You are on page 1of 17

World Development Vol. 93, pp.

108124, 2017
0305-750X/ 2017 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev
http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2016.12.028

Does Local Development Inuence Outmigration Decisions?


Evidence from Indonesia
SMRITI TIWARI*
Skidmore College, Saratoga Springs, USA
Summary. This paper takes advantage of the exogenous phasing of the district-level elections in Indonesia to establish an unbiased
causal impact of local economic development conditions on outmigration decisions. Does the change in service delivery due to decen-
tralization aect the internal migration, a phenomenon not new to Indonesia and driven by the historic uneven development across the
archipelago? Furthermore, because the services are no longer centered in Java and Bali, will the migration to these historically popular
provinces change? If yes, to what extent? This discussion is of central importance not only in the Indonesian context where rising pop-
ulation pressures in Java and Bali provinces are the governments ultimate challenge but also in the development literature, where
empirical research on such questions is made impossible by the lack of appropriate data and context. Two dierent datasets, the Indone-
sian Family Life Survey and the Indonesian Census, are used to conduct the analyses. They provide consistent results. A household in a
district that went through election is 19% less likely to be a migrant-sending household. This is true particularly for districts that are in
Java and Bali. A household in a district in Java and Bali that went through election is 27% less likely to be a migrant-sending household.
2017 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved.

Key words decentralization, local development, outmigration, Indonesia

1. INTRODUCTION exogenous phasing of direct elections in districts to extract the


causal impact. In doing so, this work contributes to current
Many developing countries employ rural development migration literature by using a natural experiment to establish
strategies that focus on employment generation, infrastructure causal validity in the determination of migration decisions
development, access to credit for small farmers, delivery of (Palloni, Massey, & Ceballos, 2001; Munshi, 2003).
health-care services, educational improvement, land reform, After more than three decades of highly centralized govern-
etc. Even though the primary motivation for such interven- ment, Indonesia went through a phased decentralization pro-
tions is improving the quality of life in rural areas, an unin- cess 1 (both scal and political) during which wide-ranging
tended consequence of such programs may be reducing rural responsibilities over basic service delivery for education,
to urban migration. Todaro (1997) and Lipton (1982) claim health, infrastructure, and general public administration were
that rural development programs are an essential solution to devolved to the district governments. The decentralization
deter excessive migration from rural to urban areas. Policy laws, which were passed in 1999 and took eect in 2001,
makers often suggest improving living conditions and diversi- devolved approximately 25% of the national budget to the dis-
fying economic opportunities in rural areas as a remedy to tricts in the form of block grants and dramatically increased
decrease migration to cities, and thus reducing population their authority over almost all sectors of government
pressures in urban centers (Rhoda, 1983). (Skouas, Ambar, Dasgupta, & Kaiser, 2011). Additionally,
However, some analyses show that such programs have not the district heads were selected through direct elections starting
been successful in doing so because rural development activities in 2005. The unique and the most important feature of this pro-
also increase access to cities, strengthen ruralurban integra- cess is that timing of the direct election in a district depended on
tion, and raise education and skill levels. This could lead to the end of the tenure of the previous headwhich was exoge-
an increase in ruralurban migration instead (Adepoju, 1983; nous. Does this change in service delivery due to decentraliza-
Rhoda, 1983; Campbell, 1988; Becker, Hamer, & Morrison, tion aect the internal migration, a phenomenon not new to
1994; Lucas, 1997; ILO, 1998). Beauchemin and Schoumaker Indonesia and driven by the historic uneven development across
(2005) nd mixed results in the context of Burkina Faso. the archipelago? Furthermore, because the increase in service
Depending on the level of analysis, public facilities and infras- delivery is observed particularly in districts outside of Java
tructure have either no eect or are more likely to increase out- and Bali, will the migration from these districts change? If yes,
migration. However, they nd that having markets in villages in what direction and to what extent?
and large companies in secondary towns reduce the risk of The literature that explores the intersection between devel-
moving to big urban cities by about 50%. The discussion on opment and migration provides ample of empirical evidence
the potential impact of local development on migration behav- on how migration may aect dierent development indicators,
iors does not provide clear evidence in the literature. Most of
all, this question is dicult to explore empirically due to the
lack of relevant context and appropriate data to study it. * I would like to thank Dr. Emmanuel Skouas (Lead Economist, Poverty
The primary challenge while studying the migration-
development interactions is that they are not independent of Global Practice, World Bank Group) for his time and suggestions in
each other. This endogenous relationship makes establishing August 2013. I am also extremely grateful to him for sharing the pilkada
causal impact in both directions challenging. In order to over- dataset, without which this study would not have been possible. I also
come the endogeneity issue, this paper takes advantage of the thank Dr. Paul Winters (Professor, Department of Economics, American
University) for his guidance. Final revision accepted: December 18, 2016.
108
DOES LOCAL DEVELOPMENT INFLUENCE OUTMIGRATION DECISIONS?EVIDENCE FROM INDONESIA 109

such as migrants own income and health, education, and 2. CONCEPTUAL FRAMEWORK IN THE INDONE-
health outcomes of children of a migrant sending household, SIAN CONTEXT
and the welfare of the migrant sending community as a whole
(Hildebrandt & McKenzie, 2005; Adams, 2006; Acosta, (a) Internal migration in Indonesia
Fajnzylber, & Lopez, 2007; Yang, 2008; Gibson, Mckenzie,
& Stillman, 2011; Antman, 2011 2). However, empirical According to the literature, internal migration in both colo-
research on the role of economic development in the migrant nial and post-colonial Indonesia points to three factors that
sending community in determining outmigration has been may have played a role in inuencing internal migration. They
slow to emerge. are: (i) income dierential generated due to high colonial
This has been particularly true of decentralization, which is pressures in Java, (ii) transmigration policy undertaken by
less an investment in a particular rural development strategy the Dutch administration, later inherited by the post-
but more a change in the management of rural development. independence Indonesian government, and (iii) the persistence
Decentralization has become more widespread in developing of uneven development across the region due to path depen-
countries 3 as economists and policy makers have increasingly dency of the institutions established by the Dutch rulers.
advocated it as a way to reduce the role of the state in general
by fragmenting central authority and introducing more inter- (i) Income dierential generated due to high colonial pressures in
governmental competition. In countries with many ethnicities, Java 4
decentralization is also regarded as a way of avoiding social The rst reason is the nature of the land in the pre-colonial
and political tensions and ensuring local cultural and political era that resulted in the historically uneven development of the
autonomy (Oates, 1993; Bardhan, 2002). Local governments, Indonesian archipelago. The Inner Indonesia (provinces 2,
with an informational advantage over the national govern- 4, 8, 1012, 34 in Figure 1), with volcanic topography and rich
ment, are in a better position to deliver public services. Empir- agricultural lands, became the center for Dutch rulers as they
ical literature examining the link between decentralization and maintained larger colonial pressures on Java than other parts
local economic development provides evidence of a strong of Indonesia. The concentration of colonial activity in Java led
positive relationship (Santos, 1998; Lin & Liu, 2000; Faguet, to an increased demand for labor, which in turn increased the
2004; Stansel, 2005; Iimi, 2005; Hammond & Tosun, 2011). income dierential between Java and other regions of Indone-
However, decentralization usually takes place in one shot for sia (Hugo, 1980). As a result, Javas population exploded in
the entire country, leaving no possibility for evaluation except the nineteenth century. During 18021900, Javas population
perhaps a before and after analysis, which is most likely to grew, on average, 2.1% annually (Van Lottum & Daan, 2012).
provide biased estimates. The fact that decentralization in
Indonesia was a phased process provides a unique opportunity (ii) Transmigration policy
to undertake a successful evaluation. The second reason is the transmigration policy, established
The empirical analyses are done using two rich and unique by the Dutch in 1905 (then known as kolonisatie or coloniza-
datasetsIndonesian Family Life Survey (IFLS) and the tion) as a means of relieving the population pressure in the
Indonesian Census. These datasets are compiled together with Inner Indonesia by giving people incentives to move to
the Pilkada dataset, assembled by Skouas, Ambar, Outer Islands. 5 Despite being abandoned due to the high
Dasgupta, and Kaiser (2014). The Pilkada dataset contains elec- costs associated with the transmigration policy, and its
toral information from 1999 to 2009 and information about insignicant 6 role in reducing the population pressures in
district-level characteristics. Most importantly, it provides dates inner islands, the policy was reinstated every time for the same
of direct elections for all the districts, which helps to identify the purpose. As a result, Indonesia not only inherited the policy
treated districts. The main outcome variablemigration status, post-independence but also made it a centerpiece of their
comes from IFLS and the census. IFLS is well suited for this development program. Suharto, Indonesias president for
analysis, as it collects detailed current and retrospective infor- almost three decades continued and accelerated the transmi-
mation about the migration histories of individuals. However, gration program. By 1989, a cumulative total of approxi-
the sample is restricted to 13 of the 34 provinces in Indonesia mately one million families, or ve million people, had been
and is representative of 83% of the Indonesian population. shipped to the outer islands as part of the ocial program
The census samples generally cover the entire country but are (Fearnside, 1997).
limited in terms of migration modules, and only provide infor-
mation about whether an individual is in a dierent district (iii) Path dependency of the institutions set up by the Dutch
from ve years prior. Since both datasets have pros and cons rulers
in terms of the information they oer, the results deduced from The concentration of colonial activity in Java led to a num-
analyzing the two separately are complementary. ber of growing urban centers, such as present-day Jakarta,
The results indicate that households in districts that went Surabaya, and Semarang (Hugo, 1980). These cities attracted
through direct elections were signicantly less likely to have people from the crowded interior because of the employment
outmigration than those that did not. This decrease was opportunities they oered (Pelzer, 1945). After the indepen-
mostly driven by the fall in the outmigration from districts dence from the Dutch rulers, the Indonesian government
in Java and Bali. Migration from districts of other provinces remained heavily central to Java, thus maintaining the path
were unaected by the direct elections. of uneven development across Indonesia. Interprovincial
Mechanisms through which local development, spurred by the migration was on the rise throughout twentieth century with
democratization and decentralization, inuences households 7% in 1970, 8.2% in 1990, and 10.1% by 2000 (Hill,
migration decisions (especially in the context of Indonesia) are Resosudarmo, & Vidyattama, 2008; Tirtosudarmo, 2009).
discussed in the following section. Background on the Indone- The inner islands, that constitute 7% of the total land in
sian decentralization process is discussed in Section 3. The rele- Indonesia, have consistently been home to around 60% of
vance of the datasets is discussed in Section 4. In Section 5, the the Indonesian population for the past few decades.
econometric strategies used to analyze the data are described fol- The literature provides some evidence on the relative
lowed by the results in Section 6 and conclusion in section 7. strengths of these three factors. Due to the abandonment of
110 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Figure 1. Administrative map of Indonesia.

