure, my questioning grew more in-depth as to why some Latin American countries

were so much poorer than their more relatively affluent counterparts.

After much reflection, my gut told me that politics had to be a defining difference.

Again, this thought process was solidified during a portion of my post-study abroad trip,

during a visit to Cusco, Peru. The bus-ride from Lima to Cusco took twice as long as

anticipated, because huge boulders and tree limbs had been strewn across the road. When

we arrived to Cusco, our first day in the city was overwhelming as an exorbitant number

of Peruvian citizens paraded around the streets, shouting “SOTEP!” at the top of their

lungs as they waved signs and banners. I came to learn that SOTEP was a teacher’s

union, and that the rocks strewn across the road were part of a massive, country-wide

protest by members of a teacher’s union against the government’s new education policy

—one that would have proposed strict testing guidelines and accountability standards for

teachers to follow.

It is not the purpose of this thesis to discuss the various efficacies of educational

policies, but it nonetheless is pertinent to take note of the fervency with which these

teachers protested a policy that was designed to improve the quality of education of the

children they taught for a living. The lesson this experience engraved in my mind is one

of utmost importance for the purpose of this thesis: large members of the population,

particularly those on the left and on the lower end of the economic spectrum (such as

teachers in a poor city like Cusco), may engage in behavior that is counterproductive to

their country’s overall wellbeing. It may be that those teachers would benefit from

reduced standards in that they may keep their jobs, but the students (importantly, the

future economic drivers of Peru) certainly would not benefit. I began to wonder about

8
other ways in which a mobilized left might take political action that would presumably be

beneficial to their interests, but in the long run would prove detrimental.

To return for a moment to the topic of development, governments have the power

to enact policies that have remarkable potential for either boosting the economic and

overall development standing of their country, or diminishing it—not only do they

control exceptionally large amounts of capital (in the form of taxes and reserves), but

they also have the power to set policies that drastically affect whether companies will

remain invested in the economy, and whether foreign capital will continue to flow

inward, sparking investment. Those are merely examples; there are of course a number

of other economic metrics that are intimately tied to the state of a country’s development.

Take the government’s role in dealing with capital, for instance. A government can

choose between redistributing all the wealth, incentivizing capital investment with no

redistribution, or engaging in macroeconomic policies to bring about a healthy mix

between the two polar extremes. 4 In each of these instances, decisions are made by

elected officials (at least in the event of democracies) who are answerable to

constituencies and political pressures that might not be aware of the most appropriate

government actions in terms of generating positive macroeconomic results.

The case of the teachers on strike in Peru serves as one pertinent example of the

ways in which the voting public may vocalize opposition to policies that could in the long

run be detrimental to their own wellbeing. But it is my intuition that behavior of this type

is not merely relegated to teachers protesting a new education policy. Rather, this

example may serve to characterize a behavior endemic to political action of left-leaning


4
Przeworski, Adam and Wallerstein, Michael. Structural Dependence of the State on Capital. The
American Political Science Review, Vol. 82, No. 1 (Mar., 1988) p. 11.

9
supporters—that, at least in regards to Latin America, they may engage in political action

that could lead to detrimental outcomes. In a discussion of economic policy, this notion

becomes particularly salient as left-leaning members of society could support political

parties taking government action that, while popular, may not be in their best economic

interests. When voters elect left-leaning politicians on the expectation of certain

government action, those politicians may engage in that partisan action even if doing so

could ultimately lead to inferior economic performance. Thus, the question arises: does

the partisan orientation of politicians and the government they comprise make a

difference in terms of economic performance when examining countries in Latin

America?

The prevailing literature discussing the broad role of partisanship in shaping

economic policy and outcomes reveals decidedly mixed results, and this literature will be

reviewed in detail in the upcoming chapters. Scholars such as William Clark, for

instance, would argue that partisanship’s effects on macroeconomic outcomes are barely

discernable, if they even exist at all. 5 But this discussion avoids investigation into the

particulars of Latin American politics and economic development. And indeed, various

countries in the region have undergone a host of different development trajectories, in the

process experiencing far greater degrees of vast political change than the OECD countries

commonly studied in the prevailing literature. Additionally, the societal cleavages

present in pan-Latin American society even today remain far more unequal than in the

OECD countries frequently studied. It is quite notable that Uruguay, the Latin American

nation with the lowest Gini coefficient (a statistical measure of inequality) in the region
5
Clark, William Roberts. Capitalism, Not Globalism: Capital Mobility, Central Bank
Independence, and the Political Control of the Economy. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor,
2003.

10
(45.2) has greater income inequality than the most unequal of the developed nations

(United States, 45) or Eastern European nations (Armenia, 37).6 Perhaps the sharp

degrees of economic polarization found across Latin America lead to decreased stability

of the political system, with partisan interests taking action in ways in which the OECD-

centric literature would not foresee.

But rather than continue to offer conjecture, it is more pertinent to evaluate the

various ways in which Latin American countries actually have developed over the last

half-century. I undertake this evaluation in order to make clear the very real differences

between the Latin American situation and the OECD7 situation, and to present a testable

possibility for the role of partisanship in causing various different development outcomes

in those Latin American countries, as measured through macroeconomic outcomes such

as GDP growth, inflation, unemployment, and other pertinent metrics. In the upcoming

chapter, I will first present a discussion on the various economic development strategies

Latin American governments implemented over the last seventy or so years. I will very

briefly contrast that discussion with the prevailing literature on partisanship’s role in

macroeconomic policies and outcomes as studied through the lens of OECD countries,

which will be examined in further depth in Chapter 3. I will then present my proposed

explanation for the differences in development outcomes in light of those strategies.

Finally, I will propose a test of my explanation whereby I outline my hypotheses and

other potentially competing hypotheses, offering some brief conjectural arguments in

6
Central Intelligence Agency. The World Factbook—Field Listing – Distribution of Family Income
– Gini Index. CIA World Factbook, April 15, 2008. Accessed April 21, 2008
https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/fields/2172.html
7
By OECD, I refer to the countries belonging to the Organization for Economic Co-operation and
Development, most of which are among the most developed in the world.

11
support of my hypothesis and its implications for the effects of partisan orientation of

governments on the economic performance of nations under their command.

12
CHAPTER 2: Economic Development Strategies in Latin America

My examination of Latin American development strategies begins in the lead-up

to the Great Depression. In the face of what many Latin American economists

determined to be chronic underdevelopment in the region during this period, a theory of

the world economy grew in popularity that placed the most developed nations in the

center, with less developed nations such as those in Latin America in the periphery. 8

Economists prescribing to this belief, led by Raúl Prebisch (director of the influential

United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America or ECLA), “attributed the

causes for Latin America’s underdevelopment to the system of international free trade”

existing at the time.9 To these economists, the neo-liberal agenda of the free market

proved untenable for the Latin American economies situated on the ‘periphery’ of the

world market, and in turn they devised an economic development strategy that sought to,

in short, “develop industries in a protected environment.” 10 Rather than focus on

liberalizing their economies, these theorists sought to generate industrial production

within their own borders in order to replace foreign-produced manufactured products that

previously had been imported. In so doing, governments would employ incentives to

create both forward and backward linkages in the industrial process and thereby

encourage further domestic economic growth.11

8
Klarén, Peter F. and Bossert, Thomas J. Promise of Development: Theories of Change in Latin
America. Westview Press, 1986, p. 15. (accessed February 19, 2009 scholar.google.com)
9
Ibid, p. 14.
10
Franko, Patrice M. The Puzzle of Latin American Economic Development. Rowman &
Littlefield, 2007, p. 59. (accessed February 20, 2009 scholar.google.com)
11
Brohman, John. Popular Development: Rethinking the Theory and Practice of Development.
Blackwell Publishing, 1996, p. 53. (accessed February 20, 2009 scholar.google.com)

13
This development trajectory was initially fairly successful in a number of Latin

American countries. During the decade of the 1930s, Latin American countries

experienced relatively prosperous levels of GDP growth (4.8% in Chile, 4.2% in

Colombia, 3.6% in Brazil) in comparison with more industrialized countries (2.7% in the

United States, -1.2% in France, 3.4% in Great Britain). 12 But a central problem with this

form of development, known as import-substitution industrialization (ISI) was that while

domestic industry shifted its orientation towards the production of non-durable goods that

were previously imported, the production of those goods required increased imports of

other prime materials and capital goods necessary for those same industries. 13

Effectively, by stimulating domestic industrial production of advanced manufacturing

goods, these economies were forced to continue to augment their degree of imports—

while they were no longer importing the goods that they had shifted domestic production

to develop, their net dependence on foreign imports (now of prime materials) actually

increased.14 With Prebisch’s ECLA garnering an official affiliation as a United Nations

institution, the ISI development policies suggested by ECLA garnered more credibility as

they spread throughout the region, representing the first region-wide school of thought

related to economic development in Latin America.”15

It is important to note, for the purpose of maintaining the focus of this thesis, the

connection of the political sphere to these policies, as they occurred during a period of

time in which the conservative agrarian oligarchies were rapidly ceding political ground
12
Maddison, A. 1982. Phases of Capitalist Development. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
13
Corbo, Vittorio. Problemas, Teoría del Desarrollo y Estrategias en América Latina. Estudios
Públicos, 32 (primavera 1988), pp. 12-13.
14
Ibid, p. 20.
15
Hirschman, A.O. 1961. “Ideologies of Economic Development in Latin America”. In A.O.
Hirschman (ed.). Latin America Issues: Essays and Comments. New York: Twentieth Century Fund,
Inc.

14
to mass movements of urban workers.16 While wealthy land-owners supported policies

oriented towards exports, increasingly mobilized workers developed important political

alliances with the new domestic industrial powers in order to continue the ISI

development trajectory, seen as favorable to both of their interests.17 This union of

worker and industry generated strong political and institutional support for maintaining

ISI development policies, with the trend occurring not merely in one country but across

wide swaths of Latin America. I do not intend to immediately claim a direct causal link

between the increased power of lower-class workers and the newly industrial sector

(perhaps represented through leftist control of government) and the continued trend

across the region towards ISI-related policies, as statistical analysis and solid data

evidence is required before making such a statement (and such analysis will be presented

in Chapter 3). But the apparent connection is indeed noteworthy.

Of course, just as noteworthy is the apparent eventual failure of ISI-style

development. Scholar Anil Hira described the failure of ISI as the result of excessive

protection, combined with increased burdens on public sector budgets and

discouragement of exportation in favor of ramping up domestic production and

consumption—all of which combined to generate an enormous debt crisis that would

cripple national economies across Latin America for years.18 As Baer writes, by the

1960s “industry had become the dominant sector in Argentina, Brazil, Mexico, and

Chile,” the four countries representing Latin America’s largest markets and those most

16
Corbo, Vittorio. Problemas, Teoría del Desarrollo y Estrategias en América Latina. Estudios
Públicos, 32 (primavera 1988), pp. 12-13.
17
Ibid, p. 19
18
Hira, Anil. Did ISI fail and is neoliberalism the answer for Latin America? Re-assessing common
wisdom regarding economic policies in the region. Brazilian Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 27
no. 3, Sao Paulo, July/Sept. 2007.

15
equipped to handle domestic growth in supply of new industrial goods.19 Coupled with

limited exports and underdeveloped national agriculture, nations across Latin America

eventually suffered from long-term imbalances in their current accounts, leading to

dramatically increased external debt.20 Faced with inherent restrictions in the size of the

domestic market towards which most industry was targeted, domestic capital was limited

in its capacity, creating demand for substantial inflows of capital from abroad with only

limited exports and outward flows of capital. This trend further exacerbated external debt

across the region. After the Mexican government implemented various policies to

stabilize its faltering economy in the late 1970s and early 1980s, including a sharp

devaluation of the peso, serious doubts were raised about Mexico’s solvency. 21 Similar

structural issues occurred across the region, and when in 1982 Mexico defaulted on its

debt, other Latin American governments followed—including Brazil, another significant

economic player in the region.22 The ISI approach towards region-wide development had

clearly ended in failure.

The trend towards ISI development policies was indeed prevalent across Latin

America, but another concurrent development trajectory also bears mention, both for its

relation to this thesis’s central argument and for its unquestioned importance in defining

the socio-economic and political struggles of post-World War II Latin America. That

policy is known as populism, defined by scholars as a political movement towards

19
Baer, Werner. Import Substitution and Industrialization in Latin America: Experiences and
Interpretations. Latin American Research Review, Vol. 7, No. 1, (Spring, 1972), p. 101.
20
Schmidt, Henry. The Mexican Foreign Debt and the Sexennial Transition from López Portillo de
la Madrid. Mexican Studies / Estudios Mexicanos. Vol. 1, No. 2, (Summer, 1985), pp. 229-30.
21
Calderón-Madrid, Angel. Currency Crises and Institutional Changes in Latin America: Lessons
from Mexico. Presented at the Conference Euro and the Dollar, Coral Gables, FL, April 2006, p. 2.
22
Silk, Leonard. Brazil’s Battle Against Banks. New York Times, March 4, 1987 (accessed
February 20, 2009 nytimes.com)

16
“expanding state activism to incorporate the workers in a process of accelerated

industrialization through ameliorative redistributive measures.”23 In the sense of

supporting domestic industrial production, macroeconomic populism carries similarities

to ISI-style development, but the important distinction lies in the explicit political

motives underlying the decision to engage in such policies—redistribution of wealth

towards the working classes. Populist macroeconomic programs typically “emphasize

three elements: reactivation, redistribution, and restructuring of the economy,” with

reactivation meaning a renewed push for growth and the restructuring occurring in the

form of “sav[ing] on foreign exchange and support[ing] higher levels of real wages and

higher growth.”24 Beneath the motives for redistribution and populist economic policy at

large lays a deep ideological impetus, characterized by Dornbusch as one promoted by

people “who see the need for social progress and are impatient about the means, who

believe the special conditions of their country yields a fruitful yet unexploited strategy for

social progress.”25 In short, political motives are inherently tied into the push for populist

macroeconomic policy.

