You are on page 1of 13

World Development Vol. 51, pp.

119131, 2013
2013 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.
0305-750X/$ - see front matter
www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2013.05.013

Are Carbon Taxes Good for the Poor? A General Equilibrium


Analysis for Vietnam
IAN COXHEAD
University of Wisconsin-Madison, USA

ANAN WATTANAKULJARUS
National Institute of Development Administration, Bangkok, Thailand

and
CHAN V. NGUYEN *
National Economics University, Hanoi, Viet Nam
Summary. We evaluate eects of an environmental tax using a general equilibrium model linked to a household database. The burden
of the tax, applied mainly to energy, is passed forward by non-tradable industries and backward by tradable industries facing xed world
prices. The tax is thus equivalent to a real exchange rate appreciation, and since export industries are labor-intensive, reduces employ-
ment, and increases poverty, especially when labor supply is responsive to wages. The use of revenues to increase transfers to households
can oset poverty increases, but does not create jobs; thus the tax will likely conict with other development policy objectives.
2013 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Key words carbon tax, environmental tax, poverty, labor market, general equilibrium, Vietnam

1. INTRODUCTION income and poverty. This in turn requires a discussion of some


important parameters about which relatively little is known.
In December 2012 the Government of Vietnam imple- Among these are elasticities of labor supply. The environmental
mented its rst law on environmental taxation. 1 The law man- tax aects real wages through a number of channels, and the ef-
dated new taxes on coal, gasoline and other fossil fuels, fect of real wage changes on labor supply determines aggregate
pesticides, and some other products. As such it bears a strong employment eects as well as contributing to distributional and
similarity to carbon taxes being implemented or debated in poverty outcomes. Our examination of the labor supply issue is
other countries. Such taxes have far-reaching economic eects, threaded throughout the paper.
so as in other countries, there is considerable uncertainty over Environmental policy issues in Vietnam have received lim-
their economic implications. It is likely that reaching their ited prior attention from a general equilibrium perspective.
nominal objectivesreduced growth rates of emissions from El Obeid, Van der Mensbrugghe, and Dessus (2002, chap. 9)
carbon-based fuelswill also require changes in the structure used a small general equilibrium model to examine the struc-
of production, employment, wages, and prices, and that these tural eects of trade policy reforms and environmental policy
changes in turn will aect the levels and distribution of house- initiatives, focusing on measuring changes in emissions of air
hold incomes. In trade-dependent low-income economies like and water pollution and solid waste, but did not explore wel-
Vietnam, therefore, the eort to reduce emissions raises addi- fare and distributional questions. In a concurrent study
tional concerns at points where it intersects with other primary Willenbockel (2011), using a smaller version of the database
targets of development policy. Do energy taxes alter the com- that we do, explores structural impacts of the environmental
petitiveness of industries producing exports and import substi- tax law. His study includes a helpful exploration of the long-
tutes? Do they alter prospects for employment growth? What er-run issue of tax-induced substitution among energy sources
eects do they have on poverty? If adverse eects are su- as well as careful predictions of environmental outcomes. We
ciently large, policymakers may be compelled to choose complement this approach by focusing on welfare issues aris-
among development policy priorities. ing from the incidence of the tax as transmitted through factor
In this paper we evaluate the likely economic impacts and
incidence of Vietnams environmental tax law. The scope of
the law ensures that its impacts will be felt throughout the econ- * The authors thank Le Dong Tam, Kim Tran Dung, and Kim Pho Chi
omy. Accordingly, we adopt a general equilibrium approach, for research assistance, The Ford Foundation and the Graduate School of
taking account of known economic linkages among production the University of Wisconsin-Madison for nancial support, and confer-
activities, employment, wages, household incomes, consumer ence/seminar participants at the University of Waikato, the National In-
expenditures, trade, government revenues, and other important stitute of Development Administration (Bangkok), the Midwest
macroeconomic variables. This methodology facilitates a rela- International Economic Development Conference, Madison, WI, and
tively complete assessment of the impacts and incidence of the two anonymous reviewers for helpful comments on earlier drafts. Address
tax. We quantify the consequences of the tax for production, for correspondence: coxhead@wisc.edu. Final revision accepted: May 15,
employment, and wagesand consequently for household 2013.
119
120 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

markets and alternative scal mechanisms, and map results to The change in the price of a good with respect to demand
a complete household survey database. In doing so, as noted growth will be equal to 1/eh when there are no foreign sales,
above, we draw attention to incipient tradeos among devel- and 1/(ef  eh) when there are no domestic sales. In the small
opment policy goals. country case foreign demand is elastic, and therefore ef > eh.
The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2 In industries whose output is sold primarily to the world mar-
we review relevant tax incidence concepts and theory. Section 3 ket, price is unresponsive to demand shocks and the tax bur-
introduces the model and its main datasets. We describe the den cannot be passed forward. In contrast, for industries
environmental tax simulation experiment in Section 4, and dis- producing non-traded or little-traded goods and services, de-
cuss the results in Section 5. In a nal section we draw some mand is less elastic and prices are more responsive. These con-
conclusions and identify areas for future research. ditions apply particularly to suppliers of domestic services
such as transportation, storage and trade, which are inputs
2. TAX INCIDENCE IN AN OPEN ECONOMY to all other productive activities and have few substitutes. If
the law of one price holds, then any tax aecting costs in these
The economic incidence of a tax diers from its statutory intermediate services will be passed forward until it reaches the
(direct) incidence. Those on whom the statutory burden falls border (that is, domestic industries competing directly with
pass the cost of the tax on, through markets, to consumers foreign producers), at which point it will bounce back onto
and the suppliers of labor and other factors (Atkinson & factors of production. This is easily seen by recalling that un-
Stiglitz, 1980). The extent to which tax burden is passed for- der constant returns to scale and competitive markets, price is
ward (to consumers) or backward (to factor owners) depends equal to unit cost. Given a vector of primary factors x with
on behavioral and technological responses to the taxfor prices w and an intermediate input z with tax-inclusive price
example the elasticity of consumer demand for a product, or q(p) = q(1 + p), unit cost is p = w0 x + q(p)z. Choose units
the extent to which a less highly taxed input to production of z such that q = 1. Then in proportional change form the
may be substituted for a more highly taxed one. In general, zero-prot condition is:
X
tax burden is redistributed according to relative magnitudes p
^ ^ i /z p
/i w ^;
of relevant elasticities of demand or supply. The less elastic is i
demand by purchasers of a taxed item, the more likely it is that P
the tax will be passed forward. In the event that demand is elas- in which the / are cost shares and i /i /z 1: When the
tic, the burden will instead be passed backward to factors. In rate of the tax increases, p must rise, and/or some wi must fall
that case, the distribution of the burden among factors will de- to maintain zero pure prots. If p is constrained from increas-
pend, in part, on relative values of their supply elasticities. The ing by limit prices set in world markets, the burden of adjust-
values of such parameters are thus crucial to the economic inci- ment falls instead on factors. In its turn, the distribution of
dence of a tax. 2 Moreover, so long as agents are heterogeneous this loss among factors will be strongly inuenced by their rel-
in terms of the services that they supply to factor markets, the ative supply elasticities. We return to this point below.
conditions under which they supply them (e.g., reservation If non-traded industries can pass the tax burden forward
wages), and/or the preferences they exhibit as consumers, then while those competing at the border cannot, then in the mac-
the shifting of the tax burden has consequences for income roeconomy, a tax on a widely used input such as energy has
distribution in addition to its impacts on aggregate welfare. eects analogous to those of a real exchange rate appreciation.
These general observations come into sharp focus in small It reduces the relative protability of producing tradable
open economies, where the dierences between domestic and goods and services, and so diminishes the countrys competi-
foreign markets become important to overall tax incidence. tiveness in world markets. This point is strikingly absent from
Suppose (for simplicity) that the supply of an exportable good standard carbon tax models, which omit or minimize the role
produced by homogeneous domestic rms is inelastic, so de- of international trade (Fullerton & Heutel, 2007; Metcalf,
mand (D) is the main determinant of its price. Denoting for- 2008). The loss of tradable sector competitiveness opens (or
eign and home markets by f and h, respectively, we have widens) a balance of trade decit, with a matching excess of
D = Df(pf) + Dh(ph), with oDi/opi < 0, i = f, h. Using the total domestic aggregate expenditure over income. For given inter-
dierential to nd the change in total demand, national capital ows, 3 the elimination of these decits re-
quires a combination of expenditure reductions and a fall in
@Df @Dh the relative level of domestic prices so as to depreciate the real
dD dpf dp :
@pf @ph h exchange rate. Among tradable industries, higher costs and
lower prots cause tax burden to be passed back in the form
If we multiply and divide the rst right-hand side term by Dfpf of lower factor prices, and ultimately to household incomes.
and the second by Dhph then divide the whole by D, we have These are likely to be important components of the adjustment
to a new equilibrium. Accordingly, the shifting incidence of
b dD ef hf ^pf eh 1  hf ^
D ph ;
D the tax aects not only the structure of production and trade,
but also factor prices and employment, and ultimately the dis-
where a hat denotes the proportional change in a variable; tribution of household income and welfare.
ei = (oDi/opi)/(pi/Di) is the absolute value of the demand elas-
ticity in the ith market, and hf is the foreign share in total de-
mand. The change in total demand is a weighted sum of price (a) Environmental taxes
changes in each market, where the weights are price elasticities
and market shares. More intuitively, if we suppose that the Environmental taxes are politically controversial, in part
good in question has close substitutes in both markets so that due to doubts over their ecacy, and in part because there
price changes are correlated, we can write ^ pf ^ph ^
p, which is much uncertainty over their economic incidence. Econo-
(after more rearranging) yields mists have also struggled to identify incidence, whether in the-
oretical models or in quantitative analyses. Taxes on energy
^p 1 sources have inherently general equilibrium eects; stylized
:
b
D ef  e h hf eh models have been used to explore structural issues (Copeland
ARE CARBON TAXES GOOD FOR THE POOR? A GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS FOR VIETNAM 121

