You are on page 1of 12

A Spatial Interpretation of the

Density Dependence Model


in Industrial Demography Leo van Wissen

ABSTRACT. In this paper the density dependence model, and demography (van Wissen, 2002). The main
which was developed in organizational ecology, is com- reasons for this increased interest are twofold:
pared to the economic-geographical notion of agglomeration
economies. There is a basic resemblance: both involve some
first, it is related and runs parallel to the increased
form of positive feedback between size of the population and awareness of the role of the SME sector in the
growth. The paper explores how the theoretical concepts economy, both in terms of its role as employment
compare to each other, and if an interdisciplinary cross- generator, and as one of the agents of innovation.
fertilization between both is fruitful. It is found that there are Second, the increased availability of (longitudinal)
a number of important similarities in the underlying theories.
These refer to the process of legitimation, which has some
micro-information of firms allows the empirical
close similarities to concepts derived from theories of new testing of theories of processes of firm formation,
industrial districts, such as social capital, institutional thick- firm growth and survival. It is probably fair to say
ness, and innovative milieux. Differences remain important that organizational sociologists have been most
as well. For instance, the sociological interpretation of com- active in this area in the last decade, as witnessed
petition is not transferable into notions of agglomeration
economies. An important conclusion is that agglomeration
for instance by the work of Carroll, Hannan, and
effects can and should be incorporated into the density depen- Freeman (Hannan and Freeman, 1989; Hannan and
dence model. Carroll, 1992; Carroll and Hannan, 2000). In the
sociological approach to the demography of the
firm, which is called organizational ecology (in
1. Introduction
this paper henceforth called OE) modelling and
Industrial demography, or demography of the firm, empirical testing of demographic processes of
is concerned with the analysis of demographic change in what is termed populations of firms are
processes of entry, exit, and firm growth in indus- very important. As a result, OE researchers have
tries. Although the field is not new, recently it has discovered a number of illuminating empirical
received renewed interest from disciplines such as laws of the demographic behaviour of populations
sociology (Hannan and Freeman, 1977, 1989; of firms over time. The model of density depen-
Carroll and Hannan, 2000), geography (van Dijk dence, which states that the growth path of an
and Pellenbarg, 2000), industrial organization industry (in OE called organizational populations)
(Geroski, 1995; Audretsch, 1997; Caves, 1998), over time is dependent on the number of firms
(size) in that industry, is particularly interesting in
Final version accepted on May 28, 2003 this respect. Understandably, their explanation of
this density dependence is founded in sociological
Faculty of Spatial Sciences
University of Groningen
theory, although there are a number of clear
P.O. Box 800 similarities with industrial organization and eco-
9700 AV, Groningen nomics (Boone and van Witteloostuijn, 1995).
The Netherlands In spatial sciences such as economic geography
and and regional science, the demography of firms is
Netherlands Interdisciplinary Demographic Institute NIDI
The Hague
used to describe and explain interregional differ-
The Netherlands ences in economic growth (Storey, 1994). This
E-mail: l.j.g.van.wissen@frw.rug.nl approach has close links with a number of other

Small Business Economics 22: 253–264, 2004.


 2004 Kluwer Academic Publishers. Printed in the Netherlands.
254 Leo van Wissen

fields: on the one hand entrepreneurship studies, almost exclusively on the number of firms, and
and on the other hand regional growth theory. puts less emphasis on firm size, firm growth and
A central concept in regional growth theory is market structure. Third, OE deals with popula-
agglomeration economies. The goal of this paper tions, not individual firms. Populations are
is to explore the linkages between the OE theory broadly similar to industries, or markets, such as
of density dependence, and the concept of agglom- beer breweries, car industries, or newspaper
eration economics, as developed by regional publishers. Fourth, the population under study is
economists and geographers. In this paper I argue homogeneous with respect to the organizational
that an interdisciplinary cross-fertilization of the activity or production process. There is a clear dif-
density dependence model with agglomeration ference here with industrial organization, which
economies potentially has a number of attractive stresses the heterogeneity of firms in a market.
features. Both include an element of positive Nevertheless, product differentiation and special-
feedback between population size and growth, or ization are also important in OE that may affect
cumulative causation. Although there are large the population density over time. Fifth, OE
differences as well, it is worthwhile to explore the focuses on founding and failure of organizations
potential benefits of cross-fertilization in terms of (firms), whereas economists prefer to talk about
theory and applications. The OE concept lacks market entry and exit. There is clearly substantial
any explicit notion of space, and it may be worth- overlap, but market entry is not only possible
while to explore if and how notions from spatial through the start of a new firm, but also through
sciences might be applicable in this setting. At the product diversification, or the opening of sub-
same time, agglomeration economies, despite sidiary units in other geographical markets by
being widely recognized as an important expla- incumbent firms. A similar argument holds for exit
nation for geographical differences in economic and firm failure. Sixth, the time horizon taken by
growth, have remained something of a black OE is usually very large. For instance, the density
box. Moreover, it has been difficult to establish dependence model of the evolution of the brewery
the precise causal linkages in empirical work. industry in Bavaria covers the period from the
Here, the methodological and empirically founded 16th century until now. The original goal of OE
approach of organizational ecology may prove to was to find empirical regularities that apply
be useful. equally for different industries in all time periods.
When two disciplines study the same phenom- Seventh, markets are not very important in OE. As
enon, there is always the problem of different ter- we shall see below, the concept of competition is
minology and concepts. In this respect terms used important, but used in a broader sense. More gen-
by OE may cause some confusion among econo- erally, the notion of rational behaviour, or profit
mists. Therefore, it may be helpful to clarify a few maximization is not accepted as the driving moti-
differences between OE and economics at the vation for firms. Rather, this role is taken by forces
outset. First, sociologists talk about organizations. of natural selection and organizational inertia.
For them firms are just a specific type of organi- The paper is organized as follows. In Section
zation, and some of these results may equally 2 the density dependence model developed by OE
apply to non-market organizations, such as labour in the field of industrial demography will be pre-
unions. In fact, OE carried out in-depth studies of sented. I will summarize the main features of the
non-market organizations, such as labour unions, concept of agglomeration economies in Section
or day-care centres. While keeping this in mind, 3. Section 4 shows how cross-fertilisation is
in this article we speak about firms throughout. possible and useful. Section 5 concludes.
Second, organizational density is the size of the
population, which is measured by the number of
2. The density dependence model
firms in the population. The density dependence
model describes the time trajectory of the number OE and industrial demographers have since long
of firms in a population. It is therefore closely discovered a basic empirical law in the develop-
related to the notion of the industry life cycle in ment of the number of firms in an industry. Based
industrial organization. However, OE focuses on these observations, they have formulated a
Density Dependence Model in Industrial Demography 255

