You are on page 1of 15

Environmental Influences on MNE Subsidiary Roles: Economic Integration and the Nordic

Countries
Author(s): G. R. G. Benito, B. Grogaard, R. Narula
Source: Journal of International Business Studies, Vol. 34, No. 5 (Sep., 2003), pp. 443-456
Published by: Palgrave Macmillan Journals
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/3557161
Accessed: 19/04/2010 22:41

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless
you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you
may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.

Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at
http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=pal.

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed
page of such transmission.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Palgrave Macmillan Journals is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Journal of
International Business Studies.

http://www.jstor.org
of International
Journal Business (2003)34,443-456
Studies
C 2003 PalgraveMacmillanLtd. Allrightsreserved0047-2506 $25.00 *X
www.jibs.net

Environmental
influences on MNE subsidiary
roles: economic integration and the Nordic
countries

GRGBenito'2, B Grogaard1, Abstract


R Narula2 We seek to examine the importance of environmental factors in determining
MNE subsidiary roles. In particular, we examine the environmental factors
associated with 'deep' integration schemes such as the EU. Such schemes
1NorwegianSchoolof ManagementBI,Elias
Smithsvei 15, N-1302 Sandvika,Norway; require a convergence of economic structure, due to the establishment of
2CopenhagenBusinessSchool,Howitzvej60, common regional institutions, regulations and policies. Specifically, we
DK-2000Frederiksberg,Denmark distinguish between the scope of activities performed by subsidiaries, and
the level of competence of those subsidiaries. The empirical analysis is based on
Correspondence: a large-scale survey of foreign-owned units in Denmark, Finland and Norway.
Professor GRGBenito, Department of These Nordic countries differ with regard to their EU-membership status -
Strategy, Norwegian School of Norway being the 'outsider', while the others are members - but are very
Management BI,EliasSmithsvei 15, N-1302 similar to each other in most other respects. Our data show that subsidiaries in
Sandvika,Norway.
Tel: + 47 67557000; Norway report significantly lower scores for both scope of activities and levels
Fax: +47 67557250; of competence. The effects remain strong even when we are controlling for
E-mail:gabriel.r.g.benito@bi.no other potentially influential factors. The findings indicate that being on the
'outside' of the EU may indeed carry the price of becoming less attractive to
MNE activity.
Journal of International Business Studies (2003) 34, 443-456, doi:10.1057/
palgrave.jibs.8400047

Keywords: subsidiaryroles; regional integration;foreign direct investment; Nordic


countries

Introduction
Strategic management literature on the role, dispersion and
development of subsidiaries is now well developed (see, e.g.,
Bartlett and Ghoshal, 1989; Birkinshaw, 1996; Birkinshaw and
Hood, 1998; Holm and Pedersen, 2000; Roth and Morrison, 1992).
Nevertheless, it has tended to focus on MNE-specific (i.e., internal)
determinants. Little attention has been given to the extent to
which a subsidiary's role and competence is determined by
environmental (i.e., external) factors (Birkinshaw and Hood,
1998). This article seeks to rectify that oversight by examining
the response of MNEs to the external environment as they locate
their subsidiaries and assign and develop different subsidiary roles
for them. It is the contention of this article that although internal
MNE factors play an important role in determining the kinds of
Received: 13 July2001
Revised: 10 January2003
activities undertaken by a subsidiary in a given location, environ-
Accepted: 14 January2003
mental factors influence both the initial entry decision and the
Online publication date: 24 July2003 competence and scope of the affiliate.
*4 [44llVllk/lllII Enw:r.nm..a-ntl .nfl.anea,
U II
anInIIIL
/1
UkMNFlclh;,[l:'a-rv
#lJItilaly
r'lIc
II
~D~_
K Ronitot
llL t /-,
-

A4AA

Environmental factors include location advantages ary roles, has greatly expanded over the last 20
issues as well as political economy issues. We do not years, beginning with the seminal work of Bartlett
intend to provide a systematic analysis of all the and Ghoshal (1986, 1989). Although they proposed
environmental determinants of subsidiary roles, nor to a close link between the influence of the subsidiary
argue their importance relative to interal decisions. and the strategic importance of its local environ-
Instead, we will illustrate that macro factors associated ment, many of their studies on subsidiary roles
with a subsidiary's location advantages are also have approached the issue mainly from an internal
significant in understanding its roles and competences. perspective. These roles have commonly been
Our focus here is on the effect of location viewed as the result of corporate headquarters
advantages associated with 'deep' regional integra- assignment or an autonomous process within the
tion schemes such as the EU. The importance of subsidiary. Lorenzoni and Baden-Fuller (1995), for
location advantages in determining MNE activity instance, credit the strategic center as having a
within the EU has largely been studied on an critical role in a network of units, adding value by
aggregate level. Considerably less attention has been contributing its own expertise as well as by
paid to the firm-level response1 to changing location coordinating the flow of knowledge within the
advantages as a result of integration, although it network. The degree of embeddedness in external
seems axiomatic that changes in economic structure business relationships has also been found to
due to integration have significant implications for influence the development of subsidiary roles
the way in which MNEs organize their activities. (Andersson and Forsgren, 2000; Andersson et al.,
Our interest in regional integration is not so much 2001). However, these studies have focused primar-
in the mechanisms of the process per se, but in what ily on immediate business relationships and not
deep integration represents at a company level. One dealt with the macro environment or possible
of the mechanisms (and indeed also an outcome) of differences between nations.
deep integration schemes is a convergence of Less attention generally has been given to the
economic structure as a result of the establishment external environment. Although the literature on
of common regional institutions, regulations and aggregate economic activity suggests that different
policies (Narula, 2003). From a European perspec- roles do evolve, the strategic management litera-
tive, there is concrete evidence that there are ture, with a few exceptions (Mariotti and Piscitello,
substantial benefits for MNEs operating within the 2001; Birkinshaw and Hood, 2000), lacks research
EU compared to those operating outside it. relating subsidiary development to exogenous
We seek to examine the importance of environ- factors that are not firm, network and/or industry-
mental factors on the development of subsidiary roles. specific.
We illustrate our arguments by focusing on the specific The external environment can have considerable
case of three otherwise-similar peripheral European impact on the scope and competence level of
countries - the Nordic countries of Denmark, Finland subsidiaries. This is often acknowledged in the
and Norway - which share a number of common literature under the rubric of location advantages.
features, but are not all members of the EU. While Considerable attention has been paid to the role of
these three countries are remarkably similar culturally location advantages in determining the initial
as well as in terms of market size and wealth, they entry decisions of MNEs in any given market (see
differ in the extent to which their economic and e.g., Benito and Gripsrud, 1992; Culem, 1988;
industrial structures have converged as a result of deep Davidson, 1980; Dunning, 1988; Jackson and
integration taking place within the EU. We use data Markowski, 1996; Lipsey and Kravis, 1982;
collected in a detailed questionnaire survey of foreign- Mudambi, 1995; Veugelers, 1991). However, once
owned companies in Denmark, Finland and Norway. the decision to enter a given market through FDI is
In all, the database comprises 809 subsidiaries of MNEs taken, the kinds of activity undertaken by the
from more than 20 countries, established over a subsidiary and its level of competence are also co-
number of years: about half of the sample was determined by the specific advantages of the host
established before the intensification of European location. That is to say, while internal factors such
regional integration from the mid-1980s. as a firm's internationalization strategy, the role
of the new location in its global portfolio of
The external environment and MNE activity subsidiaries, and the motivation for investment
The literature on subsidiary development, evaluat- are pivotal in the structure of MNE investment,
ing the dynamics behind the evolution of subsidi- these factors are dependent on the available