Populist economic policies frequently arose in the wake of conservative economic

stabilization programs designed to limit inflation but that additionally constrained growth

and kept wages low. Importantly, these conservative policies often led to surpluses of

foreign reserves, adding additional political pressure onto government to spend those idle

funds. In the case of Chile, for instance, President Salvador Allende (elected on promises

of drastically raising wages of lower- and middle-class citizens and engaging in wealth
23
Drake, P. (1982) "Conclusion: Requiem for Populism?" in Conniff, M. L. (Ed) Latin American
Populism in Comparative Perspective, Albuquerque, University of New Mexico Press.
24
Dornbusch, Rudiger and Edwards, Sebastian. Macroeconomic Populism in Latin America.
National Bureau of Economic Development, Cambridge, MA, May 1989, p. 6.
25
Ibid, p. 6.

17
redistribution) entered office with a stockpile of over $400 million US in international

reserves, equal to an entire half-year’s worth of imports. 26 The political motivations of

those interested in proposing populist macroeconomic policies are indeed perhaps best

exemplified by the Chilean case, where multiple political parties representing various

constituencies of the left bounded together in a coalition entitled Unidad Popular to

ensure that populism’s doctrine would enter the halls of government policymaking. But

make no mistake, both communists and socialists within the coalition merely “considered

the alliance and the politics that sustained it to be a tactical intermediate step that would

help set the basis for the transition to socialism.” 27 These political leaders had a

formative notion of social governance that contravened the traditional limits of

government’s role as neutral arbiter in encouraging economic gain for its citizens, and

they apparently believed that their new socialist order would prosper even if the

economic policies they engaged in were drastically unorthodox.

Unfortunately for these noble proponents of social equality, the realities of the

economic situation that their populist policies engendered proved to be unsustainable. In

describing the phases of populist macroeconomic performance, Dornbusch notes four

distinct stages—and indeed, in the first stage, policy readjustment towards real wage

growth and overall economic growth is successful, with inflation limited by price

controls and shortages alleviated by imports. 28 Yet as the effects of these policies take

full effect, stage two sets in as the economy begins to run into bottlenecks due to

expansion in demand for domestic goods and because of a growing lack of foreign
26
Dornbusch, Rudiger and Edwards, Sebastian. Macroeconomic Populism in Latin America.
National Bureau of Economic Development, Cambridge, MA, May 1989, p. 10.
27
Ibid., p. 10.
28
Dornbusch, Rudiger and Edwards, Sebastian. Macroeconomic Populism in Latin America.
National Bureau of Economic Development, Cambridge, MA, May 1989, p. 8.

18
exchange. While wages temporarily keep up with inflation, the “budget deficit worsens

tremendously as a result of pervasive subsidies on wage goods and foreign exchange.” 29

As the economic situation continues to worsen, pervasive shortages eventually lead to

massive inflation and capital flight with real wages falling severely, and ultimately a new

stabilization plan is implemented that must preside over wage drops to a level

“significantly lower than the when the whole episode began.”30

This process occurred exactly as described in Chile, where the populist

macroeconomic policies began with what any neutral observer would describe as

incredible success—“real GDP grew at 7.7 percent, average real wages increased by 17

percent, aggregate consumption grew at a real rate of 13.2 percent, and the rate of

unemployment dipped below 4 percent.”31 Yet at the same time as the Chilean economy

entered its second and third stages in the populist macroeconomic scheme described

above, political pressure from the left actually encouraged a deepening in the exercise of

populist macroeconomic policy. Cousiño notes the role of intellectual youth of the Left

who pushed the government of the Unidad Popular towards even more radical positions

at the same time as “the political climate began to demonstrate…[that the] productive and

distributive apparatus of society had failed” in its mission for growth and social

equilibrium.32 Rather than realize that their policies were destined for failure, Chilean

leftists placed a premium on installing a new ideology (of socialism) as the foundation of

their government and pushed for their policies with even increased fervency. This action

virtually assured that the political cleavage in the country would prove unsustainable, and
29
Ibid, p. 6-7.
30
Ibid, p. 7.
31
Ibid, p. 19.
32
Cousiño Valdés, Carlos. Populism and Political Radicalism During the Unidad Popular
Government (translated from Spanish). Estudios Públicos, 82 (autumn 2001), pp. 12-13.

19
the damage inflicted upon the Chilean economy and its nation’s citizens left the nation far

worse economically than when Salvador Allende first took power.

The spectacular failure of ISI and populist macroeconomic policy both in Chile

and across the region brought about a new chapter in Latin American development theory

and practice. While the transformation did not occur simultaneously across the region

(indeed, Peru was facing the brunt of its macroeconomic populism into the 1990s),

numerous countries sought international help in order to re-stabilize their economies. 33

Through coordination with the World Bank, the International Monetary Fund organized a

series of loans for Latin American nations, but predicated them on a switch to a package

of neo-liberal economic policies labeled the ‘Washington Consensus’. With main policy

components of restricted state spending, privatization of nationalized industries,

deregulation of markets, and increased openness to foreign trade, the policies marked a

sharp change from the ISI path of growth, and particularly the severe populist economic

bent that drastically affected a few of Latin America’s economies. 34 Of course, some

countries began to liberalize their economies even before the debt crisis began to sweep

the region in the 1980s—Corbo cites Uruguay, Chile, and Argentina in particular, noting

that Chile’s liberalization was the most profound (this makes intuitive sense, with a

dictatorship in power the government could implement policies damaging to a large

swath of the population without exacting detrimental political consequences).35 But in

33
Dornbusch, Rudiger and Edwards, Sebastian. Macroeconomic Populism in Latin America.
National Bureau of Economic Development, Cambridge, MA, May 1989, p. 54.
34
Washington Consensus. Center for International Development, Harvard University, April 2003
(accessed February 20, 2009 http://www.cid.harvard.edu/cidtrade/issues/washington.html)
35
Corbo, Vittorio. Problemas, Teoría del Desarrollo y Estrategias en América Latina. Estudios
Públicos, 32 (primavera 1988), pp. 12-13.

20
the instance of liberalization, the degree to which partisan politics plays a role appears far

more nuanced than in the obvious leftist-driven populist strategies examined previously.

Latin American countries across the region implemented policies of liberalization

in the aftermath of populism and ISI, including “governments of every partisan stripe.” 36

But while partisan jockeying on whether to liberalize is not immediately as visible,

Murillo found that partisan differences remained in the details regarding the ways in

which governments decided to privatize national industries and liberalize their

economies. Given a trend towards privatization, the “political bias of the privatizing

government influences institutional choices, such as regulatory institutions and the selling

conditions of privatization, which in turn affect future resource distribution in privatized

markets.”37 Murillo notes that due to the multi-class nature of Latin American parties of

the left, privatization was actually used as a tool of coalition-building, “which includes

government expenditures in addition to the allocation of market resources” in order to

curry “favor [with] these poor constituencies that cannot acquire direct property through

privatization.”38 So, at least according to Murillo, a government’s decision to privatize

can have very real and different consequences for government spending and other metrics

of policy, depending on which party is in power.

Brooks also revealed a partisan bias in regards to liberalization, finding that

“governments headed by left-popular executives adopted systematically lower levels of

capital account openness than other governments in Latin America.” 39 She posited this
36
Brooks, Sarah M. Explaining Capital Account Liberalization in Latin America: A Traditional Cost
Approach. World Politics 56 (April 2004), p. 408.
37
Murillo, M. Victoria. Political Bias in Policy Convergence: Privatization Choices in Latin
America. World Politics 54 (July 2002), p. 469.
38
Ibid, p. 473.
39
Brooks, Sarah M. Explaining Capital Account Liberalization in Latin America: A Traditional Cost
Approach. World Politics 56 (April 2004), p. 421.

21
relationship as arising “from the greater risk that left governments would lose the

confidence of their core constituency, working-class and low-skill laborers, who often

suffer greatly from capital account liberalization.”40 This view of left partisan control

leading to altered economic policies and outcomes is buttressed by findings from

Kaufman and Segura-Ubiergo. The two scholars argue that not only is “budgetary

priority attached to social security…likely to be higher during years when popularly

[Left] based governments are in power,” but that those same left-aligned governments are

“inclined to squeeze human capital expenditures, possibly to protect pension spending.” 41

Once again, the implication here is that left-aligned political representatives are seen as

engaging in partisan action affecting economic policy in order to favor the interests of

their constituencies. A further implication is that leftist governments may be engaging in

behavior that could be detrimental to economic performance (by avoiding liberalization

or investing in human capital) in order to reinforce their political viability through

increased social spending.

Brooks contrasts this view of left-controlled governments leading to altered

economic performance with that of left-controlled government performance with the

OECD countries. She first posits, in concordance with Kaufman and Segura-Ubiergo,

that leftist “governments may liberalize aggressively…to prove their credentials as

inflation fighters.”42 As Brooks continues, she contrasts this notion with the performance

of left-controlled governments in the OECD countries, arguing that transitional costs

40
Ibid, p. 421.
41
Kaufman, Robert R. and Segura-Ubiergo, Alex. Globalization, Domestic Politics, and Social
Spending in Latin America: A Time-Series Cross-Section Analysis, 1973-97. World Politics 53
(July 2001), p. 580.
42
Brooks, Sarah M. Explaining Capital Account Liberalization in Latin America: A Traditional Cost
Approach. World Politics 56 (April 2004), p. 424.

22
between left and right governments are less significant in OECD countries. As a result,

“the core constituency concerns of left governments are diminished, leaving only the

powerful incentives for such governments to signal their credibility to market actors

through financial opening.”43 In Brooks’ view, left-controlled governments behave

systematically differently in Latin America than in OECD countries in terms of the

economic policies they implement and the economic outcomes of the decisions they

make in government. And given the above discussion, Latin American governments do

appear to alter their macroeconomic policies according to partisan control of government,

with implications for differences in economic outcomes as well. But if indeed partisan

control of government does lead to altered outcomes in Latin America, why might this be

the case?

For one, the political realities of Latin America reflect a past with marked

differences from the relatively recent histories of the OECD countries. While those well-

developed nations long since banished the specter of communism from their borders,

instead turning to market-oriented economic policies and growth strategies, socialist

revolutionary thought in Latin America remained in full force in many countries until the

1970s and 1980s (Chile and Peru, respectively), and even continues to the present with

the socialist governments of Venezuela, Ecuador, and Bolivia currently in power. The

OECD-centric literature on partisanship’s role in shaping policy and outcomes assumes

that state actors operate with the knowledge that for effective economic growth to result,

they must operate within certain institutional constraints. One in particular is the

structural dependence of the state on capital, a theory arguing that because governments

43
Ibid, p. 424.

23
are dependent on revenue from business taxation for survival, they must create conditions

favorable to capitalists to continue to invest in the economy; if they fail in that regard

then government will lose its financial capabilities to function.44 This theory will be

examined in greater detail in the following chapter.

But with the Latin American left’s up-until-recent love affair with socialist and

populist macroeconomic ideology, perhaps the drive towards the formation of a new

social order blinded their eyes to these institutional constraints. Even in countries where

previously revolutionary rhetoric has since moderated, the tendency for leftist

governments to favor policies of redistribution may simply be stronger. As populism has

such a strong tradition of appealing to poorer members of society throughout Latin

America, it would not be surprising to see politicians appealing to those poorer members

of society to continue offering the rhetoric of redistribution, as that political argument

still carries weight in the voting booth even after macroeconomic populism has been

proven by scholars as a failed economic growth theory. And while it may indeed be true

that neoliberal economic policies were necessary tools of the stabilization programs put

in place after populism’s failure, the evidence indeed indicates that neoliberal policies

have contributed to increased inequality in the region—since the 1970s, “every country

[the authors examined within Latin America], with the exception of Colombia in the

1980s and Mexico and Venezuela in the 1970s, has experienced an increase in the

concentration of income and wealth.”45

44
Przeworski, Adam and Wallerstein, Michael. Structural Dependence of the State on Capital. The
American Political Science Review, Vol. 82, No. 1 (Mar., 1988).
45
Hoffman, Kelly and Angel Centeno, Miguel. The Lopsided Continent: Inequality in Latin
America. Annual Review of Sociology, Vol. 29, 2003, p. 367.

24
Given this increased inequality, and the fact that poorer members of society did

experience real wage increases under macroeconomic populism (at least for a time),

parties of the left might have more success appealing to traditional notions of populist

macroeconomic policy in attempting to get elected. Concurrently, they may implement

policies to engage in redistributive government action as it would be seen by their

constituents as necessary to counteract severe levels of inequality. Therefore, in

evaluating whether partisanship does matter for Latin American economic policies and

outcomes, I remain agnostic as to whether politicians of the left do take into account

factors constraining OECD countries such as the structural dependence of the state on

capital. The factors described above might explain why left governments continue to

implement policies that favor redistribution and perform worse in the process, if the data

does indeed reveal that to be the case.

In evaluating this possibility, there are two distinct claims between which I must

distinguish: one is the notion of the left adopting different policies from the right, and the

other entertains the possibility that those left policies lead to different economic outcomes

than those on the right. There are three possible hypotheses related to the first claim:

Hypothesis 1A: The left adopts policies indistinguishable from those of the right.

Hypothesis 1B: The left adopts more redistributive and interventionist policies
than those of the right.

Hypothesis 1C: The left adopts more conservative policies than those of the right.

And within the second claim, there are three possible hypotheses as well:

Hypothesis 2A: The left produces macroeconomic outcomes indistinguishable


from those of the right.

25
Hypothesis 2B: The left produces more growth, less inflation, and less
unemployment than the right.

Hypothesis 2C: The left produces less growth, more inflation, and more
unemployment than the parties of the right.

There are of course other possible iterations of growth, inflation and unemployment that

will be tested, but I list the above three in order to broadly distinguish between largely

positive and negative macroeconomic outcomes. Given the above discussion, I argue for

a combination of hypotheses 1B and 2C, in other words that left governments in Latin

America will engage in more redistributive policies than those of the right, and that

accordingly they will produce poor macroeconomic outcomes in terms of growth, higher

inflation, and greater unemployment.

