You are on page 1of 12

C Acodemy of Monagemenl Review, 1985, Vof, 10. No. 2. 276-2M.

'' ' * _' '


- .£<• ' .

Strategic Management in Public


and Private Organizations: Implications
of Distinctive Contexts and Constraints^
/ • \ PETER SMITH RING
University of Minnesota
JAMES L. PERRY
University of California, Irvine
Public and private sector strategic managers operate in different con-
texts tbat generate distinctive constraints on their behaviors and
choices. Key constraints on pubJic sector managers are identified in
five propositions. Implications for the evaluation of pubJic sector
management and for the behavior of public managers are drawn. It is
argued that application of private sector models to the public sector is
problematic; that general models of strategic management are needed.

Wortman (1979), in a lengthy review, suggests resource factors. This paper argues that with
that strategic management research is virtually changes in context, a unique set of managerial
nonexistent in public and other not-for-profit constraints arises (Stevens & McGowan, 1983).
organizational contexts. He argues that the appli- Following Thompson's (1967) lead, constraints
cation of the principles of strategic management are defined as fixed conditions (structural or
developed from private sector studies could help procedural) that tend to exist for some period of
these public sector organizations because "few time to which an organization and its manage-
of [them] can be acknowledged as being credita- ment must adapt. Context also influences the
bly managed in either the short or long-term" nature of managerial behavior: the actions of a
(1979, p. 353). However, in reaching this con- manager in arriving at a decision regarding how
clusion, Wortman tends to ignore the context to deal with a given context (Simon, 1957). Mana-
within which strategic management occurs, the gerial behavior is evaluated by a group of "rele-
constraints associated with particular contexts, vant others" — the stakeholders of the organiza-
and the limited ranges of managerial behavior tion. Using this general frame of reference as a
that may be available in a given context. Con- basis for discussion, an attempt is made to dem-
sequently, he fails to acknowledge that these con- onstrate that aspects of strategic management in
texts and constraints may imply that evaluators the public sector are likely to differ from those in
and the criteria of evaluation of public manage- the private sector. Dealing with these relatively
ment differ markedly from those of private sector unique needs may require managerial behavior
management. different from that usually prescribed for private
The context of strategic management can be sector managers.
defined as the societal role of the organization,
and environmental, technological, and human The Context of Strategic Management
in the Public Sector
'An earlier version of this paper was presented at the Annual Basic distinctions do exist between the public
Meeting of the Academy of Management, Western Division, and private sectors, and they are critical to under-
Monterey, California, 1981. The authors would like to thank
Craig Calhraith, Jone Pearce, Judy Rosener, and Bernard Sisco
standing differences in strategic management
for their helpful comments on earlier drafts of this paper. processes. Perhaps the most fundamental of these

276
differences stems from organic law: constitutions. ally can do so with relatively little risk to their
In an effort to maintain a separation of power, careers or to their organizations' legitimacy and
constitutional draftsmen sharply divided policy credibility.
fonnulators from policy implementors. Thus, leg- In addition to these structural distinctions,
islatures initiate, but generally do not implement, Whorton and Worthley (1981) identify signifi-
policy. Conversely, executive branch agencies cant organization culture differences between the
often can pursue only legislatively authorized two sectors. They make special note of the para-
objectives. dox of public administration: that is, a constrain-
It is difficult to conceive of situations in which ing negative force that they term "bureaucracy"
top management teams in private sector organiza- frequently is at odds with a positive force, the
tions are prohibited by corporate charter from high ideals associated with public service. They
engaging in strategy implementation, or in which identify a variey of circumstances in which public
only "outside" directors can make major strate- managers must cope with competing value sys-
gic decisions. To the contrary, a direct link tems, in addition to the demands normally associ-
between strategy formulation and implementa- ated with managerial life. In a similar vein, many
tion and the active involvement of all relevant behaviors that are viewed as acceptable strategic
parties throughout the process is deemed to be management in the private sector assume alto-
essential to effective private sector policy making. gether different symbolic meaning in the pub-
Another constraint unique to public sector stra- lic sector. For example, an outstanding performer
tegic management arises out of Civil Service awarded a bonus in a public organization often
reform. One of the objectives of reform was the is perceived, instead, as a "crony." Finally, the
insulation of government from excesses associ- public sector has established a number of formal
ated with the spoils system. The vehicle employed processes, for example, ombudsmen and ethics
was a merit-based personnel system. Public em- committees, to monitor the conduct of public
ployees no longer would be entirely dependent officials, parallels of which are rarely found in
on the good graces of political bosses for employ- the private sector.
ment, rewards, or advancement. The absence of This brief outline of some of the factors (Figure
this form of dependency relationship currently 1) influencing strategic management in the pub-
is most apparent in relations between high level lic sector is not new, nor does it exhaust the
federal political appointees and career Senior distinctions. The purpose of identifying them is
Executive Service members. In private sector to provide a basis for five propositions outlining
organizations, however, dependencies of this sort constraints related to strategic management in
are the rule rather than the exception. the public sector that are relatively unique to it
Third, public organizations are much more and that generally are not accounted for in dis-
open to the external environment. Constituents cussions of strategic management processes.
of the public sector, unlike their private sector
counterparts, have direct, constitutionally or legis- Differences in Strategic Management
latively based avenues of access to strategy mak-
ers through, for example, sunshine provisions
Between Public and Private Sectors
requiring open public meetings on most legisla- Policy Ambiguity / ,*
tive matters. They demand, and invariably re-
ceive, the attention of their elected representa- The general management functions of govern-
tives. Failure to pay attention to these constitu- ment are, as previously noted, constitutionally
ents invites grave risks for elected public sector spread out (and separated) among and across
officials, through processes such as the recall, federal, state, and local executive branches, more
referenda, or the initiative. Private sector chief than one legislative body, and a variety of judici-
executives or boards of directors, on the other aries. The purpose, Allison (1983) argues, is not
hand, may ignore most constituents' demands to promote efficiency, but to prevent the arbitrary
for direct input to the policy formulation and exercise of power. This separation of functional
implementation processes. Moreover, they gener- responsibility frequently contributes to vagueness

