You are on page 1of 6

American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 2016, 106(5): 472–477

http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.p20161112

HIV/AIDS and Development: A Reappraisal of the Productivity


and Factor Accumulation Effects†
By Théophile T. Azomahou, Raouf Boucekkine, and Bity Diene*

Besides the dreadful direct effects, enduring reduces the profitability of schooling, leading to
epidemics like HIV/AIDS induce much more a decline of human capital accumulation in the
subtle effects in the economy, principally via medium and long run. Boucekkine, de la Croix,
labor productivity and factor accumulation. and Licandro (2002) have proposed a theory of
Concerning the former, the impact of morbid- endogenous growth based on the Ben-Porath
ity on effective labor has been recognized and mechanism. Notice also that the same essential
accounted for since the early work of Over argument (that shorter time horizons discourage
(1992) and Cuddington and Hancock (1994). investment) can be applied to physical capital
The impact of mortality shocks on savings, accumulation; the latter may collapse not only
and therefore on factor accumulation, has also because of the massive increase in health expen-
been documented in this early literature, with an ditures undermining savings as in the early liter-
emphasis on the detrimental role of the induced ature but also via this indirect mechanism. Both
health expenditures. Recently, Asiedu, Jin, and channels are taken into account by Freire (2004)
Kanyama (2015) show that HIV/AIDS has a in her analysis of saving behavior in South Africa
negative but diminishing effect on foreign direct after the outbreak of the HIV/AIDS crisis.
investment (FDI), and this adverse effect occurs This paper proposes a reappraisal of the eco-
even when the prevalent HIV rate is low. In con- nomic growth cost of HIV/AIDS accounting,
trast, the consequences of HIV/AIDS on human among others, for Ben-Porath-type effects on
capital accumulation have been more rarely labor productivity and factor accumulation. We
treated. In particular, its impact on schooling use an economico-epidemiological Solow-Swan
time has been generally omitted in the macro- model. Mortality and morbidity effects on effec-
economic literature. Ferreira, Pessôa, and Dos tive labor are taken into account. The Ben-Porath
Santos (2011) is an exception. The inherent mechanism affects the dynamics of the saving
mechanism is known as the Ben-Porath mech- rate and reduces labor productivity (which is a
anism (Ben-Porath 1967): a downward trend useful shortcut to the decline of human capital
in life expectancy following mortality shocks accumulation). The main contribution of the
paper is the application to South Africa. Based
on optimal projections of the demographic
* Azomahou: UNU-MERIT, Maastricht University (including HIV prevalence rates) and economic
and CERDI, Boschstraat 24, 6211 AX Maastricht, (including saving rates, based on the work of
The Netherlands (e-mail: azomahou@merit.unu.edu);
Boucekkine: Aix-Marseille University (AMSE), CNRS Freire 2004) South African series for the period
and EHESS, 2 rue de la Charité, 13002 Marseille, France 2000–2050, two main and novel findings are
(e-mail: raouf.boucekkine@univ-amu.fr); Diene: CERDI, presented. First, we identify a delayed effect of
65 Boulevard F. Mitterrand, 63009 Clermont-Ferrand, HIV/AIDS on economic growth: the growth rate
France (e-mail: bity.diene@udamail.fr). We gratefully gap between the AIDS and no-AIDS scenarios is
acknowledge insightful discussions with Elizabeth Asiedu.
This work was supported by the FERDI (Fondation pour les rather stable between 2010 and 2020, but then it
Etudes et Recherches sur le Developpement International) increases sharply between 2020 and 2030, keeps
and the Agence Nationale de la Recherche of the French increasing at a much lower pace between 2030
government through the program “Investissements d’avenir and 2040, and finally stabilizes after 2040. Most
of the related papers (e.g., Ferreira, Pessôa, and
ANR-10-LABX-14-01.”

Go to http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.p20161112 to visit
the article page for additional materials and author disclo- Dos Santos 2011; or Corrigan, Glomm, and
sure statement(s). Mendez 2005), based on comparative statics
472
VOL. 106 NO. 5 HIV/AIDS AND DEVELOPMENT 473