& Taylor, 2003), but for applications to welfare and policy the stock is mobile among sectors, while another part is specic
use of applied general equilibrium (AGE) models is required. to each sector. Labor is divided into six categories by location
Until very recently, AGE analyses of the incidence of envi- (urban/rural) and skill (low/medium/high). 6 These categories
ronmental taxes were focused on industrialized economy are based on data in the 2007 Vietnam Social Accounting Ma-
cases. The majority of these studies nd that taxes on energy trix (SAM), which are fully documented by Arndt, Garcia,
are fully passed forward to consumers; as a result, they are Pham, McCoy, Tarp, and Thurlow (2010). Labor demands
usually found to be regressive (Metcalf, 2008; OECD, 1994, are derived in the usual way from prot-maximizing choices
1995). Possible exceptions to this regressivity exist when the made by a representative rm in each industry. The model
tax is applied to natural resources, since the (short-run) inelas- posits a nested factor demand structure, with composite factor
ticity of their supply causes part of the tax burden to be shifted demand decisions at the top level and demands for each type
back, reducing rents that often accrue to more wealthy mem- of labor determined at the next level; these are governed by
bers of society. constant elasticity of substitution (CES) production technol-
For developing countries, however, the nature of any trade- ogy. Similarly, intermediate inputs used in each industry are
o between environmental and eciency or equity objectives aggregated into a composite input using CES technology. In
remains unresolved. Most studies of carbon taxes in low-in- the long run this structure allows for the possibility of interfuel
come economies use partial equilibrium methods (Datta, substitution when tax increases energy prices at dierent rates.
2010; Sterner, 2012; Ziramba, Kumo, & Akinbiade, 2009). The possibility of substitution among fuel types is an impor-
Therefore they do not fully capture the trade competitiveness tant feature for any study of the eects of a tax in the long
and employment linkages we have described. This is a large run. However, a suitable model for that analysis must allow
source of potential bias in results (Parry, Sigman, Walls, & for capital investment and depreciation whereas our model is
Williams, 2005). Among general equilibrium studies, Coxhead focused on a shorter-run incidence analysis. Finally, the model
(2000) showed that in a developing-country setting, imposing a allows for two-way trade in each good, although the data con-
pollution tax need not reduce real wages. The most pollution- tain some pure non-traded goods such as domestic trade and
intensive industries are typically capital-intensive; a tax that transportation, public administration, and personal services.
reduces their protability has general equilibrium eects Despite two decades of rapid growth, Vietnam remains a
through the real exchange rate that cause labor demand in small player in global trade. 7 Our model reects this by
cleaner and more labor-intensive industries to expand. The assuming xed world prices of Vietnams imports and highly
key to this result is that polluting industries produce tradables, elastic global demand for its exports. This small open econ-
and so are constrained by the elasticity of demand in world omy representation distinguishes the Vietnam model from
market from passing costs forward in higher prices. Similarly, most environmental tax models for the US and other large
Yusuf (2008) showed that a reduction in fuel subsidies need industrialized economies, in which domestic markets typically
not be regressive in Indonesia, depending on compensation dominate trade. In those models, all virtually all tax burden is
schemes implemented alongside the tax reform. In general, passed forward to as higher prices to domestic consumers
however, when tax burden is passed backward rather than for- (Bovenberg & Goulder, 1996; Fullerton & Metcalf, 1997).
ward, new sources of distributional concern arise, and these Vietnams labor force consists mainly of unskilled or low-
are linked directly to the elasticity of factor supply. 4 skilled workers. In the 2006, VHLSS 44% of workers had pri-
mary or lower education; 33% had completed lower secondary
school; 19% upper secondary school, and just 4.2% some form
3. METHODS AND DATA of tertiary education. This labor force structure ensures that
the countrys comparative advantage lies, for now, rmly in
(a) The model and database the agricultural and light manufacturing sectors. Slightly less
than half the Vietnamese labor force is employed in agricul-
To evaluate the eects of Vietnams environmental tax we ture, about one-fth in manufacturing, and the remainder in
use an AGE model of the Vietnamese economy. Such models services (World Bank, WDI Online).
represent the entire economy in numerical form. They com- The model database contains 20 representative household
bine baseline data from national accounts and other sources types, distinguished by location (urban/rural), primary occu-
about the activities of rms, households, enterprises, and gov- pation (farm/nonfarm), and quintile in the aggregate expendi-
ernment with theory-based specications about market opera- ture distribution. Households earn income from their
tion, factor supplies, trade balances, and other constraints, ownership of factors, and may receive transfers from govern-
and the assumed behavior of foreign partners in trade and ment or enterprises as well as remittances from the rest of the
investment. They thus provide a consistent interface between world. They consume goods and services, both those produced
macro and micro phenomena, at least in the realm of the real domestically and those imported from abroad. Consumption
economy. 5 is assumed to take a Stone-Geary form, in which expenditure
We seek to observe the eects of tax policy shocks on prices, is allocated rst to satisfaction of minimum subsistence quan-
production and factor demand, and through these, on markets tities of goods, and then to supernumary, or discretionary,
for labor, land, and capital and thus on household incomes expenditures.
and wellbeing. Because households are heterogeneous in terms
of asset ownership, income, and expenditure we can also mea- (b) Links to national household survey data
sure eects on income distribution and poverty. The model is
based on the well-known IFPRI model (Lofgren, Harris, & For the purpose of welfare analysis, we augment this repre-
Robinson, 2002), modied to t Vietnamese data. Here, to sentative household structure by linking it recursively to the
save space we merely summarize the models main features. individual records of the 2006 Vietnam Household Living
The model identies 63 sectors, each producing a single Standards Survey (VHLSS), which contains information on
commodity. There are three aggregate primary factors: land, a representative sample of 9,185 households nationwide. As
labor, and capital. Land is used only in agriculture and natural in the SAM, each household in the VHLSS dataset can be
resource sectors. Capital has two components: part of the identied by its location, primary occupation, and position
122 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