277
Figure 1
Illustrative Factors Involved in Influencing Strategic Management in the Public Sector

CONTEXT FACTORS ,„.. ,, CONSTRAINTS ,, . ^ ,, BEHAVIORAL CUNSKQUhNCt:

Structural Procedural

• i»;j; h (Examples) ; - ; • \. (Examples)


(Examples)

Organic law Separation of Policy ambiguity Incremental decision


(constitutions) levels of making
government , '' ,
Political reform Maintaining flexibility
Separation of Diverse interest
Openness to branches of groups Bridging competing
external government . Artificial time worlds
environment constraints
Unstable coalitions Wielding influence
Public expectations not authority
Centralized merit Less dependency
based personnel between career and Minimizing
systems political officials discontinuity
' Artificial time
constraints

Sunshine laws Artificial time


constraints
Referenda, recall Responsiveness to
initiative constituents
processes

Ombudsmen High ideals reflected


_-.- -., Special prosecutors in performance
Ethics committees measures

and/or ambiguity in policy and objectives which The vagueness permits group members to go back
must be strategically managed. to their constituents and declare "victory," point-
Warwick (1975) argues that unlike the private ing to provisions of the legislation that appear to
firm, which more typically has entrepreneurial favor the claims of their constituents.
roots, public organizations are always created by Baumer (1978) provides yet another explana-
some higher, controlling body. Ths body is com- tion for the public sector's lack of policy clarity:
posed of multiple and competing interests. Once the need to create coalitions with multiple and
created, the organization is largely dependent on often competing objectives in order to gain pas-
that body for the definition of its objectives and sage of legislation. The drive for enactment fre-
the provision of its resources. One consequence, quently obscures the issue of whether the multi-
as Nutt (1979) points out, is that the individuals ple goals are compatible with one another. Thus,
who comprise the higher controlling group fre- in the case of efforts to deregulate natural gas
quently operate from agendas that are designed prices, significant specific exemptions from over-
to benefit their own constituents, but not neces- all deregulation may be accorded a single state
sarily those of others in the controlling group. and its industries in order to obtain the support
The competition among group members leads to of a key member of the Senate.
negotiated compromises that are purposely vague. Clear, unambiguous articulation of strategy by