the transmigration program after the Asian nancial crisis of more recent data nd opposite results. In the cross-country
1997 and the subsequent transition to democracy, context, Hunther and Shah (1998) provide correlation between
Tirtosudarmo (2009) speculates that migration has become scal decentralization and the quality of governance, which
predominantly a function of the labor market economy and bolsters economic growth. Lin and Liu (2000) and Akai and
was constantly increasing in recent years, driven by the wage Sakata (2002) nd that decentralization contributes to local
dierentials between provinces and the attractiveness of the economic growth in the case of China and United States 9
Jakarta area. Van Lottum and Daan (2012) test the relative respectively. Iimi (2005) highlights the fact that these studies
importance of these three factors for the period during fail to account for the endogeneity issues and oers an instru-
19302000 and nd that the presence of an urban primate mental variable approach. Focusing on the cross-county data
such as Jakarta was the most important determinant of migra- of 51 countries, Iimi (2005) concludes that decentralization is
tion. They nd that migrants tend to base their decisions on instrumental in promoting economic growth.
the more tangible prospect of economic betterment, either in A few studies have explored the role of decentralization in
the shape of improvements of ones expected income or the public service deliverywhich is crucial to local economic
attractiveness of moving to a primate city. development. As earlier mentioned, because decentralization
processes take place in one shot in most countries, studies that
(b) Decentralization and local development 7 evaluate them are unable to capture its unbiased impact.
Santos (1998) and Faguet (2004) respectively provide before
After more than three decades of highly centralized govern- and after evidence from Porto Alegre in Brazil and post-
ment, Indonesia went through a phased decentralization pro- 1994 decentralization initiative in Bolivia. During 1989 and
cessscal decentralization in 2001, and political 1996, access to sanitation and enrollment in elementary and
decentralization starting in 2005. Economists and policy mak- secondary schools more than doubled in Porto Alegre.
ers have increasingly advocated decentralization as a way to Faguet (2004) reports that public investment in education,
reduce the role of the state in general by fragmenting central water, and sanitation rose signicantly in three-quarters of
authority and introducing more intergovernmental competi- all municipalities, and service delivery responded to local
tion. Especially in countries with many ethnicities, decentral- needs with public education expenditure being larger in areas
ization is also regarded as a way of avoiding social and with lower literacy rate or with fewer private schools.
political tensions and ensuring local cultural and political Although these results may be biased, as they capture both
autonomy (Oates, 1993; Bardhan, 2002; Martinez-Vazquez the impact of decentralization and the general trend without
& McNab, 2003). Local governments, with informational decentralization, it seems likely that there has been substantial
advantage over the national government, are more ecient impact on the pattern of resource allocation across localities,
as they are in a better position to deliver public services. As especially in poorer ones. Galasso and Ravallion (2005)
a result, decentralization has become more widespread in employ careful econometrics to show that decentralization
developing countries. 8 improved pro-poor program benets in Bangladesh.
The empirical evidence on the role of decentralization on Apart from the econometric issues, there are a few concep-
economic growth initially did not provide consistent results. tual reasons why we may be seeing dierent results in dierent
In a cross-country study, Davoodi and Zou (1998) nd a sig- contexts. Bardhan (2002) and Martinez-Vazquez and McNab
nicantly negative relationship between decentralization and (2003) argue that decentralization is able to achieve the
growth in developing countries. Zhang and Zou (1998) and intended goals if and only if the structure of local accountabil-
Xie, Zou, and Davoodi (1999) also nd a negative relationship ity is in place and the local governments are not being cap-
in the case of China and the United States respectively. On the tured by the usual local elites. In other words, for
contrary, some empirical work in the same contexts using decentralization to work, it has to be complemented with a
DOES LOCAL DEVELOPMENT INFLUENCE OUTMIGRATION DECISIONS?EVIDENCE FROM INDONESIA 111

change in existing structures of power within communities Rhoda, 1983; Campbell, 1988; Becker et al., 1994; Lucas,
such that there is an improvement in the opportunities for par- 1997; ILO, 1998).
ticipation and engagement of the usually disadvantaged or dis- Given that the role of local development in determining out-
enfranchised in the political process (Bardhan, 2002; Iimi, migration is theoretically ambiguous, it becomes crucial to
2005). There is some empirical evidence on the impact of man- empirically test it in the Indonesian context. Would the
dated representations of historically disadvantaged groups like improvement in service delivery and local development condi-
women (Chattopadhyay & Duo, 2004) and landless house- tions at the district level, as a result of decentralization and
holds (Foster & Rosenzweig, 2004). democratization, alter the existing migration pattern? If yes,
In the case of Indonesia, Skouas et al. (2011) nd that the in what direction?
directly elected district heads become more responsive to local Due to the historical reasons discussed earlier, the develop-
needs at least in the area of health. Skouas et al. (2014) nd ment pattern in Indonesia is very uneven. Districts outside of
that the political decentralization increased the district govern- Java and Bali have been much less developed with fewer and
ments expenditure in general, but was most pronounced lower quality public services and amenities than those in the
specically in the sectors of education, housing, and agricul- islands of Java and Bali. There are dierences in the levels
ture. They conclude that the success of political decentraliza- of development even within the islands of Java and Bali.
tion that started in 2005 in increasing expenditures is in part For example, the districts in Jakarta are much more developed
because the scal decentralization was already in place starting than those in other parts of Java. It is also clear from the his-
in 2001. They argue that political decentralization is capable of torical migration patterns of Indonesia that migrants tend to
strengthening the incentives of local governments to better uti- base their decisions to migrate on the prospect of economic
lize the opportunities provided by the scal decentralization. betterment (Van Lottum & Daan, 2012). Not surprisingly,
The results from Kis-Katos and Sjahrir (2014) also conrm the direction of migration in Indonesia has been from outer
the importance of scal decentralization of 2001 in increasing islands to inner islands of Java and Bali and migration ow
expenditure in the sectors of education, health and physical within the islands of Java and Bali is toward Jakarta.
infrastructure. Soejoto, Subroto, and Suyanto (2015) nd that In addition to assessing the general impact of direct elections
decentralization in Indonesia had a positive impact on public on public spending, Skouas et al. (2014) also investigated if
expenditure, economic growth, and human development index. there was any heterogeneity of impacts between the inner
According to Sen (1989), development is the process of and the outer islands. They nd that the overall positive eect
expanding the substantive freedoms that people enjoy. Expen- of electoral reforms on public spending was primarily due to
diture in areas such as education, health, food, medicine and increases in the districts outside Java and Bali. If the new dis-
housing, as well as community projects in education, health, trict heads outside of Java and Bali are responding to the
and recreational facilities, should be seen as development as needs of their respective districts by investing more in educa-
long as they enhance peoples wellbeing and capabilities. tion, health, housing, and agriculture, what can be expected
Another aspect that is important to discuss here is the time to happen to the outmigration from these districts? Would
frame within which decentralization could inuence local that be dierent from the outmigration patterns from the dis-
development conditions. Faguets (2004) evaluation of Boli- tricts in islands of Java and Bali?
vias historic decentralization in 1994, based on a dataset from It is important to note that the relative economic benet for
1987 to 1996, nds the above-mentioned positive impacts after a move from outer islands to inner islands is much higher than
just two years. The success in education and sanitation is seen that from a district in Java and Bali to Jakarta. As a result, the
within seven years in Porto Alegre, Brazil (Santos, 1998). The economic conditions in districts of outer islands would have to
positive changes due to the political reservation policy for improve a lot more than that in districts of inner islands in
women in India come eight years after the policy was put in order for potential migrants to be indierent to migrate.
place in 1992. In the case of Indonesia, positive eects are vis- And, it will take much more time for districts of outer islands
ible as quickly as four years after the rst direct elections in to get there than for those of inner islands. Since the data used
2005 (Skouas et al., 2014) and eight years after the scal for the analyses are only three (IFLS) and ve (census) years
decentralization in 2001 (Kis-Katos & Sjahrir, 2014). In that after the direct elections, the results might be constrained by
way, it can be said that as the districts increase spending in time, especially for assessing outmigration from districts of
the sector of health, education, housing, agriculture, and outer islands. At the same time, the local development condi-
physical infrastructure as a result of scal and political decen- tions and migration are theoretically jointly determined. In
tralization, local economic conditions at the district level other words, they are not independent of each other or they
improve. are simultaneously occurring at the same time (De Haas,
2010). Hence, local development spurred by the decentraliza-
(c) Local development and outmigration tion process could inuence outmigration decisions within a
short period that data is available for.
An improvement in local development conditions through To summarize, the goal of this paper is to empirically
employment generation, infrastructure development, access explore the extent to which local development, spurred by
to credit for small farmers, delivery of health-care services, the democratization and decentralization at the district level,
educational improvement, land reform, etc., could reduce aects outmigration. Separate analyses are undertaken to
rural to urban migration. This seems intuitive because people assess whether there is a dierence in the outmigration pattern
migrate in expectation of nding a better or more stable liveli- from districts in outer islands and those in inner islands.
hood, and of improving their social and economic status
(Lipton, 1982; Stark, 1991; Todaro, 1997). As the economic
10
conditions improve, there is less incentive to migrate to a dif- 3. DECENTRALIZATION IN INDONESIA
ferent place. However, it can also be argued that local develop-
ment increases access to cities, strengthen ruralurban Figure 2 shows a timeline of the Indonesian decentralization
integration, and raise education and skill levels. This could process. For over three decades (19651998), Indonesia was
lead to an increase in outmigration instead (Adepoju, 1983; under a highly centralized and autocratic government (New
112 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