My logic in making this argument is as follows. Given the extreme populist

backlash seen in numerous Latin American countries against stabilization programs and

export-oriented economic strategies that limited social spending and curbed inflation at

the expense of unemployment, parties of the left in Latin America remain responsive to a

voting public that may not understand the negative economic implications involved in

policies such as wealth redistribution. In so doing, they may be more likely to engage in

economic action that would be detrimental to growth, sacrificing inflation in order to

achieve decreased unemployment, simply by virtue of the perceived demands of their

constituencies. Alternatively, parties of the right long since supported economic policies

of stabilization and of neoliberal, export-oriented growth trajectories. Given the fractured

nature of the Latin American electorate, where certain members of society earn near-first-

world livings and others live under vastly inferior means, it becomes less intuitive for a

political party to simply maneuver to the median voter, eschewing partisan goals in order

26
to take action that will ensure a balance between the needs of capitalists to feel confident

continuing to invest while recognizing the demands of a working class clamoring for

wage increases. If politicians are concerned with being elected to office, then they will

be responsive to a constituency calling for redistributive government action even if taking

that action may eventually lead to subpar economic performance.

Before answering the question on whether Latin American governments do indeed

ignore such structural limits as the state’s dependence on capital, and in order to better

distinguish between the reasoning for left governments performing differently than right

governments in Latin America, it is relevant to further examine the established literature

on the ways in which partisanship may or may not affect macroeconomic policy and

outcomes in the OECD countries. It is not my intention here to include the OECD

countries in my analysis as well, nor is it my intention to answer the partisanship question

in regards to the OECD countries. Scholars have expounded on the topic already to great

effect, and my exploration of that literature will serve as an understanding of

partisanship’s role in macroeconomic decision-making in OECD countries rather than a

challenge to that understanding. But as I formulate this study in an attempt to better

understand the ways in which partisan differences can lead to macroeconomic differences

in Latin America, it behooves me to critically engage with the substantive established

literature on the topic at large, rather than explore the topic through a purely Latin

American-centric lens.

Thus, in the following chapter I explore the larger school of thought in relation to

the possibility of partisanship affecting macroeconomic policies and outcomes. A clear

understanding of the scope and limits of the role of partisanship in economic decision-

27
making in OECD countries will guide my research and provide important insights into

why the claims I present here may be largely supported or refuted. Additionally, it may

provide insights for future scholars in determining why differences exist between Latin

America and the OECD countries regarding partisanship’s role in shaping

macroeconomic policies and outcome. With that in mind, I will now explore the

prevailing OECD-centric theories regarding the role of partisanship in shaping

macroeconomic policy and outcomes.

28
CHAPTER 3: Economic Effects of Left Partisanship in OECD Countries

For the purposes of this discussion (and indeed for the purpose of this thesis at

large), I will divide our conception of the party system into a dichotomy of left-

representing and right-representing interests, where parties of the left are generally more

representative of poor and labor interests and parties of the right are generally more

representative of capital-owning interests. This line of thinking has long existed in

political discourse, growing in prominence with the advent of Marxist theory—in

particular, Marx’s book Wage-labour, and Capital, where he describes the nuances of the

economic relationship at play between workers and the capitalists who hire them. 46 But

numerous other well-respected scholars examining the government’s role in shaping

macroeconomic outcomes have also presented their arguments within this paradigm—

Marx is far from alone in making this distinction. One pertinent example would be

scholars Adam Przeworski and Michael Wallerstein, who based their key argument

regarding the structural dependence of the state on capital (which I will be examining

shortly) on the economic distinction between wage earners and owners of capital. 47 Given

an ideological political-party breakdown along those lines, with exceptionally different

types of demands on the state found from workers versus business owners (or more

broadly, from rich versus poor), it is sensible to infer that political parties would use their

influence and power in government to enact macroeconomic policies most rewarding to

their constituents.

46
Marx, Karl. Wage-labour and Capital: Value, Price and Profit. International Publishers Co,
1935. Books.google.com (accessed January 30, 2009)
47
Przeworski, Adam and Wallerstein, Michael. Structural Dependence of the State on Capital. The
American Political Science Review, Vol. 82, No. 1 (Mar., 1988) p. 11.

29
And indeed, scholars have long sought to reconcile competing political interests

in determining how the state distributes its resources. Douglas Hibbs conducted an

examination of macroeconomic policies and their outcomes in both the United States and

Great Britain, seeking to uncover if partisan differences really played a role in the

variation in outcomes. Hibbs paid particular attention to what he called “the unfavorable

trade-off between inflation and unemployment,” otherwise known as the Phillips curve

for the scholar Alban William Phillips, who first published work documenting the

oppositional relationship between the two economic variables.48 In so doing, Hibbs

tracked the degrees of inflation and unemployment when a given party was in power –

Democrats and the Labour party on the left, and Republicans and the Conservative party

on the right, for the United States and Great Britain, respectively. Hibbs predicted that

the leftist governments would prefer “relatively low unemployment at the expense of

high rates of inflation” while “comparatively low inflation and high unemployment

[would] characterize political systems dominated by center and right-wing parties.” 49 His

conclusions and evidence heavily supported his claim, and Hibbs determined with

confidence that “macroeconomic outcomes systematically covary with the political

orientation of governments.”50 In other words, the political orientation of the governing

party makes a statistically significant difference in terms of the types of policies and

economic outputs of a given nation. It is important to note, for the sake of distinguishing

Hibbs’ analysis from future theories to be discussed below, a central assumption of his

work—that “political authorities can (and do) influence the rate of unemployment and

48
Hibbs, Douglas A., Jr. Political Parties and Macroeconomic Policy. The American Political
Science Review, Vol. 71, No. 4 (Dec., 1977), p. 1467.
49
Ibid, p. 1468.
50
Ibid, p. 1475.

30
inflation by manipulation of monetary and fiscal policy.”51 This notion has since been

challenged, and I will examine those claims below. Nevertheless, his was an important

work that outlined persuasively why partisanship does matter for economic outcomes.

An interesting alternative to Hibbs’ argument, which focuses on tax rates rather

than inflation and unemployment, is found in the work of Allan Meltzer and Scott

Richard. In 1981, the two scholars published a groundbreaking article arguing that lower

productivity members of society (wage-earners, for example) desire higher tax rates

because of the net distributional effects of tax revenue in their favor. 52 Conversely, higher

productivity members of society (capitalists) desire lower tax rates because on a net scale

they pay more into the system than they receive in public good benefits. In Meltzer and

Richard’s words, these policy goals would lead to either an increase or decrease in the

size of government.53 Given that relatively better- and poorer-off members of society

have different motives for the distribution and management of national wealth, it is

natural to assume that a political party representing the wealthy with a controlling stake

of power will engage in macroeconomic action to ensure results most favorable to its

constituency. And indeed, Hibbs, who we discussed earlier, certainly predicted that

parties would pursue policies most in line with their ideological leanings. But while

Meltzer and Richard do find a tendency for individual voters to support policies and

politicians presumably most favorable to their particular self-interest, their larger and

most groundbreaking finding is that “the size of government is determined by the

welfare-maximizing choice of a decisive individual”—the median voter. 54 In other


51
Ibid, p. 1468.
52
Meltzer, Allan H. & Richard, Scott F. A Rational Theory of the Size of Government. The Journal
of Political Economy, Vol. 89, No. 5 (Oct., 1981), p. 914.
53
Ibid, p. 916.
54
Ibid, p. 924.

31
words, one voter, based on the relation of mean income (the average income of society at

large) to his own, will have the decisive vote on whether to increase or decrease the size

of government and by extension alter macroeconomic outcomes.

This claim does not inherently lead to the conclusion that political parties do not

matter in terms of macroeconomic outcomes. As William Clark outlines in his upcoming

textbook, when combined with democracy the Meltzer-Richard theory “introduces the

possibility that the poor will seize the property of the rich through a redistributive tax

scheme,” an action more likely taken by a party of the left (though of course, both parties

may have incentive to take this action).55 The point of Meltzer and Richard’s piece is not

to take away all notions of political agency in defining outcomes, but rather to note that

political parties’ actions in the economic arena (specifically in the area of tax policy for

Meltzer and Richard’s purposes) are limited to those policies which are acceptable to the

median voter. When the median voter makes a wage substantially lower than that of the

mean of all wages in society, then that median voter will tend to support redistributive

policies. Yet just as the theory does not preclude political party agency, it does lead to the

conclusion that for a given political party to exercise power, it must cater to the median

voter—and this occurs whether that political party be from the left or right side of the

spectrum. This theory is also supported by Anthony Downs, who wrote succinctly that

“government gives voters what they want … for the government is primarily interested in

people’s votes.”56 The grand implication here is that due to attempts to appease to the

median voter, both parties will present policies that converge towards largely similar

outcomes—or in other words, re-electable macroeconomic outcomes.


55
Clark, William R. Chapter 9, Does Democracy Make a Difference? Untitled. CQ Press, 2008, p. 319.
56
Downs, Anthony. Why the Government Budget is Too Small in a Democracy. World Politics, Vol.
12, No. 4, (Jul., 1960), p. 546.

32
Yet perhaps partisan desires to enact macroeconomic policies most favorable to a

party’s constituency are limited by more than just electoral factors such as the median

voter phenomenon described above. Scholars Adam Przeworski and Michael Wallerstein

confirmed an even more pressing claim on limiting the actions of government, which

structural Marxists had long been asserting—the government’s need for capital in order to

effectively function.57 Just as in the Meltzer-Richard theory, proponents of the theory of

the structural dependence of capital divide society between wage earners and owners of

capital, but their argument goes further than simply arguing that the median voter’s will is

prevalent. Rather than curtailing policy to the median voter, the theorists argue that “all

social groups are constrained in the pursuit of their material interests by the effect of their

actions on the willingness of owners of capital to invest.” 58 As this constraint runs

throughout society, it additionally constrains government. As the theory goes, “the

pursuit of any [government] objectives that require material resources places

governments in the situation of structural dependence” on capitalists to continue to

invest, because the government relies on revenues from the fruits of that investment in

order to function.59 If the government pursues policies to the point that capitalists decide

to disinvest from the economy, then wage-earners relying on capitalist investment for

continued employment will lose their jobs, and will punish that government by voting

them out of power. Przeworski and Wallerstein explain this tendency well: “vote-

seeking politicians are dependent on owners of capital because voters are.”60 So the

theory continues, if government relies on capital both for the purposes of funding its own

57
Przeworski, Adam and Wallerstein, Michael. Structural Dependence of the State on Capital. The
American Political Science Review, Vol. 82, No. 1 (Mar., 1988) p. 11.
58
Ibid, p. 12.
59
Ibid, p. 12.
60
Ibid, p. 12.

33
objectives as well as for maintaining the employment of those who would keep that

government in power, then government will continue to exercise macroeconomic policies

that are consistent with the policy preferences of the investing class.

In examining this claim, Przeworski and Wallerstein did not in fact determine that

the state is structurally dependent on capital in the static sense—meaning, structural

dependence would not occur when assuming that non-state actors only readjust their

preferences once the state takes action on the macroeconomic scale. 61 Yet before making

any conclusions regarding the implications of this finding for partisan attempts at

manipulating macroeconomic policy to further their interests, Przeworski and Wallerstein

went one step further. Instead of stopping after examining the responses of non-state

actors (capitalists, wage-earners) to the actions of the state, the two authors evaluated the

ways in which non-state actors would respond to mere announcements of government

intentions to engage in certain types of macroeconomic action. Specifically, they

concluded that when leftist governments discussed engaging in redistributive policies, the

mere “anticipation of this moment causes a fall in investment and is costly to wage

earners’ welfare in the period before the tax increase goes into effect.” 62 So while the tax

itself on the consumption of shareholders’ income may not lead to decreased investment,

the anticipation of that policy’s implementation would cause capitalists to disinvest, thus

rendering negative macroeconomic outcomes for the very people (the wage-earners) that

the leftist government in power was trying to empower. Therefore, because the state is

inherently constricted by the threat of disinvestment of capital from the economy, it must

engage in macroeconomic action in order to maintain the confidence of capitalists and


61
Przeworski, Adam and Wallerstein, Michael. Structural Dependence of the State on Capital. The
American Political Science Review, Vol. 82, No. 1 (Mar., 1988) p. 21.
62
Ibid, p. 23.

34
keep them invested in the economy. This limitation greatly constricts the ability of states

to implement overly redistributive policies, as political parties representing labor must

balance their desire for higher wages with the knowledge that over-distribution of

national wealth will lead to disinvestment, and thus fewer economic opportunities for

wage-earners in the future.

The preceding discussion may initially lead to some confusion. It appears as

though there are indeed partisan interests from either the left or right side of the political

spectrum seeking to use their power in government to enact macroeconomic policies

most favorable to their constituents. But at the same time, it is evident that numerous

constraints exist on their capabilities to put those policies into place. As Meltzer and

Richards and Downs argued, the parties must limit those policies to those deemed

acceptable by the median voter. And additionally, Przeworski and Wallerstein

demonstrated that parties must limit those policies to those which would maintain a

climate of business confidence in investment—if overly redistributive policies were even

suggested, then capital would tend to disinvest, leading to unfavorable macroeconomic

outcomes both for society at large and in particular for the wage earners most often

targeted as benefactors of that redistributive macroeconomic policy. So the question

arises: To what extent, if at all, do differences in partisan representation in government

really affect macroeconomic outcomes? Given the above discussion, it is evident that

parties seek to implement policies most favorable to their constituents, but there

simultaneously exist numerous constraints to such action in favor of more homogenous

decision-making. Evidently, structural and electoral constraints exist such that it remains

35
unclear if differences in partisan control of government really do lead to variance in

macroeconomic outcomes.

