You are on page 1of 8

Aquaculture xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

Contents lists available at ScienceDirect

Aquaculture
journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/aquaculture

Price transmission along the Vietnamese pangasius export chain


Thi Anh Ngoc Phama,c,⁎, Miranda P.M. Meuwissena, Tru Cong Lec, Roel H. Bosmab,
Johan Verrethb, Alfons Oude Lansinka
a
Business Economics Group, Wageningen University, P.O. Box 8130, 6700 EW Wageningen, The Netherlands
b
Aquaculture and Fisheries Group, Wageningen University, P.O. Box 338, 6700 AH Wageningen, The Netherlands
c
Economics Faculty, Nong Lam University, Linh Trung Ward, Thu Duc district, Ho Chi Minh City, Vietnam

A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T

Keywords: Price transmission in international supply chains is important to ensure that price premiums paid by consumers
Price transmission for environmental sustainability labels are transmitted upstream to farmers. This facilitates investment in
Aquaculture sustainable aquaculture systems. This study analyzes the price transmission from the international retail stage to
Pangasius the Vietnamese farm, focusing on frozen pangasius fillets. We used monthly nominal prices at farm and export
Vietnam
stages in Vietnam, and at wholesale and retail stages in Poland for the period from August 2010 to December
Sustainability certification
2014. Price signals at the Polish retail stage were found to transmit back to the wholesale, export, and farm
stages. Moreover, price transmission from wholesale to export and from export to farm is characterized by both
short- and long-run symmetries. In the short run, retailers tend to transmit only wholesale price increases to their
customers and wholesalers transmit only retail price increases to exporters. A long-run relationship between
retailers and wholesalers is absent, thereby reducing the ability of chain actors to respond to all market signals,
including downward changes.
Given the delay in price transmission in the short run, the introduction of business-to-business electronic
trading or auction markets might reduce this delay along the retail, wholesale, export, and farm stages. To
enhance the long-run price relationship in the wholesale-retail market, more retailers should enter the pangasius
market. The transmission of price changes from Polish markets back to Vietnamese pangasius farmers is a
positive signal for farmers to invest in sustainable production methods, as consumer price premiums likely flow
back to the farm.

1. Introduction Labelling requirements raise compliance costs, e.g. because of


additional investments and the costs of auditing (Ngoc et al., 2016a;
Vietnam is the world's largest producer of pangasius. The European Ngoc et al., 2016b). These costs are typically passed on to the
Union (EU) is the largest export market for pangasius, and accounts for consumers (Boyd and McNevin, 2012). However, under imperfect price
22% of the value of exported Vietnamese frozen pangasius fillets transmission, price increases at the downstream stages, i.e. interna-
(EUMOFA, 2014). Although it is the largest export market, EU imports tional wholesale and retail stages, are transmitted slowly and possibly
of frozen pangasius fillets decreased from 211 thousand tonnes in not fully to the upstream stages, i.e. domestic export and farm stages
volume, at an import value of €370 million in 2010 (EUMOFA, 2014) (Meyer and von Cramon-Taubadel, 2004; Vavra and Goodwin, 2005).
to 130 thousand tonnes in volume, at an import value of €275 million in As a consequence, sufficient capital may not be allocated to meet the
2014 (CBI, 2015). This decline could be a consequence of recent claims required standards.
about the negative environmental impacts of pangasius production and Among the explanations in the literature, market power in the
food safety issues (Bush and Duijf, 2011; Little et al., 2012; Rico and downstream stages of the supply chain has been identified as the most
Van den Brink, 2014). Furthermore, retailers and customers increas- important reason for imperfect price transmission (Meyer and von
ingly demand labelled pangasius, such as pangasius with Aquaculture Cramon-Taubadel, 2004; Vavra and Goodwin, 2005; Frey and Manera,
Stewardship Council (ASC) certification, to ensure that pangasius 2007; Acharya et al., 2011). The exercise of market power at down-
products are sourced from environmentally sustainable and socially stream stages may result in weaker bargaining power at upstream
equitable production systems (Bush and Duijf, 2011; Little et al., 2012). stages (Fałkowski, 2010; Assefa et al., 2014), thus farmers may fail to


Corresponding author at: Economics Faculty, Nong Lam University, Linh Trung Ward, Thu Duc district, Ho Chi Minh City, Vietnam.
E-mail address: ngocpham@hcmuaf.edu.vn (T.A.N. Pham).

http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.aquaculture.2017.04.028
Received 27 September 2016; Received in revised form 16 March 2017; Accepted 24 April 2017
0044-8486/ © 2017 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.

Please cite this article as: Ngoc, P.T.A., Aquaculture (2017), http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.aquaculture.2017.04.028
T.A.N. Pham et al. Aquaculture xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

