You are on page 1of 10

2016 49th Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences

Decision Model for Sustainable Electricity Procurement


Using Nationwide Demand Response

Joscha Markle-Hu Stefan Feuerriegel Dirk Neumann


University of Freiburg University of Freiburg University of Freiburg
Freiburg, Germany Freiburg, Germany Freiburg, Germany
mjoscha@gmail.com stefan.feuerriegel@is.uni-freiburg.de dirk.neumann@is.uni-freiburg.de

AbstractAs part of the worldwide effort towards achieving


sustainable energy generation, an increasing share of renew-
80
able energy sources are connected to the electricity networks.
This intermittent electricity output from renewable energy
resources causes changes in prices and feed-in volumes. One
approach to compensate for the supply side uctuations is the
active management of the demand side via so-called Demand Average Price in EUR/MWh 60

Response (DR). Demand Response is dened as providing


incentives to electricity consumers to shift electricity consump-
tion to the economically most favorable time. Analyzing such
load shifts economically is challenging, as prices depend on
40
the quantity requested. We analyze this interdependency by
explicitly modeling the load dependence of electricity prices
and thus develop a decision model for nationwide electricity
expenses in the form of a quadratic optimization. Using real
market data, we show a decrease in average electricity prices 20

and price volatility.

1. Introduction 0 5 10 15 20
Time t in h

Electricity demand varies strongly throughout the day.


Figure 1. Plot shows the uctuations in average electricity prices for each
These variations are driven by consumers who usually start hour of the day, including 5 % and 95 % quantiles (EPEX spot market
using electricity in the morning with two peaks peak during between 2009 and 2012).
the day and then reduce demand again over night. This is
true for most private households, as well as many industrial
and commercial consumers. As electricity is traded on a times of high demand and high prices, where consumption
market, times of high demand especially during the day is shifted to hours of lower demand and also lower prices. It
often correlate with high prices. On the other hand, at is also possible that electricity supply may be high, e. g., due
night, demand and prices are generally low. This is shown to favorable weather for renewable generation, which could
in Figure 1 in which long-term averages of the electricity make it benecial to consume more energy at such a time
prices and their 5 % and 95 % quantiles are plotted for each even if overall demand is also high. Such shifts in consumer
hour throughout the day. electricity usage can be achieved, for example, by providing
Because of the price differences during day and night, incentives in programs or tariffs. In the following, we refer
electricity retailers who are purchasing energy on day-to- to any lever which inuences the electricity consumption as
day auctions on the spot market can achieve signicant cost Demand Response (DR) [2], [4].
savings if volume and timing of their electricity purchases As a result of their central role in purchasing and dis-
were optimized to the economically most feasible solution tributing energy, electricity retailers are often considered as
[1], [2]. Often a shift of a few hours is enough to realize innovators in establishing DR [5][7]. DR entails several
savings and for many applications does not impair the advantages, such as reduced procurement costs and improve-
customer [3], e. g., a freezers compressor is running at night ment of the grid stability; many of which benet electricity
instead of during the day. Hence, such shifts usually occur in retailers. In addition, consumers capable of shifting demand