In attempting to rectify this apparent impasse between the desires of parties to

implement partisan policies and the constraints brought about by the median voter and

the dependence of the state on capital, scholars R. Michael Alvarez, Geoffrey Garrett, and

Peter Lange added a key element to the equation. Specifically, they posited that a

significant degree of variance in the success or failure of the use of partisan-related

macroeconomic policy could be found by controlling for the degree to which labor

movements were organized and mobilized within society (or were in their words,

“encompassing”).63 When labor movements were indeed encompassing, “leftist

participation in governments was strongly associated with higher rates of growth and

with slower increases in inflation and in unemployment levels.”64 Conversely, “leftist

participation had deleterious consequences for economic performance … in countries

where union movements were less centralized.”65 The opposite was found to be true for

rightist governments; with high degrees of labor encompassment the government tended

to underperform in terms of macroeconomic outcomes, while it performed well when

labor was relatively unorganized. Accordingly, positive macroeconomic outcomes were

possible under either leftist or rightist governments, depending upon the degree to which

labor movements were encompassing. The authors additionally found that this

phenomenon occurred on a sliding scale; high degrees of encompassment would lead to

either more favorable macroeconomic outcomes for leftist governments or more

63
Alvarez, R. Michael et al. Government Partisanship, Labor Organization, and Macroeconomic
Performance. The American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 2 (Jun., 1991), p. 544.
64
Ibid, p. 549.
65
Ibid, p. 549.

36
deleterious outcomes for rightist governments.66 This argument is known as the social

democratic corporatist model, and it will be referred to throughout this section as the

SDC hypothesis.

The authors thus argued that it was possible for governance from either the left or

right to lead to macroeconomic outcomes that were favorable to society as a whole. But

they additionally found that by working within the framework of labor encompassment,

parties were able to enact policies specifically desired by their constituency while still

maintaining overall positive macroeconomic outcomes. The explanation for this

capability lies in the same notion of expectation regarding policy choices as was found in

the work of Przeworski and Wallerstein (recall their conclusion that the mere expectation

of redistributive policy led to capitalist disinvestment from the economy). For instance,

in a society with high degree of labor encompassment, “the pursuit of welfarist policies

by leftist government is likely to generate voluntary wage restraint” by labor because of

an improved understanding of the negative effects of over-redistribution (capitalist

disinvestment, in particular).67 So a leftist government with knowledge of the restraint of

the encompassed union would be better able to pursue its partisan preferences for more

interventionist policies without sparking disinvestment by capitalists because of

confidence generated by the “stable political economic environment.” 68 In this situation,

the expectations of behavior for labor, government, and capital are all clearly known and

implicitly accepted, and this stability provides confidence for capitalists to continue to

66
Ibid, p. 551.
67
Alvarez, R. Michael et al. Government Partisanship, Labor Organization, and Macroeconomic
Performance. The American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 2 (Jun., 1991), p. 542.
68
Scharpf, Fritz W. Economic and Institutional Constraints of Full-Employment Strategies: Sweden,
Austria, and West Germany, 1974-1982. In Order and Conflict in Contemporary Capitalism, ed.
John H. Goldthorpe, Clarendon Publishing, Oxford, 1984.

37
invest as they can comfortably assume that overzealous redistribution of their capital will

not occur. In alternative cases, when leftist governments were paired with low labor

encompassment or rightist governments with high labor encompassment, the outcome

was “deleterious consequences for economic performance” because of the negative

expectations for business confidence that either case would provide.69

The work of Alvarez, Garrett, and Lange was important because it successfully

outlined parameters under which partisan representation in government could affect

macroeconomic outcomes—and importantly, parameters under which partisan policies of

the left could generate positive returns in terms of macroeconomic outcomes (the

parameters being dependent upon the degree of labor encompassment). The picture on

partisan effects on macroeconomic outcomes thus becomes a bit clearer. But in response

to Alvarez et al, William Clark argued in his book Capitalism, Not Globalism that while

the SDC hypothesis made compelling claims, it neglected to mention three features of

government of utmost importance to macroeconomic outcomes: the degree of capital

mobility, the type of exchange rate regime, and the degree of central bank

independence.70 These three economic factors make up what political economists often

refer to as the “unholy trinity” of institutional constraints whereby it is impossible for

governments to have all three policy tools of a fixed exchange rate, free capital

movement (commonly referred to as capital mobility), and an independent monetary

policy.71

69
Alvarez, R. Michael et al. Government Partisanship, Labor Organization, and Macroeconomic
Performance. The American Political Science Review, Vol. 85, No. 2 (Jun., 1991), p. 549.
70
Clark, William Roberts. Capitalism, Not Globalism: Capital Mobility, Central Bank
Independence, and the Political Control of the Economy. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor,
2003, p. 105.
71
Hellwig, Timothy T. Interdependence, Government Constraints, and Economic Voting. The
Journal of Politics, Vol. 63, No. 4 (Nov., 2001), p. 1146.

38
The introduction of these three policy variations has significant implications for

the discussion on partisan variation on macroeconomic outcomes, in that an independent

central bank makes policy decisions (in particular regarding interest rates) that could lead

to differing macroeconomic outcomes on unemployment and inflation, without being

immediately answerable to politicians of either party. And exchange rate fluctuations and

increased capital mobility might extend the state’s dependence of capital beyond purely

national borders. Whatever the immediate implications of these three pillars of

macroeconomic policy, it is evident that analysis of the SDC hypothesis must include an

examination of the ways in which degrees of labor-encompassment affect policy

outcomes within the ‘unholy trinity’ framework. In response to this limitation, Clark

sought to do exactly that.

Clark began by introducing a measure of capital mobility into the SDC model,

and found that left-governments indeed were associated with higher unemployment when

labor encompassment was low, but only when capital markets were highly open. 72 Clark

was not the first scholar to make this distinction; indeed, Geoffrey Garrett intended to do

exactly that—but Clark found a limitation in Garrett’s methodology and corrected for it

in his model.73 In terms of inflation, Clark found no correlation between the model’s

predictions on labor encompassment and leftist governance in regards to inflation, no

matter what the degree of capital mobility. In fact, he found that leftist governance was

“associated with a decrease in inflation only if labor-market institutions are weak and

decentralized,” exactly the opposite conclusion one would expect given the SDC
72
Clark, William Roberts. Capitalism, Not Globalism: Capital Mobility, Central Bank
Independence, and the Political Control of the Economy. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor,
2003, p. 117.
73
Garrett, Geoffrey. Partisan Politics in the Global Economy. Cambridge Univ. Press, New York,
1998.

39
hypothesis (italics his).74 Clark went on to conduct similar tests when controlling for

various degrees of exchange rate openness and central bank independence, and once

again the evidence in favor of the SDC hypothesis was decidedly mixed in places—and

indeed, “when one controls for the modifying effects of exchange rate regime … all

evidence for the SDC hypothesis disappears entirely.” 75 All in all, Clark’s main assertion

regarding partisanship’s role in the economy is that “if partisan differences in

macroeconomic performance exist, these differences appear to be sensitive to context in

ways that we do not fully understand.”76 Because contrary to the literature on

globalization that argued that globalization’s expansion was leading to a “withering away

of the state” that was decreasing the capabilities of partisan actors to choose

macroeconomic outcomes, Clark found little evidence that partisan differences ever

existed in the first place.77

Clark’s investigation was convincing and thorough in its methodological

approach. If any limitations do exist in regards to the universality of his findings, one in

particular might be that all of his data was derived from a pool of OECD (Organization

for Economic Co-Operation and Development) countries, all of which include the world’s

most economically developed nations: the lowest current per capita gross domestic

product (GDP) when adjusted for purchasing power parity (PPP) among the countries

sampled78 was $28,500 for New Zealand, while the highest per capita GDP was $57,500
74
Clark, William Roberts. Capitalism, Not Globalism: Capital Mobility, Central Bank
Independence, and the Political Control of the Economy. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor,
2003, p. 118.
75
Ibid, p. 139.
76
Clark, William Roberts. Capitalism, Not Globalism: Capital Mobility, Central Bank
Independence, and the Political Control of the Economy. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor,
2003, p. 140.
77
Ibid, p. 140.
78
Sampled countries include: Australia, Austria, Belgium, Canada, Denmark, Finland, France, Great
Britain, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Japan, Netherlands, New Zealand, Norway, Spain, Sweden, United

40
for Norway.79 Those numbers are obviously not indicative of incomes across the rest of

the world, and in particular within Latin America. Interestingly, the other empirical

studies previously cited in this chapter also limited the scope of their analysis to

developed industrial economies. Alvarez et al, the authors of the SDC hypothesis, limited

their analysis to the developed countries found in the pool used by Clark. Przeworski and

Wallerstein’s explanation was theoretical in nature, but in explaining their positions the

authors used examples from countries such as Germany and France. The trend continues

in Meltzer and Richard’s work, who when discussing the rise in tax payments relative to

income cited how “the share has increased in all countries of western Europe and North

America during the past 25 years,”—certainly not a line of thought one would

automatically extend universally.80 Clark himself writes as a possible conclusion that

perhaps “the SDC framework is not the appropriate framework for analyzing the politics

of macroeconomic policy in OECD countries,” leaving open the possibility that the

framework would be appropriate in other instances. 81 And in his concluding words, he

argues that “if partisan differences in macroeconomic performance do exist, [then] these

differences appear to be sensitive to context in ways that we do not fully understand.”82

In elucidating these distinctions, it is not my intention to discredit the veracity of

Clark’s conclusions—within the framework of OECD countries, his analysis has shown

that extremely little evidence exists suggesting that partisan differences do play a role in

States, and West Germany.


79
CIA World Factbook, Rank Order – GDP – per capita (PPP)
https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/rankorder/2004rank.html
80
Meltzer, Allan H. & Richard, Scott F. A Rational Theory of the Size of Government. The Journal
of Political Economy, Vol. 89, No. 5 (Oct., 1981), p. 914.
81
Clark, William Roberts. Capitalism, Not Globalism: Capital Mobility, Central Bank
Independence, and the Political Control of the Economy. University of Michigan Press, Ann Arbor,
2003, p. 125.
82
Ibid, p. 140.

41
altering economic outcomes, and the complexity of his model is thorough and convincing

in its approach. But before simply accepting on face value that these conclusions

automatically apply to the rest of the world, the literature on partisanship and

macroeconomic outcomes would benefit from a systematic examination of Clark’s claims

in regards to the developing world, and in particular Latin America. I began this thesis

discussing attempts to understand the reasons behind why some countries are rich and

other countries are poor. I examined the literature regarding partisanship and

macroeconomic outcomes both within Latin America and at large, in an attempt to delve

into that timeless question. But in discussing disparities between rich countries and poor,

it is only natural to study both rich and poor countries in arriving at conclusions about

partisan control over the macroeconomic performance of those countries. Within that

developing world, the region of Latin America provides a natural starting point for

analysis.

Thus, the following chapter will engage analytically the question of whether the

partisan orientation of government can affect economic performance various Latin

American countries. I will first discuss my dependent and independent variables in

greater detail. I will then outline in detail the analytical model that will be used in the

analysis of those Latin American nations. After running a series of regressions on the

data within the bounds of the analytical model, I will present my findings and explain

them within the context of the previous academic discussion regarding the possible role

of partisan differences leading to variance in macroeconomic performance indicators. I

will then offer my conclusions, explain some limitations inherent to my study, and

suggest avenues for future research.

42
CHAPTER 4: Data and Empirical Analysis

Introduction
The preceding chapters have served to establish discrepancies within the accepted

field of knowledge regarding the role that partisan orientation of government plays in

affecting macroeconomic policy and outcomes. Within the literature specifically

regarding Latin America, case study analysis does show that partisanship affect policies

and outcomes—the instance of the rise of populism in Chile during the 1970s serves as a

fitting example. But individual instances are insufficient for attempts to understand the

broader effects that partisanship may have across an entire region. Additionally, while

some scholars have found partisan differences to play a role in altering the specificities of

government policy, they fell short of making a compelling argument regarding

partisanship’s broader macroeconomic effects as measured both within and across

countries. And within the literature that limited its analysis to OECD countries, the

results are ambiguous as well. While Hibbs outlined instances where partisanship had

quite significant effects on macroeconomic outcomes, numerous subsequent scholars

uncovered limitations of his argument (structural dependence of the state on capital, for

instance), and indeed others like William Clark issued near-complete refutations of the

Hibbsian argument. And while Clark argues convincingly that partisan effects play little

role in shaping macroeconomic policy and outcomes for OECD countries, it remains an

open question as to whether his logic can be accurately applied in the same manner to

countries in the developing world such as those found in Latin America.

Given these discrepancies, this section will examine in greater analytical detail the

role that partisan orientation of government has played on macroeconomic performance


43
in Latin American countries in particular. Specifically, I will take a measure of

partisanship as an independent variable, testing them against dependent variables

measuring various elements of macroeconomic policy and outcomes. These elements

will be outlined in greater detail shortly. In conducting this analysis, I will undertake a

panel-corrected standard errors regression of the data. I use this specific type of time-

series cross-sectional analysis, rather than a basic time-series cross-sectional analysis, due

to instances where data in a given year is a function of similar data from the previous

year. For instance, data on budget surpluses in 2000 would be a function of the degree to

which the budget was balanced in 1999. In examining the data, it is necessary to remove

such auto-correlation in order to ensure accuracy of results, and panel corrected standard

errors analysis does just that. Additionally, the use of basic time-series cross-sectional

analysis leaves open the possibility for heteroskedasticity, whereby an external variable

previously unrecognized by the model could be affecting all of the countries in the

sample differently, as well as my variable of interest (in this case, left partisanship).

Panel-corrected standard errors analysis takes this possibility into account, thereby

increasing the accuracy of my results.