278
public agencies can produce at least two counter- tbat in public policy debates, any previous posi-
productive consequences. First, clearly articu- tion may be thrown back in one's face. And be
lated strategy may serve as a rallying device for bemoans tbe fact tbat be could not cbange bis
mobilizing political opposition. Second, a clear mind in Wasbington at anywbere near tbe same
policy directive may, as Mintzberg concluded rate as be could in business without running tbe
from his analysis of strategy formulation during risk of publicly being called inconsistent.
the Vietnam War period of 1965 to 1968, permit Otber former bigb government officials have
the "bureaucracy to run like an elephant" (1978, cbaracterized tbeir experiences as "fisbbowls"
p. 947). Thus, clear and precise policy statements (Malek, 1972; Rumsfeld, 1979). They found press
may lead public executives to believe there is coverage so intense tbat, in comparison to tbeir
less need for judgments of nuance, less need to experiences in tbe business world, policy bad a
exercise caution and discretion. Tbis tendency tendency to be exposed to public scrutiny mucb
may be of concern to all decision makers, but it sooner, to be dissected mucb more tboroughly,
can be particularly troublesome for public execu- and not infrequently to be killed before it ever
tives, given the autonomy of employees in Civil really got off tbe drawing boards. Blumentbal
Service systems and tbe sensitive societal mis- (1979) argues tbat individuals, as well as groups,
have learned bow to play tbe Wasbington press
sion of most public organizations. Ambiguity in
in order to bait policy initiatives tbat an execu-
strategy, characteristic of many public organiza-
tive migbt be contemplating. Examples abound
tions, therefore, may be an asset.
of tbe constraints imposed on government man-
In contrast, private sector organizations gener-
agers as a consequence of tbe bigb degree of
ally operate within tbe framework of a limited openness. Former Interior Secretary Watt's at-
number of relatively stable goals sucb as growth, tempts to enter into coal leases on federal lands
profitability, or market share. And as Peters and were cballenged in tbe courts well before any
Waterman (1982) note, the top managements of formal agreements could be completed. In general,
more effective organizations appear to focus tbeir tbe Interior Department's ability to pursue tbe
attention on a limited set of clearly defined administration's objectives regarding federal
objectives. lands policy was significantly constrained by
As a consequence of fundamental structural intense media scrutiny of Watt's every public
differences between tbe sectors, and as a result statement.
of attempts to resolve competing demands from
the multiple constituencies of public sector or- Clearly, botb researcb and reminiscence indi-
ganizations, the following proposition describes cate tbat tbe media and otber institutions impede
an important distinction between public and pri- tborougb discussion of issues and lead policy
vate sector strategic management processes: makers to be concerned witb how policy will
Proposition 1: Policy directives tend to be more look as well as bow it will work. Thus, it appears
ill-defined for public than for private organiza- to be tbe case tbat;
tions. Proposition 2. The relative openness of decision
making creates greater constraints for public sec-
The Openness of Government tor executives and managers than for their pri-
vate sector counterparts.
Tbe role tbe media play is cited frequently as ^^
one of tbe major differences in tbe work lives of Attentive Publics
public and private managers (Bernstein, 1958;
Bower, 1977; Heclo, 1977; Rainey, Backoff, & Tbe relative openness of public sector organi-
Levine, 1976; and Rourke, 1976). Tbe empirical zations is not defined exclusively by tbe atten-
evidence leading to tbe conclusion tbat govern- tion of tbe media. Public sector executives and
ment policymaking is a more open process re- top managers must pay mucb more attention to a
ceives additional substantiation from executives diverse public, in general, tban private sector
wbo bave managed in both sectors. managers. Rainey et al. (1976) bigbligbt tbe ricb
Michael Blumentbal (1979), former Secretary variety of competing interests, inside and out-
of the Treasury and President of Bendix, notes side tbe organization, experienced by public sec-

279
tor organizations. Warwick (19751 observed the The Time Problem ' f , •;
existence of a wide variety of "controllers,"
"higher authorities," and "monitors" in the exter- Although time constraints in each sector may
nal environment, all of whom constrained the be equally severe, the sources and nature of these
actions of State Department officials. Cleveland, constraints are fundamentally different. Time
pointing to the then-existing lack of policy on becomes a major constraining factor in public
energy as an example, observed: "When the peo- strategic management processes in two impor-
ple haven't decided that they want a policy yet, tant ways. The first is associated with the tenure
there isn't any policy, no matter what Washing- of public officials; that is, their length of stay
ton does" (1979, p. 20). Allison (1983) identifies with an agency (Heclo. 1977; Malek, 1972). The
this diversity of external attention getters as a second involves time constraints that are legisla-
major difference between the two sectors. Blu- tively imposed, court imposed, or created by the
menthal (1979), taking a slightly different tack, exigencies of elective political office. See, for
argues that his efforts to develop policy within example, Allison (1983) and Bower (1977). Time
the Treasury were constrained by the belief held appears to be a less critical distinguishing factor
by many of his own subordinates, especially in the "gestation" period of a policy issue, how-
career civil servants, that they had the right to be ever. Thus, time constraints for public organiza-
in on the decision making process. In contrast, at tions tend to be generated by legislatures, fund-
Bendix he could absolutely limit participation as ing exigencies, or the employment length of pub-
he saw fit. lic officials. On the other hand, time constraints
It thus seems clear that the strategic manage- in the private sector tend to be defined by the
ment process in the public sector must take type and rate of market (broadly defined) changes.
account of a wide range of stakeholder interests. Moreover, the time constraints that private sec-
In addition, these stakeholders are likely to eval- tor managers face appear to arise out of the natu-
uate the results of the strategic management pro- ral interaction of market forces, but those con-
cess quite differently, often reaching conclusions fronting public sector managers more frequently
that are difficult to reconcile. Deregulation of the appear to be related to a lack of coordination
financial services industry provides an excellent among subsystems and thus tend to be more arti-
example of the constraints that competing stake- ficially imposed upon those managers.
holder interests pose for public policymakers. An excellent example of the constraints that
Congressional testimony suggests that Treasury time can create for public sector strategic man-
and Federal Reserve Bank officials see the issues agement processes can be found in the case of
of deregulation in quite different terms, as do a the first major overhaul of the federal personnel
number of members of Congress. Further, the system in nearly 100 years: The Civil Service
objectives of large commercial banks differ from Reform Act of 1978. As one of the major "prom-
those of smaller ones, and both large and smaller ises" of candidate Carter, the newly elected
banks evaluate policy formation from a different administration was under pressure to produce
perspective than do thrifts, savings and loans, quickly a piece of legislation on which Congress
credit unions. Sears, American Express, or other could act. There also was pressure to get the
financial intermediaries. It is equally clear that reforms implemented. Thus, the legislation man-
the general public's primary concerns regarding dated implementation of key components of the
banking deregulation are not necessarily identi- Act within very specific time frames and, gen-
cal with those of any of the other stakeholders erally, without regard to the interactive nature of
just identified. Under such circumstances, it is some of the reforms. As it happened, before some
not difficult to reach the conclusion that: of the reforms were fully implemented the Carter
administration had been rejected by the voters,
Proposition 3: Public sector policymakers are gen- and a new set of political executives were left to
eraJJy subject to more direct and sustained influ- complete the implementation process.
ence from a greater number of interest groups than
are executives or managers in the private sector. In sum, it appears that public managers face
time constraints in dealing with the strategic man-