negotiate a price premium to partially offset the high costs of labelling of live pangasius in the following crop, which drives the price upwards
compliance. However, there are also other reasons for imperfect price again (Rapsomanikis et al., 2006; Phan et al., 2009).
transmission. For example, prices at the retail level may not adjust due At the exporter stage, in 2010, about 291 pangasius processors and
to menu costs, which are costs associated with changes in retail prices traders exported to EU markets (van Duijn et al., 2012). Most of the
(Vavra and Goodwin, 2005). Furthermore, retailers might hesitate to large-scale farms are owned by Vietnamese companies that process and
raise prices of perishable products given the risk that they will be left export pangasius while most of the medium and small-scale farms are
with unsold spoiled products (Meyer and von Cramon-Taubadel, 2004; owned by individual households (van Duijn et al., 2012; Trifković,
Vavra and Goodwin, 2005). 2014). According to van Duijn et al. (2012), there was a lack of
Literature on the degree of price transmission along international integration between farmers and processors in Vietnamese pangasius
seafood supply chains trade is limited and generally focuses on trade sector. This lack of integration was inferred from the relatively volatile
within developed countries, such as the fresh French hake value chain raw material prices and the lack of experience in formulating contracts
(Jaffry, 2004), the salmon chain from Norway to France (Asche et al., to protect the benefits of both farmers and processors. Our study
2007) and the fresh farmed Canadian and Norwegian Atlantic salmon to focused on household-owned farms. In Poland, 91% of total frozen
United States (Singh, 2016). For international trade from developed to pangasius fillets originated from Vietnam (Pieniak et al., 2011;
developing countries, several studies have investigated price transmis- EUMOFA, 2014; VASEP 2014). Fish is sold in specialized stores,
sion issues, for example the relationship between export and ex-vessel supermarkets, hypermarkets, and small independent groceries. Small
prices for tuna fish in the Republic of Maldives (Gordon and Hussain, retailers source fish products from wholesalers. The largest retail chains
2015), the relationship between wholesale and retail prices in aqua- such as hypermarkets and supermarkets are the leading distribution
culture and capture fisheries in Bangladesh (Sapkota et al., 2015) and channel for seafood products in Poland (Jesús, 2011; Piotr, 2015).
the price linkages long the international value chains for Honduran
seafood (Tveteras, 2015). These studies however do not cover all stages
of the chain, i.e. producer, processor/exporter, wholesaler/importer, 2.2. Data collection
and retailer. In international seafood trade from developing to devel-
oped countries, the insights into price transmission along the chain play We used monthly nominal prices of Vietnamese pangasius at the
an important role in the switch to a more sustainable aquaculture sector farm, export, wholesale, and retail stages for the period from August
in developing countries. 2010 to December 2014. As export prices and retail prices were in
The objective of this paper was to analyze the price transmission in euros, we also converted farm and wholesale prices into euros. For farm
both directions along the international supply chain for frozen panga- prices (VND/EUR), monthly exchange rates were used from www.
sius fillets, from the Vietnamese farm to the international retail stage. ozforex.com.au. For wholesale prices (PLN/EUR), exchange rates from
We selected Poland to represent the international retail stage. Poland is www.x-rate.com were used.
the 7th largest market in the EU for Vietnamese frozen pangasius fillets, The farm prices for live pangasius were retrieved from four
accounting for 4.5% of EU import in term of value in 2013. The Departments of Aquaculture that represent the two main regions for
Vietnam to Poland chain is the only international pangasius chain with production, i.e. An Giang, Dong Thap, and Vinh Long (main fresh water
full price data available for all stages in the same period. The outcomes production region) and Tra Vinh provinces (newly developed salt water
of this study can provide a better understanding of the market intrusion region). An average of Vietnamese farm prices was then
mechanisms in the supply chain; this information is valuable for policy calculated for the analysis. We used Polish import prices as a proxy for
makers to help identify ways of increasing the sustainability of the Vietnamese export prices. Import prices were derived from monthly
Vietnamese pangasius sector. import values and quantities of frozen pangasius fillets, both obtained
This paper proceeds with a brief description of the supply chain for from Comtrade HS data.
frozen pangasius fillets from Vietnam to Poland, the data collection, With respect to Polish wholesale prices for frozen pangasius fillets,
and the price transmission models. Section 3 presents the results and average prices from all wholesalers in Poland were collected from
discussion. Conclusion and policy implications are in Section 4. www.portalspozywczy.pl. Polish retail prices were retrieved from
www.ec.europa.eu. Weekly retail prices were converted into monthly
2. Materials and methods prices by a simple average of four-weekly prices.

2.1. The supply chain for frozen pangasius fillets from Vietnam to Poland
2.3. Data description
The supply chain for frozen pangasius fillets from Vietnam to Poland
consists of four stages, i.e. farmers and exporters on the Vietnamese side Fig. 1 shows the farm, export, wholesale, and retail prices for the
and wholesalers and retailers on the Polish side. The linking markets period from August 2010 to December 2014. The prices for the farm,
can be described as follows: (i) farmers sell live pangasius that meet export, wholesale, and retail stages appear to follow a fairly similar
export requirements directly to processing factories, which are also the pattern throughout the period. The sudden jump in export prices in
exporting companies (Loc et al., 2010), (ii) at the processing/exporting August 2013 is likely associated with the shortage of live pangasius for
factories, fish are filleted, frozen, packed, and then exported to the processing, caused by low prices in the previous months, which in turn
wholesaler in Poland, and finally (iii) the products are distributed to were linked to negative media coverage by the World Wide Fund for
retailers and final consumers. Nature (WWF) in late 2010 (see Little et al. (2012) for a discussion of
Vietnamese pangasius production is characterized by an elastic the pangasius claims in the EU).
supply. In other words, the supply of Vietnamese pangasius is very Table 1 presents the descriptive statistics of the farm, export,
sensitive to the market price of live pangasius. For example, when the wholesale, and retail prices and exchange rates. The fluctuation in
price is high, farmers will quickly increase their production in the next retail prices is relatively low, with a coefficient of variation (CV) of
crop or prolong the sale (Bush and Belton, 2011; Trifković, 2014). This 0.04, compared with the fluctuation in farm prices (CV of 0.10), export
often leads to live pangasius output exceeding the processing capacity prices (0.09), and wholesale prices (0.11). Prices at the retail stage
of the industry in the following crop. This oversupply of pangasius generally adjust slowly due to menu costs and the perishable char-
inevitably drives the price down. In contrast, when the price is low, acteristics of products (Vavra and Goodwin, 2005; Guillén and Artés,
famers will reduce production in the next crop. Some famers even 2015).
temporarily stop raising pangasius, resulting in a shortage in the supply

2
T.A.N. Pham et al. Aquaculture xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

found to be integrated of order zero, and are accordingly stationary. If


the price series are integrated of the same order, there can exist a
cointegrated relationship of price series. This cointegrated relationship
will be investigated using the Johansen (1988) cointegration test.

2.4.2. Testing for cointegration


Cointegration implies that prices move closely together in the long-
run. The criterion for selecting lag length for the Johansen cointegra-
tion test was that at least three of the following five statistical tests, i.e.
AIC, Schwarz Bayesian Criterion (SBC), Hannan-Quin, likelihood ratio,
and final predictor error, should point at the same lag length, as also
suggested by Asteriou and Hall (2007), Fałkowski (2010), and Serra
and Goodwin (2003).