Journal of International Business Studies


Environmental
...... influences
...... on MNE subsidiary
-..~~~~~~~ roles GRG Benito et al
445
445

location-specific resources that can be used for that these costs are substantial (Narula, 2002). Thus,
purpose. Even if a host location does not have a where the level of competence of the subsidiary is
large domestic market, for instance, an MNE may high, the MNE is more likely to maintain it, even
still engage in local production because of import where an alternative location may provide a better
restrictions. Likewise, weak protection of intellec- fit with the firm's overall strategy.
tual property rights may limit an MNE's involve-
ment in R&D in a host location that would Economic integration as an external determinant
otherwise be an attractive location for R&D. The of subsidiary roles
point here is that even at the initial investment Regional integration schemes represent a specific
stage, the scope of activities undertaken in a host subset of location advantages (Vernon, 1996).
location is tempered by that location's character- Regional integration has occurred on a de facto
istics. These include all aspects of industrial and basis, due to economic convergence and an asso-
investment policy, which can determine the kinds ciated growing interdependence through trade and
of incentives provided by the host country, as well FDI amongst the Triad countries. In certain
as more 'traditional' location advantages such as instances it has been further reinforced by de jure
market size, agglomeration economies, infrastruc- political and economic integration between groups
ture and asset availability. of nations (Narula, 2003). This is best illustrated by
The host country's location advantages play an the case of Europe, which has been in the throes of
important role in determining the level of compe- integration for half a century.
tence of a subsidiary. This is on at least two levels. The static and dynamic gains from regional
First, the level of competence is a function of the integration schemes result in both long and short
quality of location advantages that the host loca- run economic gains. This is due, among other
tion can provide. High competence levels require things, to improved economies of scale and scope,
specific complementary assets that are often asso- increased efficiency through the rationalization
ciated with agglomeration effects, clusters and the and reallocation of firms' activities, and improved
presence of highly specialized skills. In other words, inter-regional linkages (Eden, 2001). Improvements
firms are constrained in their choice of location for in economic conditions can also be expected to
high-competence subsidiaries by resource availabil- positively influence inflows of FDI. In the context
ity. For instance, R&D activities tend to be con- of the current article, we are interested in so-called
centrated in a few locations because the appropriate deep integrationschemesthat may include common
specialized resources are associated specifically with industrial policies, elimination of all intra-regional
those locations. Second, MNEshave been shown to tariff and non-tariff barriers,and common external
prefer to engage in sequential investment in barriers. In other words, such schemes promote
locations that provide sub-optimal returns but economicintegration.Most prominent of these is the
where they have prior experience. In part this is European Union initiative, which has evolved over
because firms are not boundlessly rational (see e.g., time from a rather limited free trade agreement to a
Madhok, 1997); but it is also because although the political and economic union (Baldwin, 1997). In
scope of activities undertaken by a subsidiary can contrast, shallow integration schemes essentially
be modified more or less instantly, developing involve the reduction of tariff barriers between
competence levels takes time. MNE investments member countries. It is axiomatic that the benefits
in high value-added activities (often associated from membership of shallow agreements that have
with high competence levels) have the tendency been in place for a short period are unlikely to
to be 'sticky'. Such subsidiaries tend to be prove as beneficial as deep integration agreements
embedded with the local milieu with regard to that have been implemented for a long period.
linkages with suppliers, customers and domestic Our interest here is not in the process of regional
institutions. These linkages are both formal and integration per se, but in economic integration and
informal, and will probably have taken years - if what it represents in terms of its effect on other
not decades - to create and sustain. Firms generally location advantages. Deep integration schemes
dislike radical change, and will prefer to maintain such as the European Union influence the char-
the status quo if it does not endanger their acteristics of locations through two means.
competitiveness. When an MNE does choose to First, integration has an impact on market size,
exit, it must suffer the costs of entry in another because MNEs have potential access to a larger
location (in terms of effort, capital and time), and single market. Numerous studies have looked at the

Journal of International Business Studies


Cn.-'rnnm,Ant-l ;nfl:a.neac ,/c1 an ml-
.
IMINF c:h l.-riali
rlUl# r.lct:/ (-D(-. R,-,nit;o,,t ,,nl
IrIVnIvIIIIIeIII IIIIICIIC) Iv )ul,/ ary 1K1 IeiIu Ul

446

effects of EU integration on economic activity and de jureconvergence of important variables such


(Balasubramanyam and Greenaway, 1992; as tax rates, quality of infrastructure, competition
Chesnais and Sailleau, 2000). Although the positive law, incentive schemes, corporate governance,
trade effects of integration are transparent (Baldwin procurement regulations, etc. (Eliassen and
and Venables, 1995, Pain and Lansbury, 1997), the Monsen, 2001).
evidence of its impact on FDI is somewhat more Given the effects of regional integration on
ambiguous (Motta and Norman, 1996; Neven and economic activities such as reorganization and
Siotis, 1993; Yannopoulos, 1990). Dunning rationalization, one might conclude that some
(1997a,b), in a comprehensive survey of inward changes in subsidiary roles are inevitable. Once an
FDI into the EU, concluded that the geographical MNE rationalizes the number of subsidiaries or
and industrial distribution of inward FDIstocks had reorganizes the activities across borders, the various
changed to reflect a certain level of rationalization, units are likely to experience changes in their scope
but that overall the spatial distribution of produc- and areas of responsibility. Increases in scope can
tion activities had not undergone a major shift. typically be found when the number of subsidiaries
However, Dunning's survey - like many other is rationalized or when local conditions encourage
economic studies - is based on macro-level data, localization of activities (Birkinshaw,1996; Poynter
which obfuscates the understanding of changes in and Rugman, 1982). Similarly, the scope may be
the strategies of firms as a result of regional narrowed to focus on specific activities and build
integration. MNEs have reorganized their spatial expertise within selected areas (Surlemont, 1998;
distribution within the EU to exploit economies of Chiesa, 1995). Hence, changes in scope are often
scale and scope, and to exploit more efficiently the related to both organizational and spatial consid-
comparative advantages of the various member erations.
countries within the EU. However, while the net Scope does not necessarily always determine
effects may be zero, the importance of their subsidiary roles, however. Some studies have found
operations may well have changed. a correlation between a subsidiary'slevel of compe-
Take an automobile manufacturer with two tence and its role within the MNE (Furu, 2001).
hitherto independent subsidiaries, one in Spain Studies on 'centers of excellence', for instance,
and the other in Germany. In the interests of propose a strong relationship between the level of
exploiting economies of scale, it may concentrate influence and the subsidiary's competence level
its body production operations in Spain, its engine (Forsgrenand Pedersen, 1998; Fratocchi and Holm,
manufacturing activities in Germany, and its R&D 1998). This research also emphasizes the impor-
in Italy (where it hitherto had no activities). Thus, tance of using the subsidiary's competence in the
although there has been significant intra-EU redis- MNE in order to develop new roles for it. High
tribution of FDI, the net effect might simply be an levels of competence in areas of importance to the
increase in inward FDI in Italy, since the redistribu- MNE thus appear to result in greater subsidiary
tion of resources between Germany and Spain may autonomy.
well cancel each other out. Such restructuring has Consequently, it is useful to look at the combina-
been noted for a variety of firms across a wide tion of scope and competence levels when discuss-
spectrum of industries. ing subsidiary roles. As discussed previously,
Such reorganization has also led to a certain level regional integration often brings about changes to
of disinvestment (Benito, 1997) or downgrading of both the organization and the performance of MNE
activities in locations that have not joined the EU. activities. This can be seen in terms of changes in
Non-EU MNEs in particular, regarded the single scope and in the development and use of compe-
European market initiative as the basis for the tencies. Figure 1 illustrates the different subsidiary
creation of a 'Fortress Europe' with high costs for roles that unfold from the various combinations of
firms not already established there (Almor and scope and competence levels.
Hirsch, 1995), and reduced their investments in Because internationalization is inherently risky,
locations that were not part of the Union. everything else being equal, initial investments
Second, deep regional integration can result in an tend to be small, perhaps in a sales subsidiary or a
increasing similarity in the economic structures of small-scale production unit (Delany, 2000;
the participating countries. Common legislation Birkinshaw, 1998). Subsequent development may,
and coordination occurs through the establishment if it occurs, proceed along one or both dimensions.
of supra-regional institutions, resulting in a de facto As Figure 1 shows, subsidiarieswith many activities

