You are on page 1of 13

姝 Academy of Management Review

2005, Vol. 30, No. 3, 622–633.

WHAT DETERMINES THE SCOPE OF THE FIRM


OVER TIME? A FOCUS ON INSTITUTIONAL
RELATEDNESS
MIKE W. PENG
The Ohio State University

SEUNG-HYUN LEE
University of Texas at Dallas

DENIS Y. L. WANG
Chinese University of Hong Kong

“What determines the scope of the firm?” is one of the most fundamental questions in
strategic management. We argue that, in addition to product relatedness, a focus on
institutional relatedness—defined as an organization’s informal linkages with dom-
inant institutions that confer resources and legitimacy—helps answer this question.
We address this question both longitudinally (firms in developed and emerging
economies over time) and cross-sectionally (developed versus emerging economies),
thus contributing to an institution-based theory of corporate diversification.

As part of the broader intellectual movement search, this article addresses the question
centered on new institutionalism throughout the “What determines the scope of the firm?”— one
social sciences in recent decades (North, 1990; of the four most fundamental questions in stra-
Powell & DiMaggio, 1991; Scott, 1995; William- tegic management identified by Rumelt, Schen-
son, 2000), strategic approaches to organization del, and Teece (1994: 564).
are considering institutional forces much more Although scholars in the strategy field have
explicitly than before (Henisz, 2003; Oliver, 1997; pursued the scope of the firm question for three
Peng, 2003, 2006). Researchers increasingly real- decades, clear answers have remained elusive.
ize that institutions are more than background Drawing on three streams of research, we argue
conditions and that “institutions directly deter- that scope is driven by a combination of product
mine what arrows a firm has in its quiver as it and institutional relatedness. The first stream
struggles to formulate and implement strategy” highlights the importance of organizational in-
(Ingram & Silverman, 2002: 20; emphasis added). tegration and disintegration over time (Law-
Positioned to deepen our understanding of how rence & Lorsch, 1967). Although findings since
an institutional perspective adds to strategy re- Rumelt (1974) generally suggest that, in devel-
oped economies, unrelated product diversifica-
tion (conglomeration) tends to destroy value,
This work was supported in part by the Hong Kong Re-
search Grants Council (Competitive Earmarked Research
conglomeration has been found to add value
Grant CUHK4148/03H), the National Science Foundation (CA- during an earlier era (Davis, Diekmann, & Tins-
REER Grant SES 0238820, formerly known as a Young Inves- ley, 1994). Given that conclusions reached in dif-
tigator Award), the OSU Center for International Business ferent studies may be influenced by their sam-
Education and Research and Graduate School, and the ple period (Mayer & Whittington, 2003), a more
CUHK Faculty of Business Administration (Direct Grants
2070283, 207304, and 207204). The views expressed are ours
meaningful question seems to be “What deter-
and not those of our funding organizations. Earlier versions mines the scope of the firm over time?” (Lee,
were presented at the Academy of International Business Peng, & Lee, 2003). The second stream of re-
(Phoenix, 2000) and the Academy of Management (Seattle, search posits that conglomeration may help
2003). Finally, we thank Trevor Buck, Nancy Ettlinger, Keun firms overcome institutional imperfections prev-
Lee, Soo Hee Lee, Yongsun Paik, Agnes Peng, and Anne York
for their helpful discussions and comments, Dev Jennings
alent in emerging countries (Chang & Hong,
(action editor) and the three reviewers for editorial guidance, 2000; Guillen, 2000; Khanna & Palepu, 1997). The
and Yuanyuan Zhou for research assistance. third stream focuses on the changes in the rules
622
2005 Peng, Lee, and Wang 623