of steady state equilibria, cannot deliver such a where pans indicates the active population
picture. Second, we identify the impact of the without HIV/AIDS by age and sex, u is the
different demographic mechanisms; in partic- number of unemployed people by age and sex,
ular, we find that while the fall in active pop- and h is the number of hours worked in a year.2
ulation is the main factor behind the AIDS The basic economico-epidemiological pro-
impact on economic growth during the decade duction function above is further extended in
2020–2030, the Ben-Porath mechanism on labor two essential directions. First, the morbidity
productivity seems more relevant in the last term, xi, f (t) , is assumed to depend on health
decade, physical capital accumulation playing a expenditures devoted to fighting HIV/AIDS.
minor role. Accordingly, for given AIDS-specific health
expenditures mi, f (t) , xi, f (t) is determined by
I. The Economico-Epidemiological Model
xi, f (t) = Φ(mi, f (t)),
The framework is a Solow-Swan model in the
tradition of Cuddington and Hancock (1994). where function Φ ( · ) is decreasing. This is
The aggregate production function at time t is largely consistent with Corrigan, Glomm, and
given by Mendez (2005), who argued that health expen-
ditures improve the productivity of the infected
Y (t) = A (t) K(t) θ E(t) 1−θ, people. In contrast to the latter work, where
health expenditures are determined by individ-
where Y (t) denotes the total output (or GDP) of ual choices, we shall use real health expendi-
the economy, A (t) the total factor productivity tures data. In the implementation, we have faced
(TFP,) K (t) the physical capital, and E (t) the a data unavailability problem. Instead of the
effective labor, θ being the capital share. E (t) intended indicators Φ(mi, f (t)) , we have been
is age-structured and gender-structured as it forced to use Φ(m (t)) , where m (t) is given by
should be since epidemics do not affect all age
the relation: m (t) = txHIV _ t M
and gender classes in the same way:1 where txHIV
HIV +
represents the percentage of AIDS-related
(1) E (t) = ∑[1 − ϕi, f (t) xi, f (t)] %i, f (t) Li, f (t) ,
expenditures in the total health expenditures
i, f (Mt), and HIV + is the number of infected people.
As in Corrigan, Glomm, and Mendez (2005),
where i stands for the age index, f = 1, 2 the we pick the following analytical for Φ ( · ):
gender class, and Li, f (t) is labor services provided
by individuals of age class i and gender f. ζ
%i, f (t) captures labor-specific productivity for (2) Φ(m (t)) = 1 − ψ1 + (ψ1 − ψ0) _ ,
m (t) + ζ
age class i and gender f , and in this sense, it
could be interpreted as a human capital indicator. with: Φ (0) = 1 − ψ0 , limx→∞ Φ (x) = 1 − ψ1 ,
xi, f (t) reflects morbidity at age class i and 0 < ψ0 < ψ1 < 1 , Φ′(x) < 0, and Φ′′(x) > 0;
gender f ; a larger xi, f (t) amounts to a lower ψ1 , ψ0, and ζ are positive productivity
effective labor effort due to morbidity. Finally, parameters.3
the production function includes a term ϕi, f (t) , Second, we introduce the Ben-Porath effect
which stands for the AIDS prevalence rate at and model it as follows. We start with the tradi-
date t for age class i and gender f. In the no-AIDS tional modeling of age and gender specific pro-
case, the prevalence rates are set to zero and E (t) ductivity (see Cuddington and Hancock 1994):
= ∑ i, f μi, f (t) Li, f (t) with Li, f (t) = ( pans − u ) h ,
(3) %i, f (t) = ρ1 + ρ2(i − i ) − ρ3(i − i ) ,
– – 2

1
We insist on dealing with gender here since a crucial
recent feature of HIV/AIDS in sub-Saharan Africa (and
2
notably in South Africa) is the increasing percentage of We use 49 weeks and 40 hours by week, that is
females affected. In its 2004 report, UNAIDS mentioned h = 1960.
that close to 60 percent of HIV/AIDS infected people are 3
In our numerical experiments, we fix ψ1 = 1 , ψ0 = 0.5 ,
females in sub-Saharan Africa, the youngest being the most and we let ζ vary from 1 to 10 , with ζ = 5 in the reference
exposed to the infection risk for obvious reasons. simulation, as in Corrigan, Glomm, and Mendez (2005).
474 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2016

where ρk , k = 1, 2, 3 and i are given positive series constructed by Freire (2004) for South

constants, the last being, for example, the min- Africa under the AIDS and no-AIDS scenario
imal age to work. Productivity is an inverse as the basis of our calibration and forecasting in
U-shaped function of age, maximal productiv- this respect. Freire’s model closely follows Galí
ρ2
ity being reached at age i + 2 _