ulating that (s)he would be directly elected by citizens, and


provided a clearer denition of the heads political functioning
(Skouas et al., 2014). Based on the new Pilkada amendment,
the government decided to conduct the rst batch of direct
elections in June 2005 in the districts where the tenure of the
indirectly elected (by DPRD) district heads were ending. The
rst batch of direct elections concerned all the regional head
positions that had opened between December 2004 and April
2005. If the tenure of any DPRD head was due to end in the
rst few months of 2005, the government extended their terms
up to the direct elections. In some districts, a caretaker govern-
ment had been appointed prior to the December 2004 law,
who were allowed to serve till the elections. By June 2005,
155 districts had directly elected heads.
During 2001 and 2007, the number of districts increased from
336 to 434, and new district head positions opened up in the
newly created child districts. Given that it is dicult to compare
Figure 2. Phased in decentralization. the migration levels of districts aected by splits, this analysis
covers only those districts that are unaected by splits.
Table A2 provides the number of districts that held direct elec-
Order) under President Suharto. Despite that, the regime did tions during 200507. By 2007, 304 out of a total of 434 dis-
allow local political representation and local government. trictsincluding undivided and split districtshad held
Local governments in Indonesia were comprised of a regional direct elections. Among the 238 districts that remained undivided
head, executive agencies, and the local assembly (DPRD). during 200509, 163 districts had held direct elections for district
During Suhartos regime, the local government representatives heads by 2007, including 101 districts that did so in 2005 12.
were chosen from a closed list of candidates (mostly military) The most important feature of this process for the purpose
by the Ministry of Home aairs. As a result, majority of basic of this analysis is that the timing of the direct elections for
service delivery at the local level was still centrally controlled undivided local governments is random. The key reason
and these local governments depended on earmarks and dis- behind the phasing of the direct elections is the fact that the
cretionary transfers as well as their own sources of limited rev- regional governments in Indonesia were established at dier-
enues (Malley, 2003). ent times since its independence. Hence, the ve-year tenure
As the Indonesian economy grew, there were growing pres- cycle of the district heads was dierent for dierent districts
sures for democratization and decentralization, especially after (Pratikno, 2009).
the Asian Financial Crisis. This ultimately led to the downfall
of New Order regime in 1998 and subsequently, in June 1999,
Indonesia held its rst relatively free and fair elections in 4. DATA
34 years. The process created a new batch of more assertive
local legislatures (DPRD) and transferred the role of basic ser- Several datasets are compiled together to conduct this anal-
vice delivery to the district governments as opposed to pro- ysis. First, the Pilkada dataset, assembled by Skouas et al.
vinces (World Bank, 2003). The local legislatures had the (2014), oers electoral information for the period 19992009.
general oversight of a larger consolidated local budget It provides the most relevant information for this analysis,
(APBD) only in 2001. This round of elections is referred to i.e., whether or not a district had undergone direct elections
as indirect because the election appointed the local legislatures (treatment) by 2005 or not. It also provides detailed informa-
who in turn selected local heads. Unlike Suhartos era, the new tion on district characteristics, some of which are used as con-
legislatures could choose from more open lists of candidates, trol variables. A district is considered treated if it went
and faced less interference from the Ministry of Home Aairs through direct elections between June and December of 2005
(Decree No. 22/1999). The 1999 DPRD also had the right to and control if it did not. Among the 238 districts that did
impeach local heads, which meant a premature end of their not split, 101 districts went through direct elections between
terms. The ve-year tenure cycle of the local heads could only June and December of 2005. The 62 districts that held it dur-
be interrupted by death, illness, a no-condence vote, or the ing 200607 are omitted from the analyses for two reasons.
creation of a new district. However, because the 1999 DPRD First, enough time needed to have passed between the treat-
also had the right to impeach local heads and end their terms, ment period (JuneDecember 2005) and the post-treatment
the timing of the ve-year tenure cycle could dier across local survey (2008 for IFLS). Secondly, omitting these districts from
governments. The political powers of the local legislatures to the analyses is justied because they can possibly belong to
select, control, and even dismiss local heads raised concerns either the treatment or control groups and including them is
on two fronts. First, DPRD seemed to overreach their powers likely to bias the impacts of direct elections. In summary,
that blurred the roles of the legislative and executive agencies. migration behavior of households in 101 districts that had
Second, DPRDs politics gave way to corruption among the elections in the treatment period is being compared with that
legislatures and local heads. Regional heads were found to of households in 75 districts that did not have elections until
be accepting and distributing bribes to secure and maintain after post-treatment survey.
oce of the head of local governments 11 (Mietzner, 2007). To establish causality, the fact that the direct elections were
The concerns about indirect political accountability led to in fact exogenous and can be used as a natural experiment
the second wave of local government electoral reform toward needs to be established (Meyer, 1995; Robinson, McNulty,
direct elections (Pilkada Langsung) under Law No. 32/2004 & Krasno, 2009). The exogeneity of the treatment relies on
(Erb & Sulistiyanto, 2009; Schiller, 2009). This reform made two features: (a) direct elections in 2005 and later were held
the local head more directly accountable to the people by stip- in the districts where the terms of the previous district heads
DOES LOCAL DEVELOPMENT INFLUENCE OUTMIGRATION DECISIONS?EVIDENCE FROM INDONESIA 113

were coming to full term, and (b) the cross-district variation in Table 1b presents the marginal eects from the second
when the previous district heads term ended was due to the probit model of whether a district had an indirectly
historical dierences in the timing of election (indirectly by appointed district head in 2000, as this was the year with
DRPD) or appointment (under the New order system) of that the highest proportion (36%) of district heads appointed
individual. indirectly by the local district parliaments (DPRD) after
In order to prove the exogeneity of the direct elections, two passing of the law (Law No. 22/1999). The explanatory vari-
probit models are analyzed. Table 1a presents the marginal ables include: characteristics related to the district economy
eects from the rst probit model on whether a district has in 2000; share of urban population in the district in 2000;
had direct elections during 200507 (as per Law 34/2004). whether a district is classied administratively as a rural or
The explanatory variables include: characteristics related to an urban district; share of various sectors such as agricul-
the district economy in 2005; share of urban population in ture, service, mining, manufacturing, and nance to total dis-
the district in 2005; whether a district is classied administra- trict GDP; distances to province capital and Jakarta; and
tively as a rural or an urban district; share of various sectors regional xed eects.
such as agriculture, service, mining, manufacturing, and The rst column in Tables 1a and 1b reports results for all
nance to total district GDP; distances to province capital the districts, while the second column reports results for the
and Jakarta; and regional xed eects. 238 districts that did not split. For both models, almost

Table 1a. Marginal eects of the determinants of direct elections in districts in Indonesia
Dependent Variable: Treatment = 1 if District had a direct election between 2005 and 2007; Treatment = 0 otherwise
All districts Undivided districts
Unemployment rate in 2004 0.0044 0.0112
(0.792) (0.574)
Ln per capita Real GDP, 2005 0.0122 0.0532
(0.880) (0.568)
Share of Electricity to total GRDP, 2005 1.116 0.734
(0.746) (0.845)
Share of Mining to total GRDP, 2005 0.336 0.311
(0.376) (0.472)
Share of Agriculture to total GRDP, 2005 0.0044 0.275
(0.992) (0.570)
Share of Manufacturing to total GRDP, 2005 0.242 0.197
(0.540) (0.644)
Share of Construction to total GRDP, 2005 1.389 1.951*
(0.144) (0.093)
Share of Financial Services to total GRDP, 2005 0.576 0.248
(0.698) (0.873)
Share of Services to total GRDP, 2005 0.323 0.412
(0.611) (0.553)
Distance from district to Provinces capital 0.000 0.000
(0.257) (0.938)
Distance from district to Jakarta 0.000 0.0002*
(0.210) (0.075)
To Provinces capital, by Ocean or Land 0.0187 0.0029
(0.854) (0.982)
To Jakarta, by Ocean or Land 0.0077 0.0075
(0.950) (0.954
(1 = Kota; 0 = Kabupaten) 0.248 0.257
(0.116) (0.143)
Sumatera Island 0.002 0.0771
(0.988) (0.602)
Kalimantan Island 0.114 0.120
(0.460) (0.484)
Sulawesi Island 0.269 0.386**
(0.103) (0.041)
Nusa Tenggara & Maluku Island 0.351** 0.360*
(0.047) (0.086)
Papua Island 0.700** 0.640
(0.021) (0.127)
Urbanization (share of population that is urban), Susenas 2005 0.378 0.371*
(0.114) (0.178)
Share of villages in the district with asphalt road in 2005 0.0149 0.186
(0.923) (0.306)
Observations 315 222
*** ** *
Note: Robust standard errors adjusted for clustering at the province level; p < 0.001, p < 0.05, p < 0.1. p-Values are in parentheses.
114 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Table 1b. Marginal Eects of the determinants of indirect elections in districts in Indonesia
Dependent Variable: Treatment = 1 if District had a head who was indirectly elected in 2000; Treatment = 0 otherwise
All districts Undivided districts
Unemployment rate in 1999 0.0395 0.0304
(0.198) (0.340)
Ln per capita Real GDP, 2000 0.106 0.0778
(0.295) (0.455)
Share of Electricity to total GRDP, 2000 0.997 1.887
(0.846) (0.743)
Share of Mining to total GRDP, 2000 0.053 0.026
(0.922) (0.967)
Share of Agriculture to total GRDP, 2000 0.428 0.283
(0.441) (0.626)
Share of Manufacturing to total GRDP, 2000 0.330 0.0625
(0.527) (0.907)
Share of Construction to total GRDP, 2000 0.633 2.494
(0.606) (0.108)
Share of Financial Services to total GRDP, 2000 2.164 1.518
(0.212) (0.408)
Share of Services to total GRDP, 2000 0.149 0.628
(0.860) (0.507)
Distance from district to Provinces capital 0.000 0.000
(0.901) (0.525)
Distance from district to Jakarta 0.000 0.0004***
(0.127) (0.005)
To Provinces capital, by Ocean or Land 0.119 0.219
(0.412) (0.280)
To Jakarta, by Ocean or Land 0.0955 0.118
(0.514) (0.549)
(1 = Kota; 0 = Kabupaten) 0.118 0.207
(0.586) (0.337)
Sumatera Island 0.116 0.039
(0.473) (0.842)
Kalimantan Island 0.299 0.372
(0.113) (0.112)
Sulawesi Island 0.411** 0.591***
(0.032) (0.008)
Nusa Tenggara & Maluku Island 0.364** 0.623***
(0.089) (0.011)
Papua Island

