You are on page 1of 10

Environmental Protection versus Economic Development: A False Trade-Off?

Author(s): Richard C. Feiock and Christopher Stream


Source: Public Administration Review, Vol. 61, No. 3 (May - Jun., 2001), pp. 313-321
Published by: Blackwell Publishing on behalf of the American Society for Public
Administration
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/977602
Accessed: 19/04/2010 23:57

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at
http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless
you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you
may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use.

Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at
http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=black.

Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed
page of such transmission.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of
content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms
of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Blackwell Publishing and American Society for Public Administration are collaborating with JSTOR to
digitize, preserve and extend access to Public Administration Review.

http://www.jstor.org
RichardC. Feiock
FloridaStateUniversity
Stream
Christopher
of Idaho
University

Protection
Environmental Versus Economic
Development:A False Trade-Off?

Is a trade-offbetweenthe social benefitsof regulationand the economicbenefitsof development


inevitable?We argue thatenvironmental regulationmay detereconomicgrowthin some contexts,
however,in othercontextsthebenefitsof regulationmaybe obtainedwithlittleor no economicloss.
Wedevelopan explanationof theeconomicimpactsof stateenvironmental policybasedon a model
of publicinfluenceon privateresourceallocationdecisions.Inthismodel,we assumeutility-maximiz-
ing firmswillmakeinvestment choicesbased upontheprojectedprofitson theirinvestments and their
willingnessto acceptthe riskassociatedwiththe investments. We assertthatstatepoliciesand ad-
ministrative influence
institutions perceptions of riskby increasingor decreasinguncertaintyover
futureenvironmental policyand influencereturnon investments at particularlocationsby affecting
firm-levelproduction costs.Our confirm
results thatcertainadministrative
arrangements forenviron-
mentalregulationmay enhance,ratherthanimpede,economicdevelopment.

Overcomingtrade-offsbetween the social benefits of state environmentalprotectionand personalincome (Hall


regulationand the economic benefits of developmenthas 1994). Nevertheless,those studies do not provide system-
never been easy in practice.Tensionsbetween regulatory atic explanationsfor how environmentalpolicy enhances
and economic developmentpolicy goals at the state and economic growth,nor do they subjecttheirhypotheses to
local level haveattractedattentionto the competitionamong rigorousempiricaltests (cf. Hall 1994; Meyer 1992). This
state and local governmentsto attractbusiness and devel- articlebegins to fill this lacunaby describingthe economic
opmentalresources.While few would disputethat both a impactsof state environmentalpolicy based on a longitu-
growingeconomy and a safe andhealthyenvironmentare dinalmodel of public influenceon privateresourcealloca-
desirable,elected leaders and environmentaladministra- tion decisions. In this model, we assumethatutility-maxi-
tors are often confrontedwith choices between protecting mizing firmswill makeinvestmentchoices based uponthe
their citizens and their environmentthrough regulatory projectedprofits on their investments and their willing-
actions on the one hand,and promotingeconomic growth ness to acceptthe risk associatedwith the investments.We
and development on the other. Certain scholars (Porter
RichardC. Feiockis a professorand Ph.D.programdirectorin theAskew
1990;Templet1995) andpoliticalleaders,includingPresi- Schoolof PublicAdministration and Policyat FloridaStateUniversity. His
dentClinton,havesuggestedthisis a falsetrade-off(Clinton teachingand researchinterestsincludeurbanpoliticsand administration as
well as environmental,education,and economic-development policy. His
and Gore 1992, 99). publishedworkhas appearedin the PublicAdministration Review,Ameri-
Is a trade-offbetween the social benefits of regulation can Journalof PoliticalScience,Journalof Politics,UrbanAffairsReview,
and the economic benefitsof developmentinevitable?We and otherjournals.Email:rfeiock@garnet.acns.fsu.edu.
arguethatenvironmentalregulationmay deternew invest- Christopher Streamis an assistantprofessorin the Department of Political
Scienceand PublicAffairsResearchat theUniversity of Idaho.Histeaching
ment in some contextsby increasingproductioncosts, but and researchinterestsincludestate politicsand policy,local government
that the benefits of regulationmay be obtainedwith little healthpolicy,and intergovernmental
administration, relations.Hispublished
workhas appearedin the Journalof PublicAdministration Researchand
or no economic loss in other contexts. Recent studies re- Theory, Political Research Quarterly, and other journals. Email:
portpositive cross-sectionalcorrelationsbetweenlevels of cstream@uidaho.edu.