Variables
Concurrent with the theme of this thesis, my independent variable will be an

index of partisanship. I codify control of government as either left (0) or non-left (1), a

metric which includes both centrist and right-leaning parties. In creating this metric I

altered the formulation of a partisan variable created by Hallerberg and Marier, in which

the authors created a different codification for left, centrist, and right control of

44
government (specifically, the executive branch).83 For my analysis, both instances of

centrist and right control of the executive were coded as non-left (1). The use of the

partisanship of the executive as a proxy measurement for the partisanship of the

government varies slightly from previously-used measurements of partisanship,

particularly within the OECD literature, that largely examines the partisan orientation of

the cabinet controlling government. However, while the majority of the OECD countries

studied feature parliamentary government, Latin America is largely characterized by

presidential systems of governance, where a large degree of power is concentrated within

the confines of the office of the executive. Accordingly, a measure of partisanship

codifying the partisan orientation of the executive is therefore appropriate for the

purposes of this study.

My dependent variables will be used to measure both policies and outcomes.

Specifically, the dependent variable utilized as a proxy for economic policy will be a

measure of budget surplus as percent of GDP. I utilize this specific metric because more

expansionist policies would presumably involve increased government expenditure,

which could be represented through a tendency against budget surpluses. Leftist

governments elected on the promise of engaging in redistribution may face greater

pressures from their constituencies to take such redistributive action, increasing the

likelihood of spending more than their centrist and right counterparts. In terms of

measuring the effects of partisanship on macroeconomic outcomes, I will examine three

important metrics: GDP growth, inflation, and unemployment. The inflation variable

will be regressed after natural log has been applied to it. And for unemployment, I use
83
Hallerberg, Mark and Marier, Patrick. Executive Authority, the Personal Vote, and Budget
Discipline in Latin American and Caribbean Countries, American Journal of Political Science, Vol.
48, No. 3 (Jul. 2004)

45
urban unemployment data as the datasets were more complete than with a measure of

total unemployment.

Additionally, I will introduce a variable which could produce interesting effects:

the degree to which voters elect politicians by means of personal vote ballots. Personal

vote ballots vary from list vote ballots in that citizens vote for individual candidates

rather than for a specific party. My hypothesis predicts that as voters elect leftist

politicians, those politicians will in turn put in place economic policies that will lead to

poorer-performing economic outcomes as measured in terms of growth, inflation, and

unemployment. But perhaps incentives to cultivate personal vote could be an intervening

variable. If indeed the political ideology of the party in power determines policy (which

is my hypothesis), then in instances without incentives to cultivate the personal vote one

would expect that parties would simply implement their preferred policies. In the case of

left-wing governments, I would argue that these policies would tend to be

redistributionist in nature. But in instances where personal vote systems are indeed

apparent, politicians representing a particular ideology may be more likely to

compromise that belief in favor of getting elected, perhaps instead moving towards a

median voter that would support less redistributionist policies.

There is, of course, another possible take on the addition of the personal vote

ballot into the model. If we assume that candidates have greater incentive to appeal

directly to constituent interests when personal vote occurs, then perhaps that median

voter in Latin America has a tendency to support more redistributionist policies (indeed,

this trend may occur regardless of political party orientation). In such an instant as this,

increased personal vote might actually increase the likelihood of budget deficits. And

46
alternatively, without a personal vote ballot, results may be different by virtue of citizens

only voting for political parties as opposed to individual candidates. Rather than needing

to engage in specifically redistributive policy (because the median voter would dictate

this to be so), leftist parties could espouse their party principles in terms of rhetoric, but

in practice could behave in a manner more consistent with the predictions of Clark and

Przeworski and Wallerstein—rather, that there would be little if any degree of difference

in terms of economic performance, because specific policies will be less likely directly

implemented for immediately clientelistic purposes. Politicians may lose their original

incentive to engage in clientelistic policy action (an incentive created by means of the

personal vote) when their survival in office is more dependent on following party orders

than on catering to the whims of individual voters. Therefore, systems without personal

vote ballots may feature economic performance unaffected by the partisan orientation of

government. In other words, partisanship may only affect economic performance when

personal vote ballot systems are utilized. These possibilities will also be tested.

Data
The data used for this study was collected from a few principle sources. The

codification of partisanship was taken from the dataset of the Hallerberg and Marier

piece, with the codification altered as previously described. Data on the budget surplus

variable (represented by government’s budget surplus as percent of GDP), in addition to

economic growth and inflation numbers are all taken from the Inter-American

Development Bank.84 In terms of data for unemployment, I use urban unemployment

data from the Economic Commission for Latin America and the Caribbean. There are

84
Hallerberg, Mark and Marier, Patrick. Executive Authority, the Personal Vote, and Budget
Discipline in Latin American and Caribbean Countries, American Journal of Political Science, Vol.
48, No. 3 (Jul. 2004), p. 580.

47
some years for which certain countries did not report data; however, this urban

unemployment metric was the most complete available in terms of unemployment, and it

remains highly correlated with total unemployment. Data on personal vote is based on

the codifications of Hallerberg and Marier, and is formed on a scale from 0 to 1, with 0

indicating no personal vote at all and 1 indicating an entirely personal-vote-centric

system.

Model
The model argues that a given variable, for example budget surplus, is affected

first by the budget surplus or deficit of the previous year and then additionally by the

partisan ideology of the governing party. Specifically, I hypothesize that left ideology of

the government will lead to a negative value for budget surplus (in other words, a budget

deficit). But the model changes when including the personal vote variable into the

equation. In so doing, when personal vote is equal to zero the model should remain

unchanged. But when personal vote is equal to one (or any other non-zero number

between zero and one), the model takes on additional complexity. Expressed in

mathematical terms, the simple, unconditioned model appears as

Budget Surplusi = α0 + α1Budget Surplusi-1 + α2Left Partisan Orientation + Error

where i represents a given year between 1988 and 1997, so long as personal vote is zero.

In future equations, I will simplify the variables Budget Surplus as S, Left Partisan

Orientation as L, and Error as E. But the equation expands when personal vote gains a

non-zero value between zero and one to

Si = β0 + β1Si-1 + β2L + β3Personal Vote + β4L*Personal Vote + E

48
in order to include the interaction effects of the personal vote variable on left

partisanship. Returning for a moment to my primary hypothesis, I argue (at least when

personal vote is equal to zero) that left government should affect the coefficient of the

budget surplus variable. If my hypothesis is correct and left partisanship indeed leads to

budget deficits rather than surpluses, then the coefficient of L should have a negative

value. If I am incorrect and left partisanship actually leads to bigger surpluses, then the

coefficient of L should have a value greater than zero.

If indeed the addition of the personal vote variable dampens the effects of left

partisanship on budget balance, then as personal vote increases, we should expect the

effect of partisanship to decrease, and for the relationship between partisanship and

budget surpluses, for example, to trend towards statistical insignificance. In order to test

this, I will run a linear combination of the two coefficients at play: left partisanship, and

left partisanship multiplied with the personal vote. By running this test, I am able to

determine at which point personal vote achieves statistical significance in decreasing the

effect that partisanship has on budget balance. In so doing, I will multiply the left

variable with both personal vote and different factors of .1 (for example .2, .3, .4, etc.).

My data on personal vote is listed on a range from 0 to 1, with 0 implying no personal

vote and 1 implying that a method of election entirely based on personal vote. By

utilizing this linear combination test I can determine the level (.5, for example) at which

the personal vote variable achieves statistical significance for decreasing the effectiveness

of left in affecting budget balance.

I will conduct the study, and present the results, in the following manner. I will

first examine the interaction effects of left partisan orientation of government on budget

49
surpluses, my proxy for economic policy. I will next examine the effects of left partisan

orientation on growth, followed by inflation and then unemployment. These variables

will serve as proxies for economic outcomes. These examinations will test the first,

unconditioned model as it exists without inclusion of the personal vote variable. Next, I

will examine the conditioned model including both the personal vote variable and its

interactions with left partisanship. I will first examine the effects of the personal vote’s

inclusion on budget surpluses, followed next by growth, and then inflation and

unemployment. I begin with a test of the effects of left partisanship on budget surpluses,

ignoring for a moment the personal vote variable.

To do so, I run the panel-corrected standard errors regression of budget surplus

with left partisanship, utilizing a time lag in order to eliminate any auto-correlative

effects. There is no statistical significance between left partisanship and budget surpluses

initially, though there is a negative coefficient for left, implying that left partisanship may

have some negative effect on budget surpluses. But perhaps the analysis is still

incomplete. By adding year dummy variables, I am able to see if there is significance

when controlling for specific years that may alter the accuracy of the results. After re-

running the model with year dummy variables included, left partisanship’s effects on

budget surplus remain statistically insignificant, though again the left coefficient is

negative. I then add country variables to the model, such that both year and dummy

variables are included in the regression. In this instance, there is positive statistical

significance at 5% for Chile and the Dominican Republic and negative statistical

significance for the Bahamas, Guatemala, Honduras and Venezuela; there is negative

statistical significance at 1% for Costa Rica. Yet there is no statistical significance for the

50
actual broad effects of left on budget surplus across the entire sample (again the

coefficient of left partisanship is negative). To determine if the year dummy variables

could be outliers, I then re-run the regression using only country dummy variables but

without year dummy variables. Again, the countries that were previously statistically

significant remain statistically significant—save Guatemala, which actually loses

statistical significance for left’s effect on budget surplus. Once again, the coefficient of

left partisanship is negative, but statistically insignificant. Left partisanship does not

appear to strongly affect budget surpluses at a level of statistical significance.

Table 1: Left’s Effects on Budget Surplus; No Interaction with Personal Vote


Regressed first alone, then with year dummies, then year and country dummies, then
country dummies
(1) (2) (3) (4)

Budget Surplus as % of GDP


left -0.350 -0.334 -0.419 -0.480
(0.874) (0.874) (0.902) (0.959)
L. Budget Surplus as % of GDP 0.518 0.524 0.255 0.261
(0.218)* (0.229)* (0.287) (0.272)
y89 0.171 -0.322
(0.740) (0.585)
y90 -0.191 -0.164
(0.514) (0.487)
y91 0.250 0.347
(0.685) (0.539)
y92 -0.607 -0.378
(0.658) (0.577)
y93 -0.260 -0.174
(0.674) (0.539)
y94 0.157 0.158
(0.587) (0.478)
y95 0.128 0.306
(0.413) (0.587)
y96 -0.745 -0.554
(0.443) (0.606)
bahamas -0.859 -0.843
(0.335)* (0.337)*
barbados -0.941 -0.903
(1.679) (1.688)
belize -1.954 -1.938
(1.327) (1.319)
bolivia -0.639 -0.533
(0.535) (0.631)

51
brazil -4.469 -4.470
(3.299) (3.287)
chile 2.514 2.504
(1.223)* (1.157)*
costaric -2.195 -2.136
(0.629)** (0.577)**
columbia -0.727 -0.715
(0.701) (0.698)
domrep 1.565 1.563
(0.670)* (0.621)*
ecuador 1.032 1.098
(1.690) (1.708)
elsalvad -0.759 -0.743
(0.494) (0.493)
guatemal -0.461 -0.404
(0.206)* (0.302)
guyana -5.209 -5.076
(5.293) (5.181)
honduras -2.772 -2.742
(1.122)* (1.083)*
jamaica 1.356 1.409
(1.688) (1.698)
mexico 1.013 1.085
(0.951) (0.988)
nicaragu -6.271 -6.285
(7.678) (7.653)
panama 1.296 1.350
(3.462) (3.405)
paraguay 1.659 1.656
(1.442) (1.403)
peru -0.085 -0.058
(0.198) (0.184)
suriname -4.465 -4.462
(4.641) (4.660)
trinitob 0.049 0.145
(0.512) (0.495)
uruguay -0.337 -0.336
(0.761) (0.762)
venezuel -0.786 -0.818
(0.363)* (0.417)*
Constant -0.593 -0.467 -0.515 -0.606
(0.628) (0.621) (0.599) (0.337)
Observations 185 185 185 185
Number of country 25 25 25 25
Standard errors in parentheses
* significant at 5%; **
significant at 1%

I then repeat the above testing process for the variables serving as proxies for

macroeconomic outcomes—those of growth, inflation, and unemployment. I first

52
analyze the effects of left partisanship on growth, once again running a panel-corrected

standard errors regression. With no dummy variables, there is no statistical significance

for left’s effects on growth, and the coefficient for left is negative. With just year dummy

variables included, there is again no statistical significance for the effect of left on growth

(though the coefficient is once again negative), but there is negative significance for the

years 1989, 1990, and 1995. I then add country dummy variables. In this instance, left is

again negative but not statistically significant. There is negative statistical significance

for 1989 and 1990, as well as strong negative statistical significance (at 1%) for Bahamas

and Uruguay, and negative statistical significance (at 5%) for Barbados, Paraguay, and

Peru. Chile is positive and statistically significant at 5%. I then run the regression with

just country variables but without year dummy variables. Again, the left coefficient is

negative but statistically insignificant. There is positive country significance at 5% for

Chile, negative country significance at 5% for Paraguay and Peru, and negative country

significance at 1% for Bahamas and Uruguay. In this instance, there is some evidence of

left partisanship leading to decreased growth within certain years and countries.

