You are on page 1of 14

Political Research Quarterly

Volume 62 Number 1
March 2009 164-177
Representation and Local Policy © 2009 University of Utah
10.1177/1065912908316341
http://prq.sagepub.com
hosted at
Relating County-Level Public Opinion to Policy Outputs http://online.sagepub.com

Garrick L. Percival
University of Minnesota, Duluth
Martin Johnson
University of California, Riverside
Max Neiman
Public Policy Institute of California, San Francisco

Students of local politics have argued American federalism implies little role for local tastes in policy making. Peterson
(1979) anticipates the pursuit of a productive tax base will depress subnational government spending on social ser-
vices, while promoting developmental policies. We investigate the role public opinion plays in county-level redistrib-
utive, developmental, and allocational program spending in California, using a novel measure of county political
ideology. Our findings challenge expectations that local governments are uniformly biased against redistribution. We
find that social service spending varies across counties as a function of ideological orientation. In several policy areas,
institutional structure mediates the responsiveness of officials.

Keywords: policy representation; local politics; political ideology; public policy

S cholars of comparative state politics have long


been interested in the extent to which the public
policies of state governments reflect mass public opin-
strength of this association is conditioned by differing
county institutional structures. As a whole, these results
clarify the circumstances under which local govern-
ion in the states (Weber and Shaffer 1972; Morehouse ments will support redistributive policies, despite the
1973). Erikson, Wright, and McIver (1993) and others strong inclination for localities not to do so. By con-
have established an association between states’ general trast, our findings support the view that there is a mean-
political attitudes and the choices of state policy mak- ingful local politics, despite the substantial hemming-in
ers. We extend the investigation of subnational opinion- of local choice by mandates, constitutions, and resource
policy linkages by examining how local political constraints.
ideology shapes policy within states, asking to what
extent does localized ideological dispositions influ-
ence local-level policymaking? We argue that local Local Policy Making as
ideology should have a much greater influence on “Limited Politics”
local governments’ policy choices than is often pre-
sumed. To test this expectation, we follow methods Peterson’s (1979, 1981) seminal examination of city
employed at the state level to create a reliable and sta- policy making argues local governments’ policy choices
ble measure of local ideology by aggregating statewide are confined by the structural constraints of U.S. feder-
California Field Poll surveys (1990–1999) to the alism, and as a result, local politics is best characterized
county level and test the relationship between local as a “limited politics,” where local governments’ policy
political orientations and a broad range of policy out- agendas are relatively narrow, with an almost exclusive
puts at the county level.
We find counties’ expenditure patterns vary as a Garrick L. Percival, Assistant Professor of Political Science,
function of ideology across a number of issues; how- University of Minnesota, Duluth; e-mail: percival@d.umn.edu.
ever, the ideology-policy linkage is not straightforward. Martin Johnson, Associate Professor of Political Science, University
Specifically, the impact of county ideological disposi- of California, Riverside; e-mail: martin.johnson@ucr.edu.
tions are more likely to impact redistributive policies— Max Neiman, Associate Director, Public Policy Institute of
where political conflict is most intense—and the California; e-mail: neiman@ppic.org.
164
Percival, Johnson, and Neiman / Representation and Local Policy 165

focus on enacting policies aimed at improving eco- county governments have held a unique position in
nomic growth. In his account, there is little room for the the American governmental system, designed as
representation of local interests given the economic administrative arms of state governments that could
imperatives that limit local policy makers. conveniently and efficiently deliver state programs
Peterson’s (1981) primary argument that local within their geographic boundaries (Berman and
governments’ main goal is set on delivering eco- Salant 1996; Benton 2002a). As a result, their functional
nomic growth policies has shaped the expectations responsibilities often differed from those of munici-
many scholars have about the local policy making palities. From this perspective, as counties are
process. According to the “city limits” framework, severely restricted by top-down constraints and trend
local governments tend to shy away from policies toward producing a narrow set of state-imposed allo-
that could potentially hurt communities’ economic cational and developmental policies, one ought not to
standing. This works to create an economic and polit- expect a significant explanatory role for such factors
ical bias against redistributive policies; those policies as the ideology of their residents.
that redistribute wealth from those who are better off An alternative view advanced here posits that local
to those who are worse off. Instead, local governments ideology should have a significant impact on county
pursue what Peterson classifies as “developmental” policy processes and policy choices that elected offi-
(such as investing in an industrial park, subsidizing a cials make. This flows from an emerging body of
new shopping center, or building local schools) and literature on county government that documents
“allocational” (including street sweeping, garbage tremendous change in the role and functions of county
collection, community policing, and fire protection governments in the United States. Growing demands
policies) that together work to enhance the local tax from the bottom up, driven by increasing urbanization
base and generate additional resources that can be and suburbanization, in addition to top-down forces
used to help the welfare of the city. He assumes this such as a decline in federal revenue sharing to local
pursuit of economic growth is popular among deci- governments in the 1980s and state governments’ fiscal
sion makers, and because of this, there is generally plights in the 1990s, has not only caused counties to
less political conflict at the local level. Overall, Peterson increase the range of services they provide, but has also
claims that because local governments are less likely provided counties with significantly more authority and
to play an active role in areas of policy where politi- discretion (Benton 2002a). As many counties have
cal conflict is high, and more likely to adopt and become increasingly urbanized, especially those in the
implement policies where political conflict is low, American South and West, the demand for city-like ser-
local political forces like ideology and partisanship vices has increased (DeSantis and Renner 1996). In
should have minimal influence on policy making at response, the nature of services offered by county gov-
the local level (1981, 128). ernments has grown since the early 1980s from more
In fairness to Peterson, his framework does not pre- traditional services like property tax assessment, law
clude having local governments produce policies that enforcement, and elections (Benton and Rigos 1985;
benefit the less well-off at the expense of better-heeled Cigler 1990), to other additional services such as health
local populations. There is ample evidence to suggest care, educational services, pollution control, and mass
local institutions and local political circumstances transit among others (Duncombe 1977; Schneider and
matter in shaping policies (Clingermayer and Feiock Park 1989; Benton 2002a; 2003). In many cases, coun-
1995). However, empirical analysis of actual policy ties have begun to rival or even become the predomi-
outcomes among cities demonstrates a strong and nant provider of many municipal and regional services
consistent inclination to benefit economic and com- (Benton 2002a). To carry out increasingly complex
mercial interests, and the challenge is to ascertain functions, state governments have tended to increase
when the imperative of economic development gives the amount of policy discretion and hence decision-
way to redistributive policies (Lewis 2001a, 2001b). making authority to county governments (Bowman and
Kearney 1986; Martin and Nyhan 1994). Ideological
divisions often characterize many of these “new” poli-
Reconsidering the Role of Local Public cies being adopted and implemented at the county
Opinion in Local Policy Decisions level. These ideological divisions, coupled with
increased county authority and discretion provides a
We develop a “county limits” variation on the sound basis for our central expectation that there is sig-
Peterson theme and investigate the responsiveness of nificant “room” for local ideology to shape policy at the
county governments to local circumstances. Historically, county level.
166 Political Research Quarterly