Versus
Protection
Environmental Economic
Development: 313
A FalseTrade-Off?
assert that state policy influences perceptionsof risk by ers, taxes or subsidiesto consumers,reallocationsof prop-
increasingor decreasinguncertaintyover futureenviron- erty rights, the use of vouchersor tradablepermits,or in-
mentalpolicy and influencesreturnon investmentsat par- formation provision.
ticularlocations by affecting firm-level productioncosts. To identifythe economic developmentconsequencesof
Our preliminarytest of this model confirms that certain policy design, we startwith a simple model of how state
environmentalpolicy designs may enhance, ratherthan governments'environmentalprotectionprogramsmay in-
impede, economic development. fluence privateresourceallocationdecisions.We posit that
utility-maximizingfirms will make investmentand loca-
tion choices based on anticipatedprofit earned on those
EconomicDevelopmentand investments. State environmentalregulation has conse-
Environmental
Policy quences for two factors that shape the anticipatedreturn
The assumptionthat environmentalregulationreduces from investmentsin new development. First, state envi-
economicgrowthhas been increasinglychallenged(Feiock ronmentalregulationaffects the costs of producinggoods
1998;RingquistandFeiock 1998). Severalstate-levelstud- in a state at a particularpoint in time. Second, state envi-
ies report positive correlationsamong state rankings on ronmentalregulationinfluences the risk of these invest-
economic and environmentalindicatorsand conclude that mentsby affectingregulatoryuncertainty.Previousresearch
the statesthatdo the most to protecttheirenvironmentalso has focused almostexclusively on the implicationsof state
have the strongest economies (Hall 1994; Meyer 1992). environmentalpolicy for productioncosts and neglected
While informative,the studies that have challenged the its implicationfor the risk or uncertaintyof privateinvest-
trade-off between environmentalprotection and income ments.
growth suffer from a numberof conceptualand method- Interstatecompetitionfor economic developmentpro-
ological limitationsand have not advancedan alternative vides a context in which marginalchanges in the cost or
theoreticalmodel to explain how environmentalpolicies risk of developmentinvestmentsthatresult from state en-
influence growth. Most of the work in this traditionhas vironmentalpolicy may influence privateproductionde-
relied on cross-sectionalratherthan longitudinaldata. It cisions. Competitionprovides the option of adjustingthe
also has not attemptedto isolate the variousdimensionsor location,not merelythe level, of investmentin responseto
policy designs of environmentalprograms,and has not environmentalactions(Dye 1990). Business locationstud-
addressedhow the institutionalstructuresand administra- ies reveal that after a firm has decided to locate in a par-
tive design of environmental programs may influence ticularregionbased on non-governmentalfactors,govern-
growth(Hall 1994; Meyer 1992;Templet1995). Forthese ment policy is an importantconsiderationin the choice
reasons, extant research does not provide a convincing amongstateswithina region(Kale 1984;Wasylenko1980).
challenge to the base of empiricalevidence in economics This means that states may use environmentalregulations
andpoliticalscience thatidentifiestrade-offsbetweeneco- andincentivesto influencefirms'risksandproductioncosts
nomic and environmentalvalues in state policy decisions and gain an advantageover competitorstates (Feiock and
(Bacot and Dawes 1997; Davis 1992; Davis and Lester Rowland 1991).
1989; Feiock and Rowland 1991). None of these litera-
tureshas systematicallyexaminedthe effect of stateenvi-
ronmentalprotectionpolicy on economicdevelopmentover StateEnvironmental
Policyand
time or addressedthe consequencesof policy instruments Production
Cost
and administrativedesign. Research that investigates patternsof state economic
growth and the link between state policies and economic
performancehas flourishedin recentyears.This literature
ConceptualFramework has focused upon the impactsof investmentinducements,
Policy design has capturedincreased attentionin the tax levels, spendingpatterns,and federal transferson pri-
policy analysis literature(MacRae 1980; Salamon 1989; vate productioncosts and economic growth (Brace 1993;
WeimerandVining 1999). Salamon(1989) suggestedthe Jones 1990; Steines 1984; Warner1987). Despite the im-
need to shift the focus of policy researchaway from pro- portanceof environmentalregulatorycosts to overallcosts
gramsor organizations,andto insteadfocus on the instru- of production,surprisinglylittle attentionhas been paid to
ments or tools by which public policy goals are accom- the effects of these regulatoryrequirementson state eco-
plished. For example, a policy goal such as pollution nomic performance.Those studiesthatisolatethe marginal
reductionmight be pursuedthrougha numberof different effect of state incentives and development programson
policy mechanisms. In additionto traditionalregulation, business conclude that environmentalregulationreduces
governmentsmight employ taxes or subsidies on produc- state economic growth (Goetz, Ready, and Stone 1996).