general model of long-term organizational evolu- their minimum level, the growth rate of the
tion, which is called the density dependence model population is at its maximum. Beyond this level,
(Hannan and Freeman, 1977; Hannan and Carroll, the founding rate decreases, the mortality rate
1992; Carroll and Hannan, 2000). According to increases, and consequently the growth rate
this model, vital rates of birth and death of firms decreases. As a result, the size of the population
are dependent on the size of the population, the stabilizes at the level of the carrying capacity.
population density. Generally it is found that there This overall growth pattern of initially slow
is a non-linear effect of population size on growth, followed by rapid growth, and proceeded
founding rates, with an increasing effect at low by stabilization or decline in the size of the
levels, and a decreasing effect at high levels. population is verified empirically in numerous
Similarly, there is a non-linear effect on failure populations of firms and organizations. See Carroll
rates, with a decreasing effect at low densities, and and Hannan (2000), for an overview of the liter-
an increasing effect at high levels. This leads to a ature.
clockwise pattern of founding rates on density, and Two basic forces are responsible for the size
a U-shaped pattern of mortality on density. The dependency of firm founding and failure: legiti-
population growth rate is the combined effect of mation and competition. Both forces are linked to
birth and death rates. Due to the large variation the size of the population. Legitimation refers to
in the precise forms of these dependencies, popu- the extent that a new organizational form or
lation growth patterns vary considerably, but industry is known and accepted in society. Carroll
they are variations of a basic growth pattern, as and Hannan refer to this as the taken-for-granted-
depicted in Figure 1. When the size of the popu- ness of an organizational form, or more formally
lation is small, founding rates are small and mor- constitutive legitimation. When a new industry
tality is relatively large. Overall, growth rates are emerges, customers are not familiar with the
therefore small. For unsuccessful populations a product, investors are reluctant, and there may be
negative growth rate may even result if mortality legal or institutional constraints that prevent free
exceeds founding from the start and the popula- market introduction. Legitimation increases with
tion will cease to exist without ever having grown the number of firms: the product becomes more
to maturity. For more successful populations, familiar for customers, knowledge increases, and
initially growth rates are small, but as the density investors become less reluctant. Founding and dis-
increases (the number of firms increases) founding banding are related to the level of legitimation of
rates increase, mortality rates decrease, and the an organizational form. The founding rate is pro-
overall growth rates increases. When founding portional, and mortality is inversely proportional
rates are at their maximum and mortality rates near to the level of legitimation.
The second underlying force is competition
between firms. In OE the term competition has
predominantly a social interpretation. Here, com-
petition means conflict, rivalry. It arises as a result
of the interactions within a social system. In
addition to this social interpretation, there is also
an economic interpretation to which we will come
back below. However defined, there is clearly a
positive relationship between the number of firms
and the level of competition. As the size of the
population increases linearly, it may be argued that
competition increases geometrically (Hannan and
Carroll, 1992). This means that the addition of a
new firm to a small population has less impact
than adding an extra firm to a large population.
Figure 1. Density evolution over time in the density depen- Founding and disbanding rates are related to com-
dence model. petition. The founding rate is inversely propor-
256 Leo van Wissen