The ideological disposition of county residents these kinds of comparable data are only narrowly
could be linked to public policy in several ways. available. Scholars have also relied on the presiden-
Street-level bureaucrats in counties with distinct ide- tial vote totals as a proxy for local ideology (DeSantis
ological profiles, for example, might be more likely and Renner 1996) and most recently have used inno-
or feel compelled to implement policies in ways that vative simulation techniques to create measures of
closely reflect prevailing ideological preferences school board ideology across the states (see Berkman
(Lipsky 1980). Of course, the staff and leadership of and Plutzer 2005). The former approach brings the
local agencies might also be recruited in ways that possibility of confounding attitudes toward national
reflect the views of the local legislature (Board of office with local issues, while the latter measures rely
County Supervisors, School Boards, or City Councils). on the assumptions built into simulations, and it is
In addition, local elected officials (e.g. County Boards difficult to ascertain the extent to which they are rep-
of Supervisors) are likely to try to adopt policies that resentative. We use a different technique informed by
reflect or are consistent with the ideological prefer- an approach developed for the study of public opin-
ences of their constituents. In short, as counties become ion and policy at the state level.
involved in such controversial or divisive issues as
managing growth, implementing controversial pro-
grams in such areas as welfare, parolees, homeless- Measuring Political Orientations at the
ness, and health care for the poor, it is plausible to Local Level in California
expect that the ideological inclinations of the local
population will play a role. Based on this, our central In this research we measure local ideology using
expectation is that local ideological orientations should methods similar to those of Erikson, Wright, and
impact county-level policy outputs. McIver (1993). Their research significantly advanced
Students of representation have found public opin- the understanding of state-level public opinion by cre-
ion to have a strong influence across much of the ating reliable and valid measures of political ideology
American political system, including the voting behav- and partisanship by pooling 1976–1988 nationally
ior of members of Congress (Miller and Stokes 1963; sampled CBS/New York Times polls and aggregating
Erikson 1978), on national policy outputs (Wlezien them at the state level. In the years since Wright,
1995, 1996; Stimson, MacKuen, and Erikson 1996), Erikson, and McIver (1985) developed the approach,
and between state policy decisions and general mea- a number of scholars have studied opinion-policy
sures of political ideology and more specific public linkages at the state level, exploring patterns of female
demands of state residents (e.g., Erikson, Wright, and representation (Arceneaux 2001), the use of the death
McIver 1993; Hill and Hinton-Andersson 1995; Hill penalty (Norrander 2001), and environmental policy
and Leighley 1996). In contrast, however, little work responsiveness (Johnson, Brace, and Arceneaux 2005).
has systematically investigated policy responsiveness A recent edited volume (Cohen 2006) provides an
to ideology at the local level. excellent overview of these techniques and applica-
One major reason the relationship between ideol- tions to state politics. We use a similar approach, re-
ogy and public policy remains underexplored by aggregating to the county-level statewide California
students of local politics is the inherent difficulty of Field Poll surveys conducted 1990–1999.1
measuring local ideological orientations. In particu- Established in 1947, and continuing every year
lar, it is extremely difficult to find comparative mea- since, the Field Poll routinely fields surveys questions
sures of ideology across several localities. Earlier to California residents on a wide range of public pol-
attempts at measuring shared beliefs among commu- icy issues and questions regarding their support for
nities have led to concepts such as local “political various political candidates at the national, state, and
culture” or “political ethos” (see Banfield and Wilson local levels of government.2 For this research, data
1963; Eulau 1973). Although there were efforts to were gathered from forty-eight Field Poll surveys
measure political culture or the “ethos” of local resi- totaling 51,930 individual respondents. The Field Poll
dents, these studies involved only indirect indicators consistently asks respondents to place themselves
of voters’ views (Hawkins 1971). along a three-point political ideology continuum.
In limited cases, scholars have utilized public Specifically, respondents were asked, “Do you con-
opinion data sampled from multiple local communi- sider yourself to be politically conservative, liberal,
ties by a single research organization using compara- middle-of-the road, or don’t you think of yourself in
ble sampling and survey administration techniques this way?” Conservatives were coded 100, middle-of-
(e.g., Pierce, Lovrich, and Moon 2002). However, the-road 0, and liberals –100. In addition, the Field
Percival, Johnson, and Neiman / Representation and Local Policy 167

Table 1
Ideology Scores by County with Sample Sizes
County Name Ideology Sample Size County Name Ideology Sample Size

Sierra 50.00 14 Merced 25.12 215


Madera 41.27 127 Glenn 25.00 37
Tulare 41.23 350 Del Norte 24.24 33
Shasta 37.40 253 Lassen 24.07 55
Mariposa 37.14 37 Butte 23.75 361
Kern 36.35 666 Tuolumne 23.66 93
Inyo 35.25 34 Solano 21.01 404
Sutter 35.14 116 Monterey 21.00 430
El Dorado 34.95 208 Napa 20.75 166
Mono 34.78 23 San Diego 19.94 3,044
Fresno 34.38 774 Santa Barbara 19.73 524
San Benito 33.78 74 Sacramento 19.35 1,459
Nevada 32.61 184 San Luis Obispo 18.18 396
Tehama 31.82 89 Imperial 15.00 120
San Bernardino 31.74 1,727 Humboldt 13.27 200
Amador 31.58 57 Lake 10.59 86
Riverside 30.36 1,460 Modoc 10.53 21
Kings 30.36 116 Los Angeles 10.38 10,326
Orange 29.74 3,451 Santa Clara 8.41 2,020
San Joaquin 29.39 570 Contra Costa 8.36 1,100
Yuba 28.92 83 Mendocino 6.45 127
Ventura 27.86 854 San Mateo 3.27 973
Calaveras 27.78 72 Yolo 0.00 193
Plumas 27.78 37 Sonoma 0.00 565
Placer 27.59 296 Santa Cruz −5.81 348
Trinity 27.27 14 Alameda −7.78 1,740
Colusa 26.92 26 Marin −11.90 338
Siskiyou 26.92 78 Alpine −20.33 15
Stanislaus 26.56 441 San Francisco −25.35 1,449

Poll asks each respondent his or her county of resi- ideology measure, we use the O’Brien coefficient
dence, allowing us to link each response to a given (O’Brien 1990). Presented by Jones and Norrander
county. Individual responses were then aggregated to (1996), the O’Brien generalizability test compares
create ideological scores for California’s fifty-eight within-unit variance to the across-unit variance while
counties. The number of cases in each county ranged taking into account sample size (Norrander 2001,
from 10,326 in Los Angeles county to fourteen in Sierra 113).3 Measures of ideology will be more generaliz-
and Trinity counties (mean = 659.01). Ideology scores able across units with less intra-county variation and
ranged from the most conservative Sierra county (50.00) more variation in ideological dispositions inter-
to the most liberal San Francisco county (–25.35) with county. An O’Brien generalizability coefficient that
a mean = 21.28. Ideology scores and sample sizes for exceeds .70 is considered to be highly generalizable,
each of the fifty-eight counties are listed in Table 1. and values between .60 and .70 are considered to be
moderately generalizable. The O’Brien coefficient
for the county-level ideology measure is .96.
Auditing the County-Level
An additional test of reliability is the split-half
Measure of Ideology
approach used by Erikson, Wright, and McIver
Individual responses are treated here as aggregate (1993). The split-half approach involves splitting the
data, and therefore it is not appropriate to use stan- Field Poll sample into two subsets by assigning odd-
dard measures of individual-level reliability like year surveys to one subset and even years to the other.
Cronbach’s alpha (Brace et al. 2002). Because of this, Mean scores for county ideology were calculated for
Jones and Norrander (1996) recommend testing reli- each subset and correlated using Pearson’s r coeffi-
ability analysis on the basis of aggregate units, and cients. The Spearman-Brown prophesy formula was
not individuals. To first test the generalizability of the used to assess the reliability of each measure:
168 Political Research Quarterly