Urbanization (share of population that is urban), Susenas 2005 0.259 0.0139


(0.430) (0.970)
Share of villages in the district with asphalt road in 2005 0.0348 0.282
(0.862) (0.270)
Observations 226 164
*** **
Note: Robust standard errors adjusted for clustering at the province level; p < 0.001, p < 0.05, *p < 0.1. p-values are in parentheses.

all district-level characteristics are insignicant for both living in 13 of the 27 provinces in the country and the sample
specications, conrming that whether a district had an is representative of 83% of the Indonesian population. Cur-
indirect election in 2000 and whether a district had a direct rently, four IFLS waves have been conducted, respectively in
election in 2005 are independent of the district-level character- 1993, 1997, 2000, and 2007/2008. IFLS dataset has had above
istics that can potentially be inuential in determining migra- 90% re-contact rates in every follow-up wave, making it rich
tion. These results support the exogeneity of the direct and informative. The most important IFLS feature for the
elections, and hence, allow for causal inferences in the analyses purposes of this analysis is that it collects both current and ret-
performed using their variation in the districts as a natural rospective information about the lives of the respondents. The
experiment. dependent variablehousehold 13 migration statusis identi-
The main outcome variablemigration statuscomes from ed mostly from the retrospective information collected as a
two sets of datasets: Indonesian Family life Survey (IFLS) and part of migration history survey. Detailed information on
the Indonesian Census. Both datasets have pros and cons in household and household heads characteristics is also avail-
terms of the information they oer. Thus, the results deduced able. The 2000 and 200708 waves are used for the analysis.
from separately analyzing the two dierent datasets are com- Because IFLS constitutes of only 13 out of the 34 provinces
plementary. The IFLS, conducted by RAND Corporation in in Indonesia, the analysis based upon it may not present the
collaboration with several universities, is an ongoing survey. entire picture. To incorporate all of the 34 provinces, the
The longitudinal survey collects information on individuals Indonesian census is used to do a separate analysis.
DOES LOCAL DEVELOPMENT INFLUENCE OUTMIGRATION DECISIONS?EVIDENCE FROM INDONESIA 115

The Central Bureau of Statistics (Indonesia) has been collect- period (t = 0) is the same duration of time between January
ing population census every ten years and intercensal popula- 2002 and May 2005. A household is considered a migrant-
tion survey every ve years since 1971 14. The 10% sample of sending household in a period t if at least one member of
2010 census and the 0.51% sample of 2005 intercensal popula- the household has migrated for at least six months.
tion survey are used for the analysis. 15 The census collects The IFLS dataset also contains retrospective information on
information on all people, Indonesian and foreign residing migrants who had returned by the time of the survey as well.
in the territorial area of Indonesia, regardless of the residence This feature is useful not only because it helps include migrants
status while the intercensal survey collects information on per- who would otherwise not be identied, but also because it
manent residents only. The surveys have individuals demo- makes the construction of a panel over two periods possible.
graphic information, their social and economic activities, A total of 12,692 households living in 263 districts 16 were sur-
and their household characteristics. However, the migration veyed in the fourth wave of IFLS. Out of the 263 districts rep-
module in the census does not provide a detailed account of resented in IFLS, 137 districts did not split and did not go
individuals migration history. The questionnaire only asks through direct elections between January 2006 and December
where the individual was ve years ago. The migration vari- 2007. A balanced panel over two periods with 5,086 households
able is constructed by checking whether one is in a dierent in each period is constructed for the analysis. The sample attri-
district now than they are 5 years ago. This could be problem- tion is not systematic, implying that there are no unique char-
atic in the identication of people who migrated within the acteristics among those who do not appear in the fourth wave.
5 years period. For example, if an individual had migrated Around 57% of the households lived in districts that went
during 200609, it would not be recorded using the census. through direct elections between June and December of 2005.
Hence, the census will be useful in understanding a longer-
term migration pattern while the IFLS will be crucial in under- (b) Census
standing temporary migration. Each dataset is discussed in
detail below. Figure 4 oers a chronology of the collection of datasets and
the identication strategy for migrant sending households for
(a) Indonesian family life survey the census sample. The treatment period is June to December
of 2005. The 2010 census was conducted in May of 2010 and
Figure 3 oers a chronology of the collection of datasets and the 2005 census was conducted in June 2005. 17 The period
the identication strategy for migrant sending households for between the 2000 and 2005 Census is considered the pre-
IFLS. As discussed earlier, the treatment period is June to treatment period (t = 0) and the period between the 2005
December of 2005. The fourth wave of IFLS was conducted and 2010 Census is considered the post-treatment period
between November 2007 and May 2008. The post treatment (t = 1). A household is considered a migrant-sending house-
period (t = 1) is considered to be the period of 29 months hold in a period t if at least one member of the household
between January 2006 and May 2008 and the pre-treatment has migrated for at least six months.

Figure 3. Timeline for Indonesian family life survey.

Figure 4. Timeline for census.


116 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Among the 238 districts that did not split, 101 districts went In addition to showing that the treatment was random, the
through direct elections between June and December of 2005. descriptive statistics and the results of the test of dierences in
The 62 districts that held elections during 200607 are omitted means of household, household heads characteristics, district-
from the analyses to avoid any contamination. This leaves a level characteristics, and the household migration behavior in
total of 176 18 districts, all of which are represented in the cen- IFLS baseline and census baseline are respectively presented in
sus. A total of 114,482 households from these 174 districts Tables 2 and 3. Most of the variables, such as household
appear in the 2005 census sample while a total of 3,360,798 heads age, education, gender, and marital status are self-
households from these 174 districts appear in 2010 census sam- explanatory. Some that need explanations are discussed
ple 19. Hence, a repeated cross-sectional data over two periods below. As Islam is the most practiced religion in Indonesia,
is constructed. In 2005, around 58% of the households lived in the religion variable takes on a value of 1 if the household
districts that went through direct elections between June and head is a Muslim and 0 if they practice any other religion.
December of 2005. The oor is considered concrete if they are made up of

Table 2. Summary statistics by treatment status for IFLS


Control Treatment Test of dierence Bias
Mean Standard Deviation Mean Standard Deviation
A. Controls
Household heads Characteristics
Age 45.96 14.49 45.59 14.87 0.378 15.66
Gender 0.785 0.411 0.814 0.383 0.001 27.50
Marital Status 0.813 0.389 0.832 0.373 0.076 24.33
No Education 0.165 0.371 0.116 0.320 0.000 36.91
Some Education 0.753 0.43 0.813 0.39 0.000 46.85
Undergraduate and above 0.080 0.272 0.071 0.257 0.200 14.28
Religion is Islam 0.93 0.254 0.872 0.334 0.000 37.81
Household Characteristics
Household size 5.50 2.69 5.28 2.506 0.002 31.82
Concrete Floor 0.765 0.424 0.701 0.458 0.000 52.27
Toilet 0.663 0.473 0.629 0.483 0.015 49.18
Electricity 0.918 0.273 0.893 0.308 0.002 24.79
District Characteristics
Unemployment rate in 2002 0.0519 0.0179 0.049 0.0178 0.4970 217.06
Ln per capita Real GDP, 2003 15.43 0.695 15.35 0.602 0.447 32.57
Share of Electricity to total GRDP, 2003 0.012 0.008 0.011 0.013 0.755 13.80
Share of Mining to total GRDP, 2003 0.0459 0.137 0.0473 0.130 0.955 4.579
Share of Agriculture to total GRDP, 2003 0.269 0.203 0.284 0.191 0.662 30.85
Share of Manufacturing to total GRDP, 2003 0.195 0.184 0.155 0.137 0.128 46.05
Share of Construction to total GRDP, 2003 0.0449 0.0246 0.0526 0.0314 0.108 55.80
Share of Financial Services to total GRDP, 2003 0.051 0.0279 0.054 0.0343 0.555 21.26
Share of Services to total GRDP, 2003 0.114 0.060 0.128 0.0638 0.173 91.28
Distance from district to Provinces capital 83.97 52.86 84.45 61.15 0.960 2.208
Distance from district to Jakarta 657.34 480.49 764.4 421.41 0.234 65.59
To Provinces capital, by Ocean(1) or Land(0) 0.0323 0.178 0.024 0.152 0.750 12.67
To Jakarta, by Ocean(1) or Land(0) 0.452 0.502 0.553 0.500 0.228 319.07
(1 = Kota; 0 = Kabupaten) 0.290 0.457 0.305 0.463 0.840 28.55
Urbanization (share of population that is urban), Susenas 2003 0.493 0.328 0.468 0.353 0.673 27.09
Share of villages in the district with asphalt road in 2003 0.7094 0.246 0.722 0.231 0.760 21.06

B. Overall Migration
Pre-treatment Migration 0.137 0.343 0.1586 0.365 0.0282
Post-treatment Migration 0.1405 0.347 0.138 0.345 0.831

C. Migration from Java and Bali


Pre-treatment Migration 0.123 0.328 0.155 0.361 0.009
Post-treatment Migration 0.125 0.331 0.124 0.329 0.925
D. Migration from other regions
Pre-treatment Migration 0.167 0.373 0.165 0.371 0.912
Post-treatment Migration 0.176 0.381 0.161 0.367 0.397
Number of Observations by treatment 2,205 2,881
Total Number of Observations (per period)a 5,086
a
IFLS consisted of 147 districts that did not split and did not go through direct elections in 2006 and 2007. Out of the 147, 85 had direct elections between
June and December 2005. Out of the 87 districts in Java and Bali, 47 districts had gone through direct elections between June and December of 2005. And
out of the 60 districts in other regions, 38 districts went through direct elections between June and December of 2005.
DOES LOCAL DEVELOPMENT INFLUENCE OUTMIGRATION DECISIONS?EVIDENCE FROM INDONESIA 117