1530-1605/16 $31.00 2016 IEEE 1010


DOI 10.1109/HICSS.2016.130
can only be rewarded for their exibility if retailers provide 3) Network-driven DSM focuses on enhancing net-
appropriate contracts. However, governments and policy work stability and reducing the need for additional
makers also have stakes in DR and should seek opportunities capacities in generation and transmission.
to drive a nationwide adoption [8].
For governments and policy makers, DR is especially In addition to the above terminology, market-driven (and
important in its function as an enabler for sustainable energy partly network-driven) Demand Side Management ties to so-
generation from intermittent renewable sources. Renewable called Demand Response (DR). Demand Response is a term
energy sources are promoted by many countries [9], [10]. which has been used traditionally to describe peak clipping
However, due to specic properties of renewable generation, a measure to actively cut down demand in times of very
such as their intermittency, this also poses a challenge to high electricity usage. Recently, however, institutions such
electricity networks from the supply side [1], [11]. Active as the U. S. Department of Energy and the Federal Energy
management of the demand side can help to compensate [1], Regulatory Commission have used the term more generally
[8], [12] for an increase in electricity prices and volatility as a name for a tariff or a program established to motivate
of power generation. Furthermore, this allows to shut down changes in electric use by end-use customers in response
environmentally unfriendly generation plants (because of the to changes in the price of electricity over time, or to give
decrease in peak demand due to DR) and one can also reduce incentive payments designed to induce lower electricity use
transmission infrastructure. at times of high market prices or when grid reliability is
Previous literature has covered multiple individual as- jeopardized [4]. This includes the use of incentive- or
sessments of the benets of DR on household level [13], price-based programs to steer demand [2]. In this paper,
[14]. However, we are not aware of any nationwide analytics we use the term Demand Response to describe the shifting
or decision models to evaluate the optimal re-distribution of of load by customers in response to appropriate incentives,
demand. Furthermore, no holistic evaluation of the impact whereas DSM could include any measure that inuences
of DR on cost savings, prices and price volatility has been the demand side, such as an awareness campaign for energy
undertaken. Evaluation of these parameters is particularly efcient lighting.
challenging since prices are affected by load shifts.
In order to analyze the nationwide cost savings of De- 3. Related Work
mand Response, we propose a novel decision model for elec-
tricity expense optimization. Using a quadratic optimization In this section, we present literature which evaluates the
problem, we minimize the electricity expenses and identify benets of Demand Response and decision models for DR.
the optimal timing for load shifts.
The remainder of this paper is structured as follows.
We dene the required terminology in Section 2 before pre- 3.1. Benets of Demand Response
senting related work on the benets of Demand Response,
as well as decision models in Section 3. Next, Section 4 It is generally agreed that Demand Response entails a
presents the quadratic optimization problem, which we use large variety of benets for almost all stakeholders [2], [15]
to identify the optimal amount of load shifting throughout a [18]. Multiple studies point out how sustainable electricity
single day. This is followed by an evaluation of our decision generation based on renewable energy resources can be sup-
model based on real-world data in Section 5. Finally, we ported by the active management of the demand side through
present policy implications in Section 6 and Section 7 DR [1], [8], [12], [19]. For example, one study specically
summarizes the most important ndings. mentions the intermittent properties of renewable energy
generation which prohibit their use as dispatchable re-
2. Terminology sources [1]. Hence, Demand Response is regarded as a very
suitable instrument [20], [21] for intermittency mitigation,
in addition to other measures such as energy storage systems
A general term describing any activities within the de-
[22]. Furthermore, Demand Response and environmental
mand side of the electricity network is given by Demand
goals are called an optimal complementary approach [8].
Side Management (DSM). Three types of Demand Side
In addition, cost savings are expected for customers
Management can be identied, which differ in their objec-
capable of shifting their load; as shifts atten the overall
tives [1]:
load curve and hence reduce the general cost of electricity
1) Economic/market-driven DSM aims to reduce the production. Customers without Demand Response capability
overall cost of electricity by various means. For benet from lower overall electricity prices [18]. This comes
example, this may be achieved through a shift of at the cost of reduced prots for electricity retailers offering
demand to times with lower prices. expensive peak reserve generation capacities [23], [24].
2) Environmental-driven DSM focuses on improv- While many studies evaluate the available load potential
ing the environmental aspects of energy production (e. g. [8], [12], [19], [25], [26]), the results strongly depend
and consumption, such as the general reduction of on the underlying assumptions. Klobasa [19], [25] provides
demand and avoidance of generation technologies a very detailed bottom-up analysis for Germany calculating
that are particularly polluting. a potential of 3 GW in the industrial sector, 8 GW in the

1011
commercial sector and above 20 GW from private house- model that aggregates expenses from electricity auctions.
holds. In a second step, we extend the decision model to include
In terms of nancial savings, it is estimated that es- Demand Response usage. Here, we formulate a quadratic
tablishing smart meters in Europe could provide savings optimization problem which allows us to simulate the price
of up to EUR 67 bn if optimal adoption is achieved and dependency on the traded volumes of the (multi-)national
only EUR 14 bn for the less optimistic scenario [27]. Also, electricity exchange.
the cost of smart meters would have to be covered rst. Electricity can be purchased via different products on
Average household savings in the UK are estimated at the markets. Usually, there is a baseload product, which is
around GBP 1,800 present value over a 20 year period if at traded in options and futures to ensure the long-term supply
least 30 % of the population participate and also accept 1 h of electricity. To further differentiate these long-term needs,
of reduced consumption per day [28]. the baseload package which usually covers all 24 h of a
Altogether, knowledge of the nationwide economic po- day, may be complemented by various peak and off-peak
tential of Demand Response in liberalized markets is still products, which allow a differentiation of the time of the
limited [1], [13] and we are not aware of any analysis that day. The remaining energy is traded on a spot market, which
includes a simulation of load shifting whilst using actual is particularly important to balance day-to-day variations in
real-world data. electricity demand. In this paper, we focus on the expenses
for electricity on the spot market.
3.2. Decision Models for Demand Response
4.1. Optimization of Volume-Dependent Electricity
Using models and methods from Operations Re- Expenses
sarch (OR) to solve questions regarding the energy market
is widely established [29][32]. In this context, decision Let us calculate the nationwide costs Cnation (in
models are used to provide recommendations on how to EUR/MWh) spent on daily electricity auctions on the spot
achieve the optimal outcome for a given problem [33], [34]. market. Furthermore, let us introduce the hourly prices for
Multiple studies related to Demand Response aim to electricity auction contracts pA (t, qA (t)) and their corre-
create decision models for households [35], [36], consumer sponding traded volumes qA (t) at hour t. Here, the expres-
groups [13], [37], [38] or even individual appliances [39]. sion pA (t, qA (t)) denotes that prices at the exchange depend
However, decision models on an aggregate level are scarce. on the corresponding hours, as well as the nationwide quan-
Faruqui et al. [27] use direct calculation of savings based tities. Then, the expenses for electricity traded as auctions
on a xed reduction of peak cost by a given percentage. on a day-to-day basis may be written as
While such estimates are possible, they do not take into
account the electricity market dynamics and also provide no 
24

insight into the required load shifts and how to use different Cnation = pA (t, qA (t)) qA (t) (1)
appliances with different maximum shift durations. t=1