tional to the intensity of competition, whereas ties, and in France and Germany a comparable
mortality is proportional to it. development took place, with a stabilization
The joint effects of legitimation and competi- around 20 manufacturers. These are large corpo-
tion explain to a large degree the specific S-shaped rations and the automobile market is highly con-
structure of population growth rates over time, centrated. Although there are large variations in
from emergence to the level of the carrying the exact shape of these curves, the same clock-
capacity. Initially, when the population size is wise pattern has been observed in many different
very small, low legitimation intensity and lack of types of organizations and industries. The density
competition lead to low growth rates. As the dependence model tries to formalize this observed
population grows, legitimation increases, and empirical regularity.
competition is still very low, so that the growth Since its introduction in 1989 the density model
rate increases. At a certain level, the maximum has gained popularity, especially among organi-
level of legitimation is reached, and competition zational sociologists. Despite its success, it has
starts to increase fast. Consequently, the growth also received various criticisms. Broadly speaking,
rate decreases fast to zero or even becomes there are three major points of critique. First, no
negative. account is taken of firm size in the theory, whereas
These trends have been observed in many and clearly large and small firms have very different
diverse industries, such as the automobile industry, effects in a population (Winter, 1990; Baum and
banking and insurance, beer breweries, computer Powell, 1995). Second, legitimation and competi-
industry, but also non-market organizations such tion explain the S-shaped form of population
as labour unions, or day-care centres. For example, growth, which leads to a stable population size at
there are a number of remarkable similarities in the level of the carrying capacity. It fails to explain
the shape of the curve of the number of automo- negative growth rates and the negative slope of the
bile manufacturers across countries (Carroll and density curve beyond the peak, since a decrease in
Hannan, 1995; Hannan et al., 1995, Carroll and the population size would lead to less competi-
Hannan, 2002). The automobile industry started tion and therefore a return of the growth rate to
around 1895. In the first decade after the start of zero (Baum, 1995). Third, firms differ not only
the industry growth in the number of firms was with respect to size and economic activity, but also
slow, as a result of a very low level of legitima- with respect to geographical location, which may
tion: the product was initially largely unknown, or be labeled spatial heterogeneity. The geographical
at best a curiosity. In the US and Germany the dimension of the population is especially impor-
number of producers was less than 10, in France tant for its precise definition, and this also plays
slightly more. After 1895 a period of rapid growth a dominant role in the definition of the legitima-
in the number of manufacturers set in, which tion and competition processes (Carroll and Wade,
lasted in all countries until about 1915–1925. By 1991; Swaminathan and Wiedenmayer, 1991;
that time the US counted about 350 producers, and Bigelow and Carroll, 1997). Unfortunately, the
France about 150, while the number in Germany spatial dimension has only received limited atten-
was around 80. These levels may be interpreted as tion in OE.
the carrying capacities of the respective markets. We will concentrate in this article on the issue
The rapid growth was caused by increased legiti- of spatial heterogeneity in the evolution of the size
mation, until a level that the automobile was (density) of industries over time. More specifi-
‘taken for granted’ in society, or fully legitimized. cally, we will use the literature on spatial agglom-
With increasing numbers, competition started erations and compare it with the core concepts of
to press hard and negatively on founding and the density dependence model. OE researchers
survival rates, until net entry became zero. After have proposed a number of solutions to the
this period, failure rates exceeded founding rates, problem of spatial heterogeneity of populations
and the number of manufacturers dropped dra- (Carroll and Wade, 1991; Baum and Mezias, 1992;
matically in the next thirty or so years. After 1945 Lomi, 1995). More recently, Lomi and Larsen
the number of manufacturers in the US stabilized (1996, 2001) have introduced spatial proximity
at a number well below 50 until the late seven- into ecological models of populations. These
Density Dependence Model in Industrial Demography 257

approaches, while being highly valuable in itself, regions, whereas urbanization economies involve
do not take into account agglomeration economies regional diversification. Localization economies
explicitly. As will be shown, agglomeration are external economies of scale and may arise
economies may be viewed as an extension of the when many firms in the same industry are located
density model at the local level. At the same time, in the same region, and share the same specialized
the implications of agglomeration economies into services, specialized infrastructure, have possibil-
this framework will lead to additional require- ities for joint research and development activities,
ments for the density model. Before spelling out as well as region-wide marketing. Moreover, they
these cross-linkages, in the next section we will may benefit from the same specialized labour
very briefly point out the key features of agglom- pool. Firms in this setting are substitutes.
eration economies. Urbanization economies involve firms from
different industries. Here, inter-firm interaction is
highly important, in terms of input-output rela-
3. Agglomeration economies
tionships of suppliers and deliverers. There is a
Agglomeration economies may be regarded as cost unique mix of local industries that provides the
savings that result from the spatial concentration potential for cost advantages. Industries in this
of production at a given location. Since Krugman setting are complementary: output from one
(1995) the geographical dimension into main- industry is used as input by another industry.
stream economics is important, but it was Marshall Porter (1990) emphasized the importance of an
(1882) who already introduced the concept of industrial cluster of different industries that are
external economies. In Krugman’s models linked through intensive input-output relationships
economies of scale, the size of the home market at the national level. In his view, these industry
and transportation costs generate positive returns clusters may or may not imply a spatial clustering.
to scale. Marshall had a somewhat broader view Isard et al. (1959) developed the concept of
on external effects, which according to him are industrial complexes, which are industry clusters
various types of benefits and cost savings obtained characterized by intensive forward and backward
outside the market, but that may lead to increased input-output linkages and showing in addition a
productivity of a firm. These may be the avail- large degree of geographical clustering as well
ability of skilled labour, the availability of spe- (see also Czamanski, 1977). As it turns out,
cialized suppliers of intermediary goods, but economic linkages are often associated with geo-
also localized knowledge spillovers, or simply the graphical clustering (Ellison and Glaeser, 1997;
‘atmosphere’. These external economies are Feser and Sweeney, 2000).
usually available in larger urban centres, where As a result of these external economies, firms
similar economic activities are carried out in close have lower production costs and have a benefit
proximity. External economies are therefore often over firms in other regions. Due to this cost dif-
localized economies, and the regions where they ferential, more firms will move into the region,
appear he called industrial districts. Industrial which leads to even larger cost advantages. As a
districts are clusters of manufacturing SME result, these locations become even more attrac-
firms who benefit from external economies arising tive, which leads to additional economic growth,
from the availability of specialized labour, spe- and so on. This cumulative causation process is
cialized services and trade organizations, as well very important in explaining why economic
as the availability of specialized machinery. growth is highly unevenly distributed in space.
Although there are different typologies of agglom- In the geographical literature the economic
eration effects the most important distinction is definition of agglomeration externalities has been
between localization and urbanization economies. extended to include also many informal and/or
Localization economies result from the geograph- non-economic linkages between firms. In this
ical clustering of similar types of firms, whereas framework an extensive literature has developed
urbanization economies result from the geograph- around a number of core concepts. The notion of
ical clustering of different types of firms. Thus, the new industrial district is an extension of the
localization economies involve specialization of Marshallian concept and includes also the social
258 Leo van Wissen