280
agement of policy implementation quite unlike to obtain passage of complex legislation in a plu-
those that their private sector counterparts con- ralistic society.
front. Cleveland describes it thusly: "We are tack- These factors can lead to control problems in
ling 20-year problems v^rith five-year plans staffed the implementation of policy. Michael Blumen-
with tvkfo-year personnel funded by one-year thal (1979) observed that in business he could
appropriations" (1979, p. 25). Consequently: decide what the policy should be, delegate to
Proposition 4: Public sector management must those who would develop it, take it to the board,
cope with time constraints that are more artificial get it approved, and then control the process of
than those that confront private sector manage- implementation. He found that this simply was
ment. not the case in Washington. George Romney put
Shaky Coalitions the matter more bluntly: "Being Governor of
The four propositions developed thus far are Michigan . . . is like being quarterback of a team
not independent of each other. Quite clearly the chosen by your opponents" (Meyers, 1964, p.
constraints imposed by openness and multiple 134).
publics, coupled with contingencies of time, Illustrative of these kinds of control problems
when compounded by policy vagueness and/or and the constraints they create is the case of with-
ambiguity, can and frequently do create signifi- holding on savings accounts. Although the Reagan
cant problems in the implementation of policy administration was able to put together a coali-
(Pressman & Wildavsky, 1979). Viewed in this tion of Republicans and Democrats large enough
light, it is hardly surprising that policy forma- to gain passage of the law, it was repealed prior
tion in the public sector frequently is a process to the date on which it was scheduled to go into
of coalition building involving diverse, and oft- effect. Similarly, the same administraton has had
times competing interests. difficulty in developing a solid front on economic
A different sort of public sector constraint asso- policy and in gaining consensus from the Coun-
ciated with strategy implementation is identified cil on Economic Advisors and Secretary of the
by Nakamura (1980). He describes three kinds of Treasury. The problem is not peculiar to a partic-
legislative coalitions: (a) those that dissolve into ular administration. Presidents Carter and Ford
constituent parts upon passage of legislation; experienced similar difficulties on energy and
inflation issues. Thus, there appears to be consid-
(b) those that partially dissolve; and (c) those that
erable evidence to justify the conclusion that:
persist. The distinction to be made here between
Proposition 5; Policy legitimation coalitions are
public and private sector management is that pub-
less stable in the public sector and are more prone
lic sector executives, unlike those in the private
to disintegrate during policy implementation.
sector, frequently must create internal coalitions
to get policy passed, but these coalitions may Implications
and often do break up during implementation.
This condition is exacerbated by the great vari- These propositions carry a number of impor-
ety of public sector stakeholder groups with direct tant implications. One is that strategic manage-
access to the policymaking process and direct ment in the public sector may be extremely
interests in outcomes. difficult. Under such circumstances, if public sec-
Rourke (1976) provides insight into a unique tor performance is judged against a normative
model of strategic management developed in the
aspect of the problem: splits between political
private sector, it is likely to be found inadequate.
and career executives within an agency or an
However, judged against standards grounded in
administration. He cites three examples resulting
the public sector, different conclusions might be
in bureaucratic defiance during the Nixon admin-
drawn. Expectations about the a priori probabili-
istration: the war in Vietnam, cutbacks in domes- ties of the success of programs, the criteria of
tic welfare programs, and a weakening of civil performance, and actual assessments of accom-
rights enforcements. He also notes the intrusion plishment are all likely to change if alternative
of unions into the realm of public policy and normative models are used. For instance. Press-
executive decision making, a situation that adds man and Wildavsky (1979) concluded from their
to the instability of majority coalitions required