of the game as economies develop (Hoskisson, 1970s were less developed. Thus, conglomerates
Eden, Lau, & Wright, 2000; North, 1990), putting a were perceived ex ante by external capital mar-
great deal of emphasis not only on markets but kets to have an advantage in allocating capital.
also on institutional transitions that influence Over time, as external capital markets devel-
corporate scope. It is argued that, during an oped, this conglomerate advantage likely be-
early phase of transitions, a relationship-based came less important (Liebeskind, 2000).
strategy would be preferred (Peng & Heath, The value of product scope seems to be differ-
1996), whereas a market-centered strategy ent in emerging economies, which are “low-
would surface during a late phase of transitions income, rapid-growth countries using economic
characterized by more formal market-support- liberalization as their primary engine of growth”
ing institutions (Peng, 2003). (Hoskisson et al., 2000: 249). The striking institu-
Extending earlier work of Peng (2003)1 that tional differences between emerging and devel-
focuses on how institutional transitions affect oped economies have brought new institution-
strategic choices in general, we probe how in- alism to the center stage of strategy research on
stitutional transitions affect a specific and im- emerging economies (Peng, 2000, 2003; Wright,
portant form of corporate strategy: diversifica- Filatotchev, Hoskisson, & Peng, 2005). Although
tion. We maintain that a firm’s product scope Western media and advisors often suggest that
depends not only on its product relatedness but conglomerates destroy value and should be dis-
also its institutional relatedness, which refers to mantled, recent evidence suggests otherwise.
the degree of informal embeddedness with the For instance, in Argentina, India, Indonesia, Is-
dominant institutions in the environment that rael, Peru, South Africa, South Korea, and Tai-
confer resources and legitimacy on the focal or- wan, Chang and Hong (2000), Guillen (2000),
ganization. Since most existing work has dealt Khanna and Palepu (1999, 2000), Khanna and
with product relatedness, in the remainder of Rivkin (2001), and Lee et al. (2003) report that
this article we develop our argument focusing some (but not all) units affiliated with conglom-
on institutional relatedness and its impact on erates enjoy higher profitability than indepen-
the scope of the firm over time. dent firms. Therefore, it seems plausible to ask
whether the relatively positive link between
conglomeration and performance in emerging
DIVERSIFICATION RESEARCH IN DEVELOPED
economies is a function of the level of institu-
AND EMERGING ECONOMIES
tional (under)development, a perspective we de-
Scope refers to the number of different eco- velop next.
nomic activities (industries, segments, product
lines) a firm is engaged in (Jones & Hill, 1988). In
INSTITUTIONAL RELATEDNESS
developed economies, the value of product
scope seems to change over time. Up until the Although relatedness traditionally has been
1970s, a broad scope based on a large number of measured by product market characteristics
unrelated product markets was deemed valu- (Rumelt, 1974), recent research suggests that
able (Palich, Cardinal, & Miller, 2000). However, market-based activities are significantly influ-
the consensus since Rumelt (1974) seems to favor enced by nonmarket institutional factors (In-
related diversification and to discredit unre- gram & Silverman, 2002; Oliver, 1997; Peng, 2003,
lated diversification (Palich et al., 2000). This 2006). Extending this idea to diversification re-
change has been documented by the dramatic search, a more encompassing notion, termed in-
reversal in investor sentiment toward conglom- stitutional relatedness, seems to make sense.2
eration—”positive in the 1960s, neutral in the Specifically, we define institutional relatedness
1970s, and negative in the 1980s” (Matsusaka, as the degree of informal embeddedness or in-
1993: 358). Relative to a more recent era (since terconnectedness with dominant institutions.
the 1980s), external capital markets before the Such embeddedness confers resources and in-

2
To the best of our knowledge, Ilinitch and Zeithaml (1995)
1
In an early working paper, Shuhe Li (1999) discussed a first proposed the term institutional relatedness. However, it
series of issues related to rule- and relationship-based refers to product-based “institutional” relatedness and does
frameworks, which may be of interest to readers. not draw on the new institutionalism literature.
624 Academy of Management Review July