Nguyen and Nguyen [40] optimize electricity expenses where we sum over all hours t = 1, . . . , 24 of a single day.
with a dynamic programming backward algorithm. Using Within a reasonable neighborhood, we can assume a
stochastic optimization uncertainties are taken into account. linear relationship between volume and day-to-day prices
Yet, the problem is solved only for individual appliances [41]. This is justied when looking into the bid-ask curves
such as ventilation and electric vehicles. As prices can of the electricity exchange. Thus, we model prices with the
be assumed xed for such solitary problems, this is not linear model
very accurate. Furthermore, the DP problem has exponential
dimensionality and is computationally inefcient. pA (t, qA (t)) = (t) + (t) qA (t) (2)
Another approach [28] simulates the behavior of three
types of stakeholders: the utility, an aggregator and house- with suitable coefcients (t) and (t). These coefcients
holds. However, here the usage of Demand Response in form can, for example, be estimated via ordinary least squares or
of net curtailment and load shifting is presented as a binary other regression techniques. We show later how we derive
on-or-off decision depending on static thresholds. this linear model from actual demand curves (Section 5.2).
In summary, none of the above decision models provides Combining the previous ideas from Equations (1)
full insights in how to optimally shift loads depending on and (2), we yield a formulation in which prices are depen-
actual market data and demand curves for a given time dent on volumes via
period. 
24 
24
Cnation = (t) qA (t) + 2
(t) qA (t). (3)
t=1 t=1
4. Methodology
While the above equation for Cnation states how to calculate
In this section, we describe how nationwide usage of nationwide costs, the actual computation of qA (t) is not yet
Demand Response can be modeled by methods from Oper- specied; this is addressed in the following section where
ations Research. In a rst step, we describe the underlying we formulate a corresponding optimization problem.

1012
4.2. Electricity Expense Optimization Here, G is a diagonal matrix G R2424 , where the
diagonal entries are 2(t). Then, our constraints need to
The previous section has outlined how to model nation- be rearranged in the form
wide spending on electricity, while the actual calculation
subject to C T x = b. (10)
of qA (t) in Equation (3) is left unclear. As a remedy, we
pursue the following approach: we rst rewrite the above As electricity cannot be purchased in arbitrary amounts
model as an optimization problem and then transform it into but must meet demand, we dene the following equality
matrix notation. The matrix formulation simplies notation constraint in matrix representation using a diagonal matrix
and serves as a default input for most solvers. of ones such that
The optimization problem in order to determine the
1 0 ... 0
quantities qA (t) is given by
0 1 . . . 0
CT =
.. .. . . . .. R
2424
. (11)
min Cnation . . .
qA (1),...,qA (24)
0 0 ... 1

24 
24 (4)
= min (t) qA (t) + 2
(t) qA (t) The demand on the right-hand side is written as a vector
qA (1),...,qA (24)
t=1 t=1
D(1)
with an additional constraint as follows. Let us introduce a D(2)
new variable D(t) which denotes the nationwide electricity b=
.. R .
24
(12)
demand in hour t. Then, the quantities bought at the elec- .
tricity exchange need to equal the nationwide demand for D(24)
electricity from auctions, e. g., excluding any demand that Using general information about the electricity market
is fullled with other products, such as options and futures. we have shown how the total expenses can be derived and
Mathematically speaking, we obtain the following constraint represented in quadratic form. We can easily add further
constraints to Equation (10) by appending more rows to C .
qA (t) = D(t) for all t = 1, . . . , 24. (5)
In the next section, we show how Demand Response can be
This states that the purchased electricity power from auc- included in our model.
tions must meet total demand D(t) in every hour t = Now, it becomes obvious that our optimization problem
1, . . . , N . is quadratic with linear equality constraints. This can be
To make notation easier, we now rewrite the above easily solved with a large variety of solvers from quadratic
equations in matrix form. Hence, we dene x R24 as programming [42], [43] in polynomial time [44] if the
the quantitites of electricity purchased at every hour t. Using matrix G is positive-denite.
this, we write the nationwide electricity expense in quadratic
form as 4.3. Modeling Demand Response
1
min aT x + xT Gx. (6)
x 2 In order to extend the above quadratic optimization to
include DR, we need to introduce the following notation
Transforming the minimization problem into quadratic form
(see Figure 2). It is important to note that not all energy can
can be achieved by dening the vectors and matrices of
be shifted by the same maximum duration j . For example,
Equation (6) and Equation (10) as
heating the at may be delayed by an hour or two, whilst
washing the laundry could be delayed by j = 12 h or more.
(1)
(2) Hence, we dene LSj (t, d) as the load shift from t by d
a=
.. R ,
24
(7) hours with a maximum shift by j hours according to the
. given appliance. In other words, we denote a shift from t
(24) to t via LSj (t, t t). For example, let LS2 (t, 1) be the
potential (i. e. all appliances with maximum shift of 2 h)
qA (1) which is shifted by 1 h from t to t 1. By denition, we
qA (2) def
set all LSj (t, d) = 0 where t + d < 1 or t + d > 24 (out
x=
.. R
24
(8)
. of range). In addition, a shift LSj (t, 0) by 0 hours is not
qA (24) dened.
This notation is now used, to integrate Demand Re-
and using sponse usage into the above model. We append further
constraints and include additional components in the pa-
2(1) 0 ... 0 rameter x. Then, we obtain a new optimization problem in
0 2(2) ... 0
G=
.. .. .. .. R2424 .
(9) the following high-level formulation
. . . . min Cnation Demand Response usage. (13)
0 0 ... 2(N ) qA (t),LSj (t,d)

1013
t2 t1 t t+1 t+2

j=1
LS1(t,1) LS1(t,+1)

j=2 LS2(t,2) LS2(t,1) LS2(t,+1) LS2(t,+2)

Figure 2. Illustration of load shifted away from time slot t to adjacent time slots for appliances with maximum shifts of j = 1 h and j = 2 h.