. With a declin- (1990), a Blanchard-Yaari type of model, which
ρ3
ing life expectancy, such a magnitude is likely is more likely to capture the effects of increas-
to go down, not only mechanically but also via ing mortality on saving decisions than the arbi-
the Ben-Porath mechanism, according to which trary computation rule adopted by Cuddington
a decreasing life expectancy lowers schooling and Hancock (1994). It is worth pointing out
time, and therefore human capital and produc- that since the saving rate is not constant in our
tivity at work. We capture this mechanism by setting, there is no long-run steady state (and
assuming the following functional relationship: the inherent standard comparative statics) as in
Ferreira, Pessôa, and Dos Santos (2011).5

(4) ρ2 ≡ ρ2(i, f, t) = αi, f νi, f (t) β,


II. Application to South Africa

where νi, f (t) is the life expectancy at birth of A. Data and Variables
workers of age i (thus born at t − i) and of gen-
der f. αi, f and β are calibrated on real data. For The variables used include: (i) Economically
the calculation of ρ2 , we set for the reference active population, by age and sex (1980–2020);
year t = 0 , which corresponds to the year 2000, (ii) HIV-seroprevalence (1980–2015); (iii)
in the data, ρ2(i, f, t0) = αi νi, f (t) β = 0.005 for a HIV + (1990–2015) indicator; (iv) Life expec-
given β , then we calibrate αi = _ 0.005
, taking the tancy at birth by sex (1920–2015); (v) Total
νi, f (t)
β
health expenditure (1960–2000); (vi) Percentage
life expectancy series from the data. The deter-
expenditure of AIDS in total health expenditure
mination of αi allows us to determine the ρ2.4 β
(1960–2000); (vii) Unemployed by age and
is given values ranging from 0 (no Ben-Porath
sex (2000–2003); (viii) GDP per capita (1960–
mechanism) to 1 (a “linear” mechanism). The
2000); and (ix) Saving rates with and without
setup is completed by a capital accumulation
AIDS. See the online Appendix for further
equation:
details of these indicators and related sources.

(5) K (t) = s (t) Y (t) + (1 − δ) K (t − 1) , B. Estimation Strategy

Our estimation includes forecasting and the


where s (t) stands for the saving rate of the econ- projection of HIV prevalence. The forecast-
omy at date t and with the initial stock K0 given. ing needs first the estimation of the parame-
Cuddington and Hancock (1994) take the sav- ters of an assumed econometric specification
ing rate constant but retrieve a term xH (t) from underlying the data generating process. The
the right-hand side of equation (5), where H (t) estimation-forecasting method is applied to
stands for total health expenditures, and x is the all relevant variables of our model except HIV
fraction of these expenditures related to HIV/ prevalence, which is a specific epidemiological
AIDS. As correctly pointed out by Bloom and
Mahal (1997), health expenditures might be not
only detrimental to savings but also to consump-
tion (see a recent exploration into this import-
5
In our application, assuming an exogenously growing
1
__

( γ E2000 ) .
ant issue in Azomahou et al. 2015). To deal TFP at rate γ , K0 is computed by K0 = K2000 = _
Y2000 θ

with this crucial criticism, we use the general 0 1−θ

dynamic equation above with the saving rate The physical capital K (t) series is then obtained thanks to
the standard accumulation equation (5) with the saving rate
series constructed from Freire (2004). Moreover, to make
our results comparable with earlier findings, we use the same
4
We set the values of the other parameters as follows: parameter values as Corrigan, Glomm, and Mendez (2005):
ρ1 = 0.8 , ρ3 = − 0.0001. θ = 0.33 , γ = 0.012, and δ = 0.05.
VOL. 106 NO. 5 HIV/AIDS AND DEVELOPMENT 475

variable. To obtain the projected HIV preva- Panel A


lence, we fit a double logistic curve of the form 58
Actual mlifex
Median forecasts
56 95% confidence bands

[1 + e ] [1 + e ]
α(t−τ) −β(t−τ) 54
(6) p (t) = e
_
α(t−τ)
ae
_
β(t−τ)
+ b , 52
50
48
46
where α is the initial growth rate, a denotes the 44
peak value, β is the rate of convergence, b is the
2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050 2060

final prevalence level, and τ shifts the whole


curve backward. The value of α is chosen so that
Panel B
mlifex forecast kernel density
for observation 2015
the doubling time is 1.5 years. The latter is cho- 6 N(s = 0.102)
sen so that the doubling time at the beginning of 5
the epidemic can be ln (2) /α. This means that 4
α = ln (2) /1.5. As a result, for a given β , we 3
have to find (numerically) the parameters a , b, 2
and τ solution of the nonlinear system defining 1
0
the starting and the ending periods as well as the 47.2 47.3 47.4 47.5 47.6 47.7 47.8 47.9
peak of the epidemic. See the online Appendix
for details. Figure 1. Forecasts: Life Expectancy at Birth, Male