Table 3. Summary statistics by treatment status for census


Control Treatment Test of dierence Bias
Mean Standard Deviation Mean Standard Deviation
A. Controls
Household heads Characteristics
Age 46.00 13.85 46.19 13.87 0.024 36.08
Gender 0.861 0.346 0.867 0.339 0.008 12.25
Marital Status 0.832 0.374 0.838 0.368 0.004 12.72
No Education 0.122 0.327 0.119 0.324 0.245 9.60
Some Education 0.758 0.429 0.769 0.422 0.000 20.15
Undergraduate and above 0.121 0.326 0.112 0.315 0.000 15.15
Household Characteristics
Household size 4.04 1.76 3.98 1.73 0.000 26.22
Concrete Floor 0.887 0.317 0.875 0.330 0.000 18.5
Toilet 0.789 0.407 0.792 0.405 0.286 10.52
Rural 0.523 0.499 0.547 0.498 0.000 107.49
District Characteristics
Unemployment rate in 1999 0.0302 0.0169 0.0286 0.0172 0.5625 70.74
Ln per capita Real GDP, 2000 15.23 0.663 15.21 0.589 0.859 9.29
Share of Electricity to total GRDP, 2000 0.010 0.008 0.009 0.011 0.778 18.73
Share of Mining to total GRDP, 2000 0.0567 0.172 0.0505 0.134 0.798 8.13
Share of Agriculture to total GRDP, 2000 0.283 0.212 0.295 0.194 0.677 19.85
Share of Manufacturing to total GRDP, 2000 0.173 0.179 0.151 0.137 0.344 27.00
Share of Construction to total GRDP, 2000 0.0475 0.0282 0.0532 0.0334 0.236 45.04
Share of Financial Services to total GRDP, 2000 0.0484 0.029 0.0504 0.0327 0.680 18.71
Share of Services to total GRDP, 2000 0.119 0.060 0.129 0.067 0.289 47.43
Distance from district to Provinces capital 99.38 89.48 92.85 78.01 0.609 21.06
Distance from district to Jakarta 838.75 636.38 875.08 518.37 0.679 13.91
To Provinces capital, by Ocean(1) or Land(0) 0.067 0.251 0.0505 0.220 0.652 19.31
To Jakarta, by Ocean(1) or Land(0) 0.547 0.501 0.616 0.489 0.359 89.52
(1 = Kota; 0 = Kabupaten) 0.307 0.464 0.313 0.466 0.928 19.67
Urbanization (share of population that is urban), Susenas 2000 0.501 0.332 0.445 0.352 0.304 67.71
Share of villages in the district with asphalt road in 2000 0.698 0.241 0.683 0.251 0.683 30.24

B. Overall Migration
Pre-treatment Migration 0.086 0.2804 0.0909 0.288 0.004
Post-treatment Migration 0.084 0.277 0.0749 0.263 0.000

C. Migration from Java and Bali


Pre-treatment Migration 0.0729 0.259 0.077 0.266 0.051
Post-treatment Migration 0.0805 0.272 0.066 0.249 0.000

D. Migration from other regions


Pre-treatment Migration 0.104 0.306 0.105 0.307 0.726
Post-treatment Migration 0.095 0.294 0.096 0.295 0.417
Number of Observations by treatment 48,510 65,972
Total Number of Observations (per period)a 114,482
a
Census consisted of all the 174 districts that did not split and did not go through direct elections in 2006 and 2007. Out of the 176, 101 had direct elections
between June and December 2005.

ceramic, marble, granite, stone, tiles, terrazzo, cement, or ent from the districts that did not go through direct elections.
bricks. The district-level controls include: characteristics Rosenbaum and Rubin (1985) have suggested an alternative
related to the district economy (per capita GDP and unem- for assessing whether a comparable counterfactual has been
ployment rate); share of urban population; whether the district found. The process entails the estimation of bias by examining
is classied administratively as a rural or an urban district; the standardized dierence in means and is dened as below:
share of various sectors such as agriculture, service, mining,  
 
manufacturing, and nance to total district GDP; distances X  X 
 T C 
to province capital and Jakarta; and regional xed eects. bias 100   q  1
 s2T s2C 
Based on the test of dierences in means of the household  2

and household heads characteristics, the treatment and con-
trol households look signicantly dierent in both datasets. where X T and sT are the mean value and standard deviation
However, the districts that went through direct elections for the exogenous factor for the treatment group being consid-
between June and December of 2005 are not statistically dier- ered and X T and sT are similarly dened for the control group.
118 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Bias is simply the normalized dierence in mean between two and control households may give a biased estimate of the
groups in absolute value. Unlike the raw dierence in means, it impact.
accounts for the dierences in sample sizes and standard devi- The bias arises if there are unobserved characteristics that
ations between control and treatment groups. As evident from aect the probability of participation in the program that
Tables 2 and 3, there is a variation in sample size and standard are also correlated with the outcome of interest (migration,
deviations between the two groups. Rubin (2001) suggests that in this case). In order to get an unbiased estimate of the impact
a bias less than 25% provides evidence that the counterfactual of the program, three sources of bias need to be accounted for:
is reliable. We nd that the bias is higher than 25% for more observable dierences, time-invariant unobservable dier-
than half of the characteristics in IFLS and for a third of ences, and time-variant unobservable dierences between the
the characteristics in the census. In addition, the two methods treatment and control groups. Dierence in dierence with
do not provide consistent results. For example, the test of dif- conditioning variables 20 is used because it accounts for the
ferences in means shows that based on strictly all district-level rst two sources. By denition, dierence-in-dierence method
characteristics, the treatment and control districts are not sta- controls for the time-invariant unobservable dierences
tistically dierent. However, bias calculation shows a bias of between control and treatment because the time-invariant
more than 25% for many of these characteristics. In order to unobservable dierences are canceled out by taking the dier-
get an unbiased estimate of the impact, dierence in dierence ence in outcomes over time (Meyer, 1995; Wooldridge, 2010;
with conditioning variables approach is employed. The above- Gertler, Martinez, Premand, Rawlings, & Vermeerch, 2011).
described biases are accounted for by controlling for the dier- Inclusion of these variables not only controls for any remain-
ences in observables between treated and control groups. ing dierences between households prior to the direct elections
Part B of Tables 2 and 3 consists of the pre-treatment and but also increases precision of the estimates (Angrist &
post-treatment migration outcomes for the entire sample of Pischke, 2008).
IFLS and the census, respectively. For both of these samples, The last source of bias could arise from the violation of the
the migration patterns are statistically dierent in the pre- key identifying assumption (parallel trend assumption) of the
treatment period with a slightly higher average migration from dierence in dierence method. This assumption postulates
the treatment districts. In the IFLS sample, the migration rate that there are not any time-variant observable dierences
barely increased for the control districts while it decreased for between treatment and control group. In other words, in the
the treatment in the post-treatment period. As a result, the absence of the treatment, the trend in treatment and control
migration patterns are not statistically dierent in the post would have been the same. The parallel trend assumption is
treatment period. For the census, however, migration rates tested in two ways. First, average migration rates from 1990
slightly decreased in both treatment and control districts and to 2008 for the treatment and control groups are plotted as
remain statistically dierent in the post-treatment period. shown in Figure A1 in the Appendix. Migration rate is steady
Part C reports the same statistics for districts in Java and for both groups until June of 2005 (treatment). After the treat-
Bali. The averages for these regions in the IFLS sample ment, however, there is a fall in the migration rate for the
matched that of the entire sample in IFLS. On the other hand, treatment group but a slight increase among the control
in the census sample, migration rate increased from the control group. But because the average migration rates between these
districts while it decreased from the treatment districts. two groups are not very dierent before the treatment, the
Although the changes are very small, the migration rate of graph does not show a clear parallel trend. Thus, additionally,
the treated districts is signicantly dierent from that of the a placebo test is performed as a second test by redoing the dif-
control districts in both periods. Lastly, Part D reports the ference in dierence method with pre-treatment period as
pre-treatment and post-treatment migration outcomes for dis- time = 1 and a period prior to the pre-treatment as time = 0.
tricts outside of Java and Bali. The migration rates from the The placebo dierence-in-dierence estimate is not dierent
regions outside of Java and Bali were higher than those from from zero. This implies that the parallel trend assumption
Java and Bali, which is consistent with the historical internal holds and time-variant unobservable dierences do not exist
migration pattern in Indonesia. In the IFLS sample, migration in this case (Khandker, Koolwal, & Samad, 2010) (Results
rate increased for the control districts while it decreased provided in Table A1).
slightly for the treated districts. And, in the census, migration The following model captures the impact of the direct elec-
rate decreased for both groups. Additionally, migration pat- tion on the households decisions to migrate:
terns for the two groups are not statistically dierent for both
periods in both samples. M it b0 b1 T ij b2 t b3 T ij  t cK it dLjt
it 2
(c) Econometric specication
where Mit is a binary variable that takes a value of 1 if any
The goal of this paper is to study the relationship between member from household, i, migrated in period t and 0 if
local development and households outmigration behavior. not. The period, t is equal to 0 for the pre-treatment period
For this purpose, the exogenous direct elections held at the and 1 for the post-treatment period. Hence, this model design
district level are used as a natural experiment. In order to entails two observations for each household i: one for the
assess the households migration behavior as a response to baseline period and one for the post treatment period. The
the increase in the expenditure at the district level after the variable, Tij, is also a binary variable that takes a value of 1
direct election, migration behavior in households that if the household i belongs to a district j that went through
belonged to the district that went through the direct elections direct elections between June and December of 2005 (treat-
should be compared to what migration behavior would have ment) and 0 if it does not. The variable, t * Tij, is the interac-
been had the districts not gone through direct elections. The tion of time and treatment, and Kit is a vector of control
identication of this unobserved counterfactual is the well- variables such as household and household heads characteris-
known challenge in impact evaluation literature. Measuring tics in time t. Ljt is a vector of district characteristics, and 2it is
impact as the dierence in mean outcomes between treatment the random error.
DOES LOCAL DEVELOPMENT INFLUENCE OUTMIGRATION DECISIONS?EVIDENCE FROM INDONESIA 119

Figure A1. Test of parallel trend assumption.