2.4.3. Asymmetric price transmission models


The second step was to check for asymmetric price transmission and
Fig. 1. The evolution of monthly price series. quantify the price adjustment. Asymmetric price transmission implies
that the difference in adjustment in the response of a price to an
Table 1 increase/decrease in another price. We used the VECM for the
Descriptive statistics of price series and exchange rates. cointegrated pair-wise prices and the Houck (1977) and Ward (1982)
Price (EUR/month) Mean SD CV 5% 95%
model for non-cointegrated pair-wise prices (von Cramon-Taubadel,
1998; Bakucs et al., 2012; Verreth et al., 2015). Literature has
Farma 0.81 0.08 0.10 0.63 0.94 acknowledged the importance of the exchange rate in international
Exportb 1.64 0.15 0.09 1.37 1.86 trade (Tveteras and Asche 2008; Larsen and Kinnucan, 2009; Asche
Wholesalec 2.18 0.23 0.11 1.90 2.65
et al., 2014). Therefore, to capture the effect of the exchange rate on the
Retaild 3.15 0.12 0.04 2.96 3.32
Exchange rate price transmission mechanism, our asymmetric price transmission
VND/EUR (1,000VND/month)e 27.71 1.20 0.04 25.59 29.65 model included a variable exchange rate.
PLN/EUR (PLN/month)f 4.15 0.12 0.03 3.93 4.39
a. The vector error correction model (VECM)
Data source:
a
Departments of Aquaculture in An Giang, Dong Thap,and Vinh Long (fresh water
area) and Tra Vinh (salt water intrusion area). A weighted average of farm prices was Following von Cramon-Taubadel (1998), our asymmetric VECM
calculated; model for cointegrated pair-wise prices was specified as:
b
Comtrade HS data.
c n n n
www.portalspozywczy.pl.
d
ec.europa.eu
ΔP1,t = γ0 + ∑i=1 γ1,i ΔP1,t−i + ∑i=0 γ+2,iΔP+2,t−i + ∑i=0 γ−2,iΔP−2,t−i
e
www.ozforex.com.au. n
f
www.x-rate.com.
+ ∑i=0 γ3,i ΔEXVND,t−i + γ+4 ECT+t−1 + γ−4 ECT−t−1 + ε t (1)

2.4. Price transmission analysis1 where Δ is the first difference operator (e.g. Δ P1 = P1 , t − P1 , t − 1), n is
the lag length, and EXVND , t stands for the exchange rate from VND to
To analyze the price transmission along the stages of the Vietnamese EUR. For the exchange rate from PLN to EUR, we replaced EXVND , t by
pangasius supply chain, we followed the vector autoregressive error EXPLN , t. The error correction term ECTt − 1 is the first lagged residual of
correction model (VECM) framework (see Frey and Manera (2007) for a the long-run relationship of pair-wise prices: EC-
review). The price transmission analysis involved two main steps: (i) Tt − 1 = εt − 1 = P1 , t − 1 − β0 − β1P2 , t − 1 − β2EXt. To capture the short-
testing the stationarity of price series and the cointegration of pair-wise and long-run asymmetry in price transmission, P2 and ECT are split into
price series (pairs of prices in each linking market farm-export, export- their positive (+) and negative (−) components respectively. The
wholesale and wholesale-retail) and (ii) testing for asymmetric price parameters γ1 , i , γ2 , i , γ3 , i represent short-run responses at the time t,
transmission. showing how quickly P1 , t is corrected in the short run in response to a
change in lagged P1 , t, P2 , t, and exchange rate EXVND , t or EXPLN , t.
Similarly, the parameters γ4 represent the speed of adjustment of the
2.4.1. Testing for stationarity price P1,t in the short-run to bring P1 , t back to the long-run equilibrium
The first step of the price transmission analysis was to examine the relationship with P2 , t. When P1 , t exceeds the long-run equilibrium
stationarity of the time series data to avoid a spurious regression level with P2 , t, a downward pressure on current P1 towards the long-
(Asteriou and Hall, 2007). Stationarity means that the statistical run equilibrium price would be expected, and thus γ4 is expected to be
parameters (mean and standard deviation) over time do not change negative. In Eq. 1, the short-run price transmission elasticity measures
with time (Vavra and Goodwin, 2005).We used the Dickey-Fuller GLS the speed of adjustment of a price to a change in another price. The
(DF-GLS) and Phillips-Perron (PP) tests to test the stationarity of each cointegration vector in the Johansen cointegration test expresses the
price series (Asteriou and Hall, 2007). The null hypothesis for both tests long-run price transmission elasticity.
is that each price series is non-stationary. For the DF-GLS test, the lag The following rules were applied in calculating the negative and
length was selected using the Akaike information criterion (AIC). The positive components of the split independent variables of P2 , t and ECTt:
price series at level are found to be integrated of order one and
accordingly nonstationary. The price series at first difference form are

1
For further details in definition of technical terms, a study of Vavra and Goodwin
(2005) provided the glossary related to time series analysis.

3
T.A.N. Pham et al. Aquaculture xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

ECT+t = { ECTt if ECTt > 0


0 otherwise
and ECT−t
respect to the farm-export market, both trace and maximal eigenvalue
statistics indicate one cointegration vector, implying the existence of a
long-run relationship between farm and export prices. The null
= { ECTt if ECTt < 0
0 otherwise hypothesis that the factor loading in the equation for export prices
equals 0 is not rejected, implying that farm prices do not drive export
ΔP+2t = { ΔP2t if P2t > 0
0 otherwise
and ΔP−2t prices in the long run. The cointegration between farm prices and
export prices likely reflect the close cooperation between exporters and
= { ΔP2t if P2t < 0
0 otherwise
pangasius farmers, for example through training programs to ensure
fish quality and safety for export to the EU market (Bush and Belton,
When price transmission in pair-wise prices is asymmetric in the 2011; Khoi, 2011; Trifković, 2014). This close cooperation confirms the
short run (SR) and long-run equilibrium (LR), the F-test should reject unidirectional causality from export to farm prices. These results are in
the following hypothesis: line with findings of Ohen et al. (2007) and Asche et al. (2007) who also
n n
found the long-run relationship between farmers and exporters in live
H 0,SR : ∑i=0 γ+2,i = ∑i=0 γ−2,i and H 0,LR : γ+4 = γ−4 catfish in Nigeria, and Salmon in Norway, respectively.
Regarding the export-wholesale market, both trace and maximal
Next, we followed Boswijk and Urbain (1997) to test whether P1 , t is eigenvalue statistics suggest one cointegration vector between export
driven by P2 , t with respect to the short-run parameters in Eq. 1. The and wholesale prices. The null hypothesis that the factor loading in the
marginal model for P2 takes the form (von Cramon-Taubadel, 1998): equation for wholesale prices equals 0 is not rejected, implying that
n n
ΔP2,t = μ 0 + ∑i=1 μ1ΔP1,t−i + ∑i=1 μ 2 ΔP2,t−i + ε t export prices are driven by wholesale prices. This is consistent with the
(2)
findings of Khoi (2011), who indicated that Vietnamese pangasius
exporters want to establish long-run relationships with international
b. The Houck (1977) and Ward (1982) model wholesalers. Exporters usually set their prices based on international
import market prices, thus confirming the unidirectional causality from
Following the Houck (1977) and Ward (1982) approach for non- wholesale to export prices.
cointegrated pair-wise prices, the response of a price P1 , t to P2 , t in the In contrast, with respect to the wholesale-retail market, both trace
short run can be expressed as (Frey and Manera, 2007; Verreth et al. and maximal eigenvalue statistics suggest that the null hypothesis of
2015): zero cointegration vectors cannot be rejected. The non-cointegration of
n n n wholesale and retail prices could be attributed to private label products