creases the legitimacy of an organization powerfully fill the information needs of stake-
(Granovetter, 1985; Oliver, 1997; Powell & Di- holders in multiple industries (Khanna &
Maggio, 1991). A high degree of institutional re- Palepu, 1997). However, as formal institutions
latedness means that there is a dense network develop, the reputation effect may be more lim-
of ties with dominant institutions. ited to related products.
Institutional relatedness helps firms capital- Social, political, and reputational capital are
ize on economies of scope based on three non- critical for emerging economies (Moore & Jen-
market forms of capital: social capital, political nings, 1995; Peng, 2003).3 Conglomerates in
capital, and reputational capital. First, social emerging economies typically develop and ex-
capital is defined by Adler and Kwon as “the cel in their capability for repeated industry en-
goodwill available to individuals or groups” tries, consisting of a bundle of skills to obtain
(2002: 23). Especially in emerging economies, the licenses from the state, arrange financing, se-
uncertain environment results in a great deal of cure technology, and hire and train labor forces.
information asymmetry, leading to a potentially This generic, nonindustry-specific capability in-
high level of opportunism when dealing with volves more than ties to government officials; it
unknown parties. Therefore, social capital em- embodies an ability to leverage relationships
bedded in networks may become more impor- with a variety of crucial institutions (e.g., finan-
tant (Peng & Heath, 1996). This may be one of the cial institutions, labor forces). Moreover, this ca-
reasons why closely networked conglomerates pability is difficult to trade, because it is embod-
exist and perform better in emerging economies ied in an organization’s knowledge, contacts,
(Khanna & Palepu, 1997). However, as formal and routines. Therefore, such a capability “en-
institutions develop, external monitoring mech- courages those who possess it to diversify
anisms improve, and such nonmarket social re- across industries rather than become specialists
lationships gradually may become less impor- in one industry or product line” (Guillen, 2000:
tant (Peng, 2003, 2006). 365).
Second, political capital is geared toward in-
creasing a firm’s public reputation, social legit-
PRODUCT RELATEDNESS ⴙ INSTITUTIONAL
imacy, and political effectiveness when inter-
RELATEDNESS
acting with political actors. In emerging
economies, political connections often affect How do product and institutional relatedness
profitability (Au, Peng, & Wang, 2000; Fisman, combine to determine scope? Overall, it is im-
2001; Peng & Luo, 2000). Since it is uncertain portant to recognize that firms have limited re-
when and where opportunities from political sources and that resources are required to de-
connections would come from, it may be better velop any kind of relatedness—product,
for firms to cultivate continuous relationships institutional, or both. A value-adding strategy is
with governments. However, formal institutional to leverage appropriate resources to develop the
development, such as the creation of specialized kind of relatedness that is most conducive in
government agencies to deal with specific in- creating value in a given institutional frame-
dustries or domains (e.g., the U.S. International work. Both product and institutional relatedness
Trade Commission), would require firms to come become valuable over time as firms expand in
up with industry-specific political strategies scope, but then the value of this combined form
(Lenway & Rehbein, 1991), which may be better may change.
tailored to the business level (as opposed to the Take Figure 1, depicting a snapshot of a par-
corporate level). As a result, corporate-wide ticular period (i.e., the 1990s), as an example.
economies of scale in political activities may be Firms in Cells 1 and 2 can be found mostly in
difficult to attain when specialized formal insti- developed economies where formal institutions
tutions develop (Shaffer & Hillman, 2000). are well developed. The difference between
Third, reputational capital may reduce infor-
mation asymmetry between firms and stake- 3
holders such as consumers and employees We are not arguing that institutional relatedness is not
important in developed economies. For example, Oliver
(Shenkar & Yuchtman-Yaar, 1997). Because infor- (1997) and Ingram and Silverman (2002) argue that institu-
mation search, especially in emerging econo- tional relatedness is highly relevant for developed econo-
mies, is costly, reputation can informally but mies.
2005 Peng, Lee, and Wang 625

FIGURE 1
The Importance of Product and Institutional Relatedness: A Snapshot of the 1990s

Cells 1 and 2 boils down to whether firms pursue and costs that leads to the choice between strat-
the efficient operation of an internal capital egies” (Jones & Hill, 1988: 160). Since the eco-
market or the sharing of core competencies, re- nomic benefits of the last unit of growth (e.g., the
spectively. Firms in Cells 3 and 4 exploit insti- last acquisition) can be defined as marginal
tutional relatedness. Firms in Cell 3 are most economic benefits (MEB) and the additional bu-
likely to be found in emerging economies, where reaucratic costs incurred as marginal bureau-
institutional relatedness is important enough to cratic costs (MBC), the scope of the firm is deter-
generate most profits and value added through mined by a comparison of MEB and MBC.
product relatedness may be relatively small. Graphically (Figure 2), according to Collis and
Firms in Cell 4 are most likely to be found in an Montgomery (1997) and Jones and Hill (1988), the
economy where formal institutions are rela- optimal scope is at point A, where the level of
tively well developed but informal institutions diversification is D1. If the level of diversifica-
are still influential (e.g., Japan). tion is D2, there are some economic benefits to
Firms in Cell 3, which would be empirically gain by moving up to D1. Conversely, if a firm
classified as “unrelated” by traditional meth- overdiversifies to D3, downscoping to D1 be-
ods, may actually enjoy a great deal of insti- comes necessary.
tutional relatedness. Since institutional relat- While this framework is insightful, an institu-
edness is often less visible than product tional perspective adds that MEB and MBC are,
relatedness, firms’ capability in leveraging in- at least in part, determined by institutional re-
stitutional relatedness thus becomes a more latedness (Kogut, Walker, & Anand, 2002; Wan &
difficult-to-imitate resource (Barney, 1991), Hoskisson, 2003). Consequently, we undertake a
hence necessitating strategic consideration of series of analyses next.
its importance.
A Longitudinal Analysis in Developed
ECONOMIC BENEFITS, BUREAUCRATIC Economies
COSTS, AND INSTITUTIONAL RELATEDNESS
Taking the United States as an example, be-
The existing literature suggests that diversifi- tween the 1950s and 1970s the federal govern-
cation strategy is essentially a function of eco- ment, through a set of formal constraints, prob-
nomic benefits and bureaucratic costs. Overall, ably inadvertently promoted conglomeration.
it is “the difference between relative benefits The post-1950 antitrust policies eliminated hori-
626 Academy of Management Review July

FIGURE 2
What Determines the Scope of the Firm?