Journal of International Business Studies


_ }
Environmental influences an HIOIF cmhe;X;rvir
vlBI IVIILI=sUlIUICaJy rnlac
WI
rIo I.Pl. R',nit-
tIIILU
uKu Cb i ot nI
ul
447

beneficial - from the viewpoint of subsidiary


A

Highly
development - to be located within a regional bloc
High \ specializedunit,,
than outside it. Regional integration promotes the
q)
a)
,e.g. R&D center,,/ widening of markets, and because 'insiders' have
--
easier access to the larger market they are, all else
being equal, in a better position than 'outsiders' to
14--
0
co

0 exploit economies of scale as well as economies of


scope. The liberalization of trade and factor move-
_ " Miniature ' ments within an area should also increase the level
Low \ replica ,/ of competition throughout the area. An intensifica-
tion of competition should, in turn, lead to a
Few Many
shakeout of less-efficient actors; those that remain
value activities value activities in an industry are likely to be the most competitive
Scope of activities ones. Of course, competitive processes are never at
a standstill. As a consequence, units operating
Figure 1 Different types of subsidiaries.
within a bloc must continually strive to better their
performance, efficiency or innovativeness. Stated
but low competence levels are defined as 'miniature
differently: they have to become ever more compe-
replicas' that basically mirror the parent organiza- tent in their line of activities.
tion. These subsidiaries will typically be found in Units in 'outsider' locations may clearly also
areas that are strategic locations for the entire value
develop high levels of competence, especially if
chain in order to achieve economies of scale and
they are part of strong local industrial clusters or if
scope. Subsidiaries with few activities but high they enjoy favorable access to unique resources of
levels of competence, on the other hand, are highly various kinds. Special circumstances may make
specialized units that add value to the rest of the particular locations well suited for certain activities,
MNE through their knowledge and competence.
irrespective of the status of the host country in the
Such subsidiariesare often related to R&Dactivities. context of specific regional integration processes.
There will, without doubt, always be several
However, whenever operations are predominantly
different combinations between these two extremes oriented towards the local market, factors such as
creating a variety of roles, as illustrated by multi- weaker competition, smaller markets and more
activity units. In other words, there is a 'mid- peripheral positions in the corporate network of
ground' of subsidiary roles where probably the the parent MNE, work against subsidiaries develop-
majority of subsidiaries can be placed. Also, 'Stra- ing more advanced roles. Subsidiaries in 'outsider'
tegic centers' represent subsidiaries with a wide locations with the characteristics of, say, 'strategic
scope of activities as well as high competence centers' are hence more likely to be the 'special
levels. Such centers commonly result from a process case' rather than the 'general case'.
of rationalization and downgrading in locations Countries on the periphery suffer (prior to
outside the main areas of regional integration
integration) from smaller markets, and tend to
where the activities and core of competencies are have overcome the disadvantages of small market
united. size by instituting industrial policies that promote
import-substituting types of investment by MNEs.
Regional integration, MNE subsidiaries and Thus, such locations tend to host subsidiaries that
peripheral countries are miniature replicas. That is, the MNE is able to
Deep regional integration has a considerable effect offset the disadvantages associated with small
on the location advantages associated with periph- market size and inefficient scale economies, among
eral countries. By peripheral countries we mean other things, by opportunities associated with
countries that are smaller economies relative to the privileged access to restricted markets.
core of larger countries that 'drive' and dominate Upon membership of deep integration schemes,
the overall regional economic landscape. However, an insider peripheral country experiences a decline
this article makes a further distinction between of its location advantages associated with such
peripheral countries that are insiders (i.e., those privileges, since the state must re-orient its econo-
that are full members of the scheme) and those that my to the supra-regional norms established by the
are 'outsiders'. We expect that it is generally more core. This is assumed to be offset by an industrial

Journal of International Business Studies


_: l..d|n.re s an RIIF
'~448EIIVlIIIII IFn..: .-nm,
.nf ntal
IIIInluc II IIL ..h..l.l-:r,
)UU aUyJ ..v rnl.
Vles (.Pr
JrK Roni;n
DllLU It ot fUi
448

redistribution within the region based on compara- were concerned. It is worth noting, however, that
tive advantage, and potential access to a larger the levels of FDI in the three countries were
unified market. 'Outsider' countries, on the other remarkablysimilar by 1999 (Table 1). This suggests,
hand, experience a decline in their location on an aggregate level at least, that both Norway and
advantages, not because of industrial redistribu- Finland have been relatively more successful at
tion, but by virtue of being marginalized relative to attracting FDI flows in recent years. As a result,
neighboring 'insider' countries. there are no longer any major differences in
This article compares Denmark, Finland and location advantages, and there is no clear hierarchy
Norway as a basis for studying the effect of regional among these countries. As we have emphasized
integration on subsidiary roles in peripheral coun- earlier, however, aggregate data do not reveal the
tries. These three countries provide an ideal basis different kinds of subsidiaries, nor the nature of
for our purposes. All three are part of the 'Nordic their activities.
cluster' (Ronen and Shenkar, 1985). They have The one location advantage in which these three
similar location advantages in terms of market size, countries differ is the issue of regional integration,
income levels and labor costs (see Table 1), as well where there is considerable variation. Denmark is a
as demographics, politics and culture. In addition, 'veteran' of European integration, having joined
by virtue of their size, location and history they are the European Community after a referendum in
peripheral countries and have the limited location 1972, while Finland joined the EU in 1995. Norway
advantages associated with such countries. All three remains an 'outsider'; it is associated to the EU
countries have historically had similar economic through the European Economic Area (EEA, a
structures, dominated by small and medium sized shallow regional integration agreement between
enterprises and fostered by policies of import- some non-EU European countries and the EU),
substitution and welfare states, and have had a having rejected EU membership twice (in 1972 and
historical dependence on natural resources. 1994) but remains unlikely to consider full mem-
Although Sweden shares some of these features, bership. Their different statuses in the regional
apart from having a population twice the size of the integration process that accelerated in Europe from
other Nordic countries, Sweden has had a signifi- the 1980s onwards - Norway, the 'outsider', vs
cantly different economic history, engaging in Denmark and Finland, the 'insiders' - makes the
industrialization much earlier. Its economy has a case of FDI in these countries particularly well
disproportionately high share of large MNEs suited for such an investigation.2
(Oxelheim and Gartner, 1994). Denmark and Finland have had to harmonize
This is not to imply that there are no differences their policies and industrial structure as full
in location advantages between the three countries members of the EU. By staying out of the EU,
under study vis-a-vis MNEs. As shown in Table 1, Norway has to some extent maintained its import-
FDIactivity in 1970 (measured in terms of FDIstock substituting policies, supporting and encouraging
as a percentage of GDP)was much less significant in domestic industry through non-tariff barriers and
Norway and Finland than in Denmark, indicating subsidies in several industries. Incumbent MNE
that the location advantages of Denmark were subsidiaries are given national treatment, provided
superior to the other two countries as far as MNEs they maintain a certain scope and competence in