When using Demand Response, we actively modify the rst present our data sources and then outline how we
demand at certain hours. Furthermore, according to our model the relationship between traded electricity volume
denition any load shift must be positive, such that and corresponding price. Finally, we present our simulation
results which are based on real-world data.
LSj (t + i, i) 0 and
(14)
LSj (t i, +i) 0 for all t, j, i.
5.1. Data Sources
In addition, the load shifted away is limited by a maxi-
mum available capacity j (t). For example, the sum of all Several publications aim at quantifying the available load
LS2 (t, d) is thus bounded, i. e. LS2 (t, t 2) + LS2 (t, t shifting potential in Germany (e. g. [12], [25], [26]). In this
1) + LS2 (t, t + 1) + LS2 (t, t + 2) must be smaller or equal paper, we use the estimated DR potential from Klobasa [25]
than 2 (t). We formalize this in a second constraint as these values feature the highest granularity. In addition,
1 this DR potential ranges in the middle of the spectrum
 
j
LSj (t, i) + LSj (t, i) j (t) for all j, t. (15) when compared to other publications. These potentials are
based on a bottom up assessment of available capacities
i=j i=1
in households, commercial and industrial applications. We
Finally, our model requires a new constraint that vali- calculate the average daily shift potential in Germany and
dates if electricity demand is satised by traded quantities include only appliances which are applicable to a winter
and Demand Response usage. This is given by day. As such, we exclude, for instance, air conditioning but
qA (t) = D(t) load shifted away include heating applications. In addition, we scale the data
to also include Austria.1,2
+ load shifted here (16)
The previous description addresses the theoretically pos-
for t = 1, . . . , 24 sible Demand Response potential, based on which we derive
This expression can then be extended to the following three scenarios. These scenarios vary in terms
1 of the penetration of Demand Response that is assumed:
  
j
accordingly, we set the ratio of Demand Response utilization
qA (t) =D(t) LSj (t, i) LSj (t, i) to 1 %, 10 % and 25 %. The corresponding volumes available
j i=j i=1 for load shifting are given in Table 3.
1

(17)
 
j
In order to achieve realistic estimates of the savings pos-
+ LSj (t i, i) + LSj (t i, i) sible through Demand Response, we use actual market data
i=j i=1 from EPEX spot3 for the combined German and Austrian
for t = 1, . . . , 24 and with the original demand D(t). Then, electricity market. Here, we use hourly auction prices and
the variable qA (t) gives the quantity of electricity that needs volumes for December 19, 2012 as an exemplary simulation
to be purchased at a time t to fulll the original demand after horizon. In our calculations, we determine the electricity
load shifting for the given time slot. demand based on data from EEX transparency4 .
The previously proposed additions require multiple Finally, we need to specify how we determine electricity
changes to the quadratic implementation of this minimiza- prices when simulating traded electricity volumes that differ
tion problem. The solution vector x denoting the demand from the historic data. For this, we employ actual demand
is now extended to comprise of one value for each possible 1
Here, we choose a scaling factor of 1.11. This factor is based on
demand shift in addition to the 24 values for each hour, Eurostat data of gross inland consumption of energy for 2012 in Germany
while the cost function remains the same. and Austria.
2
Eurostat. URL: http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/statistics-explained/index.
php/Consumption of energy. Retrieved on June 6, 2015.
5. Evaluation 3
EPEX Spot. URL: http://www.epexspot.com/. Retrieved on May 15,
2015.
This section describe how we solve the quadratic opti- 4
EEX transparency. URL: http://www.eex-transparency.com/. Re-
mization problem to determine optimal load shifting. We trieved on May 14, 2015.

1014
TABLE 3. AVAILABLE ELECTRICITY VOLUME AVAILABLE FOR LOAD
SHIFTING WITH A BREAK DOWN BY THE MAXIMUM SHIFT DURATION
FOR THREE SCENARIOS WITH 100 %, 25 %, 10 % AND 1 % DR
UTILIZATION ( DATA BASED ON [25]; SCALED FOR THE COMBINED
MARKET OF G ERMANY AND AUSTRIA ; APPLIANCES FILTERED FOR A
WINTER DAY ).

Maximum Shift Maximum Load Shift j in MW


Duration j in h
100% 25% 10% 1%
1 2,117 529 212 21
2 2,819 705 282 28
3 199 50 20 2
4 197 49 20 2
12 4,391 1,098 439 44
16 567 142 57 6
24 400 100 40 4

curves from EPEX spot. These curves feature all bids for an
electricity auction in a given hour. On average, an auction
consists of 691 bids.
Figure 4. Demand curve shows individual electricity offers (blue dots); the
red dot indicates the nal market price. The shade area highlights values
5.2. Dependency of Electricity Prices on Trading selected for the actual regression to calculate the slope (Data from 4:00 am
Volumes on December 19, 2012).