in the expenditure distribution. The results of a simulation about $20/tonne on diesel, and about $47/tonne on gasoline. 11
experiment in the AGE model are transmitted to individual The latter two gures are quite high by international stan-
household eects by mapping predicted changes in prices dards, and the striking disparity between these and the implied
and supply quantities of factors, consumer prices, and trans- tax rate on coal is a further indication that environmental mo-
fers from private and government sources onto information tives were not dominant in the design of this tax structure.
about household endowments, consumption patterns, and un-
earned income. This yields household-specic predictions of
changes in income, expenditure, and price indices associated (a) Labor supply
with the ceteris paribus eects of a given policy shock applied
to the model. In Vietnam, the labor market is the most important market
This link, from macro model to micro data, makes it pos- in the economy from the point of view of household income,
sible simultaneously to conduct two types of experiments. One income distribution, and poverty. The countrys rapid growth
is macrosimulation, or experiments in which we examine the ef- over the past 20 years has seen enormous movement of labor
fects of a growth or policy shock on macroeconomic aggre- across industries and locations, and (increasingly, from a low
gates such as GDP, CPI, wages, employment, and industry base) across skill types. The large numbers of workers chang-
activity levels. The other type is microsimulation, in which ing both occupation and location in any period suggest a very
we trace the eects of the same shock(s) to the incomes and elastic labor market response to changing opportunities, with
expenditures of individual households, or to regional and internal migration by workers estimated at between 0.5 m and
other aggregates. The latter method enables us to draw conclu- 1 m per year (Phan & Coxhead, 2010). In particular, there has
sions about the eects of the shock on household real incomes been a surge of predominantly semi-skilled workers (i.e., those
and poverty, both nationally and for subsets of the population with a completed junior high school education) into urban la-
such as urban and rural households and residents of dierent bor markets. Young women are predominant among internal
administrative regions. 8 rural-urban migrants, perhaps reecting a lower opportunity
cost of their labor in source households and communities.
(c) Solution method Yet beyond these observations, surprisingly little is known
quantitatively about the responsiveness of labor supply to real
The model is implemented using GEMPACK software wage changes.
(Harrison & Pearson, 1996) and as such relies heavily on code We adapt the model to incorporate a simple labor supply
from the well-known ORANI-G model (Horridge, 2005). The structure. The representative household supplies labor that is
model is implemented in percentage changes of variables rela- dierentiated by location and by education (primary, second-
tive to a no-tax counterfactual. Thus, for example, an increase ary, and tertiary), a proxy for skill. Each of these characteris-
of 0.5% in the CPI means that imposing the tax raises the rate tics is likely to be associated with a dierent supply elasticity,
of ination (that is, the growth rate of the CPI) by 0.5% during and the mix of labor endowments within each household type
the period encompassed by the simulation, i.e., about one further dierentiates them from one another. For a worker in
year. region i with skills j, we posit the labor supply function
LSij LTij  wij =CPI j bij ;
4. ENVIRONMENTAL TAX POLICY EXPERIMENT where superscripts S and T denote labor supplied to the mar-
ket and total labor endowment respectively; the CPI is specic
The Vietnamese legislation mandates specic taxes on the to location (either rural or urban), and bij P 0 is the elasticity
volume sold of coal, gasoline and other fossil fuels, and pesti- of the labor supply with respect to the real wage. This styliza-
cides. These taxes are intended to replace fees currently levied tion ignores income eects and demographic sources of heter-
at the point of sale. 9 Using current market prices, we convert ogeneity. 12
these fees and specic taxes to their ad valorem equivalents. Other than the initial distribution of labor endowments
Table 1 shows basic data on the two main products targeted across households, the critical labor supply parameters are
by the tax, coal, and rened fuels. As legislated, these taxes the elasticities, b. We have very little information on these.
span a range of values. The last column of the table shows Classical development theory often posits a horizontal labor
the sales tax equivalent of the median tax rate for each prod- supply curve (b = 1), but this is rarely supported by the data.
uct. These are the counterfactual rates we apply in our exper- Standard trade models typically assume full employment and
iments. perfectly inelastic labor supply (b = 0), but this too is unreal-
The environmental taxes are not strictly construed as taxes istic for developing countries, especially in rural areas where
on carbon; 10 however, they are equivalent to a tax of about households typically exhibit both underemployment and
$US0.71/tonne of carbon dioxide equivalent (CO2e) on coal, unemployment. Individual workers may supply additional

Table 1. Environmental tax rates


Domestic base price Legislated environmental tax Environmental tax
(VND per ton or liter) (VND/tonne or liter) as% of base pricea
(1) (2) (3)
Coal (lignite) 450,000 10,00030,000 Minimum: 2.20
Median: 4.40
Fuel 15,000 1,0004,000 (Gasoline) Minimum: 4.30
5002,000 (Diesel) Median: 10.75
Source of tax rate data: http://bit.ly/12IHzSc, accessed May 1, 2013.
a
For fuel, tax rates are computed as 0.71 * diesel rate + 0.29 * gasoline rate based on import shares.
ARE CARBON TAXES GOOD FOR THE POOR? A GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS FOR VIETNAM 123

Table 2. Assumed values of labor supply elasticities labor either at the intensive margin (hours worked) or the
Labor type Rural Urban extensive margin (jobs taken by those previously unem-
ployed). The total elasticity of labor supply is the sum of these,
Unskilled (primary education) 1.0 0.5 but most estimates for developing countries appear to apply
Medium-skilled (secondary ed) 0.5 0.1
only to the intensive margin. 13 Household-level labor supply
High-skilled (tertiary ed) 0.1 0.1
is also more elastic than for individuals. If the household
consists only of one or two adult members, they are likely to

Table 3. Environmental taxes: macroeconomic impacts


Variables A: Elastic labor B: Elastic labor C: Fixed labor
supply, no transfers supply, transfers supply, no transfers
Real GDP, % change 0.63 0.46 0.35
Real absorption, % change 0.39 0.29 0.16
CPI, % change 0.72 0.59 0.73
Government tax revenues, % change 3.79 4.05 4.10
Government revenues, change (VND mn) 10,920 11,661 11,806
Govt transfers to households, % change 2.98 18.13 3.02
Output by aggregate sector, % change
Agriculture 2.53 1.83 1.69
Manufacturing 1.47 0.98 1.26
Services 0.50 0.74 0.29
Employment by aggregate sector, % change
Agriculture 1.90 1.30 0.52
Manufacturing 1.27 0.31 0.95
Services 0.12 0.30 0.11
Note: Complete tables of simulation results available from authors.