314 Public Review* May/June


Administration 2001,Vol.61, No.3
Regulationscan restrictland use and often impose sub- duce the uncertaintyand risks associated with collabora-
stantialcosts for pollutioncontroland abatement.Several tion. Environmentalregulationsmodify existing property
empiricalstudies documentprivatefirm compliance with rights;therefore,if they change rapidlyor unpredictably,
state environmentalregulationthat resulted in increased they createan uncertainenvironmentfor investorsand in-
productioncosts, and eventually reduced output, higher creasecapitalcosts. On the otherhand,even stringentregu-
prices, and reduced income growth (Christiansen and latory requirements,if they are clear, stable and certain,
Haveman1981; Siegel and Johnson 1993). may diminishfirms'investmentrisk (Clingermayer1989).
State-levelpolicy has come to play a largerrole in shap- The likely consequences include increased profitability
ing stateeconomiesoverthepasttwo decades(Brace1993). because returnson investmentsare more predictableand
Embeddedwithin the general question of whether state the creation of a more level playing field since all firms
policy affects the interstatemobility and location of eco- mustcomply.This suggests thatstateswith stringentregu-
nomic developmentinvestmentis the more specific ques- lationbutstableandcertainpatternsandprocessesof regu-
tion of whether regulations affect the intrajurisdictional lationmay have some hope of enjoyinga growingeconomy
allocation of these developmentalinvestments.Evidence as well as the social and environmentalbenefits resulting
frombothsurveysof executives'plant-sitingdecisions and from regulation.
econometric studies of economic performance provide This frameworksuggests thatthe organization,institu-
supportfor the position thatstatepolicies, includingregu- tional structure,and administrativedesign of regulation
lation, can have significant marginalimpacts on market programscan have importantpositive or negative conse-
resourcesand patternsof economic growthwithin a state quences for economic growth. Certainforms of state and
(Feiock 1998). local regulationmay facilitate exchange or reduce uncer-
tainty in the regulatoryenvironment.These include the
centralizationof regulatoryfunctions,the coordinationand
StateEnvironmental
Policyand streamliningof regulatoryactions, enhancedstate admin-
Uncertainty istrativecapacity,andstrategicplanningandpollutionpre-
Much less attentionhas been paid to the anticipated vention initiatives.
consequencesof state policy for risks associatedwith de-
velopmentinvestmentacrossstates.Regulatoryuncertainty
createsdisincentivesfor investmentandproduction.Prop- State EnvironmentalPolicyTools
erty rightstheoryprovidesa powerfulframeworkto iden- Unlike previous efforts to examine the effects of state
tify how environmentalprogramsaffect the certaintyof environmentalpolicy on economic performance,the theo-
propertyrights and the consequences of uncertaintyfor reticalframeworkadvancedhere does not treatstate envi-
development investment and economic growth (North ronmentalpolicy as unidimensional.Some environmental
1981). Fromthis perspective,the institutionalstructureand policy designs may deter economic growthby increasing
administrativedesign of environmentalregulationandpol- productioncosts while other environmentalpolicy tools
lutioncontrolprogramsmay haveimportantconsequences may enhance the performanceof state economies by re-
for growth.We expect that state economic growthwill be ducing market uncertaintyand providing a more stable
enhancedas transactioncosts are lessened by administra- investmentenvironment.We identify four dimensions of
tive arrangementsthat reduce uncertaintyover rights in state environmentalprogramsfor empirical investigation
property.Foster (1992) contends that effective state eco- that may influence the risk and returnof private invest-
nomic developmentfocuses on the structure,ratherthan ment: state spendingfor environmentalprotection,impo-
the stringencyof regulation:"The emergingparadigmis sition of regulatorycosts on privatepollution producers,
less concernedwith the conventionaldebateover whether tax incentives to the private sector for pollution control
thereis 'too much'or 'too little' regulation,andmore con- activities, and provisionsfor administrativeand decision-
cerned with establishing a frameworkthat will promote makinginstitutionsthatreduce uncertainty.
adaptationof the privatesector to more productiveforms
of organizationand activity"(5).
If regulationsare complex, unclear,or subject to fre- State EnvironmentalSpending
quentandunpredictable changesorrevision,it createsregu- State governments'role in environmentalmanagement
latory uncertainty.EdwardWeber's (1998) recent work has grown dramaticallyas the state role has evolved from
describedhow environmentalprogramscan be more ef- implementerof federal policy to initiatorof environmen-
fective at achieving economic and environmentalgoals tal policy (Ringquist1993). In fact, over two-thirdsof en-
when governmentprovides a set of rules to manage con- vironmentallegislation passed by state legislaturesin the
flict between businessandenvironmentalinterestsand re- early 1990s was unrelatedto federalenvironmentallegis-

Versus
Protection
Environmental Economic
Development: 315
A FalseTrade-Off?
lation(Brown1994,539). DeWittJohn(1994) has observed lution abatementprovide incentives to reduce pollution
that "virtuallyall states have taken some steps to go be- withoutreducingoutputbecausethey decreasefirms'pro-
yond federallyimposedrequirements,andsome havetaken ductioncosts. In the long run,this createsan incentivefor
the lead in severalareas.... States seem to be more willing new firms to enterthe industry(Brierly 1989).
thanthe federalgovernmentto increasespendingon envi- States also provide a wide arrayof subsidies or incen-
ronmentalprotection"(80). tives to firms for pollution control. Typicallythese are in
State budgets provide supportto a wide arrayof pro- the form of tax relief for investmentin pollution control
grams. Most state expendituresare directedto regulatory technologies (Ringquistand Feiock 1998). A majorityof
enforcement,but some resourcesare directedto activities states provide exemptionsfrom property,sales, or corpo-
that can benefit business by facilitating voluntarypollu- ratetaxesforpollutioncontrolinvestment.Some stateseven
tion reduction and subsidizing pollution prevention and provide tax exemptions for operatingcosts. In addition,
cleanup.In these situations,ratherthanimposing costs on accelerateddepreciationof pollutioncontrolequipmentis
business, state environmentalexpendituressocialize what widely used (Bartik 1980). Advocates of incentive ap-
would otherwise be privatecosts to comply with regula- proaches contend that state and local governments can
tory directives (Feiock and Rowland 1991). In doing so, improvethe efficiency of industrialoperationsand make
state spending not only reduces firms' costs, it may also firms more competitiveby creatingtax incentivesfor new
reducetheirenvironmentalrisksby reducingliability,com- investments(Steines 1984).Alternatively,these incentives
pliance, and disposal responsibility. may encouragefirmsto directtheirnew capitalinvestments
awayfromproductionresourcesandtowardpollutioncon-
trol because non-pollutioncontrol investmentsthatmight
PrivateRegulatoryCosts expandoutputarenot eligible for these incentives(Rhodes
Because state expendituresmay substitutepublic for 1988).
privatepollution abatement,we need to isolate the actual
regulatorycost incurredby firms. Environmentalregula-
tion often imposes substantialcosts on privateactors.State Administrative and Decision-Making
environmentalregulationcompels industrialfirms to ab- Institutions
sorb some or all of the costs of installing pollution abate- The institutionaldesign of stateenvironmentalagencies
mentequipment,disposingof hazardouswaste, andclean- andthe programsthey administerhave directimplications
ing up after industrial accidents. Some commentators for regulatoryuncertaintybecausethey affectprivatetrans-
argue that state environmentalcontrols have gone well action costs, the stabilityof state regulation,and the abil-
beyondfederalmandatesandhave delayedor abortednew ity of states to make credible regulatorycommitmentsto
plant construction(Site Selection Handbook 1981, 378). private actors. Organizationalstructurehas consistently
As an illustration of the magnitude of regulatory costs been linked to state environmentalpolicy choices. Lester
for business: In 1994, U.S. manufacturersreportedover (1989) arguesthatunified,ratherthanfragmented,organi-
$20.6 billion in operatingcosts and $7.8 billion in capi- zational structuresreduce coordinationcosts and ease the
tal expenditures for pollution abatement. In that year, transmissionof information.Lester et al. (1983) have ob-
pollution abatementcapital accounted for over 7 percent served "Consolidationdirectly promotes environmental
of firms' total investment in domestic plants and equip- policy formulationby concentratingboth fiscal resources
ment. In addition to large capital investments,pollution and bureaucraticexpertise into a single agency."A sub-
abatement and control may entail substantial increases stantialnumberof stateshave consolidatedtheirpollution
in operating costs to firms. Increased production costs controlfunctionsin an environmentalsuperagency.These
that result from compliance with environmentalregula- agencies' responsibilitiesextend beyond pollutioncontrol
tion have been reportedto reduce output,increaseprices, to integratepollution programswith resource conserva-
and reduce income growth (Christiansenand Haveman tion or developmentfunctions (Council of State Govern-
1981; Siegel and Johnson 1993). ments 1975). Centralizationmay reduce uncertaintybe-
cause a common set of actors and rules operate across
various programsand organizations.In addition, a super
TaxIncentivesfor PollutionControl agencymay reduceoverlapandprovidegreaterconsistency
Pollutionpreventionand abatementis capitalintensive of signals emanatingfrom regulators.Nevertheless,unity
and may requirefirms to invest in new equipment,on-site andcentralizationmay not alwaysreducetransactioncosts
facilities, or productchanges. As a result, financing be- because not all superagenciesact alike.
comes a deterrentto technologically advancedpollution Similarly,the capacity of state governmentis essential
control measures.Tax breaks,subsidies, or loans for pol- to its ability to make credible commitmentsto business.