and cultural background of the region, as well as activities are framed within a particular social
the global market in which the firms produce context. It involves social relationships with other
(Amstrong and Taylor, 2000). In this view, agents, as well as with social institutions. This
agglomeration effects are not only economic, but social context has both positive and negative
also include social, cultural and institutional consequences for (potential) new firms. Positive
dimensions. This involves notions of social capital aspects are the provision of information and
theory of values, norms, and social networks within resources, facilitating, and activity channelling.
which firms operate. Scott (1988) emphasized that Negative aspects are constraints on behaviour and
vertical specialization in a production column is information due to a (non-optimal) position in the
easier in urban districts due to lower transaction network.
costs. These arise because of larger opportunities,
and less searching costs. Firm networks are built
4. Comparing density dependence and location
around a notion of trust and confidence among the
4. theories
participants, which reduces the need for formal
contracting and other formal rules and institutions. There are a number of important cross-linkages
Other institutional factors, especially norms and between the concepts of agglomeration economies
values, and other ‘untraded interdependencies’ and the OE theory of density dependence.
may also be important (Storper, 1997). Another Both involve some form of positive feedback
central notion is knowledge accumulation and between industry size and growth potential. Below
spillover, which may lead to learning regions, and this issue will be addressed in more detail, by
innovative milieux (Lambooy, 1997). Especially answering three related questions:
tacit knowledge is shared through informal
– Are both theories consistent or conflicting with
networks of entrepreneurs and local workers.
each other?
Social structure and knowledge accumulation
– Can the geographical dimension of the density
are important aspects of agglomeration, but are not
dependence model be made explicit, using the
sufficient for successful regional development. A
framework of agglomeration economies?
region needs a certain institutional thickness as
– What can be gained by this comparison of soci-
well (Amin and Thrift, 1995): a local network of
ological and economic-geographical concepts
institutions and organizations supporting local
for OE? For agglomeration theories?
firms, e.g. banks, venture capitalists, chambers of
commerce, supportive local government agencies, These questions will be addressed in turn below.
etc. (Malmberg and Maskell, 1996). Many of these
informal and/or non-economic linkages are highly
Complementary or conflicting theories?
localized in character, and therefore emphasize
the importance of geographical clustering even We begin this discussion by elaborating upon the
more than the traditional economic linkages. For two underlying forces that according to OE shape
instance, Audretsch and Feldman (1996) showed the development of the size of an industry over
that technological spillovers typically work at time: legitimation and competition. Although com-
the very local level. Van Soest et al. (2002) and petition is an economic concept, and legitimation
Van Oort (2002) reach similar conclusions using not, it is too simple to state that they represent
data on employment growth in the Netherlands. sociological versus economic arguments, since
Audretsch (1998) shows that economic activities legitimation also covers various economic mech-
that are based on new knowledge have a tendency anisms.
to co-locate within a geographical region, the main Legitimation in OE may have two meanings.
reason being that knowledge is communicated First, it can be interpreted as conforming to a
more easily at shorter distances. These non-market set of rules or conventions. Second, and more
exchanges between firms have been categorized relevant, it may refer to constitutive legitimation,
under the name of embedding. Embeddedness is or ‘taken-for-grantedness’. New industries emerge
a frequently used concept in new approaches of as a result of an innovation. Initially, the new firm
economic geography (Amin, 1999). Economic producing the innovation (in OE the new organi-
Density Dependence Model in Industrial Demography 259

zational form) is unknown and lacks legitimation. entrepreneurs, that of being high risk-bearers.
This may imply for instance, that there is a lack They face higher intrinsic uncertainty because –
of customers and information about the product, since the population is still very small and young
that there are no suppliers of goods, services, or – they lack sufficient information to attach reliable
capital. Moreover, a pool of skilled labour with probabilities of success to their actions. The more
experience in the production process does not yet firms engage in the new routines of production,
exist. Further, an established network of similar the more reliable the probabilities of success, and
producers, who share knowledge and other infor- the lower the fundamental uncertainty about entre-
mation, is lacking, and there may be legal and preneurial actions. In this way, entrepreneurial
institutional barriers to production. As a result, the actions become established routines and in the
(potential) new entrepreneur faces large startup process they loose their innovative character. This
problems. Founding rates are low, and mortality is an important aspect of legitimation as expressed
rates are high. Nevertheless, as time progresses, by OE, and also very close to the concept of
these limitations may be overcome. This is related learning regions and regional knowledge accu-
to the build-up of a social structure of the industry mulation, one of the important features of new
(Carroll and Hannan, 2000), which includes a set industrial districts.
of roles and positions in a network of organiza- Legitimation also involves the establishment of
tions. networks: of other firms in input-output market
These indicators of legitimation resemble in relations, but also in various other informal
many respects the emergence of agglomeration networks, with other entrepreneurs, and organiza-
economies as presented above. First, they involve tions. Here, tacit and other knowledge is
elements of localization economies: the size of the exchanged, and reciprocal relationships of trust are
customer base, marketing, the size and quality of established. Thus, there are many similarities
the labour pool, and a network of producers that between the legitimation concept of OE and the
may share common knowledge and experience. geographical concepts of new industrial districts,
Second, it also contains some elements of urban- and innovative milieux.
ization economies, especially the creation of input- Despite these similarities there are strong dif-
output relationships with other industries. Third, ferences as well. First, since in the density depen-
the element of creating a social structure of an dence model legitimation is dependent on the size
industry is highly similar to the defining features of the own population, this implies that they are
of a new industrial district, based on a common only the result of localization economies. This
social and cultural background, as well as creating however ignores the inter-industry linkages and
institutional thickness and embedding. urbanization economies, which are crucial in
New organizational forms, or entrepreneurs, industrial districts. This problem arises because
when viewed in their role as innovator, are by the density dependence model is a single industry
definition stepping outside existing institutional model. A second difference is that agglomeration
settings. They create something new that did economies have in principle no upper limit, but
not exist previously, or may even threaten the according to OE there is a maximum to the level
existence of current firms and industries (cf. of legitimation. This runs parallel to the assump-
Schumpeter’s view of entrepreneurship as creative tion of a fixed (exogenous) carrying capacity for
destruction). In this way, innovation and creative a population. While this may be the case in many
destruction can be defined as institutional disem- ecological applications, it does not hold for indus-
bedding. This feature of new firm populations is tries. In urban regions under certain conditions
exactly the cause of lacking taken-for-grantedness. positive feedback between size of the agglomera-
At the same time, an innovation creates a new tion and growth may prevail for a long time,
mode of production that may be followed by although beyond a certain limit negative feedback
others. Most new firms are not pure innovators may set in, for instance as a result of congestion.
themselves, but imitators of earlier innovators Since this issue is also relevant when discussing
(Nelson and Winter, 1982). At the same time they the issue of competition in OE we will return to
do conform to another important characteristic of it below.
260 Leo van Wissen