Adapted from Jones and Hill (1988: 166) and Collis and Montgomery (1997: 115). MEB: marginal
economic benefits; MBC: marginal bureaucratic cost.

zontal and vertical expansion—viewed as po- A Cross-Sectional Analysis Between Emerging


tentially anticompetitive—as viable growth and Developed Economies
strategies. Thus, firms seeking growth were
Figure 4 shows, cross-sectionally, how con-
forced to look beyond their primary industry.
glomerates in emerging economies may add
Graphically, in Figure 3, if we hold MBC con-
stant (an assumption relaxed later), the MEB value at a higher level of diversification,
curve shifted upward between 1950 and 1970. whereas firms in developed economies are not
Consequently, the optimal scope expanded from able to. This analysis relies on two critical as-
D1 to D2. sumptions (to be relaxed later). The first is that
However, by the early 1980s, the formal con- MEBE ⬎ MEBD. Underdeveloped formal institu-
straints in favor of conglomeration changed tional frameworks in emerging economies sug-
substantially. Horizontal mergers were no gest this assumption. Politically, instability
longer critically scrutinized by the Reagan ad- plagues many emerging economies (Henisz,
ministration. Academic research since Rumelt 2003). As a result, corporate political linkages,
(1974) increasingly pointed out the rising MBC. which are beneficial for firms in developed
Innovations in takeover financing (e.g., junk economies, may be more important in emerging
bonds) made more conglomerates potential ac- economies (Peng & Luo, 2000). These conditions
quisition targets. Financial markets conse- potentially lead to some conglomeration advan-
quently reacted negatively to conglomerates. In tage (Khanna & Palepu, 1997).
other words, the previous legitimacy-enhancing The second assumption is that, at a given
informal norms in favor of conglomeration di- level of diversification, MBCE ⬍ MBCD. This pri-
minished (Davis et al., 1994). In some fashion, all marily draws on the informal aspects of the in-
these factors shifted downward, moving D2 back stitutional frameworks. In emerging economies,
to a point near D1 (e.g., D3) by approximately because of the weaknesses of formal institu-
1990 (Figure 3). tions, “informal constraints rise to play a larger
2005 Peng, Lee, and Wang 627

FIGURE 3
The Evolution of the Scope of the Firm in the United States: 1950 –1970 and 1970 –1990

role in regulating economic exchanges” (Peng & utives due to professional infights and family
Heath, 1996: 504; emphasis added). Although duels as organizational complexity grows,
managers all over the world cultivate consider- and/or (3) the arrival of Western or Western-
able interpersonal ties, managers in emerging trained managers. Therefore, firms need to
economies perhaps “rely more heavily on the downscope from point C (D2) to point B (D3), at an
cultivation of personal relationships to cope optimal level of diversification still higher than
with the exigencies of their situation” (Child, that for developed economies (i.e., D3 ⬎ D1).
1994: 150). However, if we push the MBCE2 curve to MBCE3,
Overall, for any scope between D1 and D2 (e.g., then the scope should be drastically cut back
D3) in Figure 4, firms in developed economies at from point B (D3) to point D (D4).
point C need to be downscoped toward point A Similarly, in Figure 5b, we can relax the other
(D1), whereas there is still room for firms to gain assumption by shifting MEBE1 toward MEBE2.
in emerging economies at point D, which can This may be due to improved formal institutions.
move up to point B (D2). Therefore, if MBCE1 remains the same, the opti-
mal level of diversification is reduced from point
C (D2) to point E (D5). If we use MBCE2 or MBCE3
A Longitudinal Analysis in Emerging
discussed above, then the optimal level be-
Economies
comes point F (D6) or point G (D7), respectively.
Figure 5 shows longitudinally how firms in Note that at point F (D6), conglomerates in
emerging economies may derive or lose net ben- emerging economies can still add value,
efits at a high level of diversification over time. whereas at point G (D7) they cannot.
First, in Figure 5a we shift MBCE1 up to MBCE2
(for simplicity, MEBE1 remains the same; it will
PROPOSITIONS
change in Figure 5b). The increase in MBC may
be because of (1) “overdiversification” beyond The analyses above suggest several proposi-
the optimal point C due to agency motives and tions about the changing scope of the firm over
abuses, (2) the lack of cohesion among top exec- time. Overall, it seems that “no organization can
628 Academy of Management Review July