316 Public
Administration
Review* May/June
2001,Vol.61, No.3
Attentionto state environmentalregulationhas increased of the four dimensions of environmentalpolicy defined
since the federal governmentinitiated the use of partial above as well as past investmentpatterns.State expendi-
preemptionpolicy designs over two decades ago (Davis turesfor environmentalprotectionaremeasuredby annual
1992). Under partial preemption,once federal agencies state pollution control expendituresper capita.' Regula-
promulgateminimum performancestandards,states are tory stringency is measured as annual private pollution
given the opportunityto assume program management abatement capital and operating cost per production
authority.Once a state programis authorized,the federal worker.2To measurepollutioncontrol incentives,the date
role is limitedto oversightunless the statefalls shortof the of adoptionsfor 10 specific incentives was identifiedand
minimal standards.Achievementof programresponsibil- an additiveindex of the numberof incentivesofferedeach
ity, or primacy,enhancesthe stabilityand certaintyof the year was calculated.3The index reportsthe numberof in-
regulatoryenvironmentand the ability of states to make centive programsin place for each year.Fourmeasuresof
credible regulatorycommitments. Gaining primacy is a state programsand institutionalarrangementsthat reduce
function of states' institutionalcapacity to absorbdecen- uncertaintywere also included. First is an indicator of
tralizedprograms(Davis and Lester 1988) whether environmentalprogramsare located in a super
Coordinationof regulatoryprogramsacross media and agency that consolidates environmentaland natural re-
with other state and local activities is anothermeans to source programs.4Every year after such an agency was
reduceuncertainty.Severalstateshave soughtto integrate createdis coded one, while non-adoptionstates/yearsare
pollutionpreventionwith regulatoryprogramsin a strate- coded zero. Efforts to coordinate diverse environmental
gic planningprocessby requiringpollutionpreventionplans programsacross media and with state and local programs
from selected regulatedindustries.Planningrequirements were measuredby the presenceof strategicenvironmental
in severalstates institutemandatoryfacility planningpro- plansanda systemof one-stopfacilitypermitting.The date
gramsthat requirewaste generatorsto complete compre- of adoptionof a strategicplan for environmentalprotec-
hensiveplans thatidentifyopportunitiesfor eliminatingor tion and consolidationof multi-mediafacility permitting
reducingpollutantsand incorporatepollution prevention was recorded.5Each year afterthe agency adopteda stra-
into ongoing plantprocesses (Sullivanand Floyd 1991). tegic plan is coded as one, while non-planagencies/years
In addition, some states have centralizedand stream- are coded zero. While existence of a plan does not neces-
lined their environmentalpermittingprocesses. Such an sarily show practicing strategicmanagement,this is the
approachmay ease the regulatoryburdento industryby best availablemeasureof strategicplanning.While strate-
shorteningthe developmentapprovalprocess and reduc- gic plans can be subjectto change and revision, we found
ing uncertainty.At the sametime,centralizingenvironmen- stateenvironmentalmanagementplansto provideas stable
tal permittingmight assist states in dealing with cross- policy frameworkin this time frame.6
media pollution(Rabe 1995). Finally, we measurestate-level regulatorycapacity by
the date when the state was grantedprimaryauthorityto
manage its environmentalprogramsunder the Resource
Analysis ConservationandRecoveryAct of 1976.This was recorded
This study addressesseveralof the limitationsof previ- and coded one for a primacy and zero otherwise.7The
ous researchby examining change in new capital invest- model also providesstatisticalcontrolsfor the level of new
ments in the 50 states over a 12-yearperiod from 1983- capital investmentin the preceding year and unit effects
1994.Thefederalgovernmentthroughthe 1970sdominated for time and for states.We estimate the pooled model us-
environmentalpolicy (Ringquist1993;Yandle 1989). The ing ordinaryleast squares with panel corrected standard
dramaticdevolutionof policy responsibilityto the states errors(OLS/PCSE).8
did not occur until after the election of PresidentRonald The results of this analysis, shown in table 1, provide
Reaganin 1980 (Ringquist1993;Vig andKraft1984). The supportfor the idea thatstateenvironmentalpolicy design
time frame understudy is thus ideally suited to studying can have both positive and negative implicationsfor eco-
the effects of state environmentalpolicy activities on pri- nomic development.Not surprisingly,previousinvestment
vate investment.Pooled cross-sectionaltime-seriesregres- levels were the best predictorsof future investment.The
sion techniques are used to estimate this model. Invest- inclusionof investmenttrendsin the model is necessaryto
ment is measured by new capital investments in controlfor variationin productioncosts and to isolate the
manufacturingotherthanfor pollutioncontrol.We lag all effects of policy design. Table 1 indicatesthat, even after
of ourexplanatoryvariablesone yearto evaluatethe influ- controllingforpastinvestmentpatterns,stateenvironmental
ences of statepolicies and past economic performanceon expenditureshad a positive effect on new capital invest-
new investment. ments. This is not unexpected,because state expenditures
We includeindependentvariablesto operationalizeeach typically include actions to subsidize privatecosts of pol-