281
analysis of a federal economic development pro- plification of complex problems may be extremely
gram in Oakland that the complexity of policy useful approaches to problem solving. Mintzberg
implementation usually keeps new public pro- (1978) suggests that the conventional wisdom of
grams from getting off the ground. A priori proba- strategy formulation that emphasizes the need to
bilities of success for public programs therefore state goals precisely, assess strengths and weak-
should be quite low. With respect to performance nesses, and make strategy explicit may mis-
criteria, Aharoni (1981) has argued that research lead organizations, such as those in the public
on state-owned enterprises (SOEs), a particular sector, that face a confusing reality.
type of public organization, has focused on how There is additional evidence (Allison, 1971;
these enterprises should behave rather than on Cyert & March, 1963; March & Simon, 1958;
how they do behave. Zif (1981) found that increas- Murray, 1978; Pettigrew, 1973; Quinn, 1980) that
ing political and external orientation of SOEs was processes other than those associated with ratio-
associated with their pursuit of goals quite differ- nal models are employed quite frequently in large
ent from private enterprises, for example, sales organizations, but the issue of whether such mod-
rather than profit goals and low prices relative to els ought to be employed remains an open ques-
costs. Thus performance criteria for public or- tion. The constraints to strategic management
ganizations, the ultimate basis for judgments associated with the propositions set out above
about management's performance, also appear to appear to be more easily managed by incremen-
differ qualitatively from those of the private tal processes than by those that are rigidly planned.
sector. Goodsell (1983) goes one step further after To the extent that incremental and/or emergent
reviewing survey data on public social service strategies enable public organizations to be more
clients, arguing that client satisfaction surveys responsive to the needs or demands of their
reflect a level of high performance by public constituents, they are likely to be more effective.
bureaucracies, contrary to popular opinion. Whether use of these processes makes public
These observations about evaluation of public organizations less efficient in utilizing scarce
sector strategic management are not intended as resources appears to be a more debatable question.
an apology for real inadequacies, but instead to The strategic management issues confronting
illustrate the subjectivity and probable biases of public organizations can be characterized using
conventional wisdom premised on private sector Mintzberg's (1978) typology of deliberate (in-
norms (Wortman, 1979). Despite these arguments, tended strategies that are realized), unrealized
however, it should be reiterated that the Ameri- (intended strategies that are not realized), and
can political culture will continue to set high emergent (realized strategies that were never
and frequently unattainable standards for perfor- intended) strategies. Given previous arguments
mance in the public sector. It is unlikely, there- regarding policy ambiguity, open and intense
fore, that the general public will change their influence processes, and coalition instability,
expectations for public institutions. On the other public organizations can be characterized as low
hand, scholars need to distinguish between per- on deliberate strategy and high on emergent and
formance expectations derived from political cul- unrealized strategy. If this characterization is
ture and ideology and those based on technical correct, any manager who is unable, for instance,
feasibility. to relinquish intended strategies in order to pur-
Another implication of the propositions is that sue emergent strategies is likely to fail. A few
the distinctive constraints imposed by the public threads of empirical evidence suggest that this
context require a significantly different set of may be the case. For instance, in a study of pub-
behavioral responses from public strategic mana- lic and private managers' use of time. Porter and
gers. The existence of incremental politics (Lind- Van Maanen (1970) found that the most effective
blom, 1979) suggests that rational, comprehen- public managers, in contrast to their private
sive policy models—for example, planning modes counterparts, avoided rigid time allocations but
(Mintzberg, 1978)—will rarely be appropriate in instead adapted to external demands. A recent
the public sector. In contrast, disjointed incre- empirical study (Wechsler, Backoff, & Kump,
mentalism or other calculated means for the sim- 1983) of strategy in six agencies of state govern-