FIGURE 4
The Optimal Scope of the Firm: Developed versus Emerging Economies at the Same Time

a
Subscripts D and E attached to MEB and MBC curves stand for developed and emerging economies, respec-
tively. In developed economies the optimal point of diversification is still point A at D1, as in Figure 2.

be properly understood apart from its wider so- ments in capital markets in developed econo-
cial and cultural context” (Scott, 1995: 151). By mies lies in analyzing changes in institutional
extension, we believe that no answer to the frameworks governing the relative costs and
scope of the firm question is complete without benefits of external versus internal capital mar-
an appreciation of institutional relatedness. kets. Capital market development may nullify
Above a certain threshold level (primarily for the need for informal institutional ties to do
risk reduction purposes; see Palich et al., 2000), business, because more efficient external capi-
conglomeration cannot be argued to be either tal markets may reduce the costs of formal con-
uniformly beneficial or uniformly costly without tractual relationships between firms and exter-
a specification of the institutional contingencies nal financiers. In other words, external capital
(Liebeskind, 2000). This argument, therefore, markets and conglomeration (with internal cap-
contrasts with the one-sided arguments solely ital markets) may be substitutes for each other
derived from the recent Western experience, (Liebeskind, 2000).
which discredit conglomeration. Our most fun-
Proposition 2: The higher the level of
damental proposition is as follows.
financial market development, the
Proposition 1: The higher the institu- narrower the scope of the firm.
tional relatedness (number and
Second, nonfinancial formal institutions, such
strength of informal ties with domi-
as regulatory frameworks and competition poli-
nant institutions), the greater the
cies, may also have a bearing on diversification
scope of the firm.
strategies. According to the resource-based
We consider two factors that have significant view, if conglomerates’ advantage is to be sus-
effects on institutional relatedness. One of the tained, it is imperative that certain limits to
most significant formal institutional frame- competition (e.g., government-imposed entry
works is formal financial institutions (North, barriers) exist (Guillen, 2000). Once governments
1990). One way to explain the changing senti- start the process of privatization, liberalization,
2005 Peng, Lee, and Wang 629

FIGURE 5
The Evolution of the Scope of the Firm in Emerging Economies
(a) Increase in Bureaucratic Costs

(b) Decrease in Economic Benefits

a
Subscripts D and E attached to MEB and MBC curves stand for developed and emerging
economies, respectively. In developed economies the optimal point of diversification is still
point A at D1, as in Figure 2.
630 Academy of Management Review July