VersusEconomic
Protection
Environmental A FalseTrade-Off?317
Development:
Table1 PooledCross-Sectional Time-SeriesAnalysis it didnot achievestatisticalsignificance.Overall,thesefind-
State New CapitalInvestment1983-94 ings suggest thatprogramdesign andplanningthatreduce
Variable B Std.error t uncertaintyhave the potentialto offset the negativeinvest-
Previousinvestment .7657** .0406 18.87
ment effects of regulatorycosts.
Expenditures .00003** .00001 2.38
Incentives .0119 .0329 .36
Regulatorycosts -.0022* .0013 -1.65 Conclusion
Super agency .0040 .1601 .25 The relationshipsbetweenthese specific environmental
Primacy .3780** .1661 2.28 policy designs and new investmenthighlightthe dilemma
Strategic plan .4658** .2211 2.11 facing state policy makers as they try simultaneouslyto
One-stop permitting .2586 .1793 1.44
foster economic growthandpursueenvironmentalprotec-
R2:.89
AdjustedR2:.88 tion goals that might interferewith this growth.States re-
PooledDurbin-Watson d: 1.39 tain substantialdiscretionto allocate the costs of environ-
Durbin-Watson h:.38
N = 600 mental pollution control between the public and private
**p<.05
sectorsandto directincentivesfor specific types of invest-
lution preventionor cleanup. Because our model explic- ments. Programsthatraise productioncosts or providein-
itly controls for pollution abatementcosts, the expendi- centives to divert capital from productiveresources may
tureeffects reportedherereflectthe non-regulatoryactions reduce investmentsof new capital.
of states. While state spending has increased, it has not The resultspresentedhere suggest that states may free
increasedevenly among environmentalactivities. It will themselvesfromthis dilemmaby reducinguncertaintyover
be importantfor futureresearchto isolate the specific ac- rights in propertythroughefforts to coordinateenviron-
tivities supportedby state environmentalbudgets. mental decision-makingcapacity and providing credible
Ouranalysisalso foundevidencethatimposingthe costs regulatorycommitmentsto industry.The positive relation-
of pollution control on the privatesector reduces growth, ship betweencertainadministrativearrangementsfor state
althoughthis relationshipwas only statisticallysignificant environmental programs and economic growth suggests
at a .10 level. Even in the absenceof largenegativeeffects, trade-offs between business and environmental interests
specific industriesmightbe substantiallyaffectedby these may not be inevitable. Certainly this relationship is more
pollution control costs. The effects of tax incentives for complex than the trade-off debate suggests. Some elements
pollutioncontrolon new capitalinvestmentwere not found of state environmental policy may provide disincentives
to be significant.While these incentivesmay be effective for new investment while other elements and institutions
at inducing expenditureson pollution control equipment may encourage investment.
andfacilities, at least some of the capitaldevotedto pollu- Administrativeinstitutionsandpolicy design have been
tion reductionmay be divertedfrom investmenton other neglected in the study of state environmentalpolicy. Our
resourcesfor production.Previousworkhas suggestedthat findings suggest the need to examine the consequencesof
incentivesarepositively linkedto industrialexpansion,but programdesign for bothenvironmentalandeconomic out-
has failed to separatethe effects of incentiveson pollution comes and highlightthe importanceof the choice of insti-
control investmentand non-pollutioncontrol investment. tutionalarrangements,policy designs, andpolicy tools for
These offsetting effects may account for the relationship the abilityof environmentalprogramsto mediatethe nega-
uncoveredhere. tive economic costs of regulation.Thus, institutionalre-
Finally,ouranalysisprovidessubstantialsupportfor the form provides the promise of overcoming trade-offs be-
propositionthat private sector investmentand economic tween economic and environmental policy goals and
developmentcan be enhanced by environmentalregula- deserves much more attentionfrom scholars of environ-
tion thatreducesuncertainty.We find that states'environ- mentalpolicy and public administration.
mental capacity,as indicatedby achievementof primacy
status for regulation,resulted in significant increases in
levels of new capitalinvestment.In addition,the adoption
Acknowledgments
of a strategicplan for environmentalpolicy had a strong An earlier version of this manuscriptwas presented at the
positive effect on new investment.Takentogether,capac- 1999 annual meeting of the American Society for Public Ad-
ity and strategicplanning suggest that states can produce ministration.The authors thank Evan Ringquist, Paul Brace,
settings that make it easier to work with the subjects of LauraLanger,and EdwardWeberfor comments on earlierver-
regulationand to forestall some of theirfears. The coeffi- sions of thismanuscript.Wealso wantto thankCassandraShelley,
cient for streamlinedregulatoryprocessesthatutilizedone- who was especially helpful in the collection of data.
stop permittingwas in the predictedpositive directionbut