2r12 Field Poll sample, a series of demographic character-


, istics were derived from the Field Poll sample and
1 + r12
correlated with county demographic characteristics
where r12 = the Pearson’s r correlation between the split- collected by the U.S. Census (see Brace et al. 2002).
halves. Reliability scores of .70 and above are consid- Results presented in Table 2 show that county samples
ered reliable, those between .60 and .70 are considered obtained from the Field Poll are substantially represen-
moderately reliable, and those below .60 are consid- tative. Specifically, we find a strong correlation between
ered unreliable (Jones and Norrander 1996). The the educational attainment of the sample and educa-
Spearman-Brown coefficient for the reliability of the tional attainment reported by the U.S. Census in 1990
county-level ideology measure equals .60. and 2000 (U.S. Census Bureau). A similarly strong rela-
To test the stability of the measure, the Field Poll tionship is found among between the income of Field
sample was divided into “early” and “late” subsets. The Poll respondents and U.S. Census statistics. Racial char-
early subset included survey years 1990–1995, and the acteristics of respondents, although showing a slightly
late subset 1996–1999. Mean scores for county ideol- weaker correlation to U.S. Census figures than do the
ogy were calculated and correlated. The Spearman- education and income figures, are moderately strong
Brown coefficient for the stability of county-level nonetheless. Importantly, the strong correlations for
ideology was .62, close to what is considered the mini- education and income and the moderately strong corre-
mum reliability level. In sum, the assessment of lations for the race variables suggest that the Field Poll
the reliability of the ideology measure is mixed. The samples adequately reflect county populations.
O’Brien measure is highly reliable, although the
Spearman-Brown coefficients using the split-half Expectations about Public Opinion,
approach are at the low end of scores considered to be Government Institutions, and
“moderately” reliable. Given this, in a final attempt to Policy Making
assess the validity and reliability of the measure, we
constructed an alternative measure of county-level ide- Using the measure of county ideology discussed
ology using pooled survey data from the Public Policy above, our primary expectation is that counties’ ideolog-
Institute of California (PPIC). PPIC conducted seventy- ical makeup will impact policy outputs at the county level;
one surveys from 1998 to September 2006, and each however, we expect the relative impact of county ideol-
survey included questions about political ideology that ogy to vary across issue type and differing county struc-
substantively mirrors the Field Poll question we use tures. Among different issue types, local political
here. We constructed the same ideology measure using orientations should affect redistributive policies rather
this PPIC data, aggregated to the county level. These than those policies considered to be developmental or
county-level ideology scores are highly correlated with allocational in nature (Wong 1988). Policies associated
the Field Poll county scores (r = .82, p < .01), suggest- with welfare payments and public health care are consid-
ing that with repeated sampling, the survey-based mea- ered by Peterson (1981) as redistributive policies, and as
sure we use reliably gauges local-level political noted above, these policies often raise issues that are ide-
orientations. We have chosen to use the Field Poll ide- ologically divisive and more likely to elicit support or
ology measure here, but at the same time make note of opposition along ideological lines. Traditionally, conser-
its possible deficiencies, which in the analysis would vatives push for more restrictive welfare policies and less
likely tend to attenuate findings. government spending on public health care, reflecting
their views toward limiting both the size of government
How Well Do Field Poll–Based Measures and the scope of government intervention. In contrast,
liberals have traditionally pushed for greater welfare ben-
Represent County-Level California
efits with fewer restrictions and a more active role for
Demographics? government in health care, which reflects their overarch-
California counties are not the population of inter- ing belief in the social benefits that accrue from a larger,
est for the Field Poll, and thus we cannot assume that more active role for government in fighting social ills
the sampling frame employed by that organization related to poverty (Rom 1999). These associations
produces representative estimates of county popula- between ideology and policy outputs have been empiri-
tion. As noted by Hill and Hurley (1984), a sample cally demonstrated at the state level, where research has
bias might be introduced when creating a nonrandom found greater social welfare spending among states with
sample from state residents. To test the validity of the more liberal publics and political elites (Erikson, Wright,
Percival, Johnson, and Neiman / Representation and Local Policy 169

Table 2 service delivery roles (Benton 2002b). Thus, “reformed”


Representativeness of Field Poll County Samples county governments include those with an elected or
2000 1990 Average 1990/2000 appointed executive (rather than the traditional county
commission form, which lacks a singular executive
Education .91** .91** .91** authority), home rule charters, and nonpartisan elec-
Income .90** .92** .92**
tions. Early tests of the effects of local government
White .75** .76** .76**
Black .87** .88** .88** structures on policy decisions placed emphasis on cities
Asian .86** .87** .87** rather than counties. Lineberry and Fowler (1967)
Democratic Party .76** .78** .77** found that reformed city governments (at the city level
registration reformed structures are those with council-manager
**p < .01 government and at-large and nonpartisan elections) had
Note: Education is measured by the percentage of county resi- lower taxes and expenditures than unreformed cities
dents who have earned a bachelor’s degree or higher. Income is (i.e., cities with mayor-council government and partisan
measured by correlating the percentage of Field Poll respondents elections); however, Clark (1968) found reformed gov-
who mentioned their total household income was between ernments to have higher expenditures.
$20,000 and $40,000 dollars and the median household income
of the respondent’s county reported by the U.S. Census. Racial
More recent work examining the structure-policy
characteristics are based on sample estimates drawn from self- link at the county level has consistently found that
reported information from the Field Poll and are correlated with reformed county executive structures have higher per
U.S. Census data. Democratic Party registration is based on the capita expenditures than do unreformed county com-
percentage of Field Poll respondents who identified themselves mission forms (see Schneider and Park 1989).
as members of the Democratic Party and correlated with voter
Extending this line of work, DeSantis and Renner
registration data housed by the California Secretary of State.
(1996) argue that the impact of county structure is not
necessarily additive (or direct) but rather conditions
and McIver 1993; Hill and Hinton-Andersson 1995). the influence of county contextual factors like socio-
Conversely, allocational and developmental policies are economic and political factors on policy choices at the
less likely to engender political conflict, and therefore we county level. That is, particular county government
might expect ideology to matter less with respect to these structures may facilitate or hinder counties’ abilities
and other allocational and developmental policies. to respond to specific policy demands. For example,
Following this, our first hypothesis is that more using a measure of the percentage of the two-party
liberal counties will produce higher levels of spend- (Democratic) vote in the 1988 presidential campaign
ing on redistributive social programs like welfare and as a proxy for county ideology, DeSantis and Renner
public health care relative to more ideologically con- (1996) find ideology is unrelated to expenditures in
servative counties. Because allocational and develop- either county commission or county executive struc-
mental policies are generally associated with lower tures but has a positive and significant impact on expen-
levels of political conflict, we expect ideology to ditures for county administrator forms. Overall this
have little or no effect in these areas. evidence highlights the importance of testing for con-
Formally, the following hypothesis is tested: ditional effects between county ideology, county
structure, and local policy outputs.
H1: Ceteris paribus, ideologically liberal counties In California, county government structure does not
will produce higher levels of spending in redis- differ dramatically—all counties can be considered
tributive policy areas like welfare and public “reform” governments in that they have nonpartisan
health care relative to more ideologically con- elections and appointed executives rather than county
servative counties. commissions with no executive. However, the state of
California has two classifications of counties based
A growing body of literature focused on the impact on whether a county is considered to be a home rule
of county form or structure on policy suggests that any “charter” county or a “general law” county. Among
relationship between ideological orientations and pol- California counties, fourteen of fifty-eight are consid-
icy outputs may also be influenced by county structure ered “charter” counties (Connell 2001). Generally, a
(DeSantis and Renner 1996). Contemporary reforms in home-rule charter grants a county a greater degree of
American county structures have been designed to self-rule and self-determination that frees it from some
increase professionalism and centralize executive lead- legal restrictions imposed by the state (Duncombe
ership to more effectively carry out their expanding 1977). Chartered governments can also leverage
170 Political Research Quarterly