and globalization, the relative importance of in- business opportunities in the economy” (Khanna
stitutional relatedness may decline, whereas & Palepu, 1999: 279; emphasis added).
the relative importance of product relatedness
Proposition 5: In the short run, the im-
rises. Such evolution in developed and emerg-
portance of institutional relatedness is
ing economies has been documented by Guillen
likely to increase, and the scope of the
(2000) and Toulan (2002), drawing on samples of
firm is likely to increase.
conglomerates in Spain and Argentina, respec-
tively. At first glance, Proposition 5 seems to be at
odds with Propositions 1 through 4 and, more
Proposition 3: The better developed broadly, with the recent global trend toward lib-
the formal market-supporting institu- eralization and privatization. We invoke three
tions, the narrower the scope of the arguments to make our case. First, new institu-
firm. tionalism suggests that history matters and that
the short run is closer to history than the long
Institutions are not static, nor are strategies.
run (North, 1990). Ingram and Silverman com-
How, then, do they evolve over time, especially
plain that “strategy often suffers from a tyranny
in emerging economies? In emerging economies
of the here and now, a desire to celebrate con-
formal, market-supporting institutions may
temporary phenomena and slight historical
eventually pick up some of the functions cur-
ones” (2002: 6). Although in the long run there
rently performed by conglomerates, thus reduc-
perhaps may be a convergence, the historically
ing the value of institutional relatedness (Lee et
derived emphasis on institutional relatedness
al., 2003). The development of market-supporting
in emerging economies is likely to continue to
institutions is also likely to facilitate the widen-
matter, at least in the short run.
ing of alliance relationships, because unfamil-
Second, because organizations exist in and
iar parties, who would have been deterred from
through time, it is possible that no theory or
entering into relationships before, are now con-
construct is truly “holochronic”—that is, a rela-
fident enough to collaborate in order to capture
tionship exists independent of time (Zaheer, Al-
the gains from more complex exchanges (Peng,
bert, & Zaheer, 1999: 734). Although the construct
2003). Alliances with other firms may gradually
of institutional relatedness may be nonholo-
become a less costly way of doing business,
chronic, so, too, are virtually all our theories and
compared to internalizing many transactions as
constructs. This characteristic alone does not
before.
preclude this new construct from making a con-
Proposition 4: In the long run, the im- tribution. To make further progress, a necessary
portance of institutional relatedness is first step is “to make explicit the time scales
likely to decline, and the optimal implicit in existing work . . . by a full specifica-
scope of the firm is likely to contract. tion of all relevant time scales” (Zaheer et al.,
1999: 739). Specifically, we have followed Peng’s
However, “How long is the long run?” remains (2003) “temporal bracketing” approach by limit-
debatable. Because chaos and setback may pre- ing our predictions for either the long run or the
vail, in the short run, Proposition 4 may not hold. short run. Although such an approach may re-
Although the general direction throughout duce the generalizability across time (both long
emerging economies is to introduce more formal run and short run), it “increases the precision of
market-supporting institutions, their develop- the predictions, at least within the specified pe-
ment is almost certain to be uneven (Peng, 2003). riod” (Peng, 2003: 17). This way of theorizing is in
Certain sectors are likely to be deregulated contrast with much existing strategy research,
while others remain state controlled. In these which “downplays temporal transitivity” (In-
half-reformed economies, conglomerates, by le- gram & Silverman, 2002: 6), but it may be more
veraging their institutional relatedness, may temporally informed and valid (Mayer & Whit-
emerge as intermediaries that connect the tington, 2003; Zaheer et al., 1999).
opened and closed sectors (Guillen, 2000). Dur- Finally, a better specification of what short
ing the transitions, at least in the short run, such run is helps make our case. Williamson (2000:
intermediation capabilities “are likely to be- 597) suggests an interesting classification: (1)
come more, not less, valuable for exploiting new 100 –1000 years, (2) 10 –100 years, (3) 1–10 years,
2005 Peng, Lee, and Wang 631

and (4) continuous (now). Williamson (2000: 608) 2000). The conglomerate in many emerging
argues that new institutionalism is primarily economies tends to have blurred boundaries
concerned with the second and third periods. If (Peng & Heath, 1996). Such a firm is sometimes
these two periods (1–100 years) are reasonable called a “business group.” The difficulty in
proxies of the short run, they seem to be a win- identifying its boundaries has not only led to
dow of opportunity during which Proposition 5 nontrivial measurement problems but also to
may find some empirical support. conceptual debates on whether such an organi-
Globally, three sets of preliminary evidence zation is a “firm.” Thus, future work needs to
broadly support the somewhat counterintuitive tackle this challenging problem.
Proposition 5. First, throughout emerging econ- Second, while researchers have experienced
omies, many conglomerates spearheaded e- great difficulties in measuring product related-
commerce ventures and consequently expanded ness, measuring institutional relatedness,
their scope in the 1990s. Second, conglomerates which is more informal, unique, and invisible, is
recently emerged in China and Russia for the likely to be much more challenging. For exam-
first time, thus pointing to the increasing (not ple, in Chile, Khanna and Palepu relied on “mis-
decreasing) importance of institutional related- cellaneous knowledgeable observers” (2000: 273)
ness, at least in the short run (Peng, 2000). Fi- to identify group linkages. In Indonesia, Fisman
nally, in Chile and India, the scope of conglom- (2001) used an idiosyncratic “Suharto Depen-
erates actually increased during a period of dency Index” to measure firms’ connectedness
rapid liberalization (Khanna & Palepu, 1999). with former president Suharto. These measures
inevitably carry some “noise.” How to empiri-
DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSION cally capture an inherently invisible and so-
cially complex resource such as institutional re-
In this article we have focused on one of the latedness remains a significant challenge.
four most fundamental questions in strategic Third, for conglomerates in emerging econo-
management. The article contributes to our un- mies, given the long-run needs to contract (Prop-
derstanding of the scope of the firm question by ositions 1– 4) and the short-run incentives to ex-
highlighting the importance of institutional re- pand the scope (Proposition 5), where the point
latedness in an institution-based theory of cor- of inflection is remains to be clarified (Peng,
porate diversification. Earlier, Peng (2003) artic- 2003). Further, geographical and technological
ulated how institutional transitions matter for scope (Delios & Beamish, 1999; Peng, 2006;
strategic choices in general; we have extended Wright et al., 2005), while beyond the scope of
this work by specifying under what specific in- this article, warrants further investigation.
stitutional conditions a conglomeration strategy Overall, the question “What determines the
may or may not add value. Since “we need the scope of the firm over time?” entails complex
frame-breaking experiences that only come answers. We have attempted to capture some of
from examining and comprehending organiza- this complexity by advancing and leveraging
tions operating in other places and other times” the notion of institutional relatedness. In conclu-
(Scott, 1995: 151), we have integrated research sion, if this article could contain only one mes-
not only from developed economies but also sage, we would like it to be a sense of the stag-
from emerging economies. Given the typical gering power of institutional frameworks and
one-sided emphasis on product relatedness
their transitions that help determine the strate-
(which, of course, is still important) in the liter-
gic choices and performance outcomes for cor-
ature, it seems imperative that much more re-
porate diversification over time.
search investigate the important but often
missed role of institutional relatedness in driv-
ing diversification decisions and outcomes both
across time and around the world. REFERENCES
The limitations of the present article suggest Adler, P., & Kwon, S. 2002. Social capital: Prospects for a new
a number of future directions. Perhaps the fore- concept. Academy of Management Review, 27: 17– 40.
most limitation is a focus on the nature of the Au, K., Peng, M. W., & Wang, D. 2000. Interlocking director-
firm. The firm in developed economies has rel- ates, firm strategies, and performance in Hong Kong.
atively clear legal boundaries (Williamson, Asia Pacific Journal of Management, 17: 29 – 47.
632 Academy of Management Review July