Table 1 Basicinformationabout Denmark,Finland,and Norway


Denmark Finland Norway

Population (million)a 5.3 5.1 4.5


GNP per capita (PPP) in USDa 23,800 21,000 25,100
FDIstock as percent of GDP, 1999b 24.2 24.5 25.1
FDIstock as percent of GDP, 1970b 5.9 0.6 1.6
Laborcost/h (nominal USD)c 23.0 21.1 22.7
EU membership Member since 1973 Member since 1995 Not a member
aCIAFact book (2001).
as [FDIt/GDPt]
bCalculated x 100. WorldInvestmentReport(2000), StatisticsDenmark,Bankof Denmark,StatisticsFinland,Bankof Finland,Bankof
Norway,StatisticsNorway,Statistisk
Arbok(1975 and 2000).
CEconomistIntelligenceUnitCountryReports(2001).

Journalof InternationalBusinessStudies
Environmental...... influences on
-.. MNE subsidiarv roles GRG
-11- Benito
--. 111- et al
11 -1
-*
. TX'
449

their Norwegian activities (Nygaardand Dahlstrom, countries may also show a similar tendency to
1992; Kvinge and Narula, 2001). Its membership of invest in other EU countries, in preference to
the EEA has obliged it to dismantle some of its 'outsider' countries (Mariotti and Piscitello, 2001),
subsidies. Nonetheless, barriersto trade and invest- but the relative closeness of EU locations may,
ment are still on average at least double of those in again, impede subsidiary autonomy.
most EU countries, and compared to countries such Third, we control for the nature of the subsidiary
as Germany, UK and Italy more than three times as itself. Subsidiaries that have been established
high (OECD,2000). By being the only non-member through new investment develop differently from
of the EU in Northern Europe, Norway has thus those that have been established through acquisi-
moved from being on the periphery to being 'on tions (Birkinshaw,1998; Holm and Pedersen, 2000).
the periphery of the periphery'. In addition, there may be variation in subsidiary
These arguments lead to the following proposi- evolution that reflects differences in the age of
tions: subsidiaries and/or their size and involvement in
P1: Foreign subsidiaries located in Denmark and export activities (Holm and Pedersen, 2000).
Finland - countries that are members of the EU- are
likely to perform a wider range of value-adding Method
activities than subsidiaries located in Norway, the
'outsider'country. Sampling and data collection
P2: Subsidiarieslocated in Denmark and Finland -
The data for this study were collected in autumn
countriesthat are membersof the EU - are likely to 1997 as part of a major international research
develophigherlevels of competencethan subsidiaries project looking into MNE subsidiary development
located in Norway,the 'outsider'country. (Holm and Pedersen, 2000). The general aim of the
study was to investigate the heterogeneity of
We recognize that other factors beyond member- subsidiary roles and the drivers associated with
ship of the EU may also influence subsidiary the evolution of differentiated roles. Sampling
development, and we need to control for these. procedures were designed to cover all substantial
First, there are factors related to the characteristics MNE activity in the three countries. In Denmark,
of the host country. Most significant among these is the Greens directory was used to select companies.
the issue of industrial characteristicssuch as clusters. In Finland and in Norway, companies were chosen
The presence of an agglomeration of industrial from the Dun & Bradstreetdatabase. Only foreign-
activities in a group of related industries can be an owned companies with ongoing operations of some
important location advantage that acts as a magnet significance were selected.3 The initial sample sizes
to firms operating in similar industrial sectors were 750, 1159 and 656, in Denmark, Norway and
(Benito, 2000; Birkinshaw and Hood, 2000). In Finland, respectively. The main research instru-
addition, the resource-basedsectors have tradition- ment in the study was a detailed mail questionnaire
ally been strong in the Nordic countries, attracting a developed by the team of researchers. Respondents
significant share of inward FDIinto these countries. were either subsidiary executive officers (70-80% of
Second, home country characteristics could influ- the cases) or other top-level managers such as vice
ence the competence and scope of subsidiary presidents, financial directors or marketing execu-
activities. Given the similarity of Nordic countries, tives. The survey, including two follow-up enquiries
the low psychic distance between them and the to non-respondents, resulted in a total of 809
historical relationship between these countries, replies distributed across the three countries as
MNEs from Nordic countries are probably more shown in Table 2. This gives an overall response rate
likely to invest in other Nordic countries. However,
precisely because the countries are geographically Table 2 Sample characteristics
and culturally close, units are fairly easy to monitor Number of cases
and control, and the knowledge, competence and
other resources required can easily be transferred (a) Total number of cases 809
from companies' HQs whenever needed. There may Denmark 310
therefore be fewer incentives to assist or promote Finland 238
the development of units in other Nordic countries. Norway 261

Closeness may hence actually act as a barrier to (b) Cases with missing data 81
(c) Final sample 728
subsidiary development. MNEs from other EU

journalof InternationalBusinessStudies
.r 'r-II450~ Fnv.;irnm
Vil
nVIIIIIIrIILII -nta-l ;n.fl-..,nte
IInIIISCs Ann MNF
IIuIIIyc.hkri;;iaurv rrlAfic
Vlr (rD.~
IJ R1rn;it
UCelllttJ Pt nl
ct Ul
450

of 31.5%. However, due to missing data on some countries of the MNEs, and the subsidiaries them-
variables the final sample actually used in our selves. Our controls are as follows:
analysis consists of 728 cases. CLUSTER=1if a subsidiary operates in an indus-
try with cluster characteristics, and 0 otherwise. See
Appendix for a classification of industries.
Measurement and descriptive statistics RESOURCE1 if a subsidiary operates in a
This study examines whether being a EU member resource-based industry, and 0 otherwise. The
has had any impact on the operations of MNEs in following industries were classified as resource-
the Nordic countries. The focus is on heterogeneity based: agriculture, forestry, and fishing (ISIC 11-
of subsidiaries' activities and roles. Based on 13, 3114, 3122), coal, petroleum and gas, metal ore
mining and other mining industries (ISIC21-29),
previous literature on the topic, we deal specifically
with two dimensions of subsidiary development: (i) manufacture of lumber (ISIC3311), manufacture of
the scope of activities undertaken by a given pulp and paper (ISIC 3410-3419), manufacture of
subsidiary (SCOPE)and (ii) the competence of a
basic metals (ISIC 37), electricity, gas, steam and
water supply (ISIC41, 42).
subsidiary in performing a specific task or activity
NORDIC-PARENT 1 if the parent MNE is based
(LEVEL).The two dependent variables were oper-
ationalized as follows: in another Nordic country (Denmark, Finland,
Iceland, Norway and Sweden), and 0 otherwise.
SCOPE = E ai
Similarly,EU-PARENT=1if the parent MNEis based
where ai=any given activity i (research, develop- in a EU member country, and 0 otherwise.
ment, production of goods or services, marketing/ ACQUISITION-1 if the mode of entry of the
sales, logistics/distribution, purchasing, human current parent was through a takeover, and 0 if the
resource management) undertaken by a given subsidiarywas established as a greenfield operation.
foreign-owned unit. Since it takes a value of 1 if YEARScounts the number of years elapsed since the
an activity is performed, and 0 otherwise, the subsidiarywas established or acquired by its current
variable simply sums up the number of activities. parent. SIZEis measured as the number of people
Hence, values for SCOPE range from 1 a
(i.e., single- working in the subsidiary in 1996. Even though
activity unit) to 7 (i.e., the whole range of tasks are alternative measures of size exist, such as sales or
carried out). production volumes, we chose to use number of
LEVEL= ai employees because it gives a far more stable basis
ci/ for comparisons across countries and industries.
where ci is a measure of the level of competence of Finally, we control for the extent to which
the foreign-owned subsidiary in performing a given subsidiaries operated beyond the local market in
activity i, as perceived by the respondent on a 7- 1996 by the variable EXPORTthat measures the
point scale (l=weak competence, 7=very strong export ratio of a unit (i.e., the percentage of exports
competence). Since the level of competence indi- as a share of total sales) in that year.
cator ci is counted only for activities ai actually The required information on home-country and
undertaken by a given unit, it provides a measure of subsidiary-level variables was taken from the sur-
the average overall level of competence of that vey. More descriptive statistics are given in Table 3.
subsidiary. The correlation matrix (Table 4) indicates that
The focal independent variable of this study is the multicollinearity should not be a problem in the
EU membership status of the host country. It is data set. Furthertests of potentially harmful multi-
measured by a dummy variable (EU-MEMBER), collinearity - the variance inflation factors (VIF),
taking the value of 0 for subsidiaries in Norway and the Belsley-Kuh-Welsch diagnostic (Belsley
and 1 for subsidiaries in Denmark and Finland. We et al., 1980) - also failed to detect any indications
hypothesize a positive effect of EU membership on of multicollinearity.
subsidiary development, and we therefore expect a
positive sign for this variable. Results
As noted earlier in the article, subsidiary devel- As an initial test of the propositions we conducted
opment may depend on several factors other than an ANOVA to check whether there were any
regional integration processes, and in this study we differences between the national sub-samples with
control for additional factors covering a variety of regard to the mean values of the two dependent
characteristics of the host countries, the home variables of the study. Based on our previous