different fiscal reforms that make it easier to respond with different degrees of political conflict, depending on
to increasing resident demands for an expanded menu whether it manifests primarily a redistributive, develop-
of services as well as higher levels of current services mental, or allocational dynamic.
(Benton 2002b). The California Constitution, however,
does not allow officials in charter counties extra regu- Policy Indicators
latory functions or added revenue-raising abilities, but
The Office of the State Controller in California
it does allow them the ability to consolidate or segre-
releases an annual report on county revenues and
gate different county administrative offices, provide
expenditures, separate from fiscal data of all other local
for the election or appointment of county officials, and
governments (e.g. municipalities, school districts, or
set powers and duties of all officers.4 Although the
community college districts). We draw our policy indi-
State of California provides a limited amount of free-
cators from this report.5 We identify six areas of public
dom to its charter counties vis-à-vis other state-county
expenditures (Connell 2001), two in each of Peterson’s
government arrangements, given their increased dis-
issue typology. For allocational policies, we use general
cretion and capacity relative to general law county
government expenditures, which includes budget items
structures, we might expect the ideology-policy link-
from day-to-day county administration (e.g., legislative
age to be further strengthened in those counties where
and administrative expenses, finance, counsel, person-
a charter is present.
nel, elections, property management, etc.) and public
H2: The relationship between county ideology and protection (e.g., judicial services, police protection,
redistributive policy should be strengthened in detention and correction, fire protection, etc.). The
counties where a charter is present. Among coun- developmental policies we examine are education
ties with home rule charters, ideologically conser- (school administration, library services, and agricul-
vative counties will produce lower levels of tural education) and public ways and facilities (includ-
spending on redistributive policy areas like welfare ing roads, transportation systems, and parking). Finally,
and health care while more ideologically liberal our redistributive policies are health care (public health,
counties will produce higher levels of spending. medical care, mental health, drug and alcohol abuse
services) and public assistance (welfare, social ser-
vices, general relief, etc.).
Ideology and Local Policy To match the timing of our ideology data
Outputs in California (1990–1999), we use county expenditure data from the
1998–1999 fiscal year. We transform each of these
To examine the relationship between policy and the budget lines into measures of per capita spending, by
ideological disposition of California counties, we use dividing each county’s expenditures in each area by
data from California’s Office of the Controller on estimates of the county population in 1999 (California
county-level spending across six policy areas: public Institute of County Governments 2001). Consequently,
assistance, health and sanitation, public ways and facil- the dependent variables in the models that follow are
ities, education, public protection, and general govern- estimates of per capita expenditures across six policy
mental expenditures. These measures are the study’s areas at the county level for 1998–1999.6
dependent variables. The policy measures describe a
number of different policy areas—redistributive policies Alternative Explanations
(public assistance, health care), developmental spending As noted, our main independent variable is county-
(public ways and facilities, education), and allocational level political ideology, but we also consider other
expenditures (public protection and general governmen- possible explanatory variables. For example, the liter-
tal spending). We use these policy categories for two pri- ature on local policy determinants has long suggested
mary purposes. First, these are all policy areas in which the importance of a host of social, economic, and
county governments are actively involved in regard to demographic factors that shape public policy (for an
policy formulation and implementation. Second, they excellent compilation of relevant factors see Kantor
allow us to employ Peterson’s issue typology to explore and David 1983).
the relationship of ideology with policy outputs across a
substantively wide range of issues. Following Peterson Socioeconomic characteristics. It is intuitive that
(1981), each of these policy areas is likely associated fiscal capacity is a strong predictor of policy outputs
Percival, Johnson, and Neiman / Representation and Local Policy 171

(Dye 1979). How much a jurisdiction devotes to an Moreover, when public programs are perceived to tar-
activity must, in part, reflect the ability to support such get minority groups, program allocations tend to
services. Studies of subnational governments demon- become less generous (Katz 1989). Research of most
strate that economic factors like the per capita income relevance here shows local governments tend to impose
of residents predict public sector expansion (Hawkins tougher sanctions and fewer benefits to welfare recipi-
1971; Feiock and West 1993). Education is also related ents living in racially diverse contextual environments
to local expenditures: where more educated publics are (Keiser, Mueser, and Choi 2004). To control for the
politically involved they tend to finance public pro- possible influence of race on the dependent variables,
grams. In the models presented below, we include we include a measure of the percentage of black resi-
measures of median household income and the per- dents and the percentage of non-white Hispanics resid-
centage of residents who have earned a high school ing in each county. Data are drawn from the 2000 U.S.
diploma or higher. Data are drawn from the 2000 U.S. Census (U.S. Census Bureau).
Census. It might be expected that counties with greater
median incomes and educational attainment levels
would have a greater capacity to increase spending Findings
across all the policy areas.
Table 3 provides OLS regression models for each
Intergovernmental revenues. Although county of the six policy output dependent variables. In each
spending levels can be viewed as partly a function of the regression models, we include a county struc-
of the socioeconomic characteristics of its resi- ture dummy variable (1 = charter, 0 = no charter) and
dents, we also have to take into account that county a charter*ideology interaction term to test the second
expenditures are constrained by intergovernmental hypothesis that county structure conditions the
grants-in-aid or revenue sharing from the state or fed- impact of ideology on county-level policy outputs.
eral government. For example, counties may receive Among the redistributive policy models, county-level
funding from the state or the federal government (or ideology has a negative and statistically significant
both) for welfare or health care programs, but levels influence on redistributive policy outputs after control-
of funding are often set by how many people live in a ling for other possible predictors; however, the relation-
county who meet eligibility criteria rather than how ship is only significant when considering public
much the county wants to spend. Because it is our assistance expenditures. The negative coefficient for the
goal to show that local ideological forces shape ideology measure in the public assistance model indi-
county spending choices, it is important to control for cates that ceteris paribus, liberal counties are more likely
any effects driven by federal or state revenue sent to expend greater funds on welfare and other social ser-
down to county governments. To account for county vices than counties that are more conservative. A stan-
spending choices influenced by state and federal dard deviation change in ideology exemplifies
funding levels, we include in the regression models movement from a relatively liberal place like Los
two variables labeled state funds and federal funds, Angeles County to a substantially more liberal place
which are per capita measures of state and federal like Alameda County (with cities including Oakland and
revenues directed to each county in 1998–1999 Berkeley), or alternatively a shift from Orange County
(Connell 2001). We expect higher levels of spending in southern California to Humboldt County in the north-
in those counties that receive higher per capita levels ern portion of the state. The standardized coefficient for
of state or federal funding. county ideology in the public assistance model is .28,
suggesting that a standard deviation shift in ideology
Racial politics. Increasingly, political scholars point would be associated with an additional $90.24 spent per
to racial diversity within any given environment as a capita on a county’s public assistance programs in
significant predictor of public policy and how public 1998–1999. The debate over assistance to the poor and
programs are distributed (Hero 1998). Racial diversity the scope of government involvement are more often
may impact policy in a couple ways. Geographic prox- politically contentious and structured by ideological
imity to large number of racial minorities may increase beliefs and attitudes. Given this, it is not surprising to
sentiments of racial threat among whites (Key 1949; find that local ideological dispositions relate to outputs
Stein, Post, and Rinden 2000). Perceptions of racial in this policy area.
threat tend to decrease support of policies perceived to In addition, the charter*ideology interaction term
help minority members (Stein, Post, and Rinden 2000). has a negative and statistically significant association
172 Political Research Quarterly