A third difference is the lack of an explicit geo- it rises geometrically with the number of firms in
graphical dimension in legitimation, whereas it is the population, given a fixed resource space
of central concern in agglomeration economies. (consumer market). Whereas legitimation is a
Spatial proximity is highly important for the emer- positive feedback mechanism, competition leads
gence of agglomeration economies. Transportation to negative feedback between industry size and
costs between the industry and the home market, growth. Thus, legitimation represents the cen-
or between suppliers and deliverers are lower. The tripetal forces for spatial clustering, whereas
availability of a skilled labour market is a local- competition in OE represents the centrifugal ten-
ized advantage as well. Moreover, knowledge dencies. As a result of increased competition
spillovers, networks, local institutions, and the population growth will slow down until zero at
emergence of a social structure of industry all need maximum population size (the carrying capacity).
spatial proximity. As discussed before, knowledge The OE notion of competition is therefore not
based industries benefit more from spatial prox- compatible with agglomeration economies. Much
imity. Therefore, sectoral differences exist in the can be said about the lack of economic reasoning
need for spatial clustering. Moreover, the industry in this theory, but with reference to agglomeration
life cycle is also relevant in this respect. Industries economies three issues stand out. First, agglom-
in the early stage of the life cycle are more depen- eration economies lead to competitive advantages
dent on knowledge and innovations, which may for firms. The more firms, the higher the positive
lead to a larger tendency for agglomeration (see externalities enjoyed, and the larger the competi-
also Van Oort, 2002). In later stages of the life tive advantages. These may (partly) be viewed as
cycle, firms are more likely to be engaged in price external economies of scale, but they are disre-
competition, and there is less need for spatial clus- garded in OE. In OE the evolution of the industry
tering. However, the benefits of spatial proximity is towards increasing market concentration in later
for industry growth have not been recognized in stages of the life cycle due to internal economies
OE until now. On the contrary, spatial proximity of scale. Second, and already mentioned above,
leads to negative competition effects on survival the assumption of a fixed resource space or
and growth. Baum and Mezias (1992) for instance, exogenous carrying capacity is not justified. A
in a study on the dynamics of the New York hotel fixed resource space presumes a closed market
industry, find that hotels located in the districts without trade. Introducing trade would greatly
with the highest hotel density have the highest complicate matters and bring us far beyond the
failure risks. If this were the whole story in boundaries of OE. It would introduce economic
regional industry dynamics, firms would try to geography into the model: transportation costs, the
settle as far as possible from similar firms in the size of the home market, relative prices and other
industry. elements of trade theory; important concepts that
The second process that governs the density cannot be translated directly into a sociological
dependence model is competition. Competition in model. Third, even without introducing trade, the
OE refers to either or both of two types of inter- assumption of a fixed resource space is not
action. Structured competition refers to a limited tenable. The resource space is not only made up
number of actors that are in direct rivalry with of final consumers, but also by intermediate
each other. Diffuse competition refers to a large demand. Many industries deliver primarily to
set of agents that compete for the same limited other businesses. As a result of input-output rela-
resources. The latter form of competition is of tionships and positive feedback between different
direct relevance for industrial demography, since industries, the growth of one industry population
it is directly linked to the notion of density. may enhance the resource space of other indus-
Structured competition is studied extensively in tries, and vice versa.
industrial organization. Competition is a much In summary, the process of legitimation is to a
more straightforward notion than legitimation, and certain extent very close to the geographical
can be analysed using economic concepts. concepts of new industrial district and innovative
Nevertheless, as already observed earlier, in OE milieux, especially in the non-economic exchanges
competition is given a very simple interpretation: between firms, and the build-up of a social struc-
Density Dependence Model in Industrial Demography 261