Journal of International Business Studies


Environmental influences on MNE subsidiary I roles GRGBenito et al
451

Table 3 Descriptive statistics (n=728)


Variables Description Mean (s.d.) Distribution

Dependent variables SCOPE Number of activities 4.8 (1.6)


LEVEL Competence level 5.4 (1.0)
Host country EU-MEMBER Host country is EU member 1:67.7%, 0:32.3%
CLUSTER Cluster industry 1:19.2%, 0:80.8%
RESOURCE Resource-based industry 1:5.4%, 0:94.6%
Home country EU-PARENT Parent based in EUcountry 1:68.6%, 0:31.4%
NORDIC-PARENT Parent is Nordic 1:39.6%, 0:60.4%
Subsidiary ACQUISITION Entryby acquisition 1:60.1%, 0:39.9%
YEARS Yearssince entry 15.2 (17.0)
SIZE Number of employees 217.0 (692.4)
EXPORT Exportratio 22.3 (32.5)

Table 4 Correlationsbetween independent variables(Spearman'sRho)


Variables 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8

1. EU-MEMBER
2. CLUSTER 0.101
3. RESOURCE -0.058 0.138
4. EU-PARENT -0.057 -0.029 0.022
5. NORDIC-PARENT -0.096 -0.111 0.052 0.351
6. ACQUISITION 0.154 0.037 0.017 0.008 -0.055
7. YEARS -0.032 -0.046 -0.034 0.029 0.029 -0.455
8. SIZE 0.286 0.125 -0.029 -0.055 -0.105 0.270 0.000
9. EXPORT 0.278 0.130 0.151 -0.029 0.087 0.329 -0.110 0.349

discussion, for both SCOPE and LEVELwe expected Table 5 Analysisof variancefor SCOPEand LEVEL
to find distinct differences between subsidiaries in Countries Mean scores of variables
Norway on the one hand and subsidiaries in
Denmark and Finland on the other. Formally, our SCOPE LEVEL
empirical hypotheses are 5.0484c 5.5361
I D F
(a) Denmark
N
<
H 1: cSCOPOPE SCOPESCOPE (b) Finland 4.9328c 5.4873c
(c) Norway 4.4904a,b 5.2519a,b
N I D F
H2: < L
LEVEL<LEVELEVELLEVEL Average values 4.8344 5.3719
F-statistic 8.979 (P<0.01) 5.638 (P<0.01)
where superscripts N, D and F denote Norway,
Denmark and Finland respectively. Note: Superscriptsa, b, and c, indicate whether differences in the mean
scores for subsidiariesin a given country deviate significantly(at the 0.05
The results of the analysis, which are shown in level) from the other countries.
Table 5, turned out to be in agreement with
expectations. For both SCOPE and LEVEL, the
mean values for the Norwegian sample are signifi- Even though the ANOVA results lend support to our
cantly lower than for the Danish and Finnish propositions, they must be regarded as preliminary.
samples. The difference is particularly pronounced We cannot firmly conclude that such differences
for the SCOPE variable. It is worth noting that no are associated with countries' EU membership
significant differences in mean values were found status, since the analyses are bivariate and we did
between the Danish and Finnish samples, which not control for other possible reasons for why
supports the hypothesis that differences can be systematic differences may exist between subsidi-
attributed to the EU-membership status of the aries located in different countries. In order to
countries rather than being due to some other investigate the possible influence of other factors,
national effect. a series of regression analyses was conducted

journal of International Business Studies


I
-.. MNEsubsidiary roles
Environmental influences on - ---- GRGBenito et al
452 p

introducing the selected control variables. The control variables in addition to the EU-MEMBER
regression models have the following general form: dummy, attains an adjusted R2value of 0.20, which
is quite satisfactory given the complexity of the
Yi = Xi+ pi EU-MEMBER+ iy Z + ei, phenomenon studied and the heterogeneity of the
where Z is the vector of control variables, a, /f and y sample.4In contrast, the 'full' regression model 4,
are regression coefficients, and e denotes the error for the LEVELvariable, only explains 3% of the
term. In accordance with P1 and P2 we expect that variation in that dependent variable. Turning to the
Pi> 0. The results from a total of four ordinary least control variables, it is noteworthy that the results
square regression analyses for the complete sample for subsidiary level variables (ACQUISITION, YEARS,
are presented in Table 6. The first two columns SIZEand EXPORT)are generally stronger than those
present results of the models using SCOPEas the for industry characteristics (CLUSTER,RESOURCE)
dependent variable, while the last two columns or the home region of the MNEs (EU-PARENT,
provide the regression results for the LEVEL vari- NORDIC-PARENT), and particularly so for the
able. Specifically, columns 1 and 3 present the regressions with SCOPE as the dependent variable.
results for a 'reduced' model with the EU-MEMBER The most consistent result is found for the YEARS
dummy as the only predictor, while columns 2 variable - the age of the subsidiary - which is
and 4 present the regression results for the 'full' positive (at significance level P<0.01) in both
model. regressions of the 'full' model. This indicates that
As can be seen from Table 6, the coefficients for subsidiary development takes time, which is not
EU-MEMBER- our dummy indicating whether or surprising given the complexity of such processes,
not a subsidiary was located in a EU member especially with regardto competence development.
country - are consistently positive and significant Regressions models 2 and 4 include a dummy
in all regressions. Hence, even when other factors variable, EU-PARENT,capturing whether or not
are controlled for, there remains a strong associa- the parent MNEs are EU-based. The coefficient for
tion between the EU membership status of a Nordic this dummy was insignificant in both regressions,
country and the development of foreign-owned which indicates that the origin of the parent
subsidiaries in those countries. We conclude that company does not per se explain role differentiation
support is found for both of our propositions. in Nordic subsidiaries in terms of the number of
It turns out that the regressions perform far better activities performed by the subsidiaries or their
when modelling the SCOPEdimension of subsidi- level of competence. However, the effects of various
ary heterogeneity. Model 2, which includes all our factors in explaining role differentiation could well