Table 2: Left’s Effects on Growth; No Interaction with Personal Vote


Regressed first alone, then with year dummies, then year and country dummies, then
country dummies
(1) (2) (3) (4)
GDP Growth
left -0.856 -0.698 -1.164 -1.556
(0.692) (0.632) (1.000) (1.105)
L. GDP Growth 0.397 0.392 0.280 0.288
(0.126)** (0.129)** (0.147) (0.153)
y89 -2.081 -2.157
(0.724)** (0.640)**
y90 -2.033 -2.153
(0.678)** (0.651)**
y91 -0.507 -0.667
(0.740) (0.655)
y92 -0.319 -0.313
(0.733) (0.695)

53
y93 -1.230 -1.133
(0.754) (0.761)
y94 -0.104 -0.111
(0.782) (0.751)
y95 -2.290 -2.055
(0.968)* (0.910)*
y96 -1.046 -1.093
(0.997) (0.925)
bahamas -2.409 -2.391
(0.429)** (0.419)**
barbados -2.083 -1.936
(1.026)* (1.101)
belize 0.906 0.880
(1.566) (1.527)
bolivia 0.477 0.640
(1.344) (1.415)
brazil -1.578 -1.568
(1.417) (1.449)
chile 2.728 2.684
(1.213)* (1.261)*
costaric 0.335 0.544
(0.999) (1.069)
columbia -0.422 -0.432
(0.889) (0.866)
domrep -0.204 -0.207
(2.626) (2.656)
ecuador -0.196 0.189
(1.578) (1.652)
elsalvad 0.391 0.376
(1.153) (1.139)
guatemal 0.112 -0.479
(0.412) (0.633)
guyana 1.786 2.174
(1.500) (1.585)
honduras -0.631 -0.637
(0.493) (0.522)
jamaica -0.921 -0.568
(1.912) (1.926)
mexico 0.399 0.795
(1.629) (1.665)
nicaragu 0.092 -0.512
(1.012) (1.055)
panama 1.640 1.809
(1.964) (1.700)
paraguay -0.805 -0.812
(0.409)* (0.379)*
peru -0.706 -0.601
(0.326)* (0.235)*
suriname -0.329 -1.051
(2.002) (2.135)
trinitob -1.604 -1.564
(1.552) (1.526)
uruguay -0.556 -0.556

54
(0.105)** (0.083)**
venezuel -1.079 -1.299
(3.958) (3.821)
Constant 2.409 3.480 4.187 3.088
(0.808)** (0.884)** (0.702)** (0.811)**
Observations 195 195 195 195
Number of country 25 25 25 25
Standard errors in * significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%
parentheses

I next analyze the effects of left partisanship on inflation, once again running a

panel-corrected standard errors regression. With no dummy variables, there is statistical

significance for left’s effects on inflation, with the left coefficient as positive. This would

suggest that leftist governments preside over higher inflation. But I continue the

regressions, now with dummy variables included. With just year dummy variables

included, there is again very high positive statistical significance for the effect of left on

inflation, and there is negative year significance for the years 1989 and 1993 at 1%, and

positive year significance for 1990 at 1%. I then add country dummy variables. In this

instance, left is now negative and no longer statistically significant. There is negative

statistical significance for 1989, 1993, and 1996, and positive statistical significance for

1990 and 1992. There is strong positive statistical significance (at 1%) for Bahamas,

Barbados, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Dominican Republic, El Salvador, Guyana,

Honduras, Jamaica, Mexico, Nicaragua, Paraguay, and Peru and positive statistical

significance (at 5%) for Guatemala. Panama is the only country that has negative

statistical significance at the 1% level. I then run the regression with just country

variables but without year dummy variables. In this instance, the left coefficient is

positive but not statistically insignificant. No countries gained or lost statistical

significance, though statistical significance dropped from 1% to 5% for Bahamas. Left

55
partisanship appears to have a statistically significant positive effect on inflation,

meaning that left partisanship is statistically significant for increasing inflation.

Table 3: Left’s Effects on Inflation; No Interaction with Personal Vote


Regressed first alone, then with year dummies, then year and country dummies, then
country dummies
lncpi (1) (2) (3) (4)
Natural Log
Consumer Price
Index
left 0.227 0.207 -0.034 0.039
(0.049)** (0.054)** (0.144) (0.110)
LN Cons. Price Index 0.345 0.360 0.106 0.110
(0.070)** (0.064)** (0.087) (0.102)
y89 -0.185 -0.088
(0.071)** (0.045)*
y90 0.216 0.286
(0.034)** (0.033)**
y91 0.063 0.176
(0.063) (0.073)*
y92 0.145 0.239
(0.088) (0.071)**
y93 -0.374 -0.261
(0.086)** (0.069)**
y94 -0.082 -0.087
(0.087) (0.056)
y95 -0.039 -0.051
(0.042) (0.043)
y96 -0.060 -0.068
(0.050) (0.019)**
bahamas 0.180 0.179
(0.070)** (0.070)*
barbados 0.241 0.217
(0.051)** (0.043)**
belize -0.144 -0.143
(0.270) (0.275)
bolivia 0.454 0.421
(0.283) (0.292)
brazil 0.840 0.838
(0.178)** (0.179)**
chile 0.622 0.621
(0.146)** (0.145)**
costaric 0.505 0.463
(0.275) (0.279)
columbia 0.672 0.670
(0.163)** (0.164)**
domrep 1.063 1.059
(0.190)** (0.194)**
ecuador 1.059 0.982
(0.248)** (0.227)**

56
elsalvad 0.241 0.242
(0.049)** (0.050)**
guatemal 0.547 0.657
(0.254)* (0.310)*
guyana 0.686 0.611
(0.148)** (0.112)**
honduras 0.722 0.720
(0.273)** (0.275)**
jamaica 0.896 0.828
(0.236)** (0.220)**
mexico 0.861 0.785
(0.268)** (0.249)**
nicaragu 1.307 1.316
(0.226)** (0.252)**
panama -1.266 -1.203
(0.328)** (0.342)**
paraguay 0.707 0.706
(0.107)** (0.108)**
peru 0.828 0.809
(0.062)** (0.072)**
suriname -0.568 -0.557
(0.910) (0.973)
trinitob 0.491 0.473
(0.554) (0.553)
uruguay 0.730 0.728
(0.596) (0.597)
venezuel 1.062 1.113
(0.254)** (0.264)**
Constant 2.749 2.724 3.288 3.289
(0.292)** (0.263)** (0.368)** (0.474)**
Observations 195 195 195 195
Number of country 25 25 25 25
Standard errors in
parentheses
* significant at 5%;
** significant at 1%

[insert unemployment write-up and data table here]

Yet in all of that preceding analysis, I did not test for the effects that personal vote

may have had on the statistical significance of the left correlation with budget surplus,

growth, inflation, and unemployment. Thus, I now run the regressions using the more

complex conditional model shown again here and outlined previously:

Si = β0 + β1Si-1 + β2L + β3P + β4L*P + E

57
where S is budget surplus, L is left partisanship, P is personal vote, and E is error. Once

again, I will analyze the model first without any dummy variables, then just year dummy

variables, then both year and country dummy variables, and finally with just country

dummy variables.

Just as in the regressions testing left partisanship’s effect on budget surplus that

did not include indicators of personal vote, once again we find no statistical significance

between left and budget surplus, with a negative coefficient for left partisanship. I next

run the regression including year dummy variables, but once again there is no statistical

significance, (the left coefficient is again negative). I then run the regression with both

year and country dummy variables. In this instance, there is no statistical significance for

the left variable, but the personal vote variable’s interaction effect on budget surplus was

very positive and statistically significant and the L*P variable was highly negative

statistically significant. For the individual countries, there was positive statistical

significance within 1% for Bahamas, Bolivia, Guyana, Paraguay, and Trinidad and

Tobago and positive statistical significance within 5% for Barbados. There was negative

statistical significance within 1% for Belize, Brazil, Chile, Costa Rica, Colombia,

Dominican Republic, Ecuador, El Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras, Mexico, and Panama,

and negative statistical significance within 5% for Jamaica. It is important to note that

with both year and country dummy variables, I see for the first time a positive coefficient

for left partisanship, which might indicate that left had a positive effect on budget

surplus, but again this finding was not statistically significant.

To see if the year dummy variables played any role in the country significance, I

then re-ran the regression with just the country dummy variables included, with nearly

58
identical results in terms of country statistical significance. Left partisanship does not

appear to affect budget surplus, potentially due to the inclusion of the personal vote

variable, which was highly positive and significant for budget surplus. Additionally, the

interaction variable of L*P was negative and statistically significant, indicating that the

inclusion of the personal vote variable overruled any potential effects of left partisanship

on budget surpluses. Additionally, the personal vote appeared to be highly significant for

increased budget surpluses.

Table 5: Left’s Effects on Budget Surplus When Interacting with Personal Vote
Regressed first alone, then with year dummies, then year and country dummies, then country dummies
surdef (1) (2) (3) (4)
Budget Surplus as
Percent of GDP
left -0.852 -0.806 1.305 1.198
(2.195) (2.206) (1.236) (1.189)
Personal Vote 0.343 0.379 1,085.997 1,062.555
(1.254) (1.255) (339.130)** (352.072)**
Left*Personal Vote 2.929 2.771 -10.447 -10.092
(7.653) (7.665) (4.531)* (4.573)*
L. Surplus as % GDP 0.511 0.516 0.223 0.217
(0.210)* (0.219)* (0.284) (0.273)
y89 0.077 0.232
(0.672) (0.493)
y90 -0.248 -0.050
(0.451) (0.309)
y91 0.242 0.336
(0.697) (0.372)
y92 -0.619 -0.354
(0.672) (0.405)
y93 -0.277 -0.167
(0.681) (0.378)
y94 0.141 0.303
(0.597) (0.388)
y95 0.135 0.368
(0.422) (0.416)
y96 -0.741 -0.516
(0.461) (0.419)
bahamas 5.639 5.490
(1.806)** (1.864)**
barbados 5.325 5.199
(2.376)* (2.455)*
belize -17.175 -16.855
(5.160)** (5.353)**
bolivia 15.082 14.782

59
(5.121)** (5.379)**
brazil -564.022 -552.014
(176.641)** (183.440)**
chile -349.210 -341.593
(108.902)** (113.087)**
costaric -6.930 -6.817
(1.996)** (2.009)**
columbia -713.134 -697.760
(222.518)** (231.021)**
domrep -87.400 -85.466
(27.236)** (28.298)**
ecuador -311.446 -304.678
(97.045)** (100.620)**
elsalvad -4.034 -3.972
(1.322)** (1.373)**
guatemal -143.945 -140.703
(44.887)** (46.714)**
guyana 42.214 41.171
(13.098)** (13.665)**
honduras -14.821 -14.587
(4.675)** (4.834)**
jamaica -4.486 -4.297
(1.843)* (1.757)*
mexico -64.124 -62.672
(20.087)** (20.741)**
nicaragu -11.826 -11.672
(7.443) (7.554)
panama -309.225 -302.524
(96.410)** (100.321)**
paraguay 32.169 31.527
(10.264)** (10.623)**
peru -425.025 -415.857
(132.750)** (137.792)**
suriname -196.197 -192.069
(64.030)** (66.382)**
trinitob 6.235 6.196
(1.887)** (1.987)**
uruguay -295.731 -289.356
(92.318)** (95.847)**
venezuel -132.268 -129.462
(41.364)** (43.005)**
Constant -0.690 -0.553 -115.785 -113.288
(0.369) (0.474) (36.309)** (37.604)**
Observations 185 185 185 185
Number of country 25 25 25 25
Standard errors in
parentheses
* significant at 5%; **
significant at 1%

60
In order to test the point at which the interaction effects of personal vote overtake

any influence left partisanship had in affecting budget surplus, I then run a linear

combination test, such that L + L*Personal Vote*.1 = 0, and the result is not statistically

significant. I then run a second linear combination test, this time with 0.2 rather than 0.1.

Once again, there is no statistical significance. I continue running the test, with the P>|z|

variable trending towards statistical significance, and finally reaching statistical

significance at 0.5 (with a value of 0.048). Given this information, it would seem as

though when electoral systems use personal vote to a moderate degree or more (starting

at 0.5 on the scale from 0 to 1, with 1 being a completely personal-vote-oriented system),

any effect that left may have had on budget surpluses would diminish, with personal vote

instead the cause of larger budget surpluses. Recall that left partisanship was statistically

insignificant for affecting budget surplus both in this run and in the previous run that

excluded the potential interaction effects of personal vote.

Table 6: Linear Combination Test Showing Personal Vote Interaction Effects in the
Model with Budget Surplus
PV Value Coefficient Std. Err. z P>|z| [95% Conf. Interval]
.1 .1889635 1.025667 0.18 0.854 -1.821307 2.199234
.2 -8202265 1.053178 -0.78 0.436 -2.884418 1.243965
.3 -1.829416 1.258792 -1.45 0.146 -4.296603 .6377704
.4 -2.838606 1.574202 -1.80 0.071 -5.923985 .2467719
.5 -3.847796 1.946752 -1.98 0.048* -7.663361 -.0322319
.6 -4.856986 2.349417 -2.07 0.039* -9.461759 -.2522138
.7 -5.866176 2.769089 -2.12 0.034* -11.29349 -.4388609
.8 -.875366 3.199083 -2.15 0.032* -13.14545 -.6052786
.9 -.884556 3.635738 -2.17 0.030* -15.01047 -.7586408
1 -.893746 4.076914 -2.18 0.029* -16.88435 -.9031413
* significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%

I then include the personal vote variable in the model’s examination of the

relationship between left partisanship and economic growth. Here the left coefficient is

positive though statistically insignificant. Personal vote is also positive but insignificant.

61
I then add year dummy variables. In this instance left is both positive and approaches

statistical significance with a P>|z| of 0.086, and personal vote is also positive but

statistically insignificant. There is negative statistical significance at 1% for 1989 and

1990 and at 5% for 1995. I then add country dummy variables, such that there are both

year and country dummy variables in the regression. Here, the left coefficient is positive

and very statistically significant at 1%. Personal vote is highly negative but statistically

insignificant. 1989 and 1990 are again negative and statistically significant at 1% and

1995 is negative and statistically significant at 5%. Interestingly, there is no country

statistical significance. I then regress the model with only country dummy variables.

The left coefficient is positive and highly statistically significant, indicating again a

positive relationship between left governance and economic growth, which my

hypothesis did not predict. However, there is no statistical significance at the country

level. Personal vote is again negative and insignificant. Based on these findings, left

does appear as statistically significant in positive affecting growth (a finding not

confirmed when personal vote was excluded, see Table 2). But given the highly negative

and significant coefficient of L*P, introduction of personal vote may diminish left

partisanship’s positive effects on growth.