This equation is estimated using a probit regression. Robust period. The marginal eect associated with the time variable
standard errors are estimated and intra-cluster correlations are is negative and statistically signicant only when household
accounted for by clustering the standard errors at the province and household head characteristics are controlled for in col-
level in all the regressions. In this equation, b1 captures the umn (2). This implies that levels of migration have decreased
time-invariant unobservable dierences between treatment in both treatment and control groups over this period but
and control households, and b2 captures any general trends the signicance of the trend disappears once district and regio-
over time not caused by the treatment status. The coecient nal controls are introduced in column (3). The marginal eects
of interest, b3, is an estimate of impact as it captures the dier- associated with the treatment variable are positive suggesting
ence in the change over time in treatment versus control house- slightly higher migration levels for households in districts that
holds. This estimate is simply the average treatment eect of have gone through direct election. However, this estimate is no
the direct election on migration decisions (Heckman, longer signicantly dierent from zero when district- and
Lalonde, & Smith, 1999). The DD estimate of the impact of regional-level characteristics are controlled for, indicating that
direct election on migration is the test of the null hypothesis the dierences are negligible once the dierences in district-
that b3 = 0. level are accounted for.
The marginal eects associated with the interaction between
the treatment and time variable indicate that direct elections
5. RESULTS had a negative impact on migration. For the overall IFLS
sample, it is evident from column (3) that a household in a dis-
The marginal eects of the probit model for the above- trict that went through direct elections between June and
discussed specication using IFLS and the census 21 are pre- December of 2005 is 2.89 percentage points less likely to be
sented in Tables 4 and 5 respectively. Equation (1) is estimated a migrant-sending household. This is a large eect, equal to
stepwise: column (1) provides estimates without any controls; 19.26%, 22 given the average migration rate of around 0.15
column (2) with only household and household heads charac- at baseline. The analysis done with the census sample shows
teristics; column (3) with household and household heads similar resultsa household in a district that went through
characteristics and district-level characteristics and regional direct election between June and December of 2005 is 0.72 per-
xed eects. Column (4) provides marginal eects for just Java centage points less likely to be a migrant-sending household.
and Bali region and column (5) provides marginal eects for This is an 8% decrease given an average migration rate of
regions outside Java and Bali. around 0.09. Additionally, the marginal eects of the interac-
tion term on migration are almost exactly same across the col-
(a) Entire samples umns and are statistically signicant, especially in the IFLS
sample. This indicates that there is little reason to believe that
The relationship between the direct elections and migration any bias is being introduced by heterogeneity in the eect of
behavior can be understood by analyzing three marginal the domestic economic conditions across households in the
eects associated with treatment (b1 ), time (b2 ), and the inter- Indonesian districts, or by any other unobserved heterogeneity
action between time and treatment (b3 ). These marginal eects correlated with control variables.
help us understand the dierences in the migration behavior Based on the results from column (3), it is evident that
between households in districts that went through direct elec- households with older and married heads are signicantly less
tion (treatment) and those that are in districts that did not likely to send migrants. In comparison to household heads
(control) from the pre-direct election to post-direct election without any education, those with some or higher (undergrad-
120 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Table 4. Dierence in dierence model using IFLS dataset


(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
Entire Sample Entire Sample Entire Sample Java and Bali Islands Not Java and Bali Islands
Time 0.0042 0.013** 0.006 0.002 0.013
(0.591) (0.029) (0.351) (0.573) (0.438)
Treatment 0.022* 0.0263** 0.0177 0.046*** 0.007
(0.101) (0.022) (0.288) (0.000) (0.801)
Time * Treatment 0.0239** 0.0232** 0.0289** 0.039*** 0.012
(0.024) (0.030) (0.023) (0.003) (0.662)
Household characteristics NO YES YES YES YES
Household heads age 0.001*** 0.001*** 0.001*** 0.001***
Household head is male 0.012** 0.009 0.000 0.027
Household head is married 0.453*** 0.051*** 0.056*** 0.034
Household head has some education 0.059*** 0.059*** 0.039* 0.09***
HHs education > undergrad or higher 0.121*** 0.121*** 0.097*** 0.149***
Household size 0.009* 0.012*** 0.011*** 0.016***
Household size squared 0.0003 0.0001 0.000 0.000
Household has concrete oors 0.019** 0.022*** 0.018* 0.029*
Household has a toilet 0.019* 0.017* 0.032*** 0.01
Household has electricity 0.0013 0.002 0.006 0.007
Religion is Islam 0.009 0.029* 0.047 0.0001
District characteristics & Regional controls NO NO YES YES YES
Unemployment rate in 2002 0.058 1.05** 1.61***
Ln per capita Real GDP, 2003 0.004 0.013** 0.0002
Share of Electricity to total GRDP, 2003 1.91*** 1.61*** 1.378
Share of Mining to total GRDP, 2003 0.126 0.188* 0.051
Share of Agriculture to total GRDP, 2003 0.082 0.044 0.071
Share of Manufacturing to total GRDP, 2003 0.101 0.072 0.154
Share of Construction to total GRDP, 2003 0.126 0.137* 0.04
Share of Financial Services to total GRDP, 2003 0.296 0.332 0.028
Share of Services to total GRDP, 2003 0.179 0.069 0.289
Distance from district to Provinces capital 0.0002* 0.001*** 0.0001
Distance from district to Jakarta 0.000 0.000** 0.000
To Provinces capital, by Ocean(1) or Land(0) 0.088*** 0.039 0.063***
To Jakarta, by Ocean(1) or Land(0) 0.048*** 0.064*** 
(1 = Kota; 0 = Kabupaten) 0.046 0.085*** 0.131
Share of population that is urban, Susenas 2003 0.081 0.164*** 0.18**
Share of villages with asphalt road in 2003 0.039* 0.028*** 0.12**
Total Number of Observations 10,172 10,172 10,172 6,550 3,622
*** **
Note: Robust standard errors adjusted for clustering at the province level; p < 0.001, p < 0.05, *p < 0.1. p-values are in parentheses.

Table 5. Dierence in dierence model using census


(1) (2) (3) (4) (5)
Entire Sample Entire Sample Entire Sample Java and Bali Islands Not Java and Bali Islands
Time 0.002 0.013*** 0.006** 0.000 0.010**
(0.807) (0.000) (0.042) (0.900) (0.045)
Treatment 0.0045 0.0085** 0.0108*** 0.0123*** 0.0103
(0.457) (0.038) (0.007) (0.007) (0.120)
Time *
Treatment 0.0135* 0.0080* 0.0072* 0.012*** 0.001
(0.096) (0.057) (0.053) (0.000) (0.873)
Household heads characteristics NO YES YES YES YES
District characteristics & Regional controls NO NO YES YES YES
Number of Observation 3,475,277 3,475,277 3,475,277 2,545,276 930,001
*** **
Note: Robust standard errors adjusted for clustering at the province level; p < 0.001, p < 0.05, *p < 0.1. p-Values are in parentheses

uate and above) education are more likely to send migrants. izes the non-linearity or the inverted U-curve in the relation-
Also, households with concrete oors and toilets are more ship between migration and development process (Martin &
likely to send migrants than those without. As the poorest Taylor, 1996).
are less likely to have education, concrete oors, and toilets, Among the district-level characteristics, households in dis-
the results indicate that the poorest households are less likely tricts with a higher share of energy and electricity sector in
to migrate. This is in line with the literature that conceptual- the real GDP are less likely to migrate. The results suggest that
DOES LOCAL DEVELOPMENT INFLUENCE OUTMIGRATION DECISIONS?EVIDENCE FROM INDONESIA 121

migration is lower out of districts from where province capi- the total land area of Indonesia and host 60% of its total pop-
tals can be reached by ocean than by land and higher out of ulation. As the share of villages with asphalt road increases,
those from where Jakarta can be reached by ocean rather than the likelihood of outmigration decreases for districts in Java
by land. Lastly, likelihood of migration decreases as the share and Bali.
of villages with asphalt roads increase in districts. In conclusion, analysis performed separately using two dif-
ferent datasets provides consistent results. The results indicate
(b) For Java and Bali that districts that went through direct elections were signi-
cantly less likely to have outmigration. The results for the
The results are similar when the sample is restricted to the entire sample give us a general picture of how the movements
districts in Java and Bali only. On average, before direct elec- across the archipelago are aected by decentralization and
tions, the households in districts that went through direct elec- democratization. For a country like Indonesia, where internal
tions participated in migration more than those in districts migration has been historically abundant and driven by the
that did not. The general trend in migration is on the decline disparities in economic opportunities and amenities, it is inter-
for the period between pre-treatment and post-treatment. esting to nd that overall migration is decreasing. But this
According to the results from column (4) of Table 4, a house- decrease was mostly driven by the fall in the outmigration
hold in a district in Java and Bali that went through direct from districts in Java and Bali.
elections between June and December of 2005 is 3.9 percent- The dierence in results between inner and outer islands can
age points less likely to be a migrant-sending household. This be attributed to the dierence in relative economic benet
is a large eect, equal to 27.85%, given the average migration from migration. The incentive to migrate to Jakarta decreases
rate of around 0.14. The analysis done with the census sample with very little improvement in economic conditions in the dis-
shows the same resulta household in a district in Java and tricts in Java and Bali. In contrast, despite the higher increase
Bali that went through direct election between June and in service delivery and a relatively big improvement in eco-
December of 2005 is 1.2 percentage points less likely to be a nomic conditions, the incentive to migrate to inner islands
migrant-sending household. This is a 16% decrease given an remains unaected for districts in the outer islands. Although
average migration rate of around 0.075. The concern that the outmigration from districts of outer islands was unaf-
these results could be driven by the lack of variability of treat- fected, it is noted that it did not continue with the increasing
ment in Java and Bali is invalid in this case because around trend as shown in Figure A1. This is contrary to
53% of the districts in Java and Bali went through elections Tirtosudarmos (2009) speculation that migration to Java
in 2005. and Bali would respond to the labor market economy and
thus, would increase.
(c) For other provinces