P1,t = α0 + ∑i=0 +
α1,i ΔP+2,t−i + ∑i=0 −
α1,i ΔP−2,t−i + ∑i=0 α2,i ΔEXVND,t−i introduced by retailers (Bukeviciute et al., 2009) together with the
+ εt (3) consolidation in retail chains (Wilkin et al., 2007; Fałkowski, 2010).
These in turn might influence the movement of prices, especially
where the superscript * denotes cumulative values from the starting weakening the role of wholesalers, thus leading to the possible absence
value, i.e. P1 , t∗ is P1 , t − P1 , 0. Eq. (3) considers the impact of positive of a long-run relationship between wholesale and retail prices.
(+) and negative (−) variations of P1 , t and exchange rate EXVND , t on
P2 , t, cumulated from the required lags up to the current period (i = 0). 3.3. Results of the price transmission analysis
For the exchange rate from PLN to EUR, we replaced EXVND , t by
EXPLN , t. If a serial correlation problem existed in the estimated This section presents the outcomes of the VECM for cointegrated
equation, we used the Cochrane-Orcutt procedure to correct the pair-wise prices of the farm-export and export-wholesale markets, and
problem (Pindyck and Rubinfeld, 1998). The Houck (1977) and Ward (1982) model for non-cointegrated
When price transmission in pair-wise prices is asymmetric in the wholesale-retail prices.
short run, the F-test should reject the following hypothesis:
H0 : ∑i = 0na1 , i+ = ∑i = 0na1 , i−. 3.3.1. Farm-export market
The results of the asymmetric VECM with farm prices as dependent
3. Results and discussion variable are shown in Table 4. The non-significant residuals in the
variable addition test from the marginal model (Eq. 2) of the VECM (Eq.
A summary of the results of price transmission along the Vietnamese 1) confirm that farm prices are driven by export prices. The R-squared
pangasius chain is presented in Fig. 2. This section starts with the coefficient is 0.28 and the equation is significant at the 10% critical
results of the stationarity tests of the price series, followed by the level, indicating that 28% of the variation in farm prices is explained by
cointegration tests of pair-wise prices, and the results of the price the model.
transmission analysis. Results in Table 4 suggests that changes in export prices, previous
farm prices, and exchange rates take one month to transmit to farm
3.1. Results of the stationarity tests prices. The coefficient of the lagged farm prices is positive and
statistically significant at the 1% critical level. The estimated coefficient
Table 2 reports the results of the DF-GLS and PP tests, which show is 1.76 (greater than one), indicating that farm prices respond very
that we failed to reject all the null hypotheses of non-stationarity for quickly to a change in the previous month's farm price. When the farm
export, wholesale, and retail prices and exchange rates at the 1%, 5%, price increases during the previous month, farmers expect a price
or 10% critical levels. Only farm prices are stationary at the 10% increase in the upcoming month. They may then wait a while before
critical level. However, both tests of the price series in their first selling in order to sell their fish for higher prices (Phan et al., 2009).
difference form robustly rejected the null hypothesis of non-stationarity The coefficient of the lagged exchange rate (VND/EUR) is negative
at the 1% critical level for all price series. Therefore, we conclude that and statistically significant at the 10% critical level, with a magnitude
farm, export, wholesale, and retail prices, and exchange rates are all of 0.02. This result has two implications. First, the magnitude suggests
stationary in the first difference form. that farm prices respond slowly to a change in exchange rates. Second,
the negative sign of the lagged exchange rate (VND/EUR) implies that
3.2. Results of the cointegration tests for a long-run equilibrium relationship farm prices decrease as the exchange rate increases. On the one hand,
this might be because of foreign currency speculation by the
Table 3 presents the results of the Johansen cointegration test. With Vietnamese exporter. Exporters who directly sell frozen pangasius

4
T.A.N. Pham et al. Aquaculture xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

Live pangasius Frozen pangasius fillets

Processor/
Exporter Wholesaler/
Producer Retailer
Importer

Vietnamese stages Polish stages

SR symmetry

LR symmetry

SR asymmetry

Fig. 2. Summary of findings for price transmission along the supply chain for frozen pangasius fillets from Vietnam to Poland.Notes: Dashed arrows show the directions of price
relationship; SR (short run) and LR (long run).

Table 2 Table 4
Results of stationarity tests. Results for price transmission in the farm-export market.