282
ment in Ohio concluded that patterns of strategy 1979). Finally, it seems likely that the successful
depended more frequently on ecological factors manager will avoid using preprogrammed re-
than on managerial intention. Although alterna- sponses, standard operating procedures, and the
tive inferences might be drawn from this evidence, like as control mechanisms.
it suggests that attention to emergent rather than
intended strategies may be a key feature of suc- Bridging Competing Worlds ; . ,,
cessful strategic management in the public sector. Public managers frequently function in two (or
Certainly the evidence supports the conclusion more) different cultural contexts. The prevailing
that, in probabilistic terms, strategy in the public ethos of democratic institutions mandates set-
sector tends towards the emergent rather than ting a tone of high moral character for the strate-
the deliberate. gic management process (Weinberg, 1977). At the
Cumulatively, the five propositions represent same time, large segments of the public demand
a set of demands that affect the behavior of those efficiency. They want the tasks of government
who manage the strategy process in the public accomplished without waste. Others, however,
sector. In responding to these demands, success- expect equity in its outcomes (Bower, 1983). Gov-
ful public managers resort to processes and em- ernment must treat all its constituents fairly.
ploy skills that frequently differ from those asso- The internal organization that the political
ciated with strategic management in the private executive manages frequently is a foreign and
sector, although Quinn (1980) prescribes similar hostile one, especially in the first few months
behavior for private sector managers. The pro- after appointment or election to the office. At the
cesses and skills that public sector managers tend same time the executive must learn to cope with
to rely on in coping with the demands associated other elements of the triangular relationships that
with the five propositions can be grouped under frequently characterize public sector policy pro-
the following types of behavior, especially at cesses: competing constituent groups and legisla-
higher levels of the organization. tive officials. Thus, the political executive must
bridge competing demands within the structure
Maintaining Flexibility of government, in addition to bridging compet-
If the strategy process tends to be emergent ing cultures outside the formal structure.
and more open to exogenous influences, flexibil- Coping with all these competing demands is
ity and adaptability appear to be required of pub- likely to require managers who display the attri-
lic managers. This might require, for example, butes of marginality (Cotton, 1977). Skills associ-
the loose coupling of personal staffs with inter- ated with a marginal orientation include the abil-
nal and external elements of the organization. ity to integrate competing viewpoints in decisions
In all likelihood, the need for adaptive behav- (Liddell, 1973), a self-other orientation and main-
ior also means that successful public managers, tenance of low levels of dogmatism (Ziller, Stark,
particularly those at the very highest levels of & Pruden, 1969), and openmindedness (Pruden
government, avoid becoming deeply immersed & Stark, 1971). The attributes of marginality per-
in the details of policy. Instead, they are more mit a manager to adapt to situations that require
likely to be skilled at managing the policy agenda, the manager to change hats, look to a new con-
moving items on and off as events largely exter- stituency, and explain the "facts" in new circum-
nal to the organization dictate. Because they are stances.
likely to be subject to intense media scrutiny, it
also is probable that they will learn to avoid mak- Wielding Influence, Not Authority
ing public statements that prematurely commit
themselves, or their agencies, to a given set of That many of the key actors in the strategic man-
objectives. Successful adaptive behavior also agement process are external to a focal organiza-
appears to be associated with the ability to act tion implies that the skillful exercise of influ-
quickly, to interpret the law "creatively," and to ence is likely to be more critical than the wielding
reduce the necessity for multiple clearances in of authority. The manager must cope with con-
implementing policy (Pressman & Wildavsky, frontation, without being confrontational. As

283
Sabatier and Mazmanian (1979) point out, suc- jurisdiction and political climate, the ability to
cessful policy implementation may require good define the management task clearly, the level of
political skills, the development and maintenance technical expertise brought to office, and the abil-
of good v^forking relationships with others, and ity to establish and exercise authority cJearJy.
especially the capacity to convince those opposed The need to bridge discontinuity also implies,
to, or adversely affected by, policy that they are for public managers, skills that range from the
being treated fairly. Achieving these objectives is identification and allocation of resources to the
likely to require frequent meetings with, and creation, proper care, and feeding of coalitions.
obtaining policy inputs from, those not under a Bridging the gaps of discontinuity also may
manager's direct control. demand the capacity to mobilize latent constitu-
The need to communicate effectively and quickly encies (Sabatier & Mazmanian, 1979),
with large numbers of constituent groups, many These behaviors indicate the types of responses
of which may be shaky coalitions, or to mar- managers are likely to use in directing strategy
shall their support for policy, creates special prob- while meeting the demands posed by the five
lems for managers who have no authority over propositions. These behaviors normally will be
these groups. In such circumstances the use of used in conjunction with calculated strategies
symbols, rather than facts, more probably will for the simplification of complex problems. More-
provide the means of effective management of over, as implied in the propositions, normative
external relations, especially those with the media models grounded in the public sector are neces-
(Edelman, 1964). , sary for judging the adequacy of strategic manage-
Finally, though elected and appointed officials ment in public organizations.
have constitutionally based authority to run the
government, the creation of merit based person- Conclusion
nel systems resulted in the effective separation
of the work force from the political executive's Although the propositions presented are in-
direct and immediate control. Thus, the formal tended to reflect some of the unique aspects of
protections of these systems, coupled with the strategic management in public organizations,
existence of employee unions, is likely to place a they also may have application for strategic man-
premium on the use of influence rather than agement in some private sector contexts. For
authority in managing policy within the organiza- example. Snow and Hrebiniak (1980) were sur-
tion. It also may require an ability to maintain prised to find a significant amount of self-reported
high morale within the agency, managing inter- reactor behavior, implied as pathological by Miles
nal dissent by influence rather than authority. and Snow (1978), among organizations in regu-
lated industries. Such behavior, however, may
Minimizing Discontinuity be appropriate in dealing with the constraints
In many respects, strategic management in the associated with a regulatory context. Similarly,
public sector entails the management of discon- Miles' (1982) analysis of the tobacco industry
tinuity. Coalitions are unstable, political execu- indicates that the differing contexts of domain
tive tenure is brief, agendas change constantly. creation, domain defense, and domain offense
Successful public sector managers act to mini- give rise to distinctive sets of constraints, each of
mize discontinuity and bridge the gaps that it which appears to call for its own approach to
leaves in its wake. At the highest levels, this strategic management.
probably means that the manager, upon election In addition to the potential for practical ap-
or appointment, lands running. Light's (1981) plication, the propositions and the implications
investigation of the transition process suggests drawn from them give rise to several fundamen-
the absolute necessity of staff selection and pol- tal research questions. First, building on Bracker's
icy development prior to assuming office, Wein- (1980) work, if the field of strategic management
berg (1977) describes a variety of "situational is to continue to evolve beyond the mere study of
resources" or skills that she found minimized corporate level strategy or business level policy,
the effects of discontinuity: knowledge of the it clearly requires the development of models