ture. Nevertheless, there are important differences segments (Carroll, 1984; Carroll and Hannan,
as well, especially the disregard of urbanization 2000). In the resource partitioning model, firms
linkages between different organizational popula- occupy niches in the market, which may be
tions, putting an upper limit on positive feedback defined as geographical niches. Until now, the
between population size and growth potential, and resource partitioning model has only been applied
the lack of a geographical dimension. Moreover, in a non-geographical setting. In the empirical
the competition process as depicted in the density analysis of geographically heterogeneous popula-
dependence model lacks any agglomeration mech- tions two strands of research may be observed: a
anism of positive feedbacks, and is therefore statistical approach where the optimal size of the
not compatible with any notion of agglomeration geographic region is determined as a result of an
economies. analytical model, as in Lomi (1995), and an
approach where, based on a priori reasoning, the
size of the market area is fixed (Baum and Mezias,
Introducing agglomeration effects in the density
1992). The key issues in these papers are the geo-
dependence model?
graphical definition of the population, dealing with
Space matters in economic growth, and also in heterogeneity within the population, and the effect
legitimation and competition within and between of local density on competition and founding and
industries. The geographical boundaries of the disbanding rates. These are important issues, but
market define the population density as well as the from a geographical point of view the most impor-
resource space of the population. OE has its intel- tant issue of agglomeration economies is lacking.
lectual roots in human ecology, in which spatial In order to introduce the notion of agglomera-
competition processes play an important role tion economies into the density dependence
(Park, 1925). Strangely, so far in OE, the spatial model, a number of model extensions are neces-
dimension has not been very important, and atten- sary. First, the processes of legitimation and com-
tion was solely devoted to temporal variations in petition (i.e. the market or resource space) should
population change. The theory of agglomeration be defined geographically. These spatial scales
economics makes it clear that there is a theoret- need not be similar though (Zucker, 1989; Lomi,
ical rationale for including geography into the 1995; Carroll and Hannan, 2000). Carroll and
definition of firm populations. At the same Hannan for instance conjecture that legitimation
time, according to the same theory, not all indus- and competition may work at different spatial
tries have a similar need to cluster in space. scales. They argue that legitimation often works
Agglomeration effects are stronger in knowledge at the national level, whereas competition is much
intensive industries. As noted earlier, there is also more local. We concluded in this paper on the
a link with the industry life cycle, with spatial contrary that in some situations this might well
clustering being more relevant in the early stages be the other way around. Many legitimation
of the industry life cycle, where product innova- processes, similar to the creation of new industrial
tions are important. As the industry develops, the districts, are very localized in nature, whereas the
geographical pattern that emerged in the earlier resource space may be very large, for instance
stages may have a lasting impact upon the geo- when dealing with firms operating on a global
graphical distribution of further growth. This may market. Consumer awareness and marketing com-
be labelled ‘spatial lock-in’ or path dependency. petition may be local whereas legitimation is a
There are a number of examples of spatial process on a much larger geographical scale, but
analyses within OE. Broadly speaking, geograph- legitimation entails much more than this. We
ical location in OE is viewed as one form of discussed above that knowledge spillovers,
population diversification, which calls for different institutions, social structure, and trust are very
models at different geographical scales (Barnett localized phenomena. A second model extension
and Carroll, 1987; Carroll and Wade, 1991; Baum deals with between-industry linkages. Interactions
and Mezias, 1992; Bigelow and Carroll, 1997). A between firm populations should be incorporated,
related development views resources as heteroge- in order to capture urbanization economies. This
neous, and deals with market partitioning in is certainly an interesting but complicated topic.
262 Leo van Wissen

In some respects the resulting models might of view is used in studies on the emergence of
resemble elements of existing non-economic industrial districts, such as Silicon Valley or
theories of agglomeration (Anas et al., 1998). Van Detroit, where new and successful firms in the
Wissen (2000) gives an example of such an region start as spin-offs from successful incum-
approach in the context of a microsimulation bents in the emerging period of the industry
model of industrial demography. Third, local vari- (Klepper, 2001, 2002). The density dependence
ations in population density can also have a model when applied in such a setting may there-
positive effect on founding and firm growth, espe- fore help to open up the still largely mysterious
cially in the early life cycle stages of the industry, black box of agglomeration economies.
and in knowledge based industries.
5. Summary and conclusions
Density effects in models of agglomeration
In this paper the density dependence model, which
economies?
was developed in OE was compared to the
In the previous subsection we addressed the economic-geographical notion of agglomeration
question if introducing notions from agglomera- economies. There is a basic resemblance: both
tion economies in the density dependence model involve some form of positive feedback between
would be fruitful. We may also turn this question size of the industry and growth. We explored from
around, and ask what can be gained from this com- a theoretical perspective how the theoretical
parative effort for our understanding of agglom- concepts compare to each other, and if an inter-
eration economies? In answering this question disciplinary cross-fertilization between both is
three issues should be emphasized. First, the fruitful. Two driving forces are important for the
concept of legitimation offers a new sociological temporal evolution of industries in OE: legitima-
angle to a number of processes that are studied in tion and competition. When viewed from a spatial
depth by economic geographers, especially the perspective, legitimation contains the centripetal
nature of non-market exchanges and institutional forces, and competition the centrifugal forces in
networks. Second, the density dependence model spatial cluster formation. Legitimation was
is confirmed in numerous empirical studies, and shown to have close links with the agglomeration
has attained the status of an empirical law, applic- economies literature, especially with various non-
able to many different organizational forms and in economic exchange linkages between firms,
many situations. There is also a substantial liter- embeddedness, institutional thickness, and the
ature on the exact specification of the relationship creation of social structure for new populations
between population density and founding and of firms. In legitimation we find positive feedback
disbanding processes of firms. This is quite dif- effects similar to economies of localization.
ferent in research focussing on agglomeration However, there are differences as well. Most
economies. The emphasis here is much more on importantly, urbanization economies are not
theoretical models and concepts. Empirical results covered in the model, and the model lacks a clear
are sometimes inconclusive, and despite the wide- spatial dimension. The notion of competition in
spread conviction that it is of major importance, the density dependence model is only rudimentary
empirical confirmation often remains difficult developed and the notion of external economies of
(Van Oort, 2002). To start with, economies of scale is lacking here. Competition as viewed by
localization might be specified in terms of a OE is a negative feedback mechanism, and there-
density dependence model, and this opens up fore not compatible with positive agglomeration
interesting new ways of empirical testing of effects. The comparison with the literature on
agglomeration economies. Third, OE deals with agglomeration economies shows that a number of
founding and disbanding of firms, as well as important elements are missing here. Regional dif-
growth of incumbent firms. Looking at regional ferences in founding and disbanding are at least
growth from such a firm demographic perspec- partly the result of agglomeration economies and
tive may give a strong behavioural interpretation therefore this should be taken into account in the
to agglomeration economies. Recently, this point density dependence model. The legitimation
Density Dependence Model in Industrial Demography 263