Table 3
Modeling Local Per Capita Spending across Six Policy Areas, OLS with Robust Standard Errors
Allocational Policies Developmental Policies Redistributive Policies

General Public Protection Education Public Ways and Facilities Health Care Public Assistance

Ideology –2.441 –0.177 –0.390* 2.87*** –0.093 –2.21***


(1.91) (1.112) (0.226) (0.847) (0.964) (0.708)
Income 0.005** 0.003*** 0.000 0.006*** 0.000 –0.006***
(0.002) (0.001) (0.000) (0.001) (0.001) (0.001)
Education 7.784*** 4.403*** 0.546* –2.14 –0.509** 3.998**
(2.80) (1.50) (0.291) (1.40) (2.016) (1.69)
County structure –140.22*** –72.99 –12.43*** –33.22 307.212** 40.555
(69.40) (49.62) (5.03) (43.83) (154.196) (33.78)
Charter*ideology 4.890* 1.96 0.467** –0.223 –12.102* 0.151
(2.55) (1.77) (0.212) (1.57) (5.875) (1.23)
State funds 1.359*** 1.106*** 0.080*** 0.675*** 0.348*** 0.110†
(0.251) (0.142) (0.019) (0.066) (0.090) (0.063)
Federal funds 0.233 0.074 0.022 0.522*** 0.097 0.408***
(0.185) (0.116) (0.013) (0.123) (0.095) (0.111)
Black 10.76 –30.485 14.556 –390.392 –402.125 373.299**
(392.95) (320.44) (45.93) (244.13) (522.447) (169.52)
Hispanic 391.28† 211.612 25.954 –254.638** 0.195 329.334***
(217.60) (162.68) (22.81) (121.02) 117.470 (117.91)
Constant –1306.16*** –681.630 –73.244*** –412.604*** –14.158 125.490***
(282.25) (185.11) (25.51) (110.80) (136.071) (114.890)
N = 57 N = 57 N = 57 N = 57 N = 58 N = 57
F9,47 = 5.64*** F9,47 = 9.85*** F9,47 = 4.99*** F9,47 = 147.15*** F9,48 = 3.49*** F9,47 = 70.49***
R2 = .84 R2 = .87 R2 = .78 R2 = .88 R2 = .66 R2 = .81

***p < .01, **p < .05, *p < .10


Note: Robust standard errors shown in parentheses below each coefficient. Except for the health care model San Francisco County is
excluded from the analysis because expenditures across these policy areas are not recorded in a comparable manner.

with counties’ health care expenditures, with more greater funds across each policy indicator, while
conservative counties with charters spending less, on federal funds increases counties’ spending in the
average, than more ideologically liberal counties with public ways and facilities and public assistance pol-
charters. Conversely, no relationship is found between icy categories. The county structure variable also
the charter*ideology interaction term and public appears to influence spending choices, with those coun-
assistance expenditures. At least when considering ties with home-rule charters spending more on gen-
health care expenditures, this finding suggests county eral government, education, and health care. Finally,
structure has a mediating impact on county ideology, larger black and Hispanic populations are associated
where as expected, a charter strengthens the associa- with more spending on public assistance.
tion between counties’ ideological dispositions and As expected, controlling for these alternative
policy outputs. spending explanations, we find no significant rela-
Several additional predictor variables are associ- tionship between ideology and the budget lines in the
ated with patterns of county-level spending across developmental policy areas and allocational policies
the different policy domains. Higher levels of like general government expenditures; however, con-
income are associated with more general govern- trary to our expectations, ideology had a negative and
ment, public protection, and public ways and facili- statistically significant relationship with public pro-
ties spending, but less spending on public tection spending. Overall, these findings lend support
assistance. Higher educational achievement is asso- to Peterson’s (1981) assertion that allocational poli-
ciated with more spending on general government, cies like legislative and administrative expenditures,
public protection, and public assistance, but lower and developmental policies like highway construc-
levels of health care expenditures. Counties with tion cause little political conflict, and as we advance
higher levels of per capita state funding expend here, less likely to be influenced by local ideological
Percival, Johnson, and Neiman / Representation and Local Policy 173

Table 4
Modeling Local Per Capita Spending across Six Policy Areas, Heteroskedastic Regressions
Allocational Policies Developmental Policies Redistributive Policies

Public Public Ways Health Public


General Protection Education and Facilities Care Assistance

Choice model
Ideology –0.306 0.924 –0.065 –0.165 –0.938* –1.923***
(0.59) (0.811) (0.081) (0.462) (0.559) (0.605)
Income –0.000 0.001 0.000 0.000 –0.000 –0.006***
(0.000) (0.001) (0.000) (0.000) (0.001) (0.000)
Education 1.29 0.479 0.165 0.150 1.324 3.210***
(1.129) (1.589) (0.157) (0.861) (1.786) (1.247)
County structure –35.83** –28.659 –6.420** –20.734 309.748*** 34.242
(18.721) (29.243) (2.770) (13.645) (59.681) (26.815)
Charter*ideology 0.563 –0.345 0.143 0.463 –12.016*** 0.155
(0.769) (1.170) (0.111) (0.568) (2.121) (1.041)
State funds 0.260** 0.647*** 0.016 0.063 0.201*** 0.105
(0.129) (0.141) (0.016) (0.102) (0.049) (0.067)
Federal funds –0.100 0.000 0.012 0.144** 0.120 0.460***
(.088) (0.113) (0.011) (0.070) (0.087) (0.077)
Black –184.517 –75.041 19.768 –210.452* –661.484 304.186
(155.738) (228.802) (22.220) (116.591) (414.806) (195.553)
Hispanic –33.183 8.494 –12.594 –134.158** –16.577 294.708***
(91.840) (126.35) (12.617) (70.81) (140.117) (97.025)
Constant –36.987 –86.642 –12.986 19.88 1.666 150.518
(110.304) (145.004) (14.915) (84.165) (127.453) (101.104)
Variance model
Estimated margin of error 30.205*** 18.392*** 22.699*** 37.362*** –13.886*** 7.757***
(2.827) (2.827) (2.827) (2.827) (2.804) (2.827)
Constant 5.410*** 6.752*** 1.874*** 4.503*** 10.058*** 6.999***
(0.315) (0.315) (0.316) (0.315) (0.310) (0.315)
N = 57 N = 57 N = 57 N = 57 N = 58 N = 57
χ2= 192.67*** χ2= 142.90*** χ2= 130.02*** χ2= 140.285*** χ2= 85.301*** χ2= 100.256***
ps. R2 = .23 ps. R2 = .18 ps. R2 = .25 ps. R2 = .19 ps. R2 = .11 ps. R2 = .14