Table 6 Regressionresults,complete sample, OLS-estimation(n=728)


Variables Dependent variable
SCOPE(numberof activities) LEVEL
(competence level)
Standardizedcoefficients(t-values)

Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model4

1. EU-MEMBER 0.145 (4.157)*** 0.065 (1.913)** 0.117 (3.314)*** 0.140 (3.679)***


2. CLUSTER 0.016 (0.475) -0.046 (-1.216)
3. RESOURCE -0.030 (-0.890) -0.013 (-335)
4. EU-PARENT 0.033 (0.927) -0.033 (-0.829)
5. NORDIC-PARENT 0.106 (2.957)*** -0.018 (-0.454)
6. ACQUISITION 0.225 (5.937)*** 0.046 (1.086)
7. YEARS 0.102 (2.806)*** 0.105 (2.597)***
8. SIZE 0.100 (2.953)*** 0.015 (0.414)
9. EXPORT 0.318 (8.812)*** -0.078 (-1.960)**

Model statistics F=1 7.284*** F=21.507*** F=10.982*** F=3.184***


Adjusted R2=0.02 Adjusted R2=0.20 Adjusted R2-0.01 Adjusted R2=0.03
Notes: *P<0.10, **P<0.05, ***P<0.01.

Journal of International Business Studies


Environmental influences on MNEsubsidiary roles GRGBenitoet al
453

Table 7 Regressionresults,split samples, OLS-estimation


Variables Dependent variable
SCOPE(numberof activities) LEVEL
(competence level)
Standardizedcoefficients(t-values)

Model 5: EUparents Model 6: non-EUparents Model 7: EUparents Model 8: non-EUparents

1. EU-MEMBER 0.127 (2.950)*** -0.038 (-0.629) 0.133 (2.825)** 0.140 (2.019)**


2. CLUSTER 0.016 (0.377) 0.039 (0.653) -0.049 (-1.061) -0.044 (-0.638)
3. RESOURCE -0.014 (-0.341) -0.075 (-1.230) -0.004 (-0.092) -0.030 (-0.432)
4. EU-PARENT
5. NORDIC-PARENT 0.128 (3.041)*** 0.056 (0.937) -0.023 (-0.501) 0.006 (0.093)
6. ACQUISITION 0.209 (4.539)*** 0.255 (3.732)*** 0.037 (0.736) 0.062 (0.783)
7. YEARS 0.076 (1.725)* 0.147 (2.239)** 0.118 (2.435)** 0.076 (1.005)
8. SIZE 0.095 (2.284)** 0.115 (1.956)** 0.023 (0.496) 0.010 (0.142)
9. EXPORT 0.266 (5.872)*** 0.407 (6.580)*** -0.053 (1.085) -0.131 (-1.830)*

Model statistics n=498 n=230 n=498 n=230


F=14.123*** F=10.870*** F=2.409** F=1.172
Adjusted R2=0.17 Adjusted R2=0.26 Adjusted R2=0.02 Adjusted R2=0.01
Notes: *P,0.10, **P<0.05, ***P<0.01.

differ depending on parent companies' region-of- in which we control for a range of additional factors
origin. In order to investigate further possible - support both propositions. The results show that
differences between EU and non-EU-based MNEs, membership of a deep integration scheme such as
additional regressions were run with the sample the EU, because it requires economic convergence,
split into two subsets (see Table 7, models 5-8). The the establishment of common institutions and
split sample results largely emulate the results for synchronized policy frameworks,plays a significant
the full sample.5 effect in determining differences in both scope and
competence levels. We have controlled for a variety
Discussion of other factors, including national differences, by
In this article, we have attempted to identify the selecting countries that are otherwise similar.
effect of environmental factors on subsidiary roles. Furthermore, we have controlled for industry
Although we have illustrated our arguments by effects, such as the presence of clusters, and other
focusing on European integration, this represents a important variables such as nationality of the
proxy for differences in economic structure and parent companies. The results suggest that more
industrial policies, which are prime environmental developed roles can be expected for subsidiaries
factors determining the scope and competence of located within the EU area than for subsidiaries
an operation. The growing literature on subsidiary located outside it. It is worth noting that the model
roles has mainly focused on issues internal to the evaluating competence levels has significantly
MNE, without connecting this to the external lower explanatory power than the equivalent
environment other than through firm, network or model evaluating scope. This suggests that the
industry-specific factors. Even though issues of factors influencing competence levels are not
external embeddedness have emerged from such adequately captured in the model.6 It may also
studies, these are still directly linked to immediate reflect the considerable heterogeneity of firms'
business relationships and do not consider national strategies, and the fact that the organization of
differences or changes in macro level policies their EU-based activities may reflect just part of
(Holm and Pedersen, 2000). their overall global strategies. However, it is evident
Using data on subsidiaries in the Nordic coun- that regional integration is only one of several
tries, we have tested the possible effects of environ- issues relating to the external environment and
mental factors on both the scope and the influencing subsidiary roles and competence. Long-
competence levels of subsidiaries. Our analyses - itudinal data on the subsidiary networks of MNEs

Journal of International Business Studies


*454LIIVlIIIIICIILaI Fn..lr.nm ,nt-lInfl:l.n.-c
IIIIlUCIIccc nn
Vo MNF
V111 c,.hctlla.rv
1U~IMIGII rn.Ic
S C.PC.
UU Rpnitnr
CIL ot n
CTLU
454