concept is a useful starting point here, since it Amstrong, H. and J. Taylor, 2000, Regional Economics and
links closely with existing agglomeration concepts Policy, 3rd Edition, Oxford: Blackwell Publishers.
Anas, A., R. Arnott and K. Small, 1998, ‘Urban Economic
in economic geography. In addition, however, we Structure’, Journal of Economic Literature 26(3), 1426–
need inter-population linkages, in order to capture 1464.
urbanisation economies. Such a step towards Audretsch, B., 1997, ‘Technological Regimes, Industrial
multi-population OE models is also foreseen by Demography and the Evolution of Industrial Structures’,
Carroll and Hannan (2002, p. 451), when dis- Industrial and Corporate Change 6(1), 49–82.
Audretsch, B., 1998, ‘Agglomeration and the Location of
cussing future directions of the field: Innovative Activity’, Oxford Review of Economic Policy
[. . .] a scientifically sound multipopulation design likely 14(1), 18–29.
needs to be developed. We think that an important next Audretsch, D. B. and M. P. Feldman, 1996, ‘R&D Spillovers
step in developing the demography of corporations and and the Geography of Innovation and Production’,
industries will design and conduct research on the com- American Economic Review 86(3), 630–640.
munities of interacting populations of corporations and Barnett, W. and G. Carroll, 1987, ‘Competition and Mutualism
industries (Carroll and Hannan, 2002, p. 451). among Early Telephone Companies’, Administrative
Science Quarterly 32(3), 400–421.
If this direction is taken in OE, then some of the Baum, J. A. C., 1995, ‘The Changing Basis of Competition
potential cross-fertilizations may be realized in in Organizational Populations: The Manhattan Hotel
Industry’, Social Forces 74(1), 177–205.
this programme. Incorporating agglomeration Baum, J. and S. Mezias, 1992, ‘Localized Competition and the
effects in a multi-industry density dependence Dynamics of the Manhattan Hotel Industry’, Administrative
model is an interesting but complex problem. Science Quarterly 37(4), 580–604.
Lessons could be learned here from existing (non- Baum, J. A. C. and W. W. Powell, 1995, ‘Cultivating an
economic) dynamic models of agglomeration Institutional Ecology of Organizations: Comment on
Hannan et al.’, American Sociological Review 60(4),
economies. These models often have complex 529.
dynamic properties resulting from non-linear Bigelow, L. S. and G. R. Carroll, 1997, ‘Legitimation,
dynamic relationships of interacting populations. Geographical Scale, and Organizational Density. Regional
Another result of our comparison was that Patterns of Foundings of American Automobile Producers’,
agglomeration effects will vary between indus- Social Science Research 26(4), 377–398.
Boone, C. A. J. J. and A. van Witteloostuijn, 1995, ‘Industrial
tries, and are especially relevant in the formative Organization and Organizational Ecology: The Potentials
period of the industry. This life cycle aspect may for Cross-Fertilization’, Organizational Studies 16(2),
fit neatly in the framework of the density depen- 265–298.
dence model. Carroll, G. R., 1984, ‘Concentration and Specialization:
Finally, theories and models of agglomeration Dynamics of Niche Width in Populations of
Organizations’, American Journal of Sociology 90(1),
economies may also benefit from insights derived 1262–1283.
from OE. The strong empirical roots of the density Carroll, G. R. and M. T. Hannan (eds.), 1995, Organizations
dependence model might be relevant for alterna- in Industry: Strategy, Structure, and Selection, New York:
tive tests of localization economies. Moreover, the Oxford University Press.
different conceptual angle, provided by the soci- Carroll, G. R. and M. T. Hannan, 2000, The Demography
of Corporations and Industries, Princeton: Princeton
ological concept of legitimation, but also the focus University Press.
on demographic processes of founding and dis- Carroll, G. R. and J. Wade, 1991, ‘Density Dependence in
banding, may prove to be fruitful for extending the Organizational Evolution of the American Brewing
our understanding of agglomeration economies. Industry across Different Levels of Analysis’, Social
Science Research 20(3), 217–302.
Caves, R. E., 1998, ‘Industrial Organisation and New Findings
References on the Turnover and Mobility of Firms’, Journal of
Economic Literature 36(4), 1947–1982.
Amin, A., 1999, ‘An Institutionalist Perspective on Regional Czamanski, S., 1977, ‘Needless Complexity in the
Economic Development’, International Journal of Urban Identification of Industrial Complexes: A Comment’,
and Regional Research 23(2), 365–378. Journal of Regional Science 17(3), 455–457.
Amin, A. and N. Thrift, 1995, ‘Globalisation, Institutional Ellison, G. and E. L. Glaeser, 1997, ‘Geographical
“Thickness” and the Local Economy’, in Patsy Healey, Concentration in US Manufacturing Industries: A
Stuart Cameron, Simin Davoudi, Stephen Graham and Ali Dartboard Approach’, Journal of Political Economy
Madani-Pour (eds.), Managing Cities: The New Urban 107(5), 889–927.
Context, Chichester: Wiley, pp. 92–108. Feser, E. J. and S. H. Sweeney, 2000, ‘A Test for Economic
264 Leo van Wissen