Variable Test Non-differenced Lag First difference Lag Independent variables Dependent variable
ΔPf , t
Farm pricea DF-GLS −1.862⁎ 0 −5.209⁎⁎⁎ 0
PP −2.626⁎ −5.252⁎⁎⁎ Estimated coefficient P-value
Export priceb DF-GLS −2.159 1 −9.271⁎⁎⁎ 0
PP −2.775 −9.549⁎⁎⁎ Constant 0.017 0.225
Wholesale priceb DF-GLS −2.127 0 −2.283⁎⁎⁎ 0 ΔPf , t − 1 1.761 0.002**
PP −3.279⁎ −7.890⁎⁎⁎ ΔPe , t+ − 0.075 0.466
Retail priceb DF-GLS −2.423 1 −5.825⁎⁎⁎ 0 ΔPe , t − 1+ 0.086 0.397
PP −2.504 −6.128⁎⁎⁎ ΔPe , t− 0.062 0.591
Exchange rate (EX) DF-GLS −2.978 1 −5.235⁎⁎⁎ 1 ΔPe , t − 1− 0.096 0.419
VND/EURb PP −2.146 −5.060⁎⁎⁎ ΔEXVND , t 0.007 0.367
PLN/EURa DF-GLS −2.396 3 −4.483⁎⁎⁎ 0 ΔEXVND , t − 1 − 0.023 0.060*
PP −1.800 −4.518⁎⁎⁎ ECTt − 1+ − 1.851 0.004***
ECTt − 1− − 1.385 0.029**
Notes: ***, **, and * denote the level of significance at 1%, 5% and 10% respectively. R-squared 0.283 –
a
The DF-GLS test includes an intercept. F-statistic 1.798 0.098*
b
The DF_GLS test includes an intercept and trend at non-differenced. Residual tests F-statistic
No serial correlation 0.375 0.543
Homoscedasticity 1.161 0.344
fillets to Poland might wait until the exchange rate is more favorable Normal distribution – 0.000***
before converting to the euro. At the same time, an increase in the Variable addition test for residual in Eq. 2 0.006 0.928
exchange rate (VND/EUR) might increase the fuel prices, which might Asymmetry tests
influence the operation costs for exporters, such as transportation costs. Short run 0.326 0.571
Long run 0.962 0.332
Consequently exporters may assign a temporarily lower farmer price to
compensate for the increased costs. This result is opposite to our prior Notes: ***Values significant at 1% level, ** at 5% level, and * at 10% level; LM test for
expectation. In principle, a depreciation of the domestic currency will autocorrelation; Breusch-Pagan-Godfrey test for heteroskedasticity; Histogram for nor-
boost exports, creating pressure on the domestic price to increase due to mality test.
higher demand for domestic goods (Rapsomanikis et al., 2006; Lee and
Gomez, 2011). On the other hand, the strong competition in the

Table 3
Results of Johansen cointegration tests.

Linking market Lag length Hypothesized number of cointegration vectors Trace statistic P-value Maximal eigenvalue statistic P-value

Farm-export 1 None 27.823 0.028⁎⁎ 21.348 0.025⁎⁎


At most 1 6.475 0.402 6.475 0.402
Export-wholesale 2 None 21.995 0.028⁎⁎ 18.924 0.016⁎⁎
At most 1 3.070 0.567 3.070 0.567
Wholesale-retail 1 None 10.721 0.569 6.999 0.669
At most 1 3.721 0.455 3.721 0.455

a
(Pf ,Pe): a = (−0.397; 0.283), H 0: α2 = 0; χ 2‐statistic = (4.670; 1.219), χ 20.050 = 3.841
Factor loading
(Pe,Pw): a = (−0.507; 0.047), H 0: α2 = 0; χ 2‐statistic = (4.526; 0.299), χ 20.050 = 3.841

⁎⁎
Values significant at 5% level.
a
The null hypothesis that the factor loading equals 0 in the equations for Peand Pwis not rejected.

5
T.A.N. Pham et al. Aquaculture xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

European whitefish market might lower the export prices of pangasius. Table 5
Consequently, the demand for cheap white fish products such as Results for price transmission in the export-wholesale market.
pangasius might be characterized as price inelastic. The non-signifi-
Independent variables Dependent variable
cance of current and lagged export prices suggests that a change in ΔPe , t
export price does not affect farm prices. This implies that in the short-
run, there are no transfer price changes from the exporter to the farmer. Estimated coefficient P-value
One of the possible reasons is that most of the large farms are owned
Constant 0.023 0.459
and operated by exporters, who are able to temporarily supply live ΔPe , t − 1 0.540 0.245
pangasius themselves (Phan et al., 2009; Beukers et al., 2015). ΔPe , t − 2 0.097 0.512
In the long-run equilibrium, the error correction terms ECT+ and ΔPw , t+ − 0.230 0.369
ECT− are significant at the 1% and 5% critical levels, respectively. The ΔPw , t − 1+ 0.130 0.626
ΔPw , t − 2+ − 0.021 0.911
two ECT coefficients suggest that adjustments are relatively fast, i.e. the
ΔPw , t− 0.170 0.433
speed at which the disequilibrium is corrected during the next month to ΔPw , t − 1− 0.233 0.584
reach the steady state is even > 100%. For instance, the estimated ΔPw , t − 2− − 0.340 0.137
coefficient of ECT+ implies that if the farm price is above its ΔEXPLN , t − 0.112 0.377
ΔEXPLN , t − 1 0.045 0.801
equilibrium with respect to the export price, the farm price exhibits a
ΔEXPLN , t − 2 − 0.048 0.726
downward adjustment at a speed of 185% of the value of the error ECTt − 1+ − 1.039 0.076*
correction term in the next month. Similarly, ECT− suggests that the ECTt − 1− − 0.953 0.095*
farm price exhibits an upward adjustment at a speed of 138% of the R-squared 0.449 –
value of the error correction term in the next month when the farm F-statistic 2.263 0.026**
Residual tests F-statistic
price is below its equilibrium with respect to the export price.
No serial correlation 0.403 0.671
With regard to asymmetry in price transmission, Wald tests with a Homoscedasticity 0.941 0.522
null hypothesis of symmetric price transmission could not be rejected at Normal distribution – 0.703
the 1%, 5%, or 10% critical levels, suggesting that a change in export Variable addition test for residual in Eq. 2 0.634 0.431
Asymmetry tests
price is fully transmitted to the farm price. In addition, the long-run
Short run 0.077 0.782
price transmission elasticity in the Johansen cointegration test is equal Long run 0.027 0.870
to 1, meaning that the farm-export market structure is competitive.
Results imply that even though exporters can set the farm price, farmers Notes: **Values significant at 5% level and * at 10% level; LM test for autocorrelation;
can still negotiate the prices. It is possible that farmers with larger farms Breusch-Pagan-Godfrey test for heteroskedasticity; Histogram for normality test.
who can provide quality fish and fulfil the certification requirements
are able to negotiate prices with exporters. Exporters set prices based on price transmission likely implies that exporters can attain privileged
the fish quality at the end of production cycle (Khoi, 2011; Trifković, market access by being able to comply with required standards.
2014).