***p < .01, **p < .05, *p < .10

dispositions. Significantly, these results suggest that standard errors. Still, we are concerned about poten-
the importance of ideology on local-level policy mak- tially biased coefficients in these models and hypothe-
ing will depend to an extent on the issue under con- sis tests marred by the uncertainty associated with these
sideration and the structure of county government. standard errors. Because we know that sample size will
The results presented thus far are mixed, having systematically affect the variance of the disturbances
found evidence of a direct relationship between ideol- around the regression lines, we deal with this more
ogy and redistributive policy but only when taking into systematically, by modeling the variance of the regres-
consideration public assistance expenditures like wel- sion line using heteroskedastic regression.7
fare and other social services. The absence of a statis- Table 4 shows models similar to those in Table 3,
tically significant association between county ideology reestimated with the variance models described in
and both redistributive models may be a result from Note 7. We see that, as expected, the margin of error
not having accounted adequately for the variation in we computed for each county subsample has a sys-
sample sizes used to compute the ideology measure at tematic influence on the disturbance term of the
the county level. In Table 1, we see sample sizes rang- choice model for each regression. The larger the mar-
ing from fourteen (Trinity and Sierra Counties) to gin of error, the greater the variance is around the
more than ten thousand (Los Angeles County). Given regression line for a given observation.
the obvious source of heteroskedasticity in these mod- Closely resembling the results in Table 3, the
els, we would not trust conventional standard errors, so choice models show county ideology is a significant
we estimated the models in Table 3 calculating robust predictor of public assistance spending, but not health
174 Political Research Quarterly

care expenditures. In the public assistance model, the counties producing more liberal/conservative policy
negative and significant coefficient suggests that outputs. These differences may be partly a function of
more liberal counties spend more on things like wel- the nature of political conflict surrounding welfare and
fare programs than do more ideologically conservative health care policies in the late 1990s. The late 1990s
counties. Again, the charter*ideology interaction term marked a politically contentious era in welfare policy
failed to reach statistical significance suggesting that as controversial welfare reform efforts, driven by the
the relationship between ideological dispositions and adoption of the federal 1996 TANF law, were well
public assistance programs is not conditioned by under way at the county level. Thus, relative to health
county structure. care policy, the high degree of political conflict con-
However, the charter*ideology interaction term is nected to welfare may be behind the more robust rela-
again statistically significant in the health care model. tionship between ideology and public assistance
Support for these types of health care services, similar to expenditures; however, more research is needed to
those connected to other forms of public assistance like understand these more nuanced effects among the two
welfare, tend to break down along political ideological redistributive policy areas.
lines. The finding here suggests that the influence of
county ideology on per capita spending on public health,
medical care, mental health, or drug and alcohol abuse Discussion
services is conditioned by county structure—more con-
servative counties with home rule charters spend, on The findings presented here suggest students of sub-
average, fewer dollars on health care compared to more national politics would benefit from paying additional
ideologically liberal counties with home rule charters. In attention to the ideological variation within individual
the case of health care expenditures, the influence of ide- states as well as variation between states. Using a well-
ology is only apparent when counties have greater struc- established, multiyear state survey instrument like the
tural freedom from the arms of the state government and California Field Poll to create reliable, valid, and sta-
where policy makers have greater administrative capac- ble measures of local ideology as we do here indicates
ity to match the policy to the preferences of their con- that subnational researchers can use similar method-
stituents. As expected, the choice models show that the ological tools to advance our understanding of the way
relationship between ideology and public protection local ideology influences local policy making and the
expenditures found in Table 3 disappears, with county extent to which policy represents the political interests
ideology having no significant impact on any of the allo- of diverse, localized populations.
cational or developmental policies. We find that local policy outputs are influenced by
Taken together, these results suggest that ideologi- counties’ ideological dispositions where more liberal/
cal cleavages at the local level help drive differences in conservative counties produce more liberal/conservative
counties’ spending choices across redistributive poli- outputs across a range of policy areas including public
cies. However, when considering the relationship health care and welfare. Importantly, the influence of
between local ideology and local policy outputs, the counties’ ideology varies across different policy issues
impact of counties’ ideological makeup differs with ideology playing a more important role on redistrib-
depending on the issue type under consideration, in utive policy areas—those issues characterized by a
addition to county structure. As hypothesized, county higher degree of political conflict—and a less important
ideology influences redistributive policy areas—where role on issues where little political conflict occurs. On
political conflict is more likely to be felt—rather than issues with little political conflict, intergovernmental
those that are less politically contentious at the mass expenditures and county-level demographic and socio-
level like developmental and allocation policies. Given economic contextual characteristics tend to drive expen-
this, even among redistributive policies the ideology- diture patterns across the counties. The relationship
policy linkage is not necessarily straightforward— between ideology and policy also appears to be condi-
county structure matters. When considering health care tioned by county structure. In California, a home rule
spending, the impact of county ideology is only evident charter appears to strengthen the relationship between
when coupled with a home rule charter that provides ideology and health care expenditures than the main
policy makers greater capacity to attune particular pol- effects of county ideology alone would suggest. More
icy expenditures to ideological beliefs held among conservative counties with charters are found to spend
county residents. With public assistance policy, county less on public health care relative to more ideologically
ideology appears to influence policy outputs regardless liberal counties. This set of findings challenges previous
of county structure with more liberal/conservative assumptions connected to the local policy-making
Percival, Johnson, and Neiman / Representation and Local Policy 175