Notes: mlifex is our abbreviation for male life expectancy at


III. Results birth. Panel A vertical axis is male life expectancy in years.
Panel B displays the distribution of the forecast in panel A;
A. Selected Forecasting Results the vertical axis is the density estimate and the horizontal
axis is the life expectancy.
We have generated several projections for
the key variables of the model for time hori-
zons approaching 2050.6 Figures 1 and 2 depict
respectively our forecasts of life expectancy at
birth with AIDS for males and economically Panel A
active population with AIDS for females. The 1,100
figures display both the median forecast and 1,000
900
the density estimate of the forecasted values. 800
The forecasts for life expectancy at birth dis- 700 Actu al eapf1
600 Median forecasts
play nonlinear patterns. However, there is a 500 95% confidence bands
400
clear decreasing trend for both over the whole 1950 1970 1990 2010 2030 2050 2060
horizon, 1990 to 2050. The declining trend is
sizable, and could not be omitted in any serious
long-run analysis of AIDS. Mortality shows up Panel B
clearly in the declining patterns of the active 0.03
0.025
population: Figure 2 shows indeed the dreadful 0.02
medium and long-run demographic impact of 0.015
AIDS, a marked decline especially after 2020. 0.01
0.005
0
500 600 700 800 900 1,000

eapf1 forecast kernel density for observation 2010


N(s = 774)

Figure 2. Forecasts: Economically Active Population


6
In some cases, we use the procedure to extend previ- with HIV/AIDS, Female
ous forecasts available for shorter horizons to 2050. This is
the case of saving rate forecasts: Freire’s forecasts extend to Notes: eapf1 is our abbreviation for economically active
2015; we take as given and then we use the optimal forecast- population of females. Panel A vertical axis shows the num-
ing procedure to go beyond 2015. See the online Appendix ber of eapf1s in thousands; panel B vertical axis is the den-
for details. sity estimate and the horizontal shows the number of eapfls.
476 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2016

Table 1—Growth Rates of GDP Per Capita: Gap the yearly growth rate of GDP per capita, which
between the AIDS and No-AIDS Scenarios for Varying
ζ and β
is considerable. Our distinctive contribution
is in the timing of the growth effect after the
β= 1 incorporation of the most likely medium and
ζ 1 2.5 5 10 long-run demographic trends induced by AIDS.
Incidentally we show that there might not be any
2010 0.86 0.86 0.87 0.89
2020 0.89 0.89 0.89 0.89 conflict between the results obtained by authors
2030 2.78 2.78 2.78 2.78 like Bloom and Mahal (1997), and others like
2040 3.18 3.18 3.18 3.18 Corrigan, Glomm, and Mendez (2005): a rel-
2050 2.84 2.84 2.84 2.84 atively short term assessment as in the former
β = 1/2
might not reveal any dramatic AIDS growth
effect, while a medium or long term perspective,
2010 0.85 0.85 0.86 0.89 relying on demographic dynamics and those
2020 0.88 0.88 0.88 0.88
2030 2.72 2.72 2.72 2.72
of human capital, might deliver the opposite
2040 3.02 3.02 3.02 3.02 message.
2050 2.74 2.74 2.74 2.74
C. Robustness Check
β= 0
2010 0.83 0.84 0.85 0.87 We conduct two kinds of sensitivity analysis.
2020 0.86 0.86 0.86 0.86 First, we allow the coefficient β to vary taking
1
2030 2.65 2.65 2.65 2.65 the values 1 , _
2
, and 0. See the online Appendix
2040 2.87 2.87 2.87 2.87
2050 2.65 2.65 2.65 2.65 for additional sensitivity parameters results. The
second sensitivity analysis concerns function
Φ(m (t)) (relation 2). We allow ζ to vary from 1
to 10 for each value of β. The results are given
in Table 1.
B. The Economic Growth of AIDS Quantified A first conclusion should be that the varia-
tion of parameter ζ of the health expenditures
To start with a benchmark case, let us set function does not generally change the first two
β = 1. Table 1 gives the results for different decimals of the obtained growth per capita gap
values of the health expenditures productivity figures. The same type of findings is reported by
parameter ζ. Corrigan, Glomm, and Mendez (2005). Much
Consider the case ζ = 5. One can see that the more importantly, and not surprisingly, the gap
gap in growth of GDP per capita does not move figures increase with the sensitivity parameter β .
significantly between 2010 and 2020. From A comparison between the polar cases β = 0
2020 to 2030, the gap rises sharply from 0.89 and β = 1 is useful. In the first case (and ζ = 5),
percent to 2.78 percent, which translated into the gap jumps from a 0.65 percentage point
annual rates means that AIDS causes GDP per in 2020 to 2.65 percentage points in 2030,
capita to decline by 0.19 percent in the period rises slightly to 2.87 in 2040, before coming
2020–2030, while such a decline is around 0.09 back to the 2030 level in 2050. When β = 1 ,
percent in 2000–2010 for example. Accordingly, the size of the jump between 2020 and 2030
the growth impact of AIDS in 2020–2030 more is naturally bigger, but the difference is even
than doubles compared to 2000–2010. The gap larger in 2040: the difference between the two
keeps increasing from 2030 to 2040, it reaches gaps is about 0.13 in 2030, it is more than the
3.18 percent in 2040 but at a lower pace. Finally, double (equal to 0.31) in 2040. Therefore,
the gap shrinks to 2.84 percent at 2050 mainly while the fall in active population is the main
due to HIV/AIDS prevalence rates’ values at factor behind the impact of AIDS on growth
this horizon. during 2020–2030, the Ben-Porath mecha-
Our figures for the growth gaps are a bit nism seems more relevant in the last decade.
lower than those put forward by Over (1992) Both demographic factors are consequently
for the ten most affected sub-Saharan African key to understanding the medium and long-run
countries for the period 1990–2025. In our case, economic growth effects of AIDS in our
the growth gap may be close to 0.2 percent for scenarios.
VOL. 106 NO. 5 HIV/AIDS AND DEVELOPMENT 477