3.3.3. Wholesale-retail market


3.3.2. Export-wholesale market
The Houck and Ward models with dependent variables of (i)
The estimation results of the VECM with export prices as the
wholesale prices and (ii) retail prices both have R-squared coefficients
dependent variable are presented in Table 5. The non-significant
around 0.85 and significant at the 1% critical level, suggesting that
residuals in the variable addition test from Eq. 2 in the VECM (Eq. 1)
wholesale prices influence retail prices and vice versa. Results of the
confirm that export prices are driven by wholesale prices. The R-
squared coefficient is 0.44 at the 5% critical level, showing that 44% of
Table 6
the variation in export prices is explained by the equation. Results for price transmission in the wholesale-retail market.
A lag length of two was selected based on the outcomes of the AIC,
Hannan-Quin, and final predictor error tests. In the export-wholesale Independent variables Dependent variable
market, the lags are slightly longer than in the farm-export market. This
Pw , t∗ Pr , t∗
might reflect that the transaction costs for adjusting prices are possibly
higher in international trading than in domestic trading. Estimated P-value Estimated P-value
The non-significance of lagged export prices, lagged wholesale coefficient coefficient
prices, and lagged exchange rates (PLN/EUR) indicates that changes
Constant 0.198 0.066* − 0.100 0.033**
in the previous month's export prices, wholesale prices, and exchange
ΔPr , t+ 1.226 0.002*** – –
rates do not transmit to export prices. This might be related to the ΔPr , t − 1+ 0.216 0.636 – –
expiry date of pangasius export contracts, which may affect the length ΔPr , t− 0.690 0.125 – –
of time needed for price adjustments to be incorporated. Larsen and ΔPr , t − 1− −0.364 0.579 – –
Asche (2011) suggested that export price movements are limited by the ΔPw , t+ 0.266 0.000***
ΔPw , t − 1+ 0.112 0.112
use of fixed price contracts in Norwegian salmon exports to France. ΔEXPLN , t −0.095 0.585 0.038 0.691
In the long-run equilibrium, ECT+ and ECT− are both statistically ΔEXPLN , t − 1 0.035 0.841 − 0.009 0.945
significant at the 10% critical level. Adjustments are less responsive in AR(1) 0.859 0.000*** 0.833 0.000***
the export-wholesale market than in the farm-export market. For R-squared 0.870 – 0.854 –
F-statistic 35.280 0.000*** 43.143 0.000***
example, if the export price is above/below its equilibrium with respect
Residual tests F-statistic F-statistic
to the wholesale price, the export price exhibits a downward/upward No serial correlation – – – –
adjustment at a speed of 103%/95% of the value of the error correction Homoscedasticity 0.856 0.534 1.785 0.147
term in the next month. In addition, the long-run price transmission Normal distribution – 0.021** – 0.005***
elasticity of 1.42 suggests the adjustments in the export-wholesale Asymmetry tests – –
Short run 4.816 0.033**
market is instantaneous.
With respect to asymmetry in price transmission, the Wald tests Notes: ***Values significant at 1% level, ** at 5% level, and * at 10% level; LM test for
with a null hypothesis of symmetry in the short run and long run could autocorrelation; Breusch-Pagan-Godfrey test for heteroskedasticity; Histogram for nor-
not be rejected at the 1%, 5%, or 10% critical levels. This symmetry in mality test.