For both IFLS and census samples, the direct elections had 6. CONCLUSION
no impact on the migration pattern of districts in other pro-
vinces. Most of the literature studying the relationship between
For districts in Java and Bali as well as those outside, house- migration and local development is on the role of migration/
hold heads with some years of education or undergraduate remittances on development outcomes of the migrant sending
(and higher) degrees are more likely to send migrants. House- households and communities (Antman, 2011; Gibson et al.,
holds with concrete oors are more likely to send migrants than 2011; Adams, 2006; Hildebrandt & McKenzie, 2005; Acosta
those without. For districts outside of Java and Bali, the likeli- et al., 2007; Yang, 2008). The literature, especially empirical,
hood of migration increases with increases in the unemploy- studying the extent to which local development facilitates or
ment rate of the previous year, decreases for districts from deters outmigration is less abundant because the causality in
where the province capital can be reached by ocean, decreases this direction is theoretically ambiguous and empirically di-
as the share of urban population increases, and increases when cult to establish. On one hand, improving living conditions
the share of villages with asphalt roads increases. and diversifying economic opportunities in rural areas is
However, some interesting distinctions emerge for districts expected to decrease migration to cities (Lipton, 1982;
in Java and Bali. The unemployment rate for the year prior Rhoda, 1983; Todaro, 1997). On the other hand, rural devel-
to the baseline signicantly decreases the probability of outmi- opment activities also increase access to cities, strengthen
gration in districts in Java and Bali. Migration is lower from ruralurban integration, and raise education and skill levels.
districts that are in a kota (city) versus from districts in a kabu- This could lead to an increase in ruralurban migration
paten (regency 23). As people are already in areas with rela- instead (Adepoju, 1983; Becker et al., 1994; Campbell, 1988;
tively more abundant economic opportunities, instead of Lucas, 1997; Rhoda, 1983; ILO, 1998).
looking elsewhere, people could be persistent in looking for The endogenous relationship between development and
jobs where they are. It could also be the case that as more peo- migration makes it dicult to empirically establish causality.
ple lose their jobs, they are unable to aord to migrate. A In order to overcome this issue, the analyses presented in this
higher GDP is associated with a higher probability of outmi- paper take advantage of the exogenous phasing of district-
gration but as the share of energy and electricity, mining level elections in Indonesia. With historically established
and construction in the GDP of the districts increases, it uneven development paths and internal migration patterns,
decreases. The higher the distance from the district to Jakarta, Indonesia makes an ideal case study. The empirical analyses
the less likely are households to have migrants. The likelihood conducted using two dierent datasets (IFLS and the
of migration also increases if the travel to Jakarta is by the Indonesian census) provide coherent results.
ocean. A higher share of urban population increases the like- Policy makers believe that it will aid in eciently delivering
lihood of outmigration in districts in Java and Bali. For exam- services at the local level, thus improving living conditions and
ple, as the population in Jakarta has increased over time, diversifying economic opportunities in rural areas. Even
people have moved out of Jakarta city to its suburban areas. though the initial empirical evidence on the role of democrati-
This is not surprising for islands that make up only 7% of zation and decentralization were mixed, more rigorous studies
122 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

recently have shown that decentralization could be key in likely to be a migrant-sending household. The results indicate
enhancing local economic development by more ecient ser- that even though the internal migration rate is on the decline,
vice delivery (Lin & Liu, 2000; Faguet, 2004; Iimi, 2005; it is driven by the reduction in the likelihood of outmigration
Stansel, 2005; Hammond & Tosun, 2011). from the districts in Java and Bali. In general, the decision to
This discussion is of central importance not only in the migrate is driven by the need for economic betterment. The
Indonesian contextwhere rising population pressures in Java relative economic benet for a move from outer islands to
and Bali provinces are its governments ultimate challenge inner islands is much higher than that from a district in Java
but also in the development literature, where empirical and Bali to Jakarta. As a result, just a small improvement in
research on such questions is made impossible by the lack of the economic conditions in districts of Java and Bali leads to
appropriate data and context. Indonesia, with historically a decrease in outmigration. In contrast, outmigration from
uneven development paths and high internal migration rates, districts outside of Java and Bali are unaected despite a big-
is an ideal case study. Its journey from decades of highly cen- ger improvement in their economic conditions.
tralized government into democratization and decentralization In comparison to the districts in Java and Bali, it may take
in the twenty rst century, coupled with the availability of rel- longer for local development to inuence outmigration in dis-
atively good datasets, make this study possible. tricts outside of Java and Bali because of a bigger gap in the
The results provide empirical evidence that a household in a levels of development between the inner and outer islands.
district that went through direct election between June and The 2010 census is only ve years after the election but it does
December of 2005 is 19.26% (IFLS) and 8% (census) less likely not provide detailed migration information on the years
to be a migrant-sending household. The results for the entire between the censuses. The fourth wave of IFLS provides retro-
sample give us a general idea of how the internal migration spective migration information, but it was conducted barely
across the archipelago is aected by democratization and two and half years after the elections.
decentralization at the district level. For a country like This paper takes advantage of a unique natural experiment
Indonesia, where internal migration has been historically to study the migration-development interaction that has not
abundant and driven by the disparities in economic opportu- been empirically explored before and is theoretically ambigu-
nities and amenities, a decline in overall migration as a result ous. The results support the theory that improvement in eco-
of democratization and decentralization is a promising result. nomic conditions reduces outmigration from districts in
The decline in migration is particularly strong for districts Indonesia. This is true especially for districts in Java and Bali,
that are in Java and Bali - a household in a district in Java where outmigration fell despite a smaller improvement in eco-
and Bali that went through direct election between June and nomic conditions in comparison to the districts outside of Java
December of 2005 is 27.85% (IFLS) and 16% (Census) less and Bali.

NOTES

1. Discussed in detail later. 9. Stansel (2005) and Hammond and Tosun (2011) conrm the results for
the United States.
2. To name a few.
10. Based entirely on the description provided by Skouas et al. (2014).
3. Some countries that have undergone decentralization in the past few
decades are Bolivia, Brazil, India, China, Indonesia, South Africa, Uganda, 11. Malley (2003) reports that a bribe, equivalent to the price of a car,
etc. could virtually guarantee staying in oce or getting an election vote.

4. Bali is another province that is a popular migrant destination. Even 12. All districts had direct elections by 2010.
though agriculture is still the biggest employer in Bali, in the last three
decades, tourism has taken o and is now the biggest contributor to its GDP. 13. Even though the treatment is at the district level, all the analyses are
done at the household level following the New Economics of Labor
5. Due to Javas importance as a core region, other parts of the Migration model that the decision to migrate is a joint household decision,
archipelago are usually referred to collectively as the Outer Islands. with the household sharing the costs and benets of migration with the
migrant through an explicit or implicit sharing rule.
6. During 190531, 27,338 people were moved, an average of only 1013
per year (Jones, 1979). 14. The censuses were in 1971 1980, 1990, 2000 and 2010. The rst
intercensal survey was in 1976, 1985, 1995 and 2005.
7. According to Tiebout (1956) model, as dierent local governments
oer dierent public tax-expenditure bundles, individuals are expected to 15. These samples are made available by Integrated Public Use Micro-
move based on their preferences. According to this model, data Series, International (IPUMSI).
decentralization could directly lead to migration. However, Bardhan
(2002) points out that this assumption fails in the context of poor 16. There were 434 districts in Indonesia in 2007.
countries even in mobile societies. It is unlikely that relatively poor people
take on an expensive process, such as migration, in search of higher 17. The identication of migrant sending households in the post
welfare benets. treatment period is unclear in the post treatment period. The 2010 census,
conducted in May 2010, asks the individuals location from ve years ago
8. Some countries that have undergone decentralization in the past few (May 2005). This means that individuals who migrated in May of 2005
decades are Bolivia, Brazil, India, China, Indonesia, South Africa, and the treatment period (June to December of 2005) are included in the
Uganda, etc. migrant identication in the post treatment period.
DOES LOCAL DEVELOPMENT INFLUENCE OUTMIGRATION DECISIONS?EVIDENCE FROM INDONESIA 123

18. Two districts held direct elections before June of 2005 and are not 21. The results are consistent even when the census is restricted to only
included in the analyses. those districts that are represented in IFLS.

19. IPUMSI provides a 0.51% sample of the 2005 census and a 10% 22. The average migration rate among the households in treatment
sample of the 2010 census, which is why, 2010 census sample consists of districts at baseline is 0.155 (Table 2). A fall of 2.89 percentage points is
more households than the 2005 census. Results remain consistent when a 19.26% (2.89/0.155) of the baseline average migration rate.
smaller sample of the 2010 census is used as well.
23. Indonesia is divided into provinces, which constitute regencies and
20. Another strategy to address the observable dierences would be to cities. Although considered at the same level, regencies are larger in size
use dierence in dierence with inverse propensity weightings. Results and cities have non-agriculture economic activities. Both regencies and
using this method are consistent with those using dierence in dierence cities are further divided into districts.
with conditioning variables.