Table 4. Environmental tax impact on selected sectors (base case, percentage changes)
Selected sectors Output Price Trade
Energy Domestic price
Coal mining 4.12 3.41
Crude oil 8.56 7.07
Petroleum products 5.12 8.14
Electricity and gas 1.65 1.50
Margins and non-traded goods
Retail and wholesale trade 1.97 1.92
Road transport 3.10 6.40
Air transport 2.08 4.80
Other transport 2.17 6.81
Paddy rice 1.93 0.81
Fisheriesa 5.11 7.89
Export goods Fob export price Exports
Fish processing 4.64 0.69 6.62
Textiles 0.61 0.09 0.92
Furniture 0.91 0.00 0.11
Footwear 0.80 0.00 0.02
Vegetable and fruit processing 1.21 0.07 0.72
Wood products 0.35 0.01 0.05
Other food processing 2.38 0.23 2.23
Import-competing goods Cif import price Imports
Vehicles and transport equipment 0.51 0.00 0.48
Other chemicals 1.73 0.00 1.45
Basic metals 1.09 0.00 0.85
Textiles 0.61 0.00 0.57
Metal products 1.09 0.00 0.85
Machinery and equipment 0.87 0.00 0.82
Paper products 1.35 0.00 1.03
Note: Complete tables of simulation results available from authors.
a
Just 3% of sheries output is exported.
124 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

supply additional labor only at the intensive margin. Rural elastic supplies, to 0.1 for the least. The estimation of labor
households, however, are commonly larger and may have supply parameters from household and individual data is the
some adult members (in Vietnam, often young women) who subject of ongoing research.
are openly unemployed. These households are likely to exhibit
more elastic supply at both the intensive and extensive mar- (b) Macroeconomic closure assumptions
gins.
Ocial sources in Vietnam report urban unemployment In order to conduct tax policy experiments we must make
rates to be roughly steady at around 56%, and the ratio of assumptions about the way in which the economy responds
rural hours worked to hours available at about 75% (Brassard, to a shock, choosing which variables and policy settings are
2004). About 13% of rural workers are reported in ocial sta- exogenously xed, and which may endogenously adjust.
tistics as working less than full-time and seeking more hours of We assume investment-driven savings, and a xed current
work in a week (Coxhead et al., 2010, Table 6). From our eval- account balance with no endogenous transfers to or from
uation of these admittedly fragmentary data, we surmise that the rest of the world. The latter assumption requires that the
labor supply by rural workers is in general more elastic than balance of trade must remain constant. This eliminates unac-
that for urban workers and that supply is more elastic for un- counted intertemporal borrowing, forcing all adjustment into
skilled labor than for medium or high-skilled labor. In the the single period of the simulation. The nominal exchange rate
model, we build a vector of b values from these conjectures. of VND for USD (assumed xed) is the models numeraire
The assumed values (see Table 2) range from 1 for the most price. Therefore, when a shock applied to the model creates

Table 5. Environmental tax: Impact on factor employment and real returns (percent change)
Variables A: Elastic labor supply, no B: Elastic labor supply, C: Fixed labor supply, no
transfers transfers transfers
Wage Employment Wage Employment Wage Employment
Labor
Urban, tertiary ed 0.38 0.02 1.92 0.11 1.35 0
Urban, secondary ed 0.97 0.03 1.27 0.13 2.61 0
Urban, primary ed 1.45 0.14 0.97 0.49 4.02 0
Rural, tertiary ed 0.38 0.02 1.92 0.14 1.35 0
Rural, secondary ed 0.97 0.87 1.27 0.60 2.61 0
Rural, primary ed 1.45 1.38 0.97 0.93 4.02 0
Other factors
Capital, agriculture, xed 4.05 0 2.73 0 2.54 0
Capital, agriculture, mobile 4.46 0 3.23 0 2.87 0
Capital, non-agriculture, xed 3.52 0 3.17 0 2.95 0
Capital, non-agriculture, mobile 1.68 0 1.63 0 1.38 0
Note: Nominal price changes deated by CPI change. The model species distinct urban and rural labor endowments and supply elasticities (see Table 2);
we assume mobility across locations. Changes in returns to xed capital are averages over multiple sectors.

Table 6. Real consumption changes by household type and quintile (% change from base)
Quintile and HH type Percent A: Elastic labor supply, B: Elastic labor supply, C: Fixed labor supply,
rural (%) no transfers transfers no transfers
Quintile 1 (Lowest) 93.5 1.90 0.17 1.65
Urban 2.50 0.94 2.45
Rural 1.85 0.11 1.60
Quintile 2 88.1 1.97 0.49 1.65
Urban 2.58 1.35 2.31
Rural 1.88 0.38 1.56
Quintile 3 77.8 2.06 0.68 1.69
Urban 2.40 1.18 2.03
Rural 1.96 0.53 1.59
Quintile 4 65.5 1.91 0.65 1.47
Urban 2.26 1.15 1.77
Rural 1.73 0.38 1.31
Quintile 5 (Highest) 50.4 1.61 0.50 1.08
Urban 1.70 0.71 1.09
Rural 1.53 0.30 1.08
All Households 74.9 1.89 0.50 1.51
Urban 2.10 0.99 1.62
Rural 1.82 0.33 1.47
ARE CARBON TAXES GOOD FOR THE POOR? A GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS FOR VIETNAM 125

pressures for an imbalance on the trade account, domestic being urban households in the richest two quintiles, who earn
spending, and (where applicable) factor employment must ad- almost 6.5% of income from this source. Our experiment in
just to restore external balance. Case B, therefore, simply asks whether the existing system of
In each closure we assume that half the capital in each transfer payments provides a feasible mechanism for compen-
industry is xed (immobile), while the other half is mobile (it sating households aected by the environmental tax.
can be reallocated across industries or sectors). 14 We also as- Finally, Figure 1 also conrms that households are hetero-
sume that labor of a given skill level is mobile across loca- geneous in terms of factor income shares. Labor earnings
tionsthat is, we assume costless rural-urban migration are by far the most important single income source, and as ex-
within the equilibrium timeframe of the model. pected, poorer households earn relatively higher shares of in-
Early discussions of Vietnams environmental tax law come from low-skilled labor. Policy shocks that operate
claimed that revenues were to be spent on environmental pro- through the labor market will thus have dierential eects
grams, but the legislation itself makes no mention of this, and on household income.
we can nd no evidence that this issue has received serious pol-
icy attention to date. 15 Therefore, and in order to maintain fo-
cus on the incidence of the taxes themselves, we abstract from 5. SIMULATION RESULTS
environment-specic expenditures. In the base case (Case A)
we assume that additional revenues from the tax increases are We are interested in both structural and distributional as-
spent in an equiproportional, across-the-board increase in pects of the incidence of the environmental tax. The experi-
government consumption of goods and services. Most govern- ment consists of imposing new taxes at the median rates
ment expenditure is on relatively skill-intensive services such shown in column 6 of Table 1, and we run three variants. In
as public administration and education, these are the indus- the base case (A), as just described, we assume that transfers
tries and associated factors that will gain most in this case. from government to households increase only at the same rate
For comparison of welfare outcomes, we assume alternatively as other components of public spending. Also in this closure,
that net changes in government revenue are redistributed as an labor supplies are elastic as shown in the rst column of Ta-
across-the board increase in transfers to households, again ble 2. We compare this with Case B, in which government uses
leaving the governments net budget decit unchanged. In this the additional tax revenues to increase transfer payments to
case, all existing transfer recipients will receive an equal per- poor households. For comparison with the base case, we also
centage increase in payments (this is Case B). However, trans- adopt a closure (Case C) in which the supply of all labor types
fers contribute diering shares of initial income (Figure 1), so is assumed xed. Relative to Case A, this highlights the dier-
the impact will vary across households. It should also be noted ential macroeconomic and tax incidence consequences of alter-
that an across-the-board increase in transfer payments is the nate labor supply assumptions. To save space, the tables
same as an increase in payments to the poor. Government report only the most relevant results in each case; full simula-
transfers include anti-poverty transfers along with education tion results are available from the authors.
subsidies, pensions paid to retirees and invalids, and other
transfers identied in social programs. Rural households in (a) Macroeconomic impacts
the poorest two quintiles of the expenditure distribution earn,
on average, 2.5% of their income from government transfers. Table 3 shows the main macroeconomic results for all three
Some other household groups earn a lot more, the highest cases. 16 In Case A, the model predicts that the environmental