318 Public
Administration
Review* May/June
2001,Vol.61, No.3
Notes
1. Expendituredata through 1981 is reportedin the U.S. De- 6. Therewas some concernon ourpartthatstateenvironmental
partmentof Commerce'sreportEnvironmentalQualityCon- agencieswouldchangetheirstrategicplansquiteoften, which
trol, which was discontinuedin 1981. The remainingyears could contributeto uncertaintyratherthan certainty.There-
of environmentalspendingdatawerecollectedfromtheCoun- fore, we contactedeach of the states thathad adoptedstrate-
cil of StateGovernments'ResourceGuidefor State Environ- gic plans over the period of study.We found that state envi-
mental Management.This data was compiled and reported ronmental strategic plans are much more stable than we
only in 1986, 1988, and 1991, thus expendituresfor several initially believed. State environmental agencies that had
yearsaremissing. We estimatedexpendituresfor these years adopteda strategicplanningprocess had originallyintended
using linearinterpolation. for these documentsto include annualreportingof program-
2. The impositionof pollutionabatementcosts on privatefirms matic success and to be revised "as needed."This was origi-
was taken from variousyears of PollutionAbatementCosts nally conceived to be annuallyor bi-annuallydependingon
and Expenditures,published annually by the U.S. Depart- the state budget cycle. However,this has not been the case.
ment of Commerce. The states that have strategicplans do try to revise them as
3. Pollution control incentives were taken from various issues needed, but these revisions have been done infrequently.For
of IndustrialDevelopmentand Site SelectionHandbook,pub- example, the strategicplan for the WashingtonState Depart-
lished by Conway Publication.The incentives for pollution ment of Ecology is supposedto be revised every two years
control include: real and personalpropertytax exemptions, (as part of the biennial budget preparationprocess). How-
sales/use tax exemptions of purchasesor lease of pollution ever, in actuality,the strategicgoals of the plan may or may
controlfacilities, creditagainstcorporateincome tax, accel- not change with each new gubernatorialadministration.The
erateddepreciationof pollutioncontrolequipment,exclusion department also notes thatthe strategicmission of the agency
of pollutioncontrolinvestmentfrom corporatefranchisetax, has not changed since 1988. The IndianaDepartmentof En-
exemption of cost of operatingpollution control facilities, vironmental Management (IDEM)is also typicalof the states
and state financingof pollutioncontrolfacilities. with strategic plans. The IDEM adoptedits strategicplan in
1994. In 1998, the plan was revised after the election of a
4. The point in time when a state consolidatedits environmen-
new governor.This revision falls outside of the periodof our
tal programsinto a single "super"agency was gatheredfrom
study.This is also true for many of the states. Manyrevisions
Council of State Governmentspublications,includingInte- from 1983 to
did not occur until after the studyperiod. Thus,
gration and Coordinationof State EnvironmentalPrograms
1994, state environmentalstrategicplans were quite stable
(1975) and variousyears of the Resource Guide to Environ-
and were revised very little.
mentalManagement,and the Book of the States.
7. The originalsource for when states gained primaryadminis-
5. Adoptiondatesfor environmentalstrategicplanswas derived
trativeresponsibilityfor ResourceConservationand Recov-
from Berry's (1994) survey of state agencies from 1970 to
ery Act programswas derivedfrom the U.S. Code of Federal
1991 for the Councilof StateGovernments.The surveyindi-
Regulations and the U.S. EPA Office of Air and Radiation
catedthe year stateenvironmentalagencies adopteda strate-
(Lester 1989).
gic plan.
8. We conducted a series of regression diagnostics on the re-
siduals obtainedfrom an OLS estimation.Little evidence of
auto-correlatederrorswas revealedby the DurbinWatsonh
for the estimationwith a lagged dependentvariable.