Table 7: Left’s Effects on Growth When Interacting with Personal Vote


Regressed first alone, then with year dummies, then year and country dummies, then country dummies
growth (1) (2) (3) (4)
GDP Growth
left 0.714 0.764 2.802 2.753
(0.518) (0.445) (1.062)** (1.119)*
Personal Vote 1.215 1.155 -253.178 -151.863
(0.851) (0.850) (533.809) (641.677)
Left*Personal Vote -8.481 -7.899 -25.736 -27.971
(4.735) (4.512) (8.998)** (9.100)**
L. GDP Growth 0.384 0.381 0.208 0.210
(0.126)** (0.129)** (0.137) (0.138)
y89 -1.936 -1.855

62
(0.662)** (0.537)**
y90 -1.952 -1.879
(0.624)** (0.580)**
y91 -0.515 -0.730
(0.701) (0.531)
y92 -0.283 -0.210
(0.686) (0.574)
y93 -1.186 -0.972
(0.708) (0.647)
y94 -0.031 0.098
(0.738) (0.629)
y95 -2.261 -1.895
(0.941)* (0.794)*
y96 -1.050 -1.123
(0.945) (0.751)
bahamas -4.079 -3.468
(3.326) (3.967)
barbados -4.202 -3.500
(3.396) (4.005)
belize 4.674 3.251
(7.813) (9.288)
bolivia -3.947 -2.317
(8.194) (9.752)
brazil 128.954 76.689
(275.355) (331.000)
chile 85.141 52.306
(173.117) (208.077)
costaric 0.797 0.554
(2.292) (2.773)
columbia 165.742 99.278
(350.214) (420.977)
domrep 20.580 12.272
(43.846) (52.682)
ecuador 79.515 51.066
(156.623) (187.979)
elsalvad 1.278 0.971
(2.100) (2.365)
guatemal 33.549 19.637
(70.572) (84.900)
guyana -11.963 -7.219
(24.549) (29.282)
honduras 2.202 1.086
(5.897) (7.085)
jamaica -0.681 -0.922
(3.286) (3.808)
mexico 15.864 10.207
(32.270) (38.839)
nicaragu -0.896 -1.905
(2.094) (2.642)
panama 74.311 45.542
(153.190) (183.916)
paraguay -7.830 -4.994
(14.936) (17.951)

63
peru 100.355 60.902
(209.748) (252.042)
suriname 47.941 29.767
(96.483) (115.695)
trinitob -3.959 -3.341
(3.759) (4.293)
uruguay 68.309 40.751
(145.196) (174.536)
venezuel 29.627 17.188
(64.118) (77.194)
Constant 2.137 3.172 31.099 19.403
(0.642)** (0.707)** (56.621) (68.115)
Observations 195 195 195 195
Number of country 25 25 25 25
Standard errors in parentheses
* significant at 5%; **
significant at 1%

To determine the degree of personal vote at which it begins to diminish left

partisanship’s effects on growth, I again run a linear combination test, beginning at 0.1

and ending at 1. The interaction becomes significant at .2, and is highly significant from .

3 on with statistical significance at 1%. The importance of these findings is noteworthy.

When the value for personal vote reaches even the most negligible of levels (with the

minimal personal vote value of 0.2), I find that personal vote interacts with left’s effects

on growth in a sharply negative direction, with a reported statistically significant

coefficient on L*P of -25.736 (see Table 7). Interestingly, the coefficient of the personal

vote variable was insignificant in each of the regressions ran, which contrasts sharply

with the regressions run on the budget surplus variable. There, we saw personal vote’s

effects to be statistically significant and left’s effects to be statistically insignificant

(though they trended towards greater deficits). While left partisanship is shown in this

case to be statistically significant for generating more economic growth (in particular

with year and country dummy variables included—see Table 7), the sharply negative and

statistically significant interaction effects of the personal vote on left partisanship

64
indicates that personal vote, even at minimal levels, greatly decreases the degree to which

left partisanship is a cause for that higher growth.

Table 8: Linear Combination Test Showing Personal Vote Interaction Effects in the
Model With GDP Growth
PV Value Coefficient Std. Err. z P>|z| [95% Conf. Interval]
.1 -.044203 .8466665 -0.05 0.958 -1.703639 1.615233
.2 -2.841325 1.355517 -2.10 0.036* -5.498091 -.1845599
.3 -5.638448 2.148111 -2.62 0.009** -9.848667 -1.428228
.4 -8.43557 3.00794 -2.80 0.005** -14.33102 -2.540116
.5 -11.23269 3.89068 -2.89 0.004** -18.85829 -3.607099
.6 -14.02981 4.783665 -2.93 0.003** -23.40563 -4.654003
.7 -16.82694 5.682067 -2.96 0.003** -27.96358 -5.690291
.8 -19.62406 6.583668 -2.98 0.003** -32.52781 -6.720308
.9 -22.42118 7.487312 -2.99 0.003** -37.09604 -7.746319
1 -25.2183 8.392341 -3.00 0.003** -41.66699 -8.769619
* significant at 5%; ** significant at 1%

I then take the personal vote factor into consideration in regards to the

relationship between left partisanship and inflation. Here the left coefficient is positive,

and just shy of statistically significance with a P>|z| of 0.057. Personal vote is also

positive and statistically significant. I then add year dummy variables. In this instance

left is again positive and approaches statistical significance with a P>|z| of 0.079 and

personal vote is again positive and statistically significant. There is negative significance

at 5% for 1989 and 1% for 1993 and positive significance for 1990 at 1%. I then add

country dummy variables, such that both year and country dummy variables are included

in the regression. Here, the left coefficient is negative and statistically insignificant.

Personal vote is highly significant and highly positive, indicating a substantial effect on

personal vote on increased inflation. 1990, 1991, and 1992, are positive and statistically

significant, while 1993 and 1996 are negative and statistically significant. There was

positive country significance for Bahamas, Barbados, Bolivia, Guyana, Nicaragua,

65
Panama, and Trinidad and Tobago, and negative country significance for Belize, Brazil,

Chile, Colombia, Dominican Republic, Ecuador, Guatemala, Mexico, Panama, Peru, and

Uruguay. I then run a regression of the model with only country dummy variables. Here,

the coefficient of left partisanship is negative and statistically insignificant. Personal vote

is again highly significant and highly positive. At the country level, statistical

significance remains for those listed in the previous regression. Left partisanship does

not appear to affect inflation with any degree of statistical significance, and while

personal vote does not appear to alter the effects of left partisanship on inflation, personal

vote was highly correlated and statistically significant for increased inflation.

Table 9: Left’s Effects on Inflation When Interacting with Personal Vote


Regressed first alone, then with year dummies, then year and country dummies, then country dummies
lncpi (1) (2) (3) (4)
Natural Log Consumer
Price Index
left 0.253 0.231 -0.217 -0.157
(0.133) (0.132) (0.272) (0.268)
Personal vote 0.445 0.427 92.691 102.337
(0.195)* (0.188)* (21.587)** (6.725)**
Left*Personal Vote 0.077 0.078 1.135 1.225
(0.509) (0.418) (0.699) (0.885)
L. NL CPI 0.336 0.351 0.102 0.108
(0.072)** (0.067)** (0.087) (0.100)
y89 -0.179 -0.067
(0.072)* (0.049)
y90 0.212 0.273
(0.036)** (0.037)**
y91 0.067 0.177
(0.064) (0.073)*
y92 0.149 0.236
(0.089) (0.071)**
y93 -0.369 -0.263
(0.087)** (0.068)**
y94 -0.080 -0.095
(0.090) (0.059)
y95 -0.036 -0.053
(0.042) (0.044)
y96 -0.061 -0.068
(0.052) (0.011)**
bahamas 0.737 0.794
(0.140)** (0.075)**

66
barbados 0.820 0.856
(0.154)** (0.067)**
belize -1.442 -1.576
(0.395)** (0.284)**
bolivia 1.880 1.994
(0.430)** (0.293)**
brazil -46.976 -51.955
(11.161)** (3.505)**
chile -29.409 -32.536
(7.002)** (2.192)**
costaric 0.168 0.089
(0.295) (0.288)
columbia -60.132 -66.462
(14.180)** (4.438)**
domrep -6.535 -7.330
(1.811)** (0.622)**
ecuador -26.085 -28.982
(6.299)** (1.913)**
elsalvad -0.038 -0.066
(0.075) (0.050)
guatemal -11.693 -12.852
(2.755)** (0.979)**
guyana 4.973 5.339
(0.994)** (0.278)**
honduras -0.296 -0.405
(0.375) (0.291)
jamaica 0.486 0.372
(0.295) (0.267)
mexico -4.704 -5.360
(1.338)** (0.524)**
nicaragu 0.989 0.968
(0.272)** (0.294)**
panama -27.780 -30.477
(6.057)** (1.860)**
paraguay 3.304 3.572
(0.601)** (0.202)**
peru -35.590 -39.397
(8.486)** (2.637)**
suriname -17.119 -18.821
(3.532)** (1.881)**
trinitob 1.078 1.119
(0.547)* (0.539)*
uruguay -24.479 -27.106
(5.924)** (1.952)**
venezuel -10.151 -11.268
(2.670)** (0.897)**
Constant 2.671 2.648 -6.519 -7.549
(0.307)** (0.268)** (2.469)** (1.015)**
Observations 195 195 195 195
Number of country 25 25 25 25
Standard errors in
parentheses
* significant at 5%;

67
** significant at 1%

To determine the degree of personal vote at which it begins to affect inflation with

statistical significance, I again run a linear combination test, beginning at 0.1 and ending

at 1. Interestingly, the interaction becomes highly significant at .3, but then trends

towards statistical insignificance and loses significance at 0.7, indicating significance

only at moderate levels of personal vote usage, but insignificance in instances of extreme

personal vote or very little personal vote. Given the above data from Table 9, the

personal vote variable is both positive and statistically significant for its effects on

inflation indicating that instances of personal vote led to increased inflation. When

combined with the results from the linear combination test, it appears as though the

personal vote has a significant, positive effect on inflation, though only when personal

vote appears at moderate levels (from 0.3 until 0.7).

Table 10: Linear Combination Test Showing Personal Vote Interaction Effects in the
Model with Inflation
PV Value Coefficient Std. Err. z P>|z| [95% Conf. Interval]
.1 -.0349526 .1822687 -0.19 0.848 -.3921926 .3222875
.2 .087535 .1014999 0.86 0.388 -.1114012 .2864712
.3 .2100226 .0551729 3.81 0.000 .1018857 .3181594
.4 .3325101 .106992 3.11 0.002 .1228096 .5422107
.5 .4549977 .1884462 2.41 0.016 .0856498 .8243455
.6 .5774853 .2742957 2.11 0.035 .0398756 1.115095
.7 .6999728 .3614218 1.94 0.053 -.0084008 1.408346
.8 .8224604 .4490821 1.83 0.067 -.0577243 1.702645
.9 .9449479 .5370151 1.76 0.078 -.1075822 1.997478
1 1.067436 .6251056 1.71 0.088 -.157749 2.29262

Summary of Findings
Based on the preceding analysis, my hypothesis is proven partially correct when

personal vote is excluded from the model. Left partisanship did not turn out to be

statistically significant with the budget surplus variable, which was a proxy for economic

68
policy. So it cannot be determined from this study that left partisanship does indeed lead

to substantively different economic policy than center or right governments. However,

left partisanship did appear to have a statistically significant positive effect on inflation, a

finding which supports my hypothesis. There was some limited evidence of left

partisanship leading to decreased growth within certain years and countries, which would

support my hypothesis. However, this finding was not replicated on the aggregate, and I

cannot argue that left partisanship conclusively leads to lower growth rates.

When testing the conditioned model that included the personal vote variable, my

hypothesis was largely refuted. While left partisanship had no discernable effect on

increased budget surpluses, personal vote systems were correlated with statistical

significance to larger budget surpluses. Additionally, in terms of growth, I actually found

a positive relationship between left governance and economic growth, both without

dummy variables and with year dummy variables. This finding directly contradicts my

hypothesis. However, when personal vote was introduced to the model at low non-zero

values, the degree to which left partisanship was the cause of that higher growth greatly

decreased. Personal vote itself had a negative but statistically insignificant effect on

growth, but it did decrease sharply the degree to which left partisanship was the cause of

that growth. In regards to inflation, left partisanship did not appear to affect inflation

with any degree of statistical significance, and the personal vote did not appear to alter

either negatively or positively the effects of left partisanship on inflation with any degree

of statistical significance. However, personal vote was highly correlated and statistically

significant for increased inflation across all four regressions, indicating that personal vote

does lead to higher inflation. Interestingly, this finding was significant from a personal

69
vote range of 0.3 to 0.7, indicating that personal vote positively affected inflation only at

moderate levels. When personal vote took a value from 0 to 0.2 or from 0.8 until 1, it

was not statistically significant for increasing inflation.

70
CHAPTER 5: Concluding Remarks

The discussion of partisan’s effects on economic performance in Latin America is

a pressing one, for the region is one marked by severe income inequality, with a poor

population remaining quite sympathetic to socialist and redistributionist rhetoric. In

determining the effects that left partisanship has had on economic performance in the

region, the results could indicate whether left governments remain destructive as

demonstrated in the past (the rule of the Unidad Popular in Chile is a fitting example), or

can govern in such a way as to continue and strengthen the upward trajectory of growth

that countries of the region need in order to bring their citizens closer to first-world

lifestyles. From my analysis of the history of development in Latin America, we see that

left governments have at times been destructive, but that they have begrudgingly moved

towards greater economic liberalization during the past few decades. Yet, it remained

unclear as to whether that liberalization was occurring with the same fervor and degree of

action as we would expect to see under right-controlled governments. Coupled with the

sound theories and explanations provided by scholars regarding partisanship’s effects on

economic performance in OECD countries, there remained a substantial gap in regards to

how left governments should perform both theoretically and empirically, particularly in

the context of Latin America. This study sought to at least partially fill that gap.