Figure 1. Sources of household income (percent), by type and quintile. Source: Vietnam SAM 2007 (Arndt et al., 2010).
126 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

taxes reduce GDP growth by 0.63% and increase the CPI by prices of these tradable sectors outputs hardly change. Final-
0.72%. The taxes raise government revenues by about 3.8% ly, many import-competing manufacturers are also hurt, with
(VND 10.9bn, equivalent to about $US640m). Real absorp- relatively large output cuts in energy-intensive sectors like
tion falls by 0.39%. At the level of aggregate sectors, the tax chemicals and paper products.
raises costs and reduces output in manufacturing by 2.5%, in An important insight from these results is that some indus-
services (including energy-intensive transport services) by tries experience much greater adjustment pressure than others.
0.12% in services, and in agriculture and resource sectors by In general, energy generation and energy-intensive activities
1.9%. Aggregate sectoral employment falls by somewhat more are most heavily aected, as expected. But these include some
(1.47% in manufacturing, 0.5% in services, 2.5% in agricul- industries which, because they supply domestic markets virtu-
ture). Because the supply of labor is somewhat elastic, prices ally free from international competition, have discretion to
of capital and land, which by contrast are assumed xed in raise prices, thereby passing part of their input cost increase
supply, fall further than wages in general and this induces sub- forward to other industries and nal consumers. Transport
stitution away from labor in production. services and sheries exemplify this property.
Comparing Cases A and C shows the macro implications of Other industries produce goods for which output prices are
elastic labor supply. With xed factor supplies (Case C) the set in the world market; processed seafood, fruit and vegetable
aggregate production possibilities frontier remains unaltered products, clothing, furniture, and coee are examples. Among
and overall GDP falls by much less (0.35%), whereas in Case these are several industries that are large employers, especially
A elastic labor supply permits a larger response. In both cases of low-skilled labor. In Figure 2, which for tradable industries
A and C, additional tax revenues are used by the government plots their share in total employment against their export inten-
to increase its own consumption; given base values, this favors sity, these industries are all net exporters whose shares in total
the aggregate services sectors relative to agriculture and man- employment are at or above the median. Faced with higher
ufacturing. In Case B, by contrast, it is households whose costs and elastic foreign demand, these industries cannot raise
spending pattern is inuential at the margin, and this dier- prices and so must instead cut productionand jobs. There-
ence is reected in a smaller decline in agriculture (i.e., food) fore, their contraction has relatively large impacts on employ-
output in Case B relative to Case A, and a larger decline in ser- ment and wages. These industries inherit the environmental
vices output in Case B relative to Case A. tax burden from upstream suppliers and pass it back to factor
Among individual industries, the range of impacts is wide, owners. They are not necessarily energy-intensive in produc-
and industry-level variation in production and prices illus- tion, but are aected by energy prices in other waysmost
trates the means by which the incidence of the taxes is shifted. especially through their use of domestic transport services to
Dierences among all cases are small in this respect, so we re- source inputs and to move outputs to markets and ports.
port results only for Case A, in Table 4. The industries directly We see the consequence of this adjustment in the wage and
targeted by the tax are of course seriously aected. Domestic employment data. Wages and other factor prices are reduced
output of coal falls by 4.1%, and that of fuels by 5%. Gas- by the taxes (Table 5). Due to migration, urban and rural wage
oline imports, which account for most of the domestic supply, changes are the same for each labor type. When labor supply is
fall by 5.1%. Electricity and gas output falls: this industry inelastic (Case C), dierential wage changes are driven by the
consists mainly of coal-burning electrical power generation impacts of the tax. With the largest contractions taking place
plants, so the tax drives up production costs and this eect among highly labor-intensive industries, wages for low and
dominates any substitution among energy sources, which by medium skill workers fall sharply. More elastic supply means
itself would increase electricity demand. smaller wage declines, but accompanied by falls in employ-
Other industries, especially those that are energy-intensive, ment, as in Cases A and B. Adding wage and employment
experience cost increases. Among these, transport industries changes, the earnings of unskilled labor fall in Case A by
are the most severely aected since gasoline and other fuels ac- 1.6% (urban) to 1.8% (rural); medium skilled by 1% (urban)
count for between 2235% of their costs. 17 The prices they to 1.8% (rural), while high-skilled earning rises by 0.4%. In
charge to users rise, by 6.4% (road transport), 4.8% (air trans- Case B the income declines are somewhat larger, though
port) and 6.8% (other transport, i.e., rail and water). Higher now the earnings of tertiary-educated workers also fall as
transport costs mean more costly production and distribution the increase in government expenditures is redirected from ser-
(domestic and export margins), and so raise costs throughout vices to transfers.
the economy. Other factor returns also decline in both nominal and real
Among industries that are especially badly hurt are produc- terms. Although our model does not track investment deci-
ers of some key natural resource products and exports derived sions, lower unit prices for xed and mobile capital signal that
from them. An important case is that of sheries, in which fuel expected investment returns in the medium run will be lower
accounts for 44% of input costs. When the taxes are imposed, than in the absence of the tax. Unless there are compensatory
the sheries industry experiences a large cost increase; produc- adjustments, investment at the margin will be diverted to other
tion falls by 5.1% and its price rises by almost 8%. This sec- uses, quite likely in other economies. Environmental consider-
tor sells 97% of its output in domestic markets; of this, 66% ations aside, this investment reaction threatens to undermine
goes to seafood processors, for whom purchases from sher- the basis for Vietnams economic growth.
ies, aquaculture, and upstream seafood processors make up As seen, the taxes increase overall prices due to the pervasive
81% of total cost22% of it directly from sheries. Conse- eects of energy cost hikes. Higher prices for consumer goods
quently, even though fuel is only around 1% of total produc- reduce households purchasing power, and, by lowering real
tion cost in seafood processing, this industry suers a major wages, also reduce aggregate employment when labor supply
indirect cost increase though its purchases from sheries, and is price-responsive. Table 6 summarizes key results of the tax
as a result its output falls by 4.6% and exports by 6.6%. on the real consumption expenditures of household groups.
Similarly, output and exports of other food processing indus- The pre-transfer impact of the environmental taxes is to re-
tries fall by 3.4% and 2.2% respectively, while other major ex- duce average real incomes for all household types and quin-
port industries suer declines of smaller magnitude. Because tiles. The biggest losses are by urban household groups,
Vietnam is a small supplier to global markets, however, border whose factor incomes depend relatively heavily on medium-
ARE CARBON TAXES GOOD FOR THE POOR? A GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS FOR VIETNAM 127