IV. Conclusion 352–65.


Bloom, David E., and Ajay S. Mahal. 1997. “Does
We have constructed an economico- the AIDS Epidemic Threaten Economic
epidemiological Solow-Swan model for the eco- Growth?” Jou rnal of Econometrics 77 (1):
nomic impact of HIV/AIDS. We account for the 105–24.
productivity effect of morbidity, the Ben-Porath Boucekkine, Raouf, David de la Croix, and
effect on productivity, and the impact of mor- Omar Licandro. 2002. “Vintage Human Cap-
tality on physical capital via saving dynamics. ital, Demographic Trends, and Endogenous
The model enhances the following evidence Growth.” Jou rnal of Economic Theory 104 (2):
for South Africa: while a relatively short term 340–75.
assessment might reveal no dramatic growth Corrigan, Paul, Gerhard Glomm, and Fabio
effect of AIDS, the medium- or long-run impact Mendez. 2005. “AIDS Crisis and Growth.”
can be truly sizable. In particular, we show that Jou rnal of Development Economics 77 (1):
the most painful period for economic growth is 107–24.
the decade 2020–2030, where the gap between Cuddington, John T., and John D. Hancock. 1994.
the AIDS and non-AIDS scenarios becomes “Assessing the Impact of AIDS on the Growth
deepened. This finding is mainly due to the Path of the Malawian Economy.” Jou rnal of
(slow) demographic dynamics resulting from Development Economics 43 (2): 363–68.
the epidemic shock and the delayed negative Ferreira, Pedro Cavalcanti, Samuel Pessôa, and
productivity effects, the role of physical capital Marcelo Rodrigues Dos Santos. 2011. “The
accumulation being minor. Impact of AIDS on Income and Human Capi-
tal.” Economic Inqu iry 49 (4): 1104–16.
REFERENCES Freire, Sandra. 2004. “Impact of HIV/AIDS on
Saving Behaviour in South Africa.” TIPS,
Asiedu, Elizabeth, Yi Jin, and Isaac K. Kanyama. DPRU, Cornell University, African Devel-
2015. “The Impact of HIV/AIDS on Foreign opment and Poverty Reduction Forum Paper
Direct Investment: Evidence from Sub-Saha- 2004.
ran Africa.” Jou rnal of African Trade 2 (1-2): Galí, Jordi. 1990. “Finite Horizons, Life-Cycle
1–17. Savings, and Time-Series Evidence on Con-
Azomahou, Théophile T., Bity Diene, Mbaye sumption.” Jou rnal of Monetary Economics 26
Diene, and Luc Soete. 2015. “Optimal Health (3): 433–52.
Investment and Preference Structure.” Eco- Over, Mead. 1992. “The Macroeconomic Impact
nomic Theory 60 (3): 521–65. of AIDS in Sub-Saharan Africa.” Washing-
Ben-Porath, Yoram. 1967. “The Production of ton DC, World Bank, Population and Human
Human Capital and the Life Cycle of Earn- Resources Department Technical Working
ings.” Jou rnal of Political Economy 75 (4): Paper 3.

You might also like