would be very helpful in order to explore these tion costs, among other things), MNE activities that
issues further. prior to EU membership were conducted locally
Given the considerable reliance of new and may eventually be relocated to larger, more central
prospective (and largely peripheral) EU members countries in the long run, as these peripheral
on FDI as a source of capital and technology, our markets are too remote and local market size too
results have considerable policy implications. It is small to justify such subsidiaries.
well acknowledged that the net benefits from FDI
vary in line with the kinds of activities undertaken Acknowledgements
in a given location, and that different subsidiaries Previousversionswere presented at the NordicWork-
may have widely different roles, ranging from shop in InternationalBusiness,Idoborg, Sweden, May
relatively simple distribution tasks to responsibility 2001; the Academy of InternationalBusinessAnnual
for a range of activities, including research, devel- Conference, Sydney, Australia,November 2001; and
opment and manufacturing. the EuropeanInternationalBusinessAcademy Annual
Participation in regional integration agreements Conference, Paris,France,December 2001. We thank
is a mixed blessing, insofar as improving the extent participants at these meetings, Tore Abrahamsen,
and intensity of MNE subsidiary activity is con- Trond Vahl, and the three anonymous reviewersfor
cerned. On the one hand, it implies a possible their comments. Researchfunding was provided by
advantage, in that participants in regional integra- the ResearchCouncilof Norway (project 139982/510
tion are better able to attract and retain foreign- 'Globalizationand Internationalizationof the Norwe-
owned subsidiaries than are non-participants. gian Economy').
Hence, MNE activity and subsidiary development
is more likely to take place within member Notes
countries. The increased market competitiveness 'Research on firm-level issues has concentrated
and value-added activity associated with such primarilywithin two streams, focusing on particular
activity, in turn, may have wider effects within locations or kinds of activities. The first body of
the host country. On the other hand, however, literatureis associated with the effects of integration
increased competition due to regional integration on the location of R&Dactivities(e.g., Mariani,1999;
may have adverse effects for MNE subsidiaries, since Pearce, 1999; Gerybadze and Reger, 1999). The
not all firms will survive the effects of increased second is associatedwith economic geography, focus-
competition (Benito, 1997). ing on the interactionbetween MNEsand locationbut
Furthermore,our study has focused on peripheral with an emphasis on macro-organizationaland policy
countries, both within and outside the EU. This issues. See Dicken(1998) for an overview.
study confirms that there are substantial benefits to 2lncluding another small and peripheral 'EU out-
be gained from being in the 'core' rather than the sider'country alongside Norwaywould have provided
periphery, whether in the absolute sense of being an even stronger research design; Switzerlandis an
peripheral to the EU as a unit (e.g., Norway), or the obvious, albeit not ideal, case. Unfortunately,we do
relative sense of being economically marginal in not have comparable data on foreign subsidiariesin
comparison to the core players (e.g., Denmark and Switzerland or in other small European states that
Finland compared to Germany and UK). In other remainoutside the EU.
words, while countries such as Denmark and Fin- 3Thecut-offcriteriaused in the variouscountrieswere
land derive certain benefits relative to current EU- very similar.In Denmark,only companies with at least
outsiders such as Norway, Switzerland and the 20 employees were chosen. InNorway,only companies
accession countries, both sets of countries are at a with sales of 10 millionNOKor more were selected. In
disadvantage relative to the core members of the Finland,the cut-offpointswere eithera yearlyturnover
EU. One limitation of the current study is that we of 5 millionFIMor at least 20 employees.
only have data for a single period. It may well be 41n order to check the robustness of results, an
that - except in sectors where there are important ordinal regressionwas also conducted with SCOPEas
and dynamic industrial clusters - small, geographi- dependent variable(SCOPEhas a range of 1-7, and
cally peripheral countries that are within the EU can be considered as a polytomous ordinal response
may also experience a decline in MNE subsidiary variable). The results for both the reduced and the
activity both in terms of scope and competence full models are very similarto those obtained for the
levels over time. In seeking EU-wide rationalization OLS regressions. The reduced model attained a
(through economies of scale and lower transporta- pseudo-R2(Nagelkerke)of 0.02 with the coefficientof

Journal of International Business Studies


Fnuv;rnnnant:l
LrIIVIIVllllllll
rIIIIn
'anflssonrac
u IIC s nn
IonII1-
RMNF cshcilsA:ur
ICll
rnalv
IVr I s
.P(.
KI Ponitr-, Pt
U1lllLu el
nl
uI
l/ ,IUU1 J
455

EU-MEMBER significant at P<0.01. The full model the scope of their activities whether they are located
produced pseudo-R2 (Nagelkerke) of 0.25 with the
a in Denmark, Finland or Norway. The indifference
same set of coefficients being significant as those for of non-EU-based MNEs in their choice of location may
the OLS regression in model 2 (i.e., EU-MEMBER, be due to the fact that they have fewer units elsewhere
NORDIC-PARENT,ACQUISITION, YEARS, SIZE, and in Europe on which individual subsidiaries can rely for
EXPORT).We thank an anonymous reviewer for assistance and supplies. Any given subsidiary hence has
suggesting this robustness check. to operate relatively autonomously.
5The only noteworthy exception is the SCOPE- 61n particular, subsidiary-level spending on training
regression for the sub-sample consisting of MNEs and education, which can be expected to explain much
from outside the EU (model 6), where the coefficient of the variance in competence levels, has not been
for EU-MEMBER is not significant. Hence, in contrast included in our specification. It should be emphasized
to EU-based MNEs (whose subsidiaries in Norway that the main objective of this article has not been to
are likely to conduct fewer activities than their develop a comprehensive model to explain subsidiary
counterparts in Denmark and Finland), for subsidiaries scope and competence levels, but to explain differences
of non-EU-based MNEs, it does not matter for in subsidiary roles as a result of regional integration.

References
Agarwal, J.P. (1997) 'European integration and German FDI: subsidiarycompanies', Academyof Management Review23(4):
implications for domestic investment and central European 773-795.
economies', National InstituteEconomicReview160: 100-111. Birkinshaw,J. and Hood, N. (2000) 'Characteristicsof foreign
Almor, T. and Hirsch, S. (1995) 'Outsiders' response to Europe subsidiaries in industry clusters', Journal of International
1992: theoretical considerations and empirical evidence', BusinessStudies31(1): 141-154.
Journalof InternationalBusinessStudies26(2): 223-237. Chesnais, F. and Sailleau, A. (2000) 'Foreign Direct Investment
Andersson, U. and Forsgren,M. (2000) 'In search of excellence: and European Trade', in F. Chesnais, G. letto-Gillies and R.
network embeddedness and subsidiary roles in multinational Simonetti (eds.) European Integration and Global Corporate
corporations',ManagementInternationalReview40(4): 329-350. Strategies,Routledge: London.
Andersson, U., Forsgren, M. and Holm, U. (2001) 'Subsidiary Chiesa, V. (1995) 'Globalizing R&D around centres of excel-
embeddedness and competence development in MNCs - a lence', LongRange Planning28(6): 19-28.
multi level analysis', OrganizationStudies22(6): 101 3-1034. Culem, C.G. (1988) 'The locational determinants of direct
Balasubramanyam,V.N. and Greenaway, D. (1992) 'Economic investments among industrialized countries', European Eco-
integrationand foreign direct investment: Japaneseinvestment nomic Review32: 885-904.
in the EC',Journalof CommonMarketStudies30(2): 1 75-193. Davidson, W.H. (1980) 'The location of foreign direct invest-
Baldwin, R.E. (1997) 'The causes of regionalism', The World ment activity: country characteristicsand experience effects',
Economy20(7): 865-888. Journalof InternationalBusinessStudies 11(2): 9-22.
Baldwin, R.E. and Venables, A.J. (1995) 'Regional Economic Delany, E. (2000) 'Strategic development of the multinational
Integration',in G.M. Grossmanand K. Rogoff (eds.) Handbook subsidiary through subsidiary initiative-taking', Long Range
of InternationalEconomics,Elsevier:Amsterdam. Planning33: 220-244.
Bartlett,C.A. and Ghoshal, S. (1986) 'Tap your subsidiariesfor Dicken, P. (1998) Global Shift:Transformingthe WorldEconomy,
global reach', HarvardBusinessReview64(6): 87-94. 3rd edn Paul Chapman: London.
Bartlett,C.A.and Ghoshal, S. (1989) ManagingAcrossBorders:The Dunning, J.H. (1988) ExplainingInternationalProduction,Unwin
TransnationalSolution,HarvardBusinessSchool Press:Boston. Hyman: London.
Belsley, D.A., Kuh, E. and Welsch, R.E. (1980) Regression Dunning, J.H. (1997a) 'The European internal market pro-
Diagnostics: IdentifyingInfluentialData and Sources of Colli- gramme and inbound foreign direct investment, part I',
nearity,John Wiley: New York. Journalof CommonMarketStudies 35(1): 1-30.
Benito, G.R.G. (1997) 'Divestment of foreign production Dunning, J.H. (1997b) 'The European internal market pro-
operations', AppliedEconomics29(10): 1 365-1 377. gramme and inbound foreign direct investment, part II',
Benito, G.R.G. (2000) 'IndustrialClusters and Foreign Compa- Journalof CommonMarketStudies35(2): 189-223.
nies' Centres of Excellence in Norway', in U. Holm and T. Eden, L. (2001) 'Regional Integration and Foreign Direct
Pedersen (eds.) The Emergenceand Impact of MNC Centresof Investment: Theory and Lessons from NAFTA',in M. Kotabe,
Excellence,Macmillan:Basingstoke. P. Aulakh and A. Phatak (eds.) The Challenge of International
Benito, G.R.G. and Gripsrud, G. (1992) 'The expansion of BusinessResearch,EdwardElgar:London, UK.
foreign direct investments: discrete rationallocation choices or Eliassen,K.A.and Monsen, C.B. (2001) 'Comparisonof European
a cultural learning process?', Journalof InternationalBusiness and Southeast Asian Integration', in M. Tel6 (ed.) European
Studies23(3): 461-476. Union and New Regionalism: Regional Actors and Global
Birkinshaw,J. (1996) 'How multinational subsidiary mandates Governancein a Post-HegemonicEra,Ashgate: Aldershot.
are gained and lost', Journalof InternationalBusinessStudies Forsgren, M. and Pedersen, T. (1998) 'Centres of Excellence in
27(3): 467-495. Multinational Companies: The Case of Denmark', in J.
Birkinshaw,J. (1998) 'Foreign Owned Subsidiariesand Regional Birkinshaw and N. Hood (eds.) Multinational Corporate
Development: the Case of Sweden', in J. Birkinshaw and Evolutionand SubsidiaryDevelopment,Macmillan:Basingstoke.
N. Hood (eds.) MultinationalCorporateEvolutionand Subsidiary Fratocchi, L. and Holm, U. (1998) 'Centres of Excellence in the
Development,Macmillan:Basingstoke. International Firm', in J. Birkinshaw and N. Hood (eds.)
Birkinshaw,J. and Hood, N. (1998) 'Multinational subsidiary MultinationalCorporateEvolutionand SubsidiaryDevelopment,
evolution: capability and charter change in foreign-owned Macmillan:Basingstoke.