Figure 2. Employment shares and net trade orientation of industries. Vertical line shows median employment share. Source: Vietnam SAM 2007
(Arndt et al., 2010).

skill labor and non-agricultural capital returns. When trans- poverty changes from VHLSS, we apply the predicted changes
fers take place in Case B, the picture is very dierent. For some in factor prices and supplies, transfers, and consumer prices to
groups, including the largest (rural households in quintiles 1 each household according to its endowments, initial transfer
and 2) higher transfers are almost sucient to compensate income, and expenditure pattern. This gives household-specic
for their factor income losses. Their average real income poverty change results. Table 7 shows summaries of these,
changes remain negative but are small. For others, however, constructed by weighting each household result to ensure that
the transfers diminish but do not eliminate the eect of factor poverty change measures are representative at regional and
market losses. The taxes are somewhat regressive in their im- national levels.
pact: In Case A, the average losses of all households, urban The poverty change predictions show that without transfers,
or rural, in the lowest three quintiles are equal to or greater the tax sharply raises the numbers of those counted as poor.
than the average for all households. The transfers, in contrast, Both the national headcount rate and rural poverty rise by
have weakly progressive eects among the poorer three quin- about two-thirds of one percentage point. Inclusive of trans-
tiles, but also confer larger than average gains on the richest fers, these increases in the numbers of the poor are smaller
quintile. by about half. However, the gains from increased transfers
We also impute the overall eects of the environmental taxes are unequally distributed, with the regions that are home to
on changes in household-level poverty and economic welfare, Vietnams two largest cities, Hanoi and Ho Chi Minh City,
by mapping changes from the simulation model to the VHLSS experiencing large gains relative to the no-transfer case, while
database as described above. Table 7 shows percentage more remote northern regions and the Mekong Delta, which
changes headcount poverty for the country as a whole and together account for 69% of poor households, gain much less.
for urban and rural household groups. 18 In calculating These are regions with large concentrations of low-skill labor.

Table 7. Implied changes in headcount poverty due to environmental tax


Baseline Share of Increase (percentage points from base)
povertya (%) poor HHs (%)
A: Elastic labor supply, no transfers B: Elastic labor supply, no transfers
National 15.86 0.62 0.27
Urban 6.64 0.35 0.16
Rural 19.22 0.72 0.32
Regions
Red River Delta (Inc. Hanoi) 11.78 8 0.44 0.02
North East 20.75 22 0.55 0.42
North West 45.20 19 1.04 1.12
North Central Coast 26.70 17 0.52 0.22
South Central Coast 15.71 5 0.67 0.37
Central Highlands 25.20 13 0.94 0.03
South East (inc. HCM City) 5.28 5 0.24 0.11
Mekong River Delta 11.35 11 1.02 0.56
a
Calculated from 2006 VHLSS using national poverty lines of VND 265,000/person/month for rural and VND 280,000/person/month for urban areas.
128 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Figure 3. Change in household real income due to environmental tax: Case A, no transfers. Vertical line shows national poverty line.

Figure 4. Change in household real income due to environmental tax: Case B, transfers. Vertical line shows national poverty line.

The Mekong Delta region, moreover, is the main location for goals? In this paper we predict the broad economic impacts of
Vietnams aquaculture and seafood processing industries. a set of environmental taxes recently legislated in Vietnam.
A comparison of Figures 3 and 4 provides more insight into These predictions are based on simulation experiments with
the household welfare impacts of the environmental taxes with an applied general equilibrium model of the Vietnamese econ-
and without a compensating increase in transfers. These g- omy. Our approach has been to simulate the environmental
ures plot real income changes for all households against their taxes as ad valorem sales taxes on coal, gasoline, and other
initial income (shown in log form for easier exposition). In fuels. This approach is consistent with the most important fea-
Figure 3 panel a, we see that while most rural households tures of the environmental tax legislation.
experience declining real income due to the taxes, the propen- Results from the model show counterfactual changes in
sity for losses is especially acute among initially poor house- variables such as prices, employment, incomes, and poverty.
holds (those to the left of the poverty line marked on the In order to evaluate the incidence of the taxes on household
gure). The corresponding panel of Figure 4 shows that com- welfare, we have also posited that additional revenues be
pensating transfers generate moderate to large real income either spent on increased government consumption, or re-
gains for many households, but leave many among the poor turned to households in the form of increases in the existing
relatively unaected. A similar pattern can be seen in the data pattern of government transfers.
for urban households, shown in panel b of each gure. Because these are taxes on energy, their eects on economic
activity are pervasive. Transport sectors are especially aected,
but these largely non-traded industries pass the tax burden
6. DISCUSSION AND CONCLUSIONS forward to others. As a result, energy-dependent, export-ori-
ented industries like seafood processing experience cost in-
Does the desire to contribute to a cleaner local and global creases. Since their output prices are set in the world
environment conict with other important development policy market, they also suer declines in production, exports, and
ARE CARBON TAXES GOOD FOR THE POOR? A GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS FOR VIETNAM 129