REFERENCES

Acosta, P., Fajnzylber, P., & Lopez, J. H. (2007). The impact of results from a migration lottery program. The Review of Economics and
remittances on poverty and human capital: Evidence from Latin Statistics, 93(4), 12971318.
American household surveys, Policy Research Working Paper No. Hammond, G. W., & Tosun, M. S. (2011). The impact of local
4247. Washington, DC: The World Bank. decentralization on economic growth: Evidence from US counties.
Adams, R. H. (2006). International remittances and the household: Journal of Regional Science, 51(1), 4764.
Analysis and review of global evidence. Journal of African Economies, Heckman, J. J., Lalonde, R. J., & Smith, J. A. (1999). The economics and
15, 396425. econometrics of active labor market programs. In D. Card, & O.
Adepoju, A. (1983). Issues in the study of migration and urbanization in Ashenfelter (Eds.), Handbook of labor economics (pp. 18652097).
Africa south of Sahara. In P. A. Morrison (Ed.). Population Amsterdam: North Holland.
movements: Their forms and functions in unbanization and development Hildebrandt, N., & McKenzie, D. J. (2005). The eects of migration on
(pp. 115149). Liege: Ordina IUSSP. child health in Mexico. Economia, 6, 257289.
Akai, N., & Sakata, M. (2002). Fiscal decentralization contributes to Hill, H., Resosudarmo, B., & Vidyattama, Y. (2008). Indonesias changing
economic growth: evidence from state-level cross-section data for the economic geography. Bulletin of Indonesian Economic Studies, 44(3),
United States. Journal of Urban Economies, 52(1), 93108. 407435.
Angrist, J. D., & Pischke, J. S. (2008). Mostly harmless econometrics: An Hugo, G. (1980). Population movements in Indonesia during the colonial
empiricists companion. Princeton University Press. period. Research School of Pacic Studies and Asian Studies,
Antman, F. (2011). The intergenerational eects of paternal migration on Australian National University.
schooling and work: What can we learn from childrens time Hunther, J., & Shah, A. (1998). Applying a simple measure of good
allocations?. Journal of Development Economics, 96(2), 200208. governance to the debate on scal decentralization (Vol. 1894). World
Bardhan, P. (2002). Decentralization of governance and development. Bank Publications.
Journal of Economic Perspective, 16(4), 185205. Iimi, A. (2005). Decentralization and economic growth revisited: An
Beauchemin, C., & Schoumaker, B. (2005). Migration to cities in Burkina empirical note. Journal of Urban Economics, 57(3), 449461.
Faso: Does the level of development in sending areas matter?. World ILO (1998). Migration and population distribution in developing coun-
Development, 33(7), 11291152. tries: Problems and policies. In United Nations (Ed.), Population
Becker, C. M., Hamer, A. M., & Morrison, A. R. (1994). Beyond urban distribution and migration. Proceedings of the United Nations expert
bias in Africa: Urbanization in an era of structural adjustment. group meeting on population distribution and migration, Santa Cruz,
Portsmouth London: Heine mann J. Currey. Bolivia, January 1822, 1993. New York: United Nations.
Campbell, E. K. (1988). Rural urban migration and rural development Jones, G. W. (1979). Indonesia: The transmigration programme and
interrelations in West Africa: Some obstacles to goal achievement. development planning. In R. J. Pryor (Ed.), Migration and development
African Urban Quarterly, 3(12), 3449. in South-East Asia: A demographic perspective (pp. 212221). Kuala
Chattopadhyay, R., & Duo, E. (2004). Women as policy makers: Lumpur, Malaysia: Oxford University Press.
Evidence from a randomized policy experiment in India. Econometrica, Khandker, S. R., Koolwal, G. B., & Samad, H. A. (2010). Handbook on
72(5), 14091443. impact evaluation: Quantitative methods and practices. Washington,
Davoodi, H., & Zou, H. F. (1998). Fiscal decentralization and economic DC: The World Bank.
growth: A cross-country study. Journal of Urban Economies, 43(2), Kis-Katos, K., & Sjahrir, B. S. (2014). Does local governments
244257. responsiveness increase with decentralization and democratization?
De Haas, H. (2010). Migration and development: A theoretical perspec- Evidence from sub-national budget allocation in Indonesia. IZA
tive. International Migration Review, 44(1), 227264. Discussion Paper No. 7884.
Erb, M., & Sulistiyanto, P. (2009). Deepening democracy in Indonesia?: Lin, J. Y., & Liu, Z. (2000). Fiscal decentralization and economic growth
Direct elections for local leaders (Pilkada). Jakarta: Institute of in China. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 49(1), 121.
Southeast Asian Studies. Lipton, M. (1982). Rural development and the retention of the rural
Faguet, J. P. (2004). Does decentralization increase government respon- population in the countryside of developing countries. Canadian
siveness to local needs?: Evidence from Bolivia. Journal of Public Journal of Development Studies, 3, 1137.
Economics, 88(3), 867893. Lucas, R. (1997). Internal migration in developing countries. In M. R.
Fearnside, P. M. (1997). Transmigration in Indonesia: Lessons from its Rosenzweig, & O. Stark (Eds.), Handbook of population and family
environmental and social impacts. Environmental Management, 21(4), economics (pp. 721798). Amsterdam: Elsevier Science Publishers.
553570. Malley, M. (2003). New rules, old structures and the limits of democratic
Foster, A. D., & Rosenzweig, M. R. (2004). Democratization and the decentralization. In E. Aspinall, & G. Fealy (Eds.), Local power and
distribution of local public goods in a poor rural economy. Economics politics in Indonesia: Decentralisation & democratisation (pp. 183218).
Department, Brown University. Jakarta: Institute of Southeast Asian Studies.
Galasso, E., & Ravallion, M. (2005). Decentralized targeting of an Martin, P., & Taylor, J. E. (1996). The anatomy of a migration hump. In
antipoverty program. Journal of Public Economics, 89(4), 705727. J. E. Taylor (Ed.), Development strategy, employment and migration:
Gertler, P. J., Martinez, S., Premand, P., Rawlings, L. B., & Vermeerch, C. Insights from models (pp. 4362). Paris: OECD.
M. J. (2011). Impact evaluation in practice. Washington, DC: The Martinez-Vazquez, J., & McNab, R. M. (2003). Fiscal decentralization
World Bank. and economic growth. World Development, 31(9), 15971616.
Gibson, J., Mckenzie, D., & Stillman, S. (2011). The impacts of Meyer, B. D. (1995). Natural and quasi-experiments in economics. Journal
international migration on remaining household members: Omnibus of Business and Economic Statistics, 13(2), 151161.
124 WORLD DEVELOPMENT

Mietzner, M. (2007). Party nancing in post-soeharto Indonesia: Between World Bank (2003). Decentralizing Indonesia: A regional public expendi-
state subsidies and political corruption. Contemporary Southeast Asia: ture overview report. Washington, DC: The World Bank.
A Journal of International and Strategic Aairs, 29(2), 238263. Xie, D., Zou, H. F., & Davoodi, H. (1999). Fiscal decentralization and
Munshi, K. (2003). Networks in the modern economy: Mexican migrants economic growth in the United States. Journal of Urban Economics, 45
in the US labor market. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118, 549599. (2), 228239.
Oates, W. E. (1993). Fiscal decentralization and economic development. Yang, D. (2008). International migration, remittances and household
National Tax Journal, 46(2), 237243. investment: Evidence from Philippine migrants exchange rate shocks.
Palloni, A., Massey, D. S., & Ceballos, M. (2001). Social capital and The Economic Journal, 118(528), 591630.
international migration: A test using information on family networks. Zhang, T., & Zou, H. F. (1998). Fiscal decentralization, public spending
American Journal of Sociology, 106, 12621298. and economic growth in China. Journal of Public Economies, 67(2),
Pelzer, K. J. (1945). Pioneer settlement in the Asiatic tropics: Studies in land 221240.
utilisation and agricultural colonization in Southeastern Asia. New
Haven: Yale University Press.
Pratikno (2009). Political parties in Pilkada: Some problems for demo-
cratic consolidation. In M. Erb, & P. Sulistiyanto (Eds.), Deepening
democracy in Indonesia? Direct elections for local leaders (Pilkada)
(pp. 5373). Singapore, Jakarta: Institute for South East Asian Studies. APPENDIX
Rhoda, R. (1983). Rural development and urban migration. Can we keep
them down on the farm?. International Migration Review, 17(1), 3464.
Robinson, G., McNulty, J. E., & Krasno, J. S. (2009). Observing the
counterfactual? The search for political experiments in nature. Political
Analysis, 17(4), 341357.
Rosenbaum, P. R., & Rubin, D. B. (1985). Constructing a control group
using multivariate matched sampling methods that incorporate the Table A1. Placebo test for parallel trend assumption
propensity score. The American Statistician, 39, 3338.
Rubin, D. B. (2001). Using propensity scores to help design observational (1) (2) (3)
studies: Application to the tobacco litigation. Health Service & Entire Entire Entire
Outcomes Research Methodology, 2(34), 169188. sample sample sample
Santos, B. S. (1998). Participatory budgeting in Porto Alegre: Toward a
Time 0.0174* 0.017* 0.0172**
redistributive democracy. Politics and Society, 26(4), 461510.
Schiller, J. (2009). Electing district heads in Indonesia: Democratic (0.043) (0.055) (0.050)
deepening or elite entrenchment?. In M. Erb, & P. Sulistiyanto (Eds.), Treatment 0.006 0.0103 0.0015
Deepening democracy in Indonesia? Direct elections for local leaders (0.590) (0.415) (0.913)
(Pilkada) (pp. 147173). Singapore: Institute for South East Asian Time * Treatment 0.01061 0.0157 0.158
Studies. (0.258) (0.282) (0.278)
Sen, A. (1989). Development as capability expansion. Journal of Devel-
opment Planning, 19, 1458. Household heads characteristics NO YES YES
Skouas, E., Ambar, N., Dasgupta, B., & Kaiser, K. (2011). Electoral District characteristics & Regional NO NO YES
accountability, scal decentralization and service delivery in Indonesia, controls
Policy Research Working Paper No. WPS5614. Washington, DC: The Total Number of Observations 10,172 10,172 10,172
World Bank.
Skouas, E., Ambar, N., Dasgupta, B., & Kaiser, K. (2014). Electoral Note: Robust standard errors adjusted for clustering at the province level;
***
accountability, scal decentralization and service delivery in Indonesia, p < 0.001, **p < 0.05, *p < 0.1. p-Values are in parentheses.
Policy Research Working Paper No. WPS6782. Washington, DC: The
World Bank.
Soejoto, A., Subroto, W. T., & Suyanto, Y. (2015). Fiscal decentralization
policy in promoting Indonesia human development. International Table A2. Timing of direct elections of district heads during 200507
Journal of Economics and Financial Issues, 5(3), 763771.
All districts (304) Undivided districts (163)
Stansel, D. (2005). Local decentralization and local economic growth: A
cross-sectional examination of US metropolitan areas. Journal of 2005Q1 0 0
Urban Economics, 57(1), 5572. 2005Q2 155 67
Stark, O. (1991). The migration of labor. Cambridge, Oxford: B. Blackwell. 2005Q3 36 25
Tiebout, C. M. (1956). A pure theory of local expenditure. Journal of 2005Q4 12 9
Political Economy, 64(5), 416424.
2006Q1 16 13
Tirtosudarmo, R. (2009). Mobility and human development in Indonesia,
UNDP Human Development Research Paper No. 2009/19. New York: 2006Q2 22 20
United Nations. 2006Q3 9 5
Todaro, M. (1997). Urbanization, unemployment and migration in Africa: 2006Q4 27 7
Theory and policy, Policy Research Division Working Paper No. 104. 2007Q1 2 2
New York: Population Council. 2007Q2 4 4
Van Lottum, J., & Daan, M. (2012). The determinants of internal 2007Q3 7 4
migration in a developing country: Quantitative evidence for Indone- 2007Q4 14 7
sia, 19302000. Applied Economics, 44(34), 44854494.
Wooldridge, J. M. (2010). Econometric analysis of cross section and panel
data. MIT Press.

Available online at www.sciencedirect.com

ScienceDirect

You might also like