Journalof InternationalBusinessStudies
* Environmental influences on MNE subsidiary roles GRG Benito et al
456

Furu,P. (2001) 'Driversof competence development in different Roth, K. and Morrison, A.j. (1992) 'Implementing global
types of multinational R&Dsubsidiaries',ScandinavianJournal strategy: characteristicsof global subsidiarymandates', Journal
of Management 17(1): 133-149. of InternationalBusinessStudies23(4): 715-735.
Gerybadze, A. and Reger, G. (1999) 'Globalization of R&D: Surlemont, B. (1998) 'A Typology of Centres within Multi-
recent changes in the management of innovation in national Corporations: an Empirical Investigation', in J.
transnational corporations', Research Policy 28(2-3): Birkinshaw and N. Hood (eds.) Multinational Corporate
151-152. Evolutionand SubsidiaryDevelopment,Macmillan:Basingstoke.
Holm, U. and Pedersen, T. (eds.) (2000) The Emergenceand Vernon, R.(1996) 'Passingthrough regionalism:the transitionto
Impact of MNC Centresof Excellence,Macmillan:Basingstoke. global markets', The WorldEconomy19(6): 621-633.
Jackson, S. and Markowski, S. (1996) 'The attractiveness of Veugelers,R.(1991) 'Locationaldeterminantsand rankingsof host
countries to foreign direct investors', Australian Journal of countries:an empiricalassessment', KYKLOS 44(3): 363-382.
Management 21(2): 113-138. Yannopoulos, G.N. (1990) 'Foreign direct investment and
Kvinge,T. and Narula, R.(2001) 'FDIin Norway's manufacturing European integration: the evidence from the formative years
sector', Working Paper 9/2001, Center for Technology, of the European community', Journal of Common Market
Innovation and Culture, Universityof Oslo. Studies28(3): 235-259.
Lipsey, R.E. and Kravis, I.B. (1982) 'The location of overseas
production and production for export by US multin-
ational firms', Journal of International Economics 12(3/4):
201-223.
Appendix
Lorenzoni, G. and Baden-Fuller,C. (1995) 'Creating a strategic Classification of cluster industries in the Nordic
center to manage a web of partners', CaliforniaManagement
Review 37(3): 146-163. countries, see Table Al.
Madhok, A. (1997) 'Cost, value and foreign market entry mode:
the transaction and the firm', Strategic Management Journal Table A1
18(1): 39-61.
Mariani, M. (1999) 'Next to production or technological Cluster ISICcodes
clusters?', The Economics of Management of R&D Location. Country
MERITResearch Memorandum, 99-129.
Denmark ITand 3830-39,7202
Mariotti, S. and Piscitello, L. (2001) 'Localized capabilities and
the internationalizationof manufacturing activities by SMEs', telecommunication
Entrepreneurship & RegionalDevelopment13: 65-80. Healthcare 3522,9330
Motta, M. and Norman, G. (1996) 'Does economic integration Energy/environment 4100-99
cause foreign direct investment?', International Economic Functionalfoods 3100-99
Review37(4): 757-783.
Mudambi, R. (1995) 'The MNE investment location decision: Furnitureand design 3321-22
some empirical evidence', Managerialand Decision Economics Professionalservices 7202
16: 249-257. Construction 3513,3522,5012
Narula, R. (2002) 'Innovation systems and 'inertia' in R&D
location: Norwegian firms and the role of systemic lock-in',
ResearchPolicy31: 795-816. Finland ITand 3832,8323
Narula, R. (2003) 'MultinationalFirms,Regional Integrationand telecommunication
Globalising Markets: Implications for Developing Countries', Healthcare 3522
in R. Devlin and A. Estevadeordal (eds.) Trade and Regional Energy/environment 4100-99
Integrationin the DevelopmentAgenda, Inter-AmericanDevel- Food industry 3121
opment Bank:Washington, DC.
Neven, D. and Siotis, G. (1993) 'Foreigndirect investment in the Forestry,wood 1200-99,3300-99,3400-99
European community: some policy issues', Oxford Reviewof and paper
EconomicPolicy9(2): 72-93. Ship building 3841
Nygaard, A. and Dahlstrom, R. (1992) 'Multinationalcompany Engineering services 8324
strategy and host country policy', Scandinavian Journal of Metals 3811-19
Management 8(1): 3-13.
OECD(2000) EconomicSurveyof Norway, OECD:Paris.
Oxelheim, L.and Gartner,R. (1994) 'Small country manufactur- Norway ITand 3832,7123,7202,8323
ing industries in transition - the case of the Nordic region', telecommunication
Management InternationalReview34(4): 331-356. Healthcare 3850-59
Pain, N. and Lansbury,M. (1997) 'Regional economic integra-
tion and foreign direct investment: the case of German Oil and gas, energy 2200-99,3821,4100-99,
investment in Europe', National Institute Economic Review 4200-99,5023,7115
160: 87-99. Fishery 1300-99,3114,3122
Pearce, R.D. (1999) 'Decentralised R&Dand strategic competi- Furnitureand 3311,3321
tiveness: globalised approaches to generation and use of
wood products
technology in MNEs', ResearchPolicy28: 157-178.
Poynter, T.A. and Rugman, A.M. (1982) 'World product Shipping 3841,7120
mandates: how will multinationals respond?', BusinessQuar- Stones and metals 2900-99
terly47(3): 54-61. Light metals 3720-29
Ronen, S. and Shenkar, 0. (1985) 'Clustering countries on
attitudinal dimensions: a review and synthesis', Academy of Source: Konkurransekraft
i Norden, Nordisk Ministerrad,Copenhagen:
Management Review10(3): 435-454. TemaNord 2000: 537.

Acceptedby Tom Brewer,outgoingEditor, 14 January2003.

Journal of International Business Studies

You might also like