Economic
Versus
Protection
Environmental Development: 319
A FalseTrade-Off?
References
Averch,Harvey.1990. PrivateMarketsand Public Intervention. .1989. Resource Guide to EnvironmentManagement.
Pittsburgh:Universityof PittsburghPress. Lexington,KY: Council of State Governments.
Bacot, A. Hunter,and Roy A. Dawes. 1997. State Expenditures . 1992. Resource Guide to EnvironmentManagement.
and Policy Outcomesin EnvironmentalManagement.Policy Lexington,KY: Council of State Governments.
StudiesJournal 25(2): 355-70. Davis, Charles.1992. StateEnvironmentalRegulationandEco-
Bartik,TimothyJ. 1988. The Effects of EnvironmentalRegula- nomic Development:Are They Compatible?Policy Studies
tion on Business Location in the United States. Growthand Review 11(2): 149-57.
Change 19(1): 22-44. Davis, Charles,andJamesLester. 1988. Dimensions of Hazard-
Beck, Nathaniel,and JonathanN. Katz. 1995. What to do (and ous WastePolitics and Policy. New York:GreenwoodPress.
not to do) with Time-Series Cross-Section Data. American . 1989. Federalismand EnvironmentalPolicy. In Envi-
Political Science Review 89(3): 634-47. ronmentalPolitics and Policy: Theoriesand Evidence,edited
Berry,Francis. 1994. Innovationsin Public Management:The by JamesLester, 1-22. Durham,NC: Duke UniversityPress.
Adoption of StrategicPlanning. Public AdministrationRe- Dean, ThomasD., and RobertL. Brown. 1995. PollutionRegu-
view 54(4): 322-30. lation as a Barrierto New Firm Entry.Academyof Manage-
Bowman,Ann O'M., and MarkE. Tompkins.1992. The Green- mentJournal 38(2): 288-303.
ing of StatePolicies: EconomicDevelopmentandor is it "or" Deurksen,ChristopherJ. 1983. EnvironmentalRegulationand
EnvironmentalProtection.Paperpresentedatthe annualmeet- IndustrialPlant Siting.Washington,DC: ConservationFoun-
ing of the AmericanPolitical Science Association, Septem- dation.
ber 3-6, Chicago, Illinois. Dye, ThomasR. 1980. TaxingSpendingand Economic Growth
Brace, Paul. 1993. State Governmentand Economic Perfor- in the AmericanStates.Journal of Politics 42(4): 1085-107.
mance. Baltimore,MD: Johns HopkinsUniversityPress. . 1990. AmericanFederalism:CompetitionAmongGov-
Brierly,Allen B. 1989. Assessing EnvironmentalPolicy Strate- ernments.Lexington,KY: LexingtonBooks.
gies: The Effects of PollutionControlSubsidies and Regula- Dye, Thomas R., and RichardC. Feiock. 1995. State Income
tory Standardson Economic Growthin the AmericanStates. Tax Adoption and Economic Growth.Social Science Quar-
Paperpresentedat the annualmeeting of the SouthernPoliti- terly 76(4): 648-54.
cal Science Association, November9-13, Atlanta,Georgia. Farr,CherylA. 1984. Shapingthe Local Economy:CurrentPer-
Brown,R. Steven. 1992. EnvironmentalDevelopment:Merging spectives on Economic Development.Washington,DC: In-
EnvironmentalProtectionand Economic Development Pri- ternationalCity ManagementAssociation.
orities.TheBookof theStates1992-93. Lexington,KY:Coun- Feiock, Richard.1994. The Political Economy of GrowthMan-
cil of State Governments. agement.AmericanPolitics Quarterly22(2): 208-20.
. 1994. Emerging Models for EnvironmentalManage- .1998. GovernmentRegulationandEconomic Develop-
ment.TheBook of the States 1994-95. Lexington,KY:Coun- ment. In Handbook of Economic Development, edited by
cil of State Governments. KuotasiTom Liou, 229-39. New York:Marcel Dekker.
Centerfor Policy Alternatives.1975. National Supportfor Sci- Feiock, Richard,andC.K. Rowland.1991. EnvironmentalRegu-
ence and Technology:An Examinationof the ForeignExperi- lation and Economic Development. WesternPolitical Quar-
ence. Cambridge,MA: MIT. terly 44(2): 561-76.
ChristiansenG.B., and R.H. Haveman. 1981. The Contribution Foster, R. Scott. 1992. State Economic Policy: The Emerging
of EnvironmentalRegulationsto the Slowdown in Produc- Paradigm.EconomicDevelopmentQuarterly6(1): 3.
tivity Growth.Journal of EnvironmentalManagement8(3): Goetz, Stephan,RichardC. Ready, and Brad Stone. 1996. U.S.
381-90. EconomicGrowthvs. EnvironmentalConditions.Growthand
Clingermayer,James. 1989. RegulatoryUncertainty,Investment Change 27(2): 97-1 10.
Climates, and State Economic Growth. Paper presented at Gunther,William D. 1991. Plant Location and Environmental
the annualmeetingof the SoutheasternConferenceon Public Regulation. In Energy,Environmentand Public Policy, ed-
Administration,October3-5, Jackson,Missouri. ited by David L. McKee, 60-84. New York:Praeger.
Clinton,Bill, andAl Gore. 1992. Putting the People First: How Hall, Bob. 1994. Gold and Green. Durham, NC: Institutefor
WeCan All ChangeAmerica.New York:Times Books. SouthernStudies.
Coase, Ronald. 1960. The Problem of Social Cost. Journal of Hamrin, Robert. 1981. EnvironmentalQuality and Economic
Law and Economics 3(l):1-44. Growth.Washington,DC: Council of State PlanningAgen-
Council of State Governments.1975. Integrationand Coordi- cies.
nation of State EnvironmentalPrograms. Lexington, KY: John, DeWitt. 1994. Civic Environmentalism.WashingtonDC:
Council of State Governments. CongressionalQuarterlyPress.
.1987. Resource Guide to EnvironmentManagement. Judge, George G., R. CarterHill, William E. Griffiths,Helmut
Lexington,KY:Council of State Governments. Lutkepohl,and Tsoung-ChaoLee. 1988. Introductionto the
Theoryand Practiceof Econometrics.2nded. New York:John
Wiley and Sons.