284
with more general applicability. This paper pres- drawn without regard for the possibility that each
ents a reasonable argument that existing models may require a different managerial focus, contin-
do not capture the legitimate strategic manage- gent upon what it is that is being managed—for
ment processes required by the differing contexts example, constituent expectation or human re-
of the public sector. sources. Research exploring this issue within pub-
Second, more research on strategic management lic organizations and across the two sectors
processes must be undertaken within a frame- appears warranted.
work that recognizes the existence of separate In short, a strong case has been made that a
sets of rules governing organizational conduct number of research issues related to strategic
within the two sectors. The literature clearly management processes might profitably be ex-
establishes that there are accepted standards that plored prior to concluding that private sector
apply, quite appropriately, only to market con- models have general application to public sector
duct and those that apply only to political eco- organizations. It is hoped that questions raised
nomies, democratic or otherwise (Lindblom, by this paper will stimulate additional critical
1977). thought and research on strategic management
Third, implications regarding the four types of processes in both the public and private sectors.
managerial behavior just discussed have been
References
Aharoni. Y. Performance evaluation of state-owned enter- Edelman, M. J. The symbolic uses of politics. Urbana. IL:
prises: A process perspective. Management Science. 1981, University of Illinois Press, 1964.
27. 1340-1347. Goodsell, G. The case/or bureaucracy. Ghatam. NJ : Ghatam
Allison. G. T., )r. The essence of decision. Boston: Little, Press. 1983.
Brown. 1971. Heclo, H. A government of strangers: Executive politics in
Allison, G. T.. Jr. Public and private management: Are they Washington. Washington. D.G.: Brookings Institution, 1977.
fundamentally alike in all unimportant respects? In ). L. Liddell, W. W. Marginality and integrative decisions. Acad-
Perry & K. L. Kraemer (Eds.). Public management: Public emy o/Management /ournaJ, 1973, 16. 154-156.
and private perspectives. Palo Alto. CA: Mayfield. 1983,
Light, P. G. The president's agenda, notes on the timing of
72-92.
domestic choice. Presidential Studies Ouarterly. 1981,
Baumer, D. G. Implementing public service employment. In 11(1), 67-82.
J. V. May & A. B. Wildavsky (Eds.), The policy cycle. Beverly
Lindblom, G. Politics and markets. New York: Basic Books,
Hills, GA: Sage, 1978, 169-197.
1977.
Bernstein, M. The job of the federal executive. Washington.
Lindblom, G. Still muddling, not yet through. Public Ad-
D.G.: Brookings Institute, 1958.
ministration Review, 1979, 39, 517-526.
Blumenthal, M. Gandid reflections of a businessman in Wash-
Malek, F. V. Mr. executive goes to Washington. Harvard Busi-
ington. Fortune, January 29, 1979, pp. 36-49.
ness Review, 1972, 50(5), 63, 68.
Bower. J. L. Effective public management. Harvard Business
March. J. G., & Simon, H. A. Organizations. New York: Wiley.
Review, 1977, 55(2), 131-140.
1958.
Bower, J. Managing for efficiency, managing for equity. Har-
Meyers, H. B. Businessman in a political jungle. Fortune,
vard Business Review, 1983, 61(4). 83-90.
April 1964, 133-135, 187-195.
Bracker, ). The historical development of the strategic man-
Miles, R. Coffin nails and corporate strategy. Englewood Gliffs,
agement concept. Academy o/Management Review, 1980,
NJ: Prentice-Hall, 1982.
5, 219-224.
Miles, R. E., & Snow, G. G. Organization strategy, structure,
Gleveland, H. Public management research: The theory of
and process. New York: McGraw-Hill, 1978.
practice and vice versa. Paper presented at the Public Man-
agement Research Gonference, Brookings Institution, Wash- Mintzberg, H. Patterns in strategy formulation. Management
ington, D.G., 1979. Science, 1978. 24, 934-948.
Gotton. G. Marginality—A neglected dimension in work de- Murray, E. A., Jr. Strategic choice as a negotiated outcome.
sign. Academy of Management Review, 1977, 2, 133-138. Management Science. 1978, 24. 960-971.
Gyert, R. M., & March, ). G. A behavioral theory of the firm. Nakamura, R. T. Further thoughts on defining policy during
Englewood Gliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall, 1963. implementation. Paper presented at the Association for