process. Prior research suggests that local economic con- that a variety of local political forces continues to
siderations are the main driving force behind local policy shape policy and provides a framework for a produc-
decisions and local governments should be biased tive and rewarding research agenda in the area of
against redistributive policies. Taken as a whole, we local government policy making.
show that that under the right political and structural con-
ditions, there is still room for local politics to influence
policy choices at the local level of government. Notes
Finally, it is important to consider the extent to
1. Cohen (2006, 6–10) describes a variety of alternatives to
which our findings here are representative of the local
measuring state public opinion using pooled national sample sur-
ideology-policy relationship in other county govern- veys. In principle, these alternatives are also feasible for measuring
ments across the U.S. political system. Does the fact county-level ideology. These alternatives include pooling surveys
that we find associations between ideology and policy with subunit samples (Jones and Norrander 1996), combining
in California suggest that these same forces spill over independent surveys taken within comparable subnational geo-
to other county governments in other regions such as graphic units (Beyle, Niemi, and Sigelman 2002) and simulating
public opinion using survey data or other political information
the Northeast, South, or Midwest? (Weber et al. 1972–1973; Berry et al. 1998; Park, Bafumi, and
DeSantis and Renner (1996) note significant vari- Gelman 2003). Given the absence of California surveys with com-
ation in county spending levels throughout different parable county-level subunit samples or any comparable indepen-
regions of the United States. Traditionally, western dent surveys of California counties, we are unable to pursue two of
counties spend more (in absolute terms) than counties these alternatives. Simulating county-level ideology is a reasonable
alternative (see Berkman and Plutzer 2005), but these techniques
in other regions—especially those counties in the
generally rely on extensive assumptions about connections
South, which tend to have more powerful state between individual demographic attributes and opinions. We make
governments relative to local governments. The different assumptions, namely that the coverage of county resi-
Progressive movement of the early twentieth century dents in these pooled statewide samples of California allow us to
has left a lasting legacy on Western county govern- capture a meaningful county-level measure of ideology. Scholars
ments as most are considered “reformed” govern- who simulate public opinion measures share our assumptions
about forming public opinion from the aggregation of individual
ments and, with that, have a greater capacity to opinions. In sum, the simulation of public opinion is complemen-
deliver an increasing array of services. Our study, tary to the approach we take, but not clearly preferable.
which examines the influence of local political ideol- 2. The Field Poll uses samples of the California telephone
ogy on policy in the State of California, with its household population drawn from random digit dial (RDD) sam-
reformed county structures and relatively active ples of Survey Sampling Incorporated. The sample is a stratified
sample of California counties where samples are systematically
county governments is most likely to be representa-
stratified to all counties in proportion to each county’s share of
tive of local policy making in the western United telephone households in the survey area. Further sampling infor-
States. As the population of California and the rest of mation can be referenced from the California Field Poll Code
the western states continues to grow and as local Books 1990–1999.
communities form unique political attitudes caused 3. O’Brien’s (1990) generalizability coefficient for the R:A
by increasing racial and ethnic diversity, finding asso- design contemplates the mean square, an estimate of the popula-
tion variance between aggregate units, MS(a), and the mean
ciations between local ideological attitudes and local square for individual-level scores within the aggregated units,
policy is an important contribution by itself. MS(r:a), using the formula:
Although absolute spending levels have been doc-
umented to be highest in the West, there remains a [MS(a) – MS (r:a)]
strong likelihood that creating reliable and valid mea- E ^ρ2 =
MS(a)
sures of county ideology can be shown to shape rela-
tive spending levels in counties in regions of the
country that have traditionally spent fewer dollars in MS(a) and MS(r:a) were estimated using the one-way ANOVA
procedure in SPSS.
absolute terms. In the end, this is an empirical ques- 4. However, in both home rule charter and general law coun-
tion that is beyond the scope of this research. A ties, the county sheriff, district attorney, and assessor must be
number of regular, institutionalized state-level sur- elected.
veys (National Network of State Polls 2007) suggest 5. The definitions of the budget items providing the policy
the possibility that scholars can create ideology mea- indicators are discussed in an appendix to the State of California
Counties Annual Report (Connell 2001, 145–7).
sures like those used here to test the influence of ide-
6. We follow other researchers who have investigated policy-
ology in counties outside the western region of the oriented dependent variables from a cross-sectional measure, or
United States. Importantly, we believe the analysis based on a small number of years using an independent variable
here adds to the growing body of work suggesting constructed from data from an inclusive larger set of years (e.g.,
176 Political Research Quarterly

Schneider and Jacoby 2006; Uslaner 2006). The indicators we Benton, Edwin J., and Platon Rigos. 1985. Patterns of metropol-
and other researchers use are contemporaneous. itan service dominance: Central city and central county ser-
7. Harvey (1976) develops a regression model that allows us vice roles compared. Urban Affairs Quarterly 220:285-302.
to systematically model sources of heteroskedasticity. A choice Berkman, Michael B., and Eric Plutzer. 2005. Ten thousand
model is used to test hypotheses about the dependent variable, democracies: Politics and public opinion in America’s school
and a variance model is used to explore systematic variance in the districts. Washington, DC: Georgetown University Press.
choice model’s disturbance term: Berman, David R., and Tanis J. Salant. 1996. The changing role
of counties in the intergovernmental system. In The American
yi = xiβ + ui (i = 1, 2, 3, . . ., n), (1) county: Frontiers of knowledge, ed. Donald C. Menzel.
Tuscaloosa: The University of Alabama Press.
Berry, William D., Evan J. Ringquist, Richard C. Fording, and
σi2 = eziα (i = 1, 2, 3, . . ., n), (2)
Russell L. Hanson. 1998. Measuring citizen and government
ideology in the American states, 1960-93. American Journal
where yi is a vector of observations on the dependent variable, xi is a of Political Science 42:327-48.
vector of observations on independent variables, β is a vector of para- Beyle, Thad, Richard G. Niemi, and Lee Sigelman. 2002.
meters, ui is the disturbance term of the choice model, σi2 is the vari- Gubernatorial, senatorial, and state-level presidential job
ance of the disturbance term, zi is a vector of observations of approval: The U.S. officials job approval ratings (JAR) collec-
independent variables, and α is a vector of parameters. In the tradi- tion. State Politics and Policy Quarterly 2:215-31.
tional regression model, we assume the disturbances around the Bowman, Ann O’m, and Richard C. Kearney. 1986. The resur-
regression line are distributed Normal with a mean of 0 and a fixed gence of the states. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall.
variance (ui ~ N[0, σ2]). Harvey’s multiplicative heteroskedasticity Brace, Paul, Kellie N. Butler, Kevin Arceneaux, and Martin
model, we anticipate systematic variance in the disturbance term. Johnson. 2002. Measuring public opinion in the American
Here we model the variance of the residuals of the choice model states: An expanded range of aggregated measures, 1974-
as a function of a computed margin of error, which takes into 1998. American Journal of Political Science 46:173-89.
account sizes of the county subsamples, as well as the size of the California Institute of County Governments. 2001. The
underlying population of the county sampled. This is roughly equiv- California county fact book. Sacramento: California Institute
alent to the margin of error discussed with polling results, plus or of County Governments in conjunction with California State
minus some percentage that depends primarily on the number of Association of Counties. http://www.cicg.org/data (accessed
people surveyed, as well as the size of the population of interest. March 10, 2003).
Given the wide variance of county sizes as well as wide variance of Cigler, Beverly A. 1990. County government: A century of change. In
subsample sizes, we thought it important to take both into account. The Municipal Yearbook 1989. Washington DC: ICMA, 55-65.
We calculate margin of error (see Weisbert, Krosnick, and Bowen Clark, Terry N. 1968. Community structure, decision making,
1996, 74) using the following formula: budget expenditures, and urban renewal in 51 cities. American
Sociological Review 33:576-93.
rffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi Clingermayer, James C., and Richard Feiock. 1995. Council
pð1 − pÞpffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffiffi (3)
MOE = +t 1−f, views toward targeting developmental policy benefits. The
N −1 Journal of Politics 57 (2): 508-20.
Cohen, Jeffrey E. 2006. Introduction: Studying public opinion in
where t = 1.96 for a 95 percent confidence interval, p = the sam- the American states. In Public opinion in state politics, ed.
ple proportion which we set at .5 to calculate a conservative mar- Jeffrey E. Cohen. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
gin of error, N = number of observations in county subsample, Connell, Kathleen. 2001. State of California counties annual
and f = the sampling fraction, or the number of respondents in the report, fiscal year 1998-1999. Sacramento: Office of California
county subsample divided by the total county population. Using State Controller. http://www.sco.ca.gov/ard/local/locrep/
the formula, we compute margins of error for the county-level counties/9899/index.shtml (accessed April 17, 2006).
ideology scores that vary from ±1.0 percent (Los Angeles DeSantis, Victor S., and Tari Renner. 1996. Structure and policy
County) to ±27.2 percent (Trinity County). expenditures in American counties. In The American county:
Frontiers of knowledge, ed. Donald C. Menzel. Tuscaloosa:
The University of Alabama Press.
References Duncombe, Herbert S. 1977. Modern county government.
Washington, DC: National Association of Counties.
Arceneaux, Kevin. 2001. The “gender gap” in state legislative Dye, Thomas. 1979. Politics and economics: The development of
representation: New data to tackle an old question. Political the literature on policy determination. Policy Studies Journal
Research Quarterly 54:143-60. (June): 652-62.
Banfield, Edward, and James Q. Wilson. 1963. City politics. Erikson, Robert S. 1978. Constituency opinion and congressional
Cambridge, MA: Harvard and MIT Press. behavior: A reexamination of the Miller-Stokes representation
Benton, Edwin J. 2002a. Counties as service delivery agents: data. American Journal of Political Science 22:511-35.
Changing expectations and roles. New York: Praeger. Erikson, Robert S., Gerald C. Wright, and John P. McIver. 1993.
Benton, Edwin J. 2002b. County service delivery: Does govern- Statehouse democracy: Public opinion and policy in the
ment structure matter? Public Administration Review 62:471-9. American states. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Benton, Edwin J. 2003. County governments. In Encyclopedia of Eulau, Heinz. 1973. Labyrinths of democracy: Adaptation, linkages,
public administration and public policy, ed. Jack Rabin. New representation, and policies in urban politics. Indianapolis, IN:
York: Marcel Dekker. Bobbs-Merrill.
Percival, Johnson, and Neiman / Representation and Local Policy 177