employment. These losses are then passed back to factor Second, in the absence of better information, we have as-
owners. sumed that revenue gains from the taxes are either spent on
Among factor markets, that for labor is the most important additional government consumption or on increases in existing
channel for translating changes in economic activity into transfers from government to households. These are useful
changes in household welfare. We investigate this channel un- mechanisms for the purpose of evaluating the incidence of
der the assumption that the supply of certain types of labor is the taxes themselves. But they are not by any means the only
responsive to real wage changes, and also (for comparison) un- or the best way to dispose of additional revenues. The double
der the standard assumption of full employment and zero dividend literature identies improvements in the eciency of
elasticity of labor supply response. The resulting dierences the tax system as a second gain beyond the environmental ben-
in predicted changes in wages and aggregate employment ets themselves (Bovenberg & Goulder, 1996). Distortionary
map into contrasting household welfare changes. More impor- taxes reduce social welfare; therefore, if revenue gains from
tant still is the decision by the government to return all addi- environmental taxes (which themselves reduce distortions, by
tional tax revenues to households in the form of proportional helping to correct pollution externalities) are used in budget-
increases in existing transfer payments. This leads to an out- neutral fashion to reduce the rate of more distortionary taxes
come in which the environmental taxes reduce real GDP and such as import taris or factor income taxes, then social wel-
aggregate employment by somewhat less than when the pat- fare may improve. Once again, because we have not included
tern of government expenditures remains unchanged. How- such possibilities, our experiments may underestimate the po-
ever, the transfer system is not strongly progressive, so the tential social gains from the environmental taxes.
poorest households still experience substantial losses. Third, new tax revenues could also be used to oset cost in-
The experiments thus yield mixed results for policy. The uni- creases in energy-intensive and/or employment-intensive indus-
lateral adoption of environmental taxes hurts a small econ- tries. Our experiments show that tradable sectors in particular
omys competitiveness in global markets for a wide range of suer contractions and job losses because they are unable to
products. In the case of Vietnam, a low-income, labor-intensive pass on tax-related cost increases. To minimize the impact on
economy, the losers include some of its largest and most labor- these industries, and therefore on national employment and ex-
intensive export industries, even through these are not them- port competitiveness, the Vietnamese government might con-
selves highly energy-intensive in production. The losses they sider using environmental tax receipts to compensate them,
experience impede job growth, which is an important consider- for example by means of a corporate tax rebate proportionate
ation in an economy where the labor force is still growing at to their input cost increases. This revenue-recycling strategy is
more than 1.7% per year, adding about 900,000 new job-seekers more narrowly targeted than that discussed in the previous par-
each year. 19 Signicantly higher revenues enable government, agraph, and as such bears substantial risks (for rent-seeking
in principle, to compensate poor households for losses shifted and corrupt practices) along with its potential gains. On the
forward to them (as consumers) and backward to them (as fac- other hand, its potential for benecial impacts on employment
tor owners). However, increasing the rate of existing transfers growth and export revenues may well justify such risks.
to households does not eliminate the losses of the poorest Finally, since the lower emissions create a global externality
households, because it does not compensate for lost jobs. (lower GHG emissions), there is a compelling case for com-
In the longer run, an economy responds to higher energy pensation from the international community. In principle, this
prices in multifarious ways; these include interfuel substitution, could be sucient to fully compensate for the loss of aggregate
improvements in technology and eciency, and many smaller income. The UN Clean Development Mechanism (CDM),
adjustments in policy. Therefore the experimental results re- established under the Kyoto Protocol, would seem to provide
ported here, in which many other variables are held constant, a vehicle for such compensation. The CDM allows Kyoto Pro-
are indicative but not conclusive predictions of real-world out- tocol Annex I states (mainly OECD members) to sponsor
comes. However, they reveal some important but indirect chan- emissions-reducing projects in non-Annex I states (mainly
nels of tax incidence, and because of this it is our view that they developing countries) as a way of helping meet their own
merit careful consideration at policy level. An initial reaction GHG reduction commitments. More than 4,000 projects have
might be to regard the impending environmental taxes as a been funded to date, and by raising about $18bn in direct car-
costly threat to continued economic growth and development bon revenues over its 200112 implementation period, the
in a lower-income economy. We do not support this conclusion, CDM is the dominant emissions reduction mechanism for
because other consequences of the taxes, not captured or valued developing countries (World Bank, 2010: 262). Two issues re-
in this model, have yet to be taken into account. To frame ongo- main, however. First, by themselves any transfers to Vietnam
ing debate, we oer the following thoughts. from the international community would no more address
First, although we can estimate likely reductions in the non-environmental development targets (such as job creation)
growth of industrial emissions, we lack the information neces- than would compensation paid to households by the Vietnam-
sary to assign valuations of the environmental benets of the ese governmentas discussed above. Second, to date all pro-
new taxes. These may take the form of reduced abatement jects funded under the CDM have been linked to specic
costs (that is, costs associated with remediation of pollution, activities such as reaorestation, introduction of new technol-
clean-up of water supplies, waste disposal, and so on), and ogies, fuel substitution, etc. We know of no project as yet
also lower incidence of pollution-related damages to health. funded that rewards a country for implementing emissions-
Studies in other developing countries indicate that particulate reducing incentive mechanisms such as energy taxes. Indeed,
matter and gaseous emissions from industries and vehicles the CDM Methodology Booklet (UNFCCC, 2010), which lists
have large and costly impacts on human health, as well as and describes hundreds of CDM-permissible methodologies
reducing the productivity of labor. If environmental taxes re- for emissions reduction, contains no mention at all of taxes
duce emissions growth, then they also deliver benets in the or other mechanisms based only on incentives to alter behav-
form of a more healthy and productive workforce. These ben- ior. So deployment of the CDM in support of an environmen-
ets should be taken into account when evaluating the net tal tax such as that legislated in Vietnam would seem also to
gains and losses from an environmental tax. Because we do require a substantial change in the mode of operation of that
not, our results may understate the gains from the new taxes. international mechanism.
130 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

NOTES

1. The law passed the National Assembly in November 2010. For an margin (hours worked) and at the extensive margin (labor force
English language version see http://bit.ly/12IHzSc. participation). Moreover, family labor supply diers substantively from
that by individuals. Preference heterogeneity within familiesand across
2. Fullerton and Metcalf (2002) provide a helpful model illustrating these the labor force as a wholeis associated with more elastic labor supply.
points.
13. Empirically, our search for estimates of labor supply elasticities in
3. We return to this point in the concluding section of the paper. developing countries returned few results. Rosenzweig (1980), using
individual data, found inelastic o-farm supply of labor hours by men and
women with land, but considerably more elastic supply from landless
4. Some more recent contributions focus on labor markets using a workers. Using data from Sri Lanka, Sahn and Alderman (1988) nd the
HarrisTodaro migration structure. See, for example, Daitoh and Omote elasticity of rural labor supply w.r.t. wages of 0.135 (men) and 0.149
(2011). (women), with smaller values (0.07 and 0.03) for urban workers. These are
based on individuals and apply only to the intensive margin, and so are at
5. For recent surveys of AGE models applied to the Vietnamese the lower bound of such estimates. In more complete analyses, supply
economy, see Coxhead et al. (2010) and Abbott, Bentzen, & Tarp, 2009. elasticities at the extensive margin dominate (in magnitude) those at the
intensive margin (Blundell & McCurdy, 1999; Heckman, 1993). The
6. Earlier editions of the Vietnam SAM identied male and female latters surveys of empirical estimates range very widely, with some
workers separately, but the 2007 SAM makes no such distinction. empirical models yielding values of 1 and even more, especially for
women.
7. Vietnams shares in world exports and imports are 0.53% and 0.58%
respectively (WTO, http://stat.wto.org/CountryProle/ 14. The Vietnam SAM provides no guidance on xed and mobile capital,
WSDBCountryPFView.aspx?Language=E&Country=VN, accessed and our 50-50 division is merely an ad hoc assumption. However,
March 1, 2013). robustness checks using 25-75 and 72-25 splits show that the results are
not very sensitive to the exact percentage allocations.
8. In structure, our model is a hybrid. It is simultaneous in the behavior
of the household categories embedded in the social accounting matrix, but 15. The lack of a direct link to environmental measures is a distinctive
recursive in the mapping from these to the full sample of VHLSS feature of Vietnams tax when compared with similar policies in other
households. This structure means that we can calculate unique household countries (see Gale, Brown, & Saltiel, 2013 for a survey). The most likely
impacts of each shock in the VHLSS sample, but imposes the assumption reason for this disconnect is institutional: the tax is designed and
that all households within each category respond identically to a given implemented by the Ministry of Finance, whereas responsibility for
shock. environmental policy rests with the Ministry of Environment and Natural
Resources, and there are few meaningful mechanisms for interagency
9. Vietnam uses a variety of instruments to pursue fuel price stabiliza- coordination. There are no mentions of the environmental tax law
tion, including a price stabilization fund and point of sale price limits accessible on the MONRE website http://www.monre.gov.vn/, accessed
(Kojima, 2013). In the longer run, however, domestic price changes have March 1, 2013).
tracked trends in global benchmark prices (see data at http://energype-
dia.info/wiki/Fuel_Prices_Vietnam, accessed May 8, 2013).
16. More complete details of the model, database and results are
available from the authors.
10. Only EU, Australia, and New Zealand currently have carbon taxes.
Several developing countries have implemented or are proposing taxes on
energy similar to the Vietnamese tax. 17. These and other baseline data reported in the text are calculated from
the 2007 SAM; see Arndt et al. (2010).
11. Calculated at the rate of VND18,000:US$1, and with emissions
coecients of (coal) 2,336 kg CO2e/tonne; (diesel) 2.68 kg CO2e/l;
(gasoline) 2.32 kg CO2e/l. Source for CO2e conversions: http://www.car- 18. It is important to notice that although these predictions are
bontrust.co.uk/cut-carbon-reduce-costs/calculate/carbon-footprinting/ aggregated into the same set of household groups as in Table 6, they
pages/conversion-factors.aspx. are obtained from a dierent data set and are not precisely comparable.