and Spatial Clustering’, Journal of Geographical Systems Park, R., 1925, ‘The Urban Community as a Spatial Pattern
2(4), 349–373. and a Moral Order’, Publications of the American
Geroski, P. A., 1995 ‘What Do We Know about Entry?’, Sociological Society 20(1), 1–14.
International Journal of Industrial Organization 13(4), Porter, M. E., 1990, The Competitive Advantage of Nations,
421–440. New York: Free Press.
Hannan, M. T. and G. R. Carroll, 1992, Dynamics of Scott, A., 1988, New Industrial Spaces: Flexible Production
Organizational Populations: Density, Legitimation and Organization and Regional Development in Northern
Competition, New York: Oxford University Press. America and Western Europe, London: Pion.
Hannan, M. T., G. R. Carroll, E. A. Dundon and J. C. Torres, Storey, D. J., 1994, Understanding the Small Business Sector,
1995, ‘Organizational Evolution in Multinational Context: London: Routledge.
Entries of Automobile Manufacturers in Belgium, Britain, Storper, M., 1997, The Regional World: Territorial
France, Germany and Italy’, American Sociological Review Development in a Global Economy, New York: Guildford
60(4), 509–528. Press.
Hannan, M. T. and J. Freeman, 1977, ‘The Population Ecology Swaminathan, A. and G. Wiedenmayer, 1991, ‘Does the
of Organizations’, American Journal of Sociology 82(1), Pattern of Density Dependence in Organizational Mortality
929–964. Rates Vary across Levels of Analysis? Evidence from the
Hannan, M. T. and J. Freeman, 1989, Organizational Ecology, German Brewing Industry’, Social Science Research 20(1),
Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. 45–73.
Isard, W., E. W. Schooler and T. Vietorisz, 1959, Industrial Taylor, M. J., 1970, ‘Location Decisions of Small Firms’, Area
Complex Analysis and Regional Development, Cambridge, 2(1), 51–54.
MA: MIT Press. Van Dijk, J. and P. H. Pellenbarg, 2000, ‘The Demography
Klepper, S., 2001, ‘Employee Startups in High-Tech of Firms: Progress and Problems in Empirical Research’,
Industries’, Industrial and Corporate Change 10(4), in J. van Dijk and P. H. Pellenbarg (eds.), Demography
639–674. of Firms; Spatial Dynamics of Firm Behaviour,
Klepper, S., 2002, ‘The Capabilities of New Firms and the Utrecht/Groningen: Netherlands Geographical Studies 262,
Evolution of the US Automobile Industry’, Industrial and KNAG/FRW RUG, pp. 325–337
Corporate Change 11(4), 645–666. Van Oort, F., 2002, Agglomeration, Economic Growth and
Krugman, P., 1995, Development, Geography and Economic Innovation. Research Series no. 260, Amsterdam:
Theory, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Tinbergen Institute/Thela Thesis.
Lambooy, J., 1997, ‘Knowledge Production, Organization, and Van Soest, D., F.van Oort, and S. D. Gerking, 2002,
Agglomeration Economies’, Geojournal 41(4), 293–300. ‘Knowledge Externalities, Agglomeration Economies, and
Lomi, A., 1995, ‘The Population Ecology of Organizational Employment Growth in Dutch Cities’. Discussion Paper
Founding: Location Dependence and Unobserved 2002-14, Tilburg: Tilburg University.
Heterogeneity’, Administrative Science Quarterly 40(1), Van Wissen, L. J. G., 2000, ‘A Micro-Simulation Model of
111–144. Firms: Applications of Concepts of the Demography of
Lomi, A. and E. R. Larsen, 1996, ‘Interacting Locally and Firms’, Papers in Regional Science 79(1), 111–134.
Evolving Globally: A Computational Approach to the Van Wissen, L. J. G. 2002, ‘Demography of the Firm. A
Dynamics of Organizational Populations’, Academy of Useful Metaphor?’, European Journal of Population 18(3),
Management Journal 39(5), 1287–1321. 263–279.
Lomi, A. and E. R. Larsen, 2001, Dynamics of Organizations, Winter, S., 1990, ‘Survival, Selection and Inheritance in
Live Oak: MIT Press. Evolutionary Theories of Organization’, in J. Singh (ed.),
Malmberg, A. and P. Maskell, 1996, ‘Towards and Organizational Evolution: New Directions, Newbury Park
Explanation of Regional Specialization and Industry CA: Sage, pp. 269–297.
Agglomeration’, European Planning Studies 5(1), 25–39. Zucker, L., 1989, ‘Combining Institutional Theory and
Marshall, A., 1892, The Economics of Industry, London: Population Ecology: No Legitimacy, No History’,
Macmillan. American Sociological Review 54(1), 242–245.
Nelson, R. R. and S. Winter, 1982, An Evolutionary Theory
of Economic Change, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University
Press.

You might also like