In economics, relationships between variables are fre-


quently assumed to be linear for a given neighborhood of economic effects across all three scenarios, nding a similar
observed data [45]. Accordingly, we adopt this approach pattern for the expected savings.
and also assume a linear relationship between electricity Figure 5 illustrates how electricity demand is shifted
price and traded volume [41]. We validate this procedure to minimize costs. Here, the x-axis shows the hour of the
visually by depicted all bids for an exemplary electricity day and the y-axis the volumes shifted. Bars in positive
auction in Figure 4. Here, the red dot indicates the actual direction indicate that electricity was shifted from some time
market price and we see that a linear relationship is valid to this hour, whereas negative bars reveal that electricity
in its neighborhood. was shifted to other hours. The colors of the bar denote the
In order to calculate the gradient, we rst lter the data duration of the shift. Overall, we see the following pattern:
and then perform a linear regression. For the former, we electricity is mostly shifted to night hours from 0 to 5 am
choose the 0.5 % and 99.5 % quantiles of all electricity and from 9 pm to midnight. During the day, electricity
prices between 2009 and 2012. These represent a set of is mostly shifted away, except for a peak at 3 pm when
feasible prices which we can expect during normal op- relatively low electricity prices promote higher usage. Fur-
erations on the electricity exchange. Hence, our regres- thermore, these shift mainly originate from appliances that
sion is thus based on prices between 0.04 EUR/MWh and are highly exible in terms of scheduling. More precisely, all
93.81 EUR/MWh in order to compute the gradient. This shift durations j are used to relocate the electricity demand.
range is highlighted by an shaded area in Figure 4. Interest- One and two hour shift potentials are activated to shift peak
ingly, the intercept from the linear model is not needed for demand to times of lower electricity usage at the boundaries
further evaluations, instead we only use the slope from the and the potentials with longer shifts, such as 12 h, 16 h and
regression and then calculate the simulated price based on 24 h, are used in the morning and evening to shift electricity
gradient and the historic price. towards midnight.
The previous ndings are conrmed by Table 6 in more
5.3. Results detail: the net effect from Demand Response remains posi-
tive for a given hour if this hour receives more energy than
We now evaluate the effects from Demand Response is shifted away. Night hours, especially in the early morn-
usage on electricity prices and their volatility. Thereby, we ing, receive up to 4.1 GW electricity, whereas our decision
compare three different scenarios that vary in the utilization model shifts electricity most away during day time. The
(1 %, 10 % and 25 %) of the theoretically available DR po- maximum Demand Response potential for each individual
tential. In our analysis of shifted volumes, we predominantly hour accounts for 2.7 GW, which is equivalent to using the
focus on the 25 % simulation to provide insights on how full 25 % potential. This happens at 7 pm, which is also one
the shifts work. In addition, we compare and discuss the of the hours with highest electricity prices (cf. the original

1015
4000

Max. Shift (j) in h


2000 01
Volume in MWh

02
03
04
12
0
16
24

2000

0 5 10 15 20
Time t in h

Figure 5. Bar chart shows load shifts by hour. In short, load is shifted from the morning and afternoon to the night times. When electricity volume is
received, this is shown in the positive range of the y -axis; load shifted away appears as a negative bar. The color indicates the maximum possible shift
duration in hours (scenario with DR utilization of 25 % of the theoretically possible potential).

electricity prices in Table 6). In contrast, receiving electricity


is not limited by this volume, since electricity can be shifted DR potential 0% 1% 10% 25%

from multiple hours to another.


Figure 7 compares visually the simulated electricity
prices across all three Demand Response scenarios. The
solid line represents the benchmark without Demand Re- 70
sponse. These prices are equivalent to the originally ob-
served ones. Based on the simulated prices, we observe
two peaks in the late morning and early evening, which
Price in EUR/MWh

both mirror the previous load shifting. In the scenarios 60

with Demand Response potential, load is shifted, resulting


into prices that are more balanced. Interestingly, we nd
evidence of considerably more stable and less volatile prices
50
in scenarios with higher Demand Response utilization. For
instance, the simulated prices in the 25 % scenario (dashed
line) is above the original prices during night hours and
below during daytime. 40

Furthermore, we observe one interesting pattern in sim-


ulation using 25 % of the theoretically available shift po-
tentials. In this case, some prices during the night are
0 5 10 15 20
higher than during the day. These effects are driven by the Time t in h
large volumes of shifted load. As a consequence, it is not
realistic to study DR utilization of above 25 % with the Figure 7. Plot shows simulated electricity prices for each hour across
given decision model as this might violate the assumption different Demand Response scenarios. A higher share of DR utilization
of a linear relationship between electricity price and traded attens the price curve and thus reduces volatility.
volume. For such evaluations, one needs to either develop
a different decision model or validate the outcomes with
results from practical experiments. vide descriptive statistics of simulated electricity prices
Finally, we compare the effects on electricity prices from Demand Response usage in Table 8. When using
across all Demand Response scenarios. As such, we pro- Demand Response, the mean electricity price decreases for

1016
TABLE 6. OVERVIEW OF HOURLY NET EFFECT INDUCED BY D EMAND R ESPONSE USAGE ACROSS EACH HOUR OF THE DAY FROM VOLUME SHIFTS
( SCENARIO WITH 25 % DR PENETRATION ).