320 Public
Administration
Review* May/June
2001,Vol.61, No.3
Kale, Steven R. 1984. U.S. IndustrialDevelopment Incentives Ringquist, Evan, and Richard C. Feiock. 1998. Economy vs.
and ManufacturingGrowthDuring the 1970's. Growthand Environment:Evaluatingthe Effects of State Environmental
Change 15(1): 26-34. Regulationon Economic GrowthandAir Quality.Paperpre-
Kneese,Allen, and CharlesSchultz, 1975. Pollution,Prices and sented at the annual meeting of the Association of Public
Public Policy. Washington,DC: BrookingsInstitution. Policy Analysis and Management,November3-5, Washing-
Lester,JamesP. 1989. Implementationof the ResourceConser- ton, DC.
vation and RecoveryAct. Book of the States 1988-89. Lex- Salamon, Lester M. 1989. Beyond Privatization:The Tools of
ington, KY:Council of State Governments. GovernmentAction. Washington,DC: The UrbanInstitute.
Lester,James P., James Franke,Ann O'M Bowman, and Ken- Siegel, P.B., and T. G. Johnson. 1993. Measuringthe Economic
neth Kramer.1983. HazardousWastes, Politics, and Public Impactsof ReducingEnvironmentallyDamagingProduction
Policy:A ComparativeStateAnalysis.WesternPoliticalQuar- Activities. TheReview of Regional Studies 23(2): 237-53.
terly 36(2): 257-85. Site Selection Handbook. 1981. Atlanta,GA: Conway Publica-
Liou, KuotasiTom. 1999.Handbookof EconomicDevelopment. tions.
New York:MarcelDekker. Stein, Jay M. 1993. GrowthManagement:The Planning Chal-
MacRae,Duncan. 1980. Policy Analysis Methodsand Govern- lenge of the 1990s. NewburyPark,CA: Sage Publications.
mental Functions. In ImprovingPolicy Analysis, edited by Steines, Donald D. 1984. Business Climate,TaxIncentives,and
StuartS. Nagel, 16. Beverly Hills, CA: Sage Publications. RegionalEconomicDevelopment.Growthand Change 15(1):
Mays, RichardH. 1993. EnvironmentalLaws: Impacton Busi- 38-47.
ness Transactions.Washington,DC: Bureauof NationalAf- Stimson,James. 1985. RegressionModels in Space andTime:A
fairs. StatisticalEssay.AmericanJournalof PoliticalScience 29(4):
Meiners,RogerE., and BruceYandle.1993. Takingthe Environ- 914-47.
mentSeriously.Boston: Romanand Littlefield. Sullivan,Robin M., and DonaldW. Floyd. 1991. Pollution Pre-
Meyer,StephenM. 1992.Environmentalism andEconomicPros- ventionPlanning:An Analysis of StatutoryStructurefor Suc-
perity:Testingthe EnvironmentalImpactHypothesis.Unpub- cessful Policy Implementation.The EnvironmentalProfes-
lished manuscript,Cambridge,MA. sional 13(3): 293-304.
McKee, DavidL. 1991. Energy,Environmentand Public Policy. Taggert,WilliamA. 1982. TheInnovationand Diffusion of En-
New York:Praeger. vironmentalPolicies in the American States. Unpublished
NationalAdvisory Council for EnvironmentalPolicy and Tech- dissertation,FloridaState University.
nology. 1992. BuildingState and Local PollutionPrevention Templet,PaulH. 1995. The PositiveRelationshipBetween Jobs,
Programs.WashingtonDC: U.S. EPA. Environment,and the Economy:An EmpiricalAnalysis and
Nelson, Robert.H. 1993. How Much is Enough?An Overview Review. Spectrum1(Spring):37-49.
of the Benefits and Costs of EnvironmentalProtection. In U. S. Departmentof Commerce,Bureauof the Census.Various
TakingtheEnvironment Seriously,editedby RogerE. Meiners years.Environmental Quality Control:State and Local Gov-
and BruceYandle, 122-34. Boston: Roman and Littlefield. ernmentSpecial Studies,WashingtonDC: GovernmentPrint-
North, Douglas C. 1981. Structureand Change in Economic ing Office.
History.New York:Norton. Warner,Paul. 1987. Business Climate, Taxes and Economic
Olson, Mancur. 1982. The Rise and Decline of Nations. New Development.EconomicDevelopmentQuarterly1(3): 383-
Haven, CT:Yale UniversityPress. 90.
Pashigan,B.P. 1984. The Effects of EnvironmentalRegulation Wasylenko,Michael. 1980. Evidence of Fiscal Differentialsand
on OptimalPlantSize andFactorShares.Journalof Law and IntrametropolitanFirm Relocation. Land Economics 56(3):
Economics57(1): 1-17. 339-49.
Porter,Michael. 1990. The CompetitiveAdvantageof Nations. Wasylenko, Michael, and Theresa McGuire. 1985. Jobs and
New York:Free Press. Taxes:The Effects of Business Climateson States'Employ-
Rabe, BarryG. 1986. Fragmentationand Integrationin State ment GrowthRates.National TaxJournal 38(4): 497-511.
EnvironmentalManagement.WashingtonDC: Conservation Weber,EdwardP. 1998. Pluralism by the Rules: Conflict and
Foundation. Cooperationin EnvironmentalRegulation.WashingtonDC:
.1995. IntegratedEnvironmentalPermitting:Experience GeorgetownUniversityPress.
and Innovationat the State Level. State and Local Govern- Weimer,David, andAdrianVining. 1999. PolicyAnalysis. Con-
mentReview 27(2): 209-20. cepts and Practice, 3rd ed. New York:PrenticeHall.
Rhoades, Steven E. 1985. The Economist'sViewof the World: Williams, Marva. 1994. EnvironmentalBribery:Integrationof
Government,Markets,and Public Policy. New York:Cam- Economic Development and Pollution Prevention.Unpub-
bridgeUniversityPress. lished paper,RutgersUniversity.
Ringquist, Evan 1993. EnvironmentalProtection at the State Yandle, Bruce. 1984. Environmental Control and Regional
Level. Armonk:NY: M.E. Sharpe. Growth.Growthand Change 14(1): 39-42.
. 1989. Trackingthe Unicorn: The Political Limits of
EnvironmentalRegulation.New York:Quorum.

Economic
Versus
Protection
Environmental Development: 321
A FalseTrade-Off?

You might also like