6
T.A.N. Pham et al. Aquaculture xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

two models are shown in Table 6. A lag length of one was selected sustainable production methods, as consumer price premiums paid for
based on the SBC, Hannan-Quin, and likelihood ratio tests. sustainable fish likely flow back to the farm level.
In the first model, where the retail price drives the wholesale price,
only the positive cumulative coefficient of current retail price is Acknowledgements
statistically significant at the 1% critical level. The estimated coefficient
is 1.22, implying that wholesale prices respond quickly to an increase in This research was financed under the SUPA project (improving
retail prices. The question remains however whether price premiums waste management for pangasius culture in the Mekong Delta of
for certified pangasius products at retail level are present. As such, there Vietnam), funded by the bilateral Vietnamese-Netherlands Public
is a need for further research in the willingness to pay for certified Private Partnership between the Vietnamese Ministry of Agriculture
pangasius products in international trading. Similarly, in the model and Rural Development (MARD), the Ministry of Economic Affairs from
where the wholesale price drives the retail price, only the positive the Netherlands (15/0019) and several European and Vietnamese
cumulative coefficient of current wholesale price is statistically sig- private companies. The authors wish to acknowledge NUFFIC
nificant at the 1% critical level. The estimated coefficient of 0.26 (Netherlands Organization for International Cooperation in Higher
suggests that retail prices respond slowly to an increase in wholesale Education) for awarding a partial fellowship, which has made it
prices; this might be due to the existence of menu costs at the retail possible to finish this study. We are grateful to the aquaculture officers
stage (Vavra and Goodwin, 2005; Guillén and Artés, 2015). in An Giang, Dong Thap, Tra Vinh, and Vinh Long provinces for
In both models, the non-significance of the exchange-rate (PLN/ providing price data at farm level. Our special thanks go to Mr. Willem
EUR) and its lags suggests that a change in exchange rates in the van der Pijl from LEI Wageningen UR for sharing import price data.
previous month does not affect wholesale or retail prices. This is
understandable as the transaction between wholesalers and retailers References
has been made in the Polish currency (PLN), not in euros.
With regard to asymmetric price transmission, the Wald test in the Acharya, R.N., Kinnucan, H.W., Caudill, S.B., 2011. Asymmetric farm–retail price
first model where the retail price drives the wholesale price with a null transmission and market power: a new test. Appl. Econ. 43 (30), 4759–4768.
Asche, F., Jaffry, S., Hartmann, J., 2007. Price transmission and market integration:
hypothesis of symmetry was rejected at the 5% critical levels, suggest- vertical and horizontal price linkages for salmon. Appl. Econ. 39 (19), 2535–2545.
ing asymmetric price transmission between wholesalers and retailers. Asche, F., Dahl, R.E., Valderrama, D., Zhang, D., 2014. Price transmission in new supply
Several studies have also shown that retailers use their market power to chains—the case of salmon in France. Aquac. Econ. Manag. 18 (2), 205–219.
Assefa, T.T., Kuiper, W.E., Meuwissen, M.P., 2014. The effect of farmer market power on
transmit price decreases more than price increases to upstream stages the degree of farm retail price transmission: a simulation model with an application
(Fałkowski, 2010; Assefa et al., 2014; Sapkota et al., 2015). In addition, to the Dutch ware potato supply chain. Agribusiness 30 (4), 424–437.
our findings in the model where the retail price drives the wholesale Asteriou, D., Hall, S.G., 2007. Applied Econometrics: A Modern Approach Using Eviews
and Microfit Revised Edition. Palgrave Macmillan, London.
price show that wholesale prices could also respond to retail price
Bakucs, Z., Falkowski, J., Ferto, I., 2012. Price transmission in the milk sectors of Poland
increases. Poor transportation and perishability of the product might and Hungary. Post-Communist Econ. 24 (3), 419–432.
affect the leadership of retail prices over wholesale prices in the short Beukers, R., van der Pijl, W., van Duijn, A.P., 2015. Pangasius in the EU Market; Prospects
for the Position of (ASC-certified) Pangasius in the EU Retail and Food Service Sector.
run (Sapkota et al., 2015).
CBI, The Hague, The Netherlands (Centre for the promotion of imports from
developing countries).
4. Conclusion and policy implications Boswijk, H., Urbain, J.-P., 1997. Lagrance-multiplier tersts for weak exogeneity: a
synthesis. Econ. Rev. 16 (1), 21–38.
Boyd, C.E., McNevin, A.A., 2012. An early assessment of the effectiveness of aquaculture
This study contributes to the literature on price transmission in certification and standards. In: Berry, M., Cashore, B., Clay, J., Fernandez, M., Label,
aquaculture by providing an empirical analysis of the price relation- L., Lyon, T., Mallett, P., Vandenbergh, M., Vis, J.K., Whelan, T. (Eds.), Toward
ships along all stages of an international supply chain from a developing Sustainability: The Roles and Limitations of Certification. Resolve, Inc., Washington,
D.C., pp. A-35–A-69.
to a developed country. Specifically, we have investigated how prices Bukeviciute, L., Dierx, A., Ilzkovitz, F., Roty, G., 2009. Price transmission along the food
transmit from the Polish retail stage to Vietnamese pangasius farms and supply chain in the European Union. In: 112th Seminar of the European Association
vice versa. of Agricultural Economists.
Bush, S.R., Belton, B., 2011. Out of the factory and into the fish pond: can certification
From our findings, we conclude that price changes at the Polish transform Vietnamese Pangasius. In: Spaargaren, G., Oosterveer, P., Loeber, A. (Eds.),
retail stage do transmit to wholesale, export, and Vietnamese pangasius Food Practices in Transition—Changing Food Consumption, Retail and Production in
farm stages with some delay (a month for both farm-export and the Age of Reflexive Modernity. Taylor & Francis, New York, London.
Bush, S.R., Duijf, M., 2011. Searching for (un)sustainabilty in pangasius aquaculture: a
wholesale-retail markets, and two months for the export-wholesale political economy of quality in European retail. Geoforum 42 (2), 185–196.
market). Moreover, price transmissions from wholesale to export and CBI, 2015. Exporting Pangasius to Europe. In: Market Information. Centre for the
from export to farm are characterized by both short- and long-run Promotion of Imports from developing countries, The Hague, The Netherlands.
von Cramon-Taubadel, S., 1998. Estimating asymmetric price transmission with the error
symmetries. In the short run, retailers tend to transmit only wholesale
correction representation: an application to the German pork market. Eur. Rev. Agric.
price increases to their customers and wholesalers transmit only retail Econ. 25 (1), 1–18.
price increases to exporters. In addition, a long-run relationship van Duijn, A., Beukers, R., van der Pijl, W., 2012. The Vietnamese Seafood Sector: A Value
between wholesalers and retailers is absent, thereby reducing the Chain Analysis, CBI/LEI, Part of Wageningen UR.
EUMOFA, 2014. Pangasius imported in the EU. In: Monthly Highlights No. 4/2014.
ability of chain actors to respond to all market signals, including European Market Observatory for Fisheries and Aquaculture Products.
downward changes. However, this study did not study the degree of Fałkowski, J., 2010. Price transmission and market power in a transition context:
market power at wholesale and retail stages, the extent to which the evidence from the Polish fluid milk sector. Post-Communist Econ. 22 (4), 513–529.
Frey, G., Manera, M., 2007. Econometric models of asymmetric price transmission. J.
absence of long-run relationship between wholesalers and retailers is Econ. Surv. 21 (2), 349–415.
unclear and remains a topic for future research. Furthermore, informa- Gordon, D.V., Hussain, S., 2015. Price determination and demand flexibilities in the ex-
tion on the structure of the Vietnamese pangasius export chain is vessel market for tuna in the Republic of Maldives. Aquac. Econ. Manag. 19 (1), 8–28.
Guillén, J., Artés, R.F., 2015. Price transmission and volatility along the Spanish fresh fish
generally limited. More detail about the structure of the export chain market chain. New Medit Mediterr. J. Econ. Agric. Environ. 14 (1), 4–11 (Revue
could enhance the robustness of the conclusions. méditerranéenne d'economie, agriculture et environment).
Our findings have important policy implications. Given the delay in Houck, J.P., 1977. An approach to specifying and estimating nonreversible functions. Am.
J. Agric. Econ. 59 (3), 570–572.
price transmission among market stages, policies could introduce Jaffry, S., 2004. Asymmetric price transmission: a case study of the French hake value
business-to-business electronic trading or auction markets with more chain. Mar. Resour. Econ. 19 (4), 511–523.
flexible pricing. In addition, the transmission of price changes from EU Jesús, I.M., 2011. Fisheries in Poland. Fisheries. Policies, Brussels, European Parliament.
Johansen, S., 1988. Statistical analysis of cointegration vectors. J. Econ. Dyn. Control. 12
markets back to developing country producers is a positive signal for
(2–3), 231–254.
policy makers to stimulate local aquaculture farmers to invest in