285
Public Policy Analysis and Management. 1980 Annual con- Snow. C. C. & Hrebiniak, L. G. Strategy, distinctive compe-
ference. Boston. 1980. tence, and organizational performance. Administrative
Science Quarterly, 1980, 25, 317-336.
Nutt, P. C. Calling out and calling off the dogs: Managerial
diagnosis in public service organizations. Academy of Man- Stevens, J. M., & McGowan, J. R. Managerial strategies in
agement Review. 1979, 4, 203-214. municipal government organizations. Academy of Man-
agement Journal, 1983, 26, 527-534.
Peters. T. J. & Waterman. R. H. In search of excellence. New
York: Harper & Row, 1982. Thompson, J. D. Oi^anizations in action. New York: McGraw-
Hill, 1967.
Pettigrew, A. The politics of organizational decision making.
London: Tavistock, 1973. Warwick, D. P. A theory of public bureaucracy. Cambridge,
MA: Harvard University Press, 1975.
Porter. L. W., & Van Maanen, J. Task accomplishment and
management of time. In B. Bass (Ed), Managing /or accom- Wechsler. B., Backoff, R. W., & Kump, W. I. Strategic man-
plishment. Lexington. MA: Lexington Books, 1970.180-192. agement: The nexus of politics and administration. Paper
presented at the Annual Meeting of the Amercian Political
Pressman, J., & Wildavsky, A. Implementation. 2nd. ed. Science Association, Chicago, 1983.
Berkeley, CA: University of California Press, 1979.
Weinberg, M. W. Managing the state. Cambridge, MA: MTT
Pruden. H. O. & Stark. B. ). Marginality associated with in- Press. 1977.
terorganizational linking processes, productivity and satis-
faction. Academy of Management Journal. 1971, 14, 145- Whorton, J. W.. & Worthley, J. H. A perspective on the chal-
148. lenge of public management: Environmental paradox and
organizational culture. Academy of Management Review,
Quinn, J. G. Strategies for change. Homewood. IL: Irwin. 1980. 1981,6, 357-361.
Rainey, H. C Backoff. R. W.. & Levine, C. H. Comparing public Wortman, M. S., Jr. Strategic management: Not-for-profit or-
and private organizations. Public Administration Review, ganizations. In D. E. Schendel & C. W. Hofer (Eds.), Strategic
1976. 36. 233-244. management: A new view of business policy and planning.
Rourke, F. E. Bureaucracy, politics and public policy. 2nd ed. Boston: Little, Brown, 1979, 353-381.
Boston: Little. Brown, 1976. Zif, J. Managerial strategic behavior in state-owned enter-
Rumsfeld, D. A politician turned executive. Fortune, Sep- prises—Business and political orientations. Management
tember 10, 1979, 88-94. Science, 1981, 27, 1326-1339.
Sabatier, P., » Mazmanian, D. The conditions of effective Ziller, R. C, Stark, B. J., & Pruden, H. O. Marginality and
implementation: A guide to accomplishing policy objec- integration management positions. Academy of Manage-
tives. Policy Analysis, 1979, 5, 481-504. ment Journal, 1969, 12, 487-493.
Simon, H. A. Administrative behavior. 2nd. ed. New York:
Free Press. 1957.

Peter Smith Ring is Associate Professor of Manage-


ment in the School of Management, University of
Minnesota, Minneapolis.

James L. Perry is Professor of Administration in the


Graduate School of Management, University of Cali-
fornia, Irvine.

286

You might also like