Barney, J. 1991. Firm resources and sustained competitive Lawrence, P., & Lorsch, J. 1967. Organization and environ-
advantage. Journal of Management, 17: 99 –120. ment. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.
Chang, S., & Hong, J. 2000. Economic performance of group- Lee, K. B., Peng, M. W., & Lee, K. 2003. From diversification
affiliated companies in Korea: Intragroup resource shar- premium to diversification discount during institutional
ing and internal business transactions. Academy of transitions. Working paper, Fisher College of Business,
Management Journal, 43: 429 – 449. The Ohio State University, Columbus.
Child, J. 1994. Management in China during the age of re- Lenway, S., & Rehbein, K. 1991. Leaders, followers, and free
form. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. riders: An empirical test of variation in corporate polit-
Collis, D., & Montgomery, C. 1997. Corporate strategy. Chi- ical involvement. Academy of Management Journal, 34:
cago: Irwin. 893–905.

Davis, G., Diekmann, K., & Tinsley, C. 1994. The decline and Li, S. 1999. The benefits and costs of relation-based gover-
fall of the conglomerate firm in the 1990s: The deinsti- nance: An explanation of the East Asian miracle and
tutionalization of an organizational form. American So- crisis. Working paper, City University of Hong Kong.
ciological Review, 59: 547–570. Liebeskind, J. 2000. Internal capital markets: Benefits, costs,
Delios, A., & Beamish, P. 1999. Geographic scope, product and organizational arrangements. Organization Sci-
diversification, and the corporate performance of Japa- ence, 11: 58 –76.
nese firms. Strategic Management Journal, 20: 711–727. Matsusaka, J. 1993. Takeover motives during the conglomer-
Fisman, R. 2001. Estimating the value of political connec- ate merger wave. RAND Journal of Economics, 24: 357–
tions. American Economic Review, 91: 1095–1102. 379.

Granovetter, M. 1985. Economic action and social structure: Mayer, M., & Whittington, R. 2003. Diversification in context:
The problem of embeddedness. American Journal of So- A cross-national and cross-temporal extension. Strate-
ciology, 91: 481–510. gic Management Journal, 24: 773–781.

Guillen, M. 2000. Business groups in emerging economies: A Moore, L., & Jennings, P. D. 1995. Human resources manage-
resource-based view. Academy of Management Journal, ment on the Pacific Rim: Institutions, practices, and at-
43: 362–380. titudes. Berlin & New York: Walter de Gruyter.

Henisz, W. 2003. The power of the Buckley and Casson thesis: North, D. 1990. Institutions, institutional change, and eco-
The ability to manage institutional idiosyncrasies. Jour- nomic performance. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univer-
nal of International Business Studies, 34: 173–184. sity Press.

Hoskisson, R., Eden, L., Lau, C. M., & Wright, M. 2000. Strategy Oliver, C. 1997. Sustainable competitive advantage: Com-
in emerging economies. Academy of Management Jour- bining institutional and resource-based views. Strategic
nal, 43: 249 –267. Management Journal, 18: 679 –713.