Feiock, Richard C., and Jonathan West. 1993. Testing competing O’Brien, Robert M. 1990. Estimating the reliability of aggregate-
explanations for local policy adoption: Municipal solid waste level variables on individual-level characteristics. Sociological
recycling programs. Political Research Quarterly 46 (2): 399-419. Methods and Research 18:473-504.
Harvey, A. C. 1976. Estimating regression models with multi- Park, David K., Joseph Bafumi, and Andrew Gelman. 2003.
plicative heteroskedasticity. Econometrica 44:461-65. Bayesian multilevel estimation with post stratification:
Hawkins, Brett W. 1971. Politics and urban policies. Indianapolis, State-level estimates from national polls. Political Analysis
IN: Bobbs-Merrill. 12:375-85.
Hero, Rodney E. 1998. Faces of inequality: Social diversity in Peterson, Paul E. 1979. A unitary model of local taxation and
American politics. New York: Oxford University Press. expenditure policies in the United States. British Journal of
Hill, Kim Quaile, and Angela Hinton-Andersson. 1995. Pathways Political Science 9:281-314.
of representation: A causal analysis of public opinion-policy Peterson, Paul E. 1981. City limits. Chicago: University of Chicago
linkages. American Journal of Political Science 39:924-35. Press.
Hill, Kim Quaile, and Patricia A. Hurley. 1984. Estimating con- Pierce, John, Nicholas Lovrich, and C. David Moon. 2002. Social
gressional district attitudes with national election study data: capital and government performance: An analysis of twenty
A reliability assessment. Political Methodology 10:447-63. American cities. Public Productivity and Management Review
Hill, Kim Quaile, and Jan E. Leighley. 1996. Political parties and 25:381-97.
class mobilization in contemporary United States elections. Rom, Mark C. 1999. Transforming state health and welfare pro-
American Journal of Political Science 40:787-804. grams. In Politics in the American states, ed. Virginia Gray
Johnson, Martin, Paul Brace, and Kevin Arceneaux. 2005. Public and Herbert Jacobs. Washington, DC: CQ Press.
opinion and dynamic representation in the American states: Schneider, Mark, and Kee Ok Park. 1989. Metropolitan counties
The case of environmental attitudes. Social Science Quarterly as service delivery agents: The still forgotten governments.
86:87-108. Public Administration Review 49:345-52.
Jones, Bradford S., and Barbara Norrander. 1996. The reliability Schneider, Saundra K., and William G. Jacoby. 2006. Citizen
of aggregated public opinion measures. American Journal of influences on state policy priorities: The interplay of public
Political Science 40:295-309. opinion and interest groups. In Public opinion in the states, ed.
Kantor, Paul, and Stephen David. 1983. The political economy of Jeffrey E. Cohen. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
change in urban budgetary politics: A framework for analysis Stein, Robert M., Stephanie Shirley Post, and Allison L. Rinden.
and a case study. British Journal of Political Science 23:251-74. 2000. Reconciling context and contact effects on racial atti-
Katz, Michael R. 1989. The undeserving poor: From the war on tudes. Political Research Quarterly 53:285-303.
poverty to the war on welfare. New York. Pantheon. Stimson, James A., Michael B. MacKuen, and Robert S. Erikson.
Keiser, Lael R., Peter R. Mueser, and Seung-Whan Choi. 2004. 1996. Dynamic representation. American Political Science
Race, bureaucratic discretion, and the implementation of wel- Review 89:543-65.
fare reform. American Journal of Political Science 48:314-328. U.S. Census Bureau. State and county quick facts.
Key, V. O. 1949. Southern politics in state and nation. New York. http://www.quickfacts.census.gov/qfd/states/06000.html
Alfred A. Knopf. (accessed March 21, 2003).
Lewis, Paul. 2001a. Looking outward or turning inward? Uslaner, Eric M. 2006. The civic state: Trust, polarization, and
Motivations for development decisions in central cities and the quality of state government. In Public opinion in the
suburbs. Urban Affairs Review 36:296-320. states, ed. Jeffrey E. Cohen. Stanford, CA: Stanford
Lewis, Paul. 2001b. Retail politics: Local sales taxes and the fiscal- University Press.
ization of land use. Economic Development Quarterly 15:21-35. Weber, Ronald E., Anne H. Hopkins, Michael L. Mezey, and
Lineberry, Robert L., and Edmund P. Fowler. 1967. Reformism Frank Munger. 1972-1973. Computer simulation of state elec-
and public policies in American cities. American Political torates. Public Opinion Quarterly 36:49-65.
Science Review 61:701-16. Weber, Ronald E., and William R. Shaffer. 1972. Public opinion
Lipsky, Michael. 1980. Street-level bureaucracy: Dilemmas of and American state policy-making. Midwest Journal of
the individual in public services. New York: Russell Sage Political Science 16:683-99.
Foundation. Weisbert, Herbert F., Jon A. Krosnick, and Bruce D. Bowen.
Martin, Lawrence L., and Ronald C. Nyhan. 1994. Determinants 1996. An introduction to survey research, polling, and data
of county charter home rule. International Journal of Public analysis. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.
Administration 17:955-70. Wlezien, Christopher. 1995. The public as thermostat: Dynamics
Miller, Warren E., and Donald E. Stokes. 1963. Constituency of preferences for spending. American Journal of Political
influence in Congress. American Political Science Review Science 39:981-1000.
57:45-56. Wlezien, Christopher. 1996. Dynamics of representation: The
Morehouse, Sarah McCally. 1973. The state political party and case of U.S. spending on defence. British Journal of Political
the policy-making process. American Political Science Science 26:81-103.
Review 67: 55-72. Wong, Kenneth K. 1988. Economic constraint and political
National Network of State Polls. 2007. NNSP: National network choice in urban policymaking. American Journal of Political
of state polls. Last updated April 14, 2007. Lexington: Survey Science 32:1-18.
Research Center, University of Kentucky. http://survey.rgs. Wright, Gerald C., Robert S. Erikson, and John P. McIver. 1985.
uky.edu/nnsp/ (accessed August 29, 2007). Measuring state partisanship and ideology with survey data.
Norrander, Barbara. 2001. Measuring state public opinion with Journal of Politics 47:469-89.
the senate national election study. State Politics and Policy
Quarterly 1:111-25.

You might also like