The findings from my data indicate that both sides of the argument on

partisanship have some merit. Those arguing that left partisanship does indeed negatively

affect economic outcomes would be vindicated by my findings of statistical significance

for left governance leading to higher inflation. The Hibbsian worldview was also

71
vindicated by my findings that left governance was, at least in some instances, proven

statistically significant with higher growth (though this finding does admittedly disagree

with my original hypothesis). It is important to note, however, that this finding only

came about after including personal vote as an additional variable interacting in the

model (this will be discussed in greater detail momentarily). In regards to left

partisanship’s effects on budget surpluses, a proxy for economic policy that would help

us determine if indeed the left was engaging in more redistribution, the data was

insignificant. While there was a negative relationship between left partisanship and the

budget surpluses, indicating the possibility of a relationship between increased left power

and higher budget deficits, these findings were not statistically significant. [Insert

remarks regarding effect of left on unemployment here].

The introduction of the personal vote variable into the model produced some

unexpected and interesting results. Personal vote systems were found to be significant

with higher budget surpluses, but only when the electoral system had at least a moderate

score for personal vote (0.5 or above). Personal vote systems were found to be

insignificant in regards to growth, but were found significant for diminishing any positive

effects on growth that left partisanship may have had when reaching or exceeding a value

of just 0.2. And the personal vote variable was found to be highly significant for higher

inflation. But that claim comes with a twist, as the interaction effects of introducing

personal vote only became significant for moderate levels of personal vote (between 0.3

and 0.7), but not for either high or low extremes. It is interesting to posit the reasons as

to why this could be so. Perhaps by virtue of the nature of personal vote systems,

whereby politicians must appeal directly to individual voters—or perhaps the median

72
voter—these politicians must engage in more redistributionist activity simply because the

median voter supports policies such as government redistribution even as these policies

have been confirmed empirically as an ineffective long-term strategy for sustained

positive economic performance. However, this conclusion is tempered by the knowledge

that my analysis proved insignificant for the effects of left governance on budget

surpluses, as I cannot conclude with any level of certainty that these left governments are

systematically spending more money and generating higher deficits than their right-

controlled counterparts. Perhaps there are additional metrics that could be better suited to

analyzing the intricacies of economic policy beyond budget balance. I acknowledge the

use of only one variable as a proxy for economic outcomes as a limitation of this study.

In terms of the finding that the personal vote variable was statistically significant

for higher inflation only for moderate degrees of personal vote, a certain intuitive logic

may be buried in those findings. Perhaps in instances of a minimal personal vote score

(0.2 or below), left partisans would simply enact policies within limits brought about by

the structural dependence of capital, such that these policies would bear striking

similarity to the policies of their right-leaning counterparts. And in instances of moderate

personal vote (with a score from 0.3 to 0.7), perhaps the higher inflation occurred as a

result of appeals to the median voter (who may support redistributive economic policies)

tempered by partisan notions of engaging in economic action limited by the state’s

dependence on capital. Finally, in instances of extreme personal vote (with a score from

0.8 to 1), higher inflation may have been insignificant because even as the party line

became decreasingly significant and the median voter decreased in importance,

politicians engaging in clientelistic policy may have actually implemented policies that

73
led to positive economic performance. Yet these explanations are mere conjecture.

Further study is undoubtedly warranted in order to better understand the subtle nuances

with which personal vote interacts with partisan control over the direction of economic

policy and performance.

My study was additionally limited by a number of factors. Firstly, the data set

from which I have been operating examines Latin America from 1988 to 1997. However,

more recent data is available. Additional studies on this topic would do well to analyze

these effects over more extended periods of time, potentially from 1988 until the most

recent years for which data is available, typically 2005 or 2006. The notion of increasing

the time-span of the study becomes increasingly relevant given the rise of socialist

governments in Venezuela, Ecuador, and Bolivia. An investigation of the performance of

these left-oriented partisan governments compared with other left-oriented governments

that do not specifically proscribe to socialist ideology may lead to interesting results, as

different types of left-oriented governments (with some proscribing socialism and others

proscribing greater liberalism) could potentially behave in systematically different

manners both in terms of their economic policy choices and in terms of macroeconomic

outcomes. It is conceivable that socialist governments support more redistributionist

policies than other left-controlled governments following a more comparatively

conservative tract, and such a notion is worthy of further research.

The study also may have benefited from the inclusion of additional metrics as

proxies for economic policy. It remains to be seen if left partisanship really does have an

effect on economic policy in Latin America; my data was not statistically significant but

did consistently trend towards negative budget balances. Future studies would do well to

74
include additional metrics of economic policy in conducting such analysis. Also, future

testing might benefit from a more detailed coding of parties, perhaps with left as -1,

center as 0, and right as 1, in order to better understand the distinctions between the three

ideological orientations of governments. And indeed, perhaps certain socialist-oriented

leftist-controlled governments are worthy of their own codification as well. Additionally,

my data for unemployment only examined urban unemployment, but there remains a

substantial rural poor in Latin America. Future studies might do well to analyze the

policies and partisanship of the left for both urban unemployment and unemployment as a

whole.

There are a number of additional directions I urge scholars to follow in continuing

to analyze the role of partisanship in shaping macroeconomic performance. Future

analyses of Latin America would benefit from a more rigorous analytical approach, such

as the one encompassed by Bill Clark and described in Chapter 3—namely, it would be

useful to include variables such as central bank independence, exchange rate regime, and

degree of capital account liberalization, in order to determine if any of these variables

have intervening effects on the relationship between partisanship and economic

performance. Additionally, a test of the SDC hypothesis might be useful for Latin

America as well, for labor movements certainly have played a broad history in shaping

the economy of the region. Moreover, it may be worthwhile to directly analyze the

importance of the median voter to the government’s economic decision-making, rather

than merely make conjecture as this thesis does. Future studies may determine that all of

the preceding suggestions pale in regards to the whims of the median voter; this question

75
is indisputably deserving of exploration in greater depth, and in regards to Latin America

in particular.

The findings of this study certainly have broader implications for Latin America.

If left governments do indeed lead to higher growth but also higher inflation, then

citizens electing officials must determine the macroeconomic outcomes most favorable to

them and to their nation as a whole, making a tradeoff between higher growth or lower

inflation. Importantly, there are also substantial implications of the notion that personal

vote has intervening effects in this analysis. Governments seeking to limit negative

economic outcomes such as high inflation and negative budget deficits might construct

electoral systems limiting the personal vote, such that voters vote for political party rather

than for individual politicians. And of course, the implementation of less personal-vote-

centric systems must be evaluated in terms of the tradeoffs that would occur as a result of

leaving behind such systems—increased party control and homogenization, and

potentially less responsiveness between government action and the true will of the voters.

The discussion regarding the role of partisanship’s influence on economic

performance, both in Latin America and in regards to the world at large, remains robust

and a salient topic of both academic and political debate. The findings in this piece were

not altogether conclusive, and further research must surely be done to better analyze the

ways in which the partisan orientation of government interacts with economic

performance, in particular in Latin America. But perhaps this piece will nevertheless

serve as an addition to the literature in demonstrating that under certain conditions,

partisanship can play a role in shaping economic performance in Latin America. And

importantly, this piece raises several questions regarding the ways in which electoral

76
systems such as personal vote ballots interact in with partisan goals and economic

decision-making. Scholars analyzing Latin America, other emerging markets, or even

primarily OECD countries would do well to take note of the possible implications of the

personal vote ballot’s effects on macroeconomic performance when engaging in future

research into this field of study.

77
BIBLIOGRAPHY

Alvarez, R. Michael et al. Government Partisanship, Labor Organization, and


Macroeconomic Performance. The American Political Science Review, Vol. 85,
No. 2 (Jun., 1991), p. 542, 544, 549, 551.

Baer, Werner. Import Substitution and Industrialization in Latin America: Experiences


and Interpretations. Latin American Research Review, Vol. 7, No. 1, (Spring,
1972), p. 101.

Brohman, John. Popular Development: Rethinking the Theory and Practice of


Development. Blackwell Publishing, 1996, p. 53. (accessed February 20, 2009
scholar.google.com)

Brooks, Sarah M. Explaining Capital Account Liberalization in Latin America: A


Traditional Cost Approach. World Politics 56 (April 2004), p. 408, 421, 424.

Calderón-Madrid, Angel. Currency Crises and Institutional Changes in Latin America:


Lessons from Mexico. Presented at the Conference Euro and the Dollar, Coral
Gables, FL, April 2006, p. 2.

Central Intelligence Agency World Factbook. Rank Order – life expectancy at birth.
https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-
factbook/rankorder/2102rank.html (access January 17, 2009)

CIA World Factbook, Rank Order – GDP – per capita (PPP)


https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-
factbook/rankorder/2004rank.html

Central Intelligence Agency. The World Factbook—Field Listing – Distribution of


Family Income – Gini Index. CIA World Factbook, April 15, 2008. Accessed
April 21, 2008 https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-
factbook/fields/2172.html

Clark, William Roberts. Capitalism, Not Globalism: Capital Mobility, Central Bank
Independence, and the Political Control of the Economy. University of Michigan
Press, Ann Arbor, 2003, p. 105, 117, 118, 125, 139, 140.

Clark, William Roberts. Chapter 9, Does Democracy Make a Difference? Untitled. CQ


Press, 2008, p. 319.

Corbo, Vittorio. Problemas, Teoría del Desarrollo y Estrategias en América Latina.


Estudios Públicos, 32 (primavera 1988), pp. 12-13.

78
Cousiño Valdés, Carlos. Populism and Political Radicalism During the Unidad Popular
Government (translated from Spanish). Estudios Públicos, 82 (autumn 2001), pp.
12-13.

Dornbusch, Rudiger and Edwards, Sebastian. Macroeconomic Populism in Latin


America. National Bureau of Economic Development, Cambridge, MA, May
1989, p. 6, 8, 10, 54.

Downs, Anthony. Why the Government Budget is Too Small in a Democracy. World
Politics, Vol. 12, No. 4, (Jul., 1960), p. 546.

Drake, P. (1982) "Conclusion: Requiem for Populism?" in Conniff, M. L. (Ed) Latin


American Populism in Comparative Perspective, Albuquerque, University of New
Mexico Press.

Franko, Patrice M. The Puzzle of Latin American Economic Development. Rowman &
Littlefield, 2007, p. 59. (accessed February 20, 2009 scholar.google.com)

Garrett, Geoffrey. Partisan Politics in the Global Economy. Cambridge Univ. Press,
New York, 1998.

Hallerberg, Mark and Marier, Patrick. Executive Authority, the Personal Vote, and
Budget Discipline in Latin American and Caribbean Countries, American Journal
of Political Science, Vol. 48, No. 3 (Jul. 2004), p. 580.

Hellwig, Timothy T. Interdependence, Government Constraints, and Economic Voting.


The Journal of Politics, Vol. 63, No. 4 (Nov., 2001), p. 1146.

Hibbs, Douglas A., Jr. Political Parties and Macroeconomic Policy. The American
Political Science Review, Vol. 71, No. 4 (Dec., 1977), p. 1467-8, 1475.

Hira, Anil. Did ISI fail and is neoliberalism the answer for Latin America? Re-assessing
common wisdom regarding economic policies in the region. Brazilian Journal of
Political Economy, Vol. 27 no. 3, Sao Paulo, July/Sept. 2007.

Hirschman, A.O. 1961. “Ideologies of Economic Development in Latin America”. In


A.O. Hirschman (ed.). Latin America Issues: Essays and Comments. New York:
Twentieth Century Fund, Inc.

Hoffman, Kelly and Angel Centeno, Miguel. The Lopsided Continent: Inequality in
Latin America. Annual Review of Sociology, Vol. 29, 2003, p. 367.

Kaufman, Robert R. and Segura-Ubiergo, Alex. Globalization, Domestic Politics, and


Social Spending in Latin America: A Time-Series Cross-Section Analysis, 1973-
97. World Politics 53 (July 2001), p. 580.

79
Klarén, Peter F. and Bossert, Thomas J. Promise of Development: Theories of Change in
Latin America. Westview Press, 1986, p. 15. (accessed February 19, 2009
scholar.google.com)

Maddison, A. 1982. Phases of Capitalist Development. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

Mainwaring, Scott and Shugart, Matthew Soburg. Presidentialism and Democracy in


Latin America, Cambridge University Press, 1997, p. 13.

Marx, Karl. Wage-labour and Capital: Value, Price and Profit. International Publishers
Co, 1935. Books.google.com (accessed January 30, 2009)

Meltzer, Allan H. & Richard, Scott F. A Rational Theory of the Size of Government.
The Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 89, No. 5 (Oct., 1981), p. 914-6, 924.

Murillo, M. Victoria. Political Bias in Policy Convergence: Privatization Choices in


Latin America. World Politics 54 (July 2002), p. 469.

Przeworski, Adam and Wallerstein, Michael. Structural Dependence of the State on


Capital. The American Political Science Review, Vol. 82, No. 1 (Mar., 1988) p. 11-
12, 21, 23.

Scharpf, Fritz W. Economic and Institutional Constraints of Full-Employment Strategies:


Sweden, Austria, and West Germany, 1974-1982. In Order and Conflict in
Contemporary Capitalism, ed. John H. Goldthorpe, Clarendon Publishing, Oxford,
1984.

Schmidt, Henry. The Mexican Foreign Debt and the Sexennial Transition from López
Portillo de la Madrid. Mexican Studies / Estudios Mexicanos. Vol. 1, No. 2,
(Summer, 1985), pp. 229-30.

Silk, Leonard. Brazil’s Battle Against Banks. New York Times, March 4, 1987 (accessed
February 20, 2009 nytimes.com)

Walter, Matthew. Chile, Seeking First-World Status, Tackles Santiago River Mess.
Bloomberg.com, May 17, 2007 (accessed February 17, 2009
http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?
pid=20601087&sid=aXT9fzUY3Ti0&refer=home)

Washington Consensus. Center for International Development, Harvard University, April


2003 (accessed February 20, 2009
http://www.cid.harvard.edu/cidtrade/issues/washington.html)

80

You might also like