12. The denition of labor supply and the means of measuring it are both
19. Data from World Bank: World Development Indicators Online,
controversial (e.g. Blundell & McCurdy, 2008). Among many key issues
accessed on March 1, 2013.
relevant to our study are the distinction between supply at the intensive

REFERENCES

Abbott, P., Bentzen, J., & Tarp, F. (2009). Trade and development: Blundell, R., & McCurdy, T. (1999). Labour supply: A review of
Lessons from Vietnams past trade agreements. World Development, alternative approaches. In O. Ashenfelter, & D. Card (Eds.).
37(2). Handbook of labor economics (Vol. 3, pp. 15601695). Amsterdam:
Arndt, C., Garcia, A., Pham, Hoang Ha, McCoy, S., Tarp, F., North-Holland.
Thurlow, J. (2010). A 2007 social accounting matrix (SAM) for Blundell, R., & McCurdy, T. (2008). Labour supply. In S. N. Durlauf, &
Vietnam. In Study Prepared under the CIEM-Danida Project L. E. Blume (Eds.), The new Palgrave dictionary of economics (2nd ed.).
Strengthening the Development, Research and Policy Analysis Palgrave Macmillan.
Capacity of CIEM (mimeo). Bovenberg, L., & Goulder, L. (1996). Optimal environmental policies in
Atkinson, A. B., & Stiglitz, J. E. (1980). Lectures on public economics. New the presence of other taxes: General equilibrium analyses. American
York: McGraw-Hill. Economic Review, 86(4), 9851000.
ARE CARBON TAXES GOOD FOR THE POOR? A GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM ANALYSIS FOR VIETNAM 131

Brassard, C. (2004). Wage and labour regulation in Vietnam within the Lofgren, H., Harris, R. L., & Robinson, S. (2002). A standard computable
poverty reduction agenda. Public Policy Programme, National Univer- general equilibrium (CGE) model in GAMS. Washington, DC: Inter-
sity of Singapore, manuscript. national Food Policy Research Institute.
Copeland, B. R., & Taylor, M. S. (2003). Trade and the environment: Metcalf, G. (2008). Environmental taxation: What have we learned in this
Theory and evidence. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. decade?. Conference on tax policy lessons from the 2000s, May 30 2008.
Coxhead, I. (2000). Trade and tax policy reform and the environment in Washington, DC: American Enterprise Institute.
developing economies: Is a double dividend possible? FEEM Working OECD (1994). The distributive eects of economic instruments for
Papers No. 88.2000. Milan. environmental policy. Paris: OECD.
Coxhead, I., Nguyen, Chan V., Wattanakuljarus, Anan, Kim, Tran Thi OECD (1995). Climate change, economic instruments and income distribu-
Dung, Kim, Pho Chi, et al. 2010. A general equilibrium model for the tion. Paris: OECD.
study of globalization, poverty and the environment in Vietnam. Parry, I., Sigman, H., Walls, M., & Williams, R. C., III (2005). The
University of Wisconsin-Madison and National Economics University, incidence of pollution control policies, NBER Working Papers No.
Hanoi, Vietnam. Accessible at: <http://www.aae.wisc.edu/coxhead/ 11438.
papers/VNCGE-ModelDescription.pdf>. Phan, Diep, & Coxhead, I. (2010). Interprovincial migration and
Daitoh, I., & Omote, M. (2011). The optimal environmental tax and urban inequality during Vietnams transition. Journal of Development Eco-
unemployment in an open economy. Review of Development Econom- nomics, 91(1), 100112.
ics, 15(1), 168179. Rosenzweig, M. R. (1980). Neoclassical theory and the optimizing
Datta, A. (2010). The incidence of fuel taxation in India. Energy peasant: An econometric analysis of market family labor supply in
Economics, 32(Suppl. 1), S26S33. a developing country. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 94(1),
El Obeid, A., Van der Mensbrugghe, D., & Dessus, S. (2002). Outward 3155.
orientation, growth, and the environment in Vietnam. In J. Beghin, D. Sahn, D. E., & Alderman, H. (1988). The eects of human capital on
Roland-Holst, & D. van der Mensbrugghe (Eds.), Trade and the wages, and the determinants of labor supply in a developing country.
environment in general equilibrium: Evidence from developing economies. Journal of Development Economics, 29(2), 157183.
Boston: Kluwer Academic Publishers. Sterner, T. (Ed.) (2012). Fuel Taxes and the Poor: The Distributional
Fullerton, D., & Heutel, G. (2007). The general equilibrium incidence of Eects of Gasoline Taxation and Their Implications for Climate Policy.
environmental taxes. Journal of Public Economics, 91(34), 571591. Oxford, UK and Washington DC, USA: RFF Press.
Fullerton, D., & Metcalf, G. (1997). Environmental taxes and the double- UNFCCC (United National Framework Convention on Climate
dividend hypothesis: Did you really expect something for nothing? NBER Change). (2010). CDM Methodology Booklet. <http://cdm.unfcc-
Working Papers No. 6199. c.int/methodologies/documentation/meth_booklet.pdf> Accessed
Fullerton, D., & Metcalf, G. (2002). Tax incidence. NBER Working 23.07.11.
Papers No. 8829. Willenbockel, D. (2011). Environmental tax reforms in Vietnam: An ex
Gale, W. G., Brown, S., & Saltiel, F. (2013). Carbon taxes as part of the scal ante general equilibrium assessment. In Paper for presentation at
solution. Manuscript, Brookings Institution. <http://www.brookings.edu/ Ecomod 2011, University of the Azores, Ponta Delgada, July 2011.
research/papers/2013/03/12-carbon-tax-gale> Accessed 31.03.13. <http://ecomod.net/system/les/EcoMod2011_VietnamEcoTax_0.pdf>
Harrison, W. J., & Pearson, K. R. (1996). Computing solutions for large Accessed 01.08.11.
general equilibrium models using GEMPACK. Computational Eco- World Bank (2010). World Development Report 2010: Development and
nomics, 9, 83127. climate change. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Heckman, J. J. (1993). What has been learned about labor supply in the Yusuf, A. A. (2008). The distributional impact of environmental policy: The
past twenty years?. American Economic Review, Papers and Proceed- case of carbon tax and energy pricing reform in Indonesia. Report No.
ings, 83(2), 116121. 2008-RR1. Singapore: Environment and Economy Program for
Horridge, M. (2005). ORANI-G: A generic single-country computable Southeast Asia Research.
general equilibrium model Edition prepared for the Practical GE Ziramba, E., Kumo, W. L., & Akinbiade, O. A. (2009). Economic
Modelling Course, February 711, 2005. Australia: Centre of Policy instruments for environmental regulation in Africa: An analysis of the
Studies and Impact Project, Monash University. ecacy of fuel taxation for pollution control in South Africa. CEEPA
Kojima, M. (2013). Petroleum product pricing and complementary policies: Discussion Paper No. 44. <http://www.ceepa.co.za/Discussionpaper-
Experience of 65 developing countries since 2009. Washington, DC: no44.pdf> Accessed 02.05.11.
World Bank.

You might also like