Time Slot t (in h) 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11


Original Volume (in GW) 23.8 24.4 23.8 23.5 23.0 23.3 25.0 24.3 27.8 28.4 28.8 29.4
Volume After DR (in GW) 27.8 28.2 27.8 26.5 25.2 25.1 24.3 23.0 25.5 25.9 26.5 26.9
Net Effect (in GW) 4.0 3.7 4.1 2.9 2.3 1.8 0.7 1.3 2.3 2.5 2.3 2.5
Original Price (in EUR/MWh) 36.07 35.32 35.21 34.22 34.20 36.99 44.28 60.45 66.35 66.22 65.10 63.91
Price After DR (in EUR/MWh) 55.60 53.50 55.09 49.97 47.28 47.38 40.16 50.77 42.67 40.65 41.71 39.10
Price Change (in EUR/MWh) 19.53 18.18 19.88 15.75 13.08 10.39 4.12 9.68 23.68 25.57 23.39 24.81

Time Slot t (in h) 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23


Original Volume (in GW) 29.7 28.9 27.6 25.4 23.7 25.4 27.1 26.9 24.4 23.6 23.6 24.6
Volume After DR (in GW) 28.2 27.5 27.1 26.0 23.0 23.3 24.5 24.3 23.1 25.2 25.1 26.6
Net Effect (in GW) 1.4 1.4 0.4 0.6 0.8 2.2 2.6 2.7 1.3 1.6 1.5 2.0
Original Price (in EUR/MWh) 60.02 59.90 58.27 57.95 63.92 77.40 69.94 62.16 55.08 48.48 42.13 37.65
Price After DR (in EUR/MWh) 47.54 47.23 54.64 62.62 56.58 54.98 43.31 33.47 46.32 56.95 50.63 48.60
Price Change (in EUR/MWh) 12.48 12.67 3.63 4.67 7.34 22.42 26.63 28.69 8.76 8.47 8.50 10.95

TABLE 8. D ESCRIPTIVE STATISTICS OF SIMULATED PRICES ACROSS Response can also compensate for uctuations in the power
DIFFERENT DR SCENARIOS . generation of renewable energies [1], [11]. In addition, this
paper provides evidence that load shifting reduces average
DR Scenario Mean Median Stand. Dev. Min. Max. Skew. Kurt.
electricity prices and their volatility. Hence, it is desirable
0% 52.97 58.11 13.58 34.2 77.4 0.13 1.49
1% 52.78 58.36 12.95 34.18 76.52 0.13 1.46 to advance smart metering and generally any technology
10 % 51.16 52.65 8.16 37.69 68.64 0.02 0.86 which allows load shifting [27], [46], [47]. Consequently,
25 % 48.61 48.07 6.94 33.47 62.62 0.14 0.68
governments should consider supporting this trend with
appropriate policies [48].
all scenarios; for example, from 52.97 EUR/MWh down to Challenges in the nationwide adoption of Demand Re-
48.61 EUR/MWh in the 25 % scenario. Similarly, Demand sponse have been clustered into four groups in a recent
Response usage also reduces the volatility of electricity study for the Federal Energy Regulatory Commission [49]:
prices, as well as the minimum and maximum price. regulatory, technical, economic and other. These are as fol-
Overall, nationwide costs for electricity procurement lows: (1) regulatory challenges refer to any barriers created
from day-ahead auctions accounts for EUR 33.12 mn. De- through policies. (2) Technical obstacles denote the need
mand Response can diminish these costs. In the scenarios for new types of appliances, communication protocols and
with 1 %, 10 % and 25 % DR potential, total costs account advances in metering technology. (3) Economic challenges
for EUR 32.95 mn, EUR 31.65 mn and EUR 30.00 mn include all cases in which the nancial benets are not clear.
respectively. This totals to savings of EUR 0.17 mn, (4) Finally, the category other comprises the remaining
EUR 1.47 mn and EUR 3.12 mn for each of the scenarios difculties. Examples include customer perception of DR
one the given day. and their willingness to enroll. Clearly, governments should
These ndings fully conrm the positive impact of De- tackle these challenges in the pursuit of increasing Demand
mand Response on electricity prices. Even in the very con- Response adoption [27], [48], [50]. Also, any initiative in
servative scenario, which uses only 1 % of the theoretically support of DR should be carefully designed to provide an
available DR potential, signicant savings are possible. If effective measure [51].
we assume that this single day represents average electricity In future, additional Demand Response potentials can be
consumption, annual savings of approximately EUR 62 mn unlocked as technology improves, for instance, from smart
could be achieved. In case of higher DR potentials such as cars [16] and home electricity storage systems [15], [36].
25 %, these could potentially increase to about EUR 1.1 bn These technologies entail the advantage of providing highly
savings from simple load shifting. We also note that further exible load shifting, which fosters their use in stabilizing
savings can originate from second order effects, such as the electricity grid. Hence, it should be a key goal of policy
the reduction of transmission infrastructure and reduced makers to bolster the introduction of such technologies from
expenses for load balancing. an early point onwards.