7
T.A.N. Pham et al. Aquaculture xxx (xxxx) xxx–xxx

Khoi, L.N.D., 2011. Quality Management in the Pangasius Export Supply Chain in Rapsomanikis, G., Hallam, D., Conforti, P., 2006. Market integration and price
Vietnam: The Case of Small-Scale Pangasius Farming in the Mekong River Delta. transmission in selected food and cash crop markets of developing countries: review
University of Groningen, Groningen. and applications. In: Agricultural Commodity Markets and Trade. Edward Elgar,
Larsen, T.A., Asche, F., 2011. Contracts in the salmon aquaculture industry: an analysis of Cheltenham, UK, pp. 187–217.
Norwegian salmon exports. Mar. Resour. Econ. 26 (2), 141–150. Rico, A., Van den Brink, P.J., 2014. Probabilistic risk assessment of veterinary medicines
Larsen, T.A., Kinnucan, H.W., 2009. The effect of exchange rates on international applied to four major aquaculture species produced in Asia. Sci. Total Environ. 468,
marketing margins. Aquac. Econ. Manag. 13 (2), 124–137. 630–641.
Lee, J., Gomez, M.I., 2011. Price Transmission Asymmetries and Nonlinearities in the Sapkota, P., Dey, M.M., Alam, M.F., Singh, K., 2015. Price transmission relationships
International Coffee Supply Chain. 2011 Annual Meeting, July 24–26, 2011. along the seafood value chain in Bangladesh: aquaculture and capture fisheries.
Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania, Agricultural and Applied Economics Association. Aquac. Econ. Manag. 19 (1), 82–103.
Little, D.C., Bush, S.R., Belton, B., Phuong, N.T., Young, J.A., Murray, F.J., 2012. Serra, T., Goodwin, B.K., 2003. Price transmission and asymmetric adjustment in the
Whitefish wars: Pangasius, politics and consumer confusion in Europe. Mar. Policy 36 Spanish dairy sector. Appl. Econ. 35 (18), 1889–1899.
(3), 738–745. Singh, K., 2016. Price transmission among different Atlantic salmon products in the U.S.
Loc, V., Bush, S., Sinh, L., Khiem, N., 2010. High and low value fish chains in the Mekong import market. Aquac. Econ. Manag. 20 (3), 253–271.
Delta: challenges for livelihoods and governance. Environ. Dev. Sustain. 12 (6), Trifković, N., 2014. Certified standards and vertical coordination in aquaculture: the case
889–908. of Pangasius from Vietnam. Aquaculture 433 (0), 235–246.
Meyer, J., von Cramon-Taubadel, S., 2004. Asymmetric price transmission: a survey. J. Tveteras, S., Asche, F., 2008. International fish trade and exchange rates: an application
Agric. Econ. 55 (3), 581–611. to the trade with salmon and fishmeal. Appl. Econ. 40 (13), 1745–1755.
Ngoc, P.T.A., Meuwissen, M.P.M., Le, T.C., Bosma, R.H., Verreth, J.A.J., Oude Lansink, Tveteras, S., 2015. Price Analysis of Export Behavior of Aquaculture Producers in
A.G.J.M., 2016a. Adoption of recirculating aquaculture systems in large Pangasius Hondouras and Peru. Aquac. Econ. Manag. 19 (1), 125–147.
farms: a choice experiment. Aquaculture 460, 90–97. Vavra, P., Goodwin, B., 2005. Analysis of Price Transmission Along the Food Chain. OECD
Ngoc, P.T.A., Meuwissen, M.P.M., Le, T.C., Verreth, J.A.J., Bosma, R.H., Oude Lansink, Publishing.
A.G.J.M., 2016b. Economic feasibility of recirculating aquaculture systems in Verreth, D.M., Emvalomatis, G., Bunte, F., Kemp, R., Oude Lansink, A.G., 2015. Price
Pangasius farming. Aquac. Econ. Manag. 20 (2), 185–200. Transmission, International Trade, and Asymmetric Relationships in the Dutch Agri-
Ohen, S., Abang, S., Idiong, I., 2007. Price transmission and market integration: vertical Food Chain. Agribusiness 31 (4), 521–542.
and horizontal price linkages for live catfish in Nigeria. J. Agric. Social Sci. 3 (3), Ward, R.W., 1982. Asymmetry in retail, wholesale, and shipping point pricing for fresh
79–82. vegetables. Am. J. Agric. Econ. 64 (2), 205–212.
Phan, L.T., Bui, T.M., Nguyen, T.T.T., Gooley, G.J., Ingram, B.A., Nguyen, H.V., Nguyen, Wilkin, J., Milczarek, D., Malak-Rawlikowska, A., Fałkowski, J., 2007. The Dairy Sector in
P.T., De Silva, S.S., 2009. Current status of farming practices of striped catfish, Poland. Series: Regoverning Markets Agrifood Sector Study, International Institute
Pangasianodon hypophthalmus in the Mekong Delta, Vietnam. Aquaculture 296 for Environment and Development (IIED), London.
(3–4), 227–236.
Pieniak, Z., Kołodziejczyk, M., Kowrygo, B., Verbeke, W., 2011. Consumption patterns
and labelling of fish and fishery products in Poland after the EU accession. Food Web references
Control 22 (6), 843–850.
Pindyck, R.S., Rubinfeld, D.L., 1998. Econometric Models and Economic Forecasts. Irwin/ VASEP. (2014). “Poland increased imports chilled and fresh pangasius fillets.” Retrieved
McGraw-Hill, Boston. 18 February 2016, from http://www.seafood.vasep.com.vn/Daily-News/378_9744/
Piotr, R., 2015. Fish and seafood market in Poland. In: Fishery Products. USDA, American Poland-increased-imports-chilled-and-fresh-pangasius-fillets.html.
Embassy, Foreign Agricultural Service, Warsaw, Poland.

You might also like