Ilinitch, A. Y., & Zeithaml, C. 1995. Operationalizing and Palich, L., Cardinal, L., & Miller, C. 2000. Curvilinearity in the
testing Galbriath’s center of gravity theory. Strategic diversification-performance linkage: An examination of
Management Journal, 16: 401– 410. over three decades of research. Strategic Management
Journal, 21: 155–174.
Ingram, P., & Silverman, B. 2002. Introduction. In P. Ingram &
B. Silverman (Eds.), The new institutionalism in strategic Peng, M. W. 2000. Business strategies in transition economies.
management: 1–30. Amsterdam: Elsevier. Thousand Oaks, CA: Sage.

Jones, G., & Hill, C. 1988. Transaction cost analysis of strat- Peng, M. W. 2003. Institutional transitions and strategic
egy-structure choice. Strategic Management Journal, 9: choices. Academy of Management Review, 28: 275–296.
159 –172. Peng, M. W. 2006. Global strategy. Cincinnati: Thomson
Khanna, T., & Palepu, K. 1997. Why focused strategies may South-Western.
be wrong for emerging markets. Harvard Business Re- Peng, M. W., & Heath, P. 1996. The growth of the firm in
view, 75(4): 41–51. planned economies in transition: Institutions, organiza-
Khanna, T., & Palepu, K. 1999. Policy shocks, market inter- tions, and strategic choice. Academy of Management
mediaries, and corporate strategy. Journal of Economics Review, 21: 492–528.
and Management Strategy, 8: 271–310. Peng, M. W., & Luo, Y. 2000. Managerial ties and firm perfor-
Khanna, T., & Palepu, K. 2000. The future of business groups mance in a transition economy: The nature of a micro-
in emerging markets: Long-run evidence from Chile. macro link. Academy of Management Journal, 43: 486 –
Academy of Management Journal, 43: 268 –285. 501.

Khanna, T., & Rivkin, J. 2001. Estimating the performance Powell, W., & DiMaggio, P. (Eds.). 1991. The new institution-
effects of business groups in emerging markets. Strate- alism in organizational analysis. Chicago: University of
gic Management Journal, 22: 45–74. Chicago Press.

Kogut, B., Walker, G., & Anand, J. 2002. Agency and institu- Rumelt, R. 1974. Strategy, structure, and economic perfor-
tions: National divergence in diversification behavior. mance. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.
Organization Science, 13: 162–178. Rumelt, R., Schendel, D., & Teece, D. (Eds.). 1994. Fundamen-
2005 Peng, Lee, and Wang 633

tal issues in strategy. Boston: Harvard Business School Wan, W., & Hoskisson, R. 2003. Home country environments,
Press. corporate diversification strategies, and firm perfor-
Scott, W. R. 1995. Institutions and organizations. Thousand mance. Academy of Management Journal, 46: 27– 45.
Oaks, CA: Sage. Williamson, O. 2000. The new institutional economics: Tak-
Shaffer, B., & Hillman, A. 2000. The development of business- ing stock, looking ahead. Journal of Economic Literature,
government strategies by diversified firms. Strategic 38: 595– 613.
Management Journal, 21: 175–190. Wright, M., Filatotchev, I., Hoskisson, R., & Peng, M. W. 2005.
Shenkar, O., & Yuchtman-Yaar, E. 1997. Reputation, image, Guest editors’ introduction: Strategy research in emerg-
prestige, and goodwill: An interdisciplinary approach to ing economies: Challenging conventional wisdom. Jour-
organizational standing. Human Relations, 50: 1361–1381. nal of Management Studies, 42: 1–33.
Toulan, O. 2002. The impact of market liberalization on ver- Zaheer, S., Albert, S., & Zaheer, A. 1999. Time scales and
tical scope: The case of Argentina. Strategic Manage- organizational theory. Academy of Management Re-
ment Journal, 23: 551–560. view, 24: 725–741.

Mike W. Peng is an associate professor of management at the Fisher College of


Business, The Ohio State University. In autumn 2005 he will become the first Provost’s
Distinguished Professor of Global Strategy at the University of Texas at Dallas. He
received his Ph.D. from the University of Washington. His current research focuses on
business strategies in emerging economies.

Seung-Hyun Lee is an assistant professor of international business at the University


of Texas at Dallas. He received his Ph.D. from the The Ohio State University. His
current research focuses on institutional change and its implications for firm perfor-
mance.

Denis Y. L. Wang is an associate professor of management at the Chinese University


of Hong Kong and Inaugural HSBC Visiting Chair Professor of International Business
at the University of British Columbia. He received his M.B.A. from York University. His
current research interests are strategies and investments in emerging economies,
with a focus on China.

You might also like