6. Policy Implications 7. Conclusion and Outlook

The manifold benets of Demand Response make it an Demand Response serves as an effective instrument to
intriguing lever for any sustainability strategy. Individual mitigate the intermittency of renewable energy resources,
advantages are as follows: Demand Response usage can whilst also providing very promising nancial savings to
result in cost and infrastructure savings [16][18]. Demand electricity retailers and consumers. While previous research

1017
has predominantly addressed the nancial savings on house- [10] European Union, Decision No 406/2009/EC of the European
hold or retailer level, little is known on the economic Parliament and of the Council of 23 April 2009 on the Effort
of Member States to Reduce their Greenhouse Gas Emissions
consequences on a nationwide dimension. Hence, this paper to Meet the Communitys Greenhouse Gas Emission Reduction
proposes a decision model in order to simulate implications Commitments up to 2020, Ofcial Journal of the European Union,
of Demand Response usage for nancial savings and elec- vol. L 140/136, no. Decision No 406/2009/EC, p. 136, 2009. [Online].
tricity prices. Since price and volume are dependent on each Available: http://eur-lex.europa.eu/legal-content/EN/TXT/?uri=OJ:L:
2009:140:TOC
other, we need to implement a corresponding price model
in form of a quadratic optimization problem. [11] R. Walawalkar, S. Fernands, N. Thakur, and K. R. Chevva, Evolution
and Current Status of Demand Response (DR) in Electricity Markets:
Based on our decision model, we infer optimal load Insights from PJM and NYISO, Energy, vol. 35, no. 4, pp. 1553
shifts for a simulation scenario based on the German and 1560, 2010.
Austrian spot market. When assuming a 25 % penetration [12] M. E. Dyson, S. D. Borgeson, M. D. Tabone, and D. S. Callaway,
of the theoretic Demand Response potential, our simula- Using Smart Meter Data to Estimate Demand Response Potential,
tion reveals nationwide savings for a single day of up to with Application to Solar Energy Integration, Energy Policy, vol. 73,
EUR 3.12 mn. This result should make the adoption of pp. 607619, 2014.
Demand Response an obvious choice for electricity retail- [13] S. Feuerriegel and D. Neumann, Measuring the Financial Impact of
ers wherever feasible. In addition, governments and policy Demand Response for Electricity Retailers, Energy Policy, vol. 65,
pp. 359368, 2014.
makers should evaluate the benets of Demand Response
especially with regards to enabling sustainable electricity [14] M. Vasirani and S. Ossowski, Smart Consumer Load Balancing:
generation and cost savings. State of the Art and an Empirical Evaluation in the Spanish Electricity
Market, Articial Intelligence Review, vol. 39, no. 1, pp. 8195,
While we have chosen a sample day for all evaluations in 2013.
this paper, future work will focus on making the results more
[15] O. Erdinc, N. G. Paterakis, I. N. Pappi, A. G. Bakirtzis, and J. P.
reliable by studying longer time horizons. Furthermore, Catalao, A New Perspective for Sizing of Distributed Generation
policy makers would also benet from detailed assessments and Energy Storage for Smart Households under Demand Response,
of the cost structure for all Demand Response scenarios in Applied Energy, vol. 143, pp. 2637, 2015.
order to evaluate the total net benet of Demand Response. [16] P. Siano, Demand Response and Smart Grids: A Survey, Renewable
and Sustainable Energy Reviews, vol. 30, pp. 461478, 2014.
References [17] A. Safdarian, M. Fotuhi-Firuzabad, and M. Lehtonen, Benets of
Demand Response on Operation of Distribution Networks: A Case
[1] J. Aghaei and M.-I. Alizadeh, Demand Response in Smart Elec- Study, IEEE Systems Journal, vol. PP, no. 99, pp. 19, 2014.
tricity Grids Equipped with Renewable Energy Sources: A Review, [18] C.-L. Su and D. Kirschen, Quantifying the Effect of Demand Re-
Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews, vol. 18, pp. 6472, 2013. sponse on Electricity Markets, IEEE Transactions on Power Systems,
[2] M. Albadi and E. El-Saadany, A Summary of Demand Response vol. 24, no. 3, pp. 11991207, 2009.
in Electricity Markets, Electric Power Systems Research, vol. 78, [19] M. Klobasa, Analysis of Demand Response and Wind Integration
no. 11, pp. 19891996, 2008. in Germanys Electricity Market, IET Renewable Power Generation,
[3] S. Gottwalt, W. Ketter, C. Block, J. Collins, and C. Weinhardt, vol. 4, no. 1, pp. 5563, 2010.
Demand Side Management: A Simulation of Household Behavior
[20] A. Papavasiliou and S. S. Oren, Large-Scale Integration of De-
under Variable Prices, Energy Policy, vol. 39, no. 12, pp. 81638174,
ferrable Demand and Renewable Energy Sources, IEEE Transactions
2011.
on Power Systems, vol. 29, no. 1, pp. 489499, 2014.
[4] U.S. Department of Energy, Benets of Demand Response in Elec-
tricity Markets and Recommendations for Achieving them: A Report [21] P. Finn and C. Fitzpatrick, Demand Side Management of Industrial
to the United States Congress Pursuant to Section 1252 of the Energy Electricity Consumption: Promoting the Use of Renewable Energy
Policy Act of 2005, 2006. hrough Real-time Pricing, Applied Energy, vol. 113, pp. 1121, 2014.
[5] EU-DEEP, The Birth of a European Distributed Energy Partnership [22] J. P. Barton and D. G. Ineld, Energy Storage and Its Use with
that will Help the Large-scale Implementation of Distributed Energy Intermittent Renewable Energy, IEEE Transactions on Energy Con-
Resources in Europe: FP6 - Sustainable Energy Systems: Project version, vol. 19, no. 2, pp. 441448, 2004.
reference 503516, 2009. [Online]. Available: http://cordis.europa. [23] S. Stoft, Power system economics: Designing Markets for Electricity.
eu/project/rcn/73969 en.html Piscataway, NJ, New York: IEEE Press, Wiley-Interscience, 2002.
[6] Smart Energy Demand Coalition, The Demand Response Snap Shot: [24] C.-L. Su, Optimal Demand-Side Participation in Day-Ahead
The Reality For Demand Response Providers Working in Europe To- Electricity Markets, Ph.D. dissertation, The University of
day, 2011. [Online]. Available: http://sedc-coalition.eu/wp-content/ Manchester, 2007. [Online]. Available: http://www.ee.washington.
uploads/2011/09/SEDC-DR-Snap-Shot.-FINAL-20112.pdf edu/research/real/Library/Thesis/Chua-Liang SU.pdf
[7] A. Faruqui and S. Sergici, Household Response to Dynamic Pricing
of Electricity: A Survey of 15 Experiments, Journal of Regulatory [25] M. Klobasa, Dynamische Simulation eines Lastmanagements und
Economics, vol. 38, no. 2, pp. 193225, 2010. Integration von Windenergie in ein Elektrizitatsnetz, ser. ISI-
Schriftenreihe Innovationspotenziale. Stuttgart: Fraunhofer-IRB-
[8] C. Bergaentzle, C. Clastres, and H. Khalfallah, Demand-Side Man- Verl., 2009.
agement and European Environmental and Energy Goals: An Optimal
Complementary Approach, Energy Policy, vol. 67, pp. 858869, [26] H. C. Gils, Assessment of the Theoretical Demand Response Poten-
2014. tial in Europe, Energy, vol. 67, pp. 118, 2014.
[9] The White House, U.S.-China Joint Announcement on Climate [27] A. Faruqui, D. Harris, and R. Hledik, Unlocking the e53 Billion
Change, Ofce of the Press Secretary, 2014. [Online]. Savings from Smart Meters in the EU: How Increasing the Adoption
Available: https://www.whitehouse.gov/the-press-ofce/2014/11/11/ of Dynamic Tariffs Could Make or Break the EUs Smart Grid
us-china-joint-announcement-climate-change Investment, Energy Policy, vol. 38, no. 10, pp. 62226231, 2010.

1018
[28] S. Dave, M. Sooriyabandara, and M. Yearworth, System Behaviour [40] M. Y. Nguyen and D. M. Nguyen, A Generalized Formulation
Modelling for Demand Response Provision in a Smart Grid, Energy of Demand Response under Market Environments, International
Policy, vol. 61, pp. 172181, 2013. Journal of Emerging Electric Power Systems, vol. 16, no. 3, 2015.
[29] C. H. Antunes and A. Gomes, Operational Research Models and [41] W. Bonte, S. Nielen, N. Valitov, and T. Engelmeyer, Price elasticity
Methods in the Energy Sector, European Journal of Operational of demand in the EPEX spot market for electricityNew empirical
Research, vol. 197, no. 3, pp. 997998, 2009. evidence, Economics Letters, vol. 135, pp. 58, 2015.
[30] R. Banos, F. Manzano-Agugliaro, F. G. Montoya, C. Gil, A. Alcayde, [42] D. Goldfarb and A. Idnani, Dual and Primal-Dual Methods for
and J. Gomez, Optimization Methods Applied to Renewable and Solving Strictly Convex Quadratic Programs, in Numerical Analysis,
Sustainable Energy: A Review, Renewable and Sustainable Energy ser. Lecture Notes in Mathematics, J. P. Hennart, Ed. Springer Berlin
Reviews, vol. 15, no. 4, pp. 17531766, 2011. Heidelberg, 1982, vol. 909, pp. 226239.
[31] K. Kowalski, S. Stagl, R. Madlener, and I. Omann, Sustainable [43] , A Numerically Stable Dual Method for Solving Strictly Con-
Energy Futures: Methodological Challenges in Combining Scenar- vex Quadratic Programs, Mathematical Programming, vol. 27, no. 1,
ios and Participatory Multi-criteria Analysis, European Journal of pp. 133, 1983.
Operational Research, vol. 197, no. 3, pp. 10631074, 2009.
[44] M. K. Kozlov, S. P. Tarasov, and L. G. Khachiyan, The Polynomial
[32] S. D. Pohekar and M. Ramachandran, Application of Multi-Criteria Solvability of Convex Quadratic Programming, USSR Computational
Decision Making to Sustainable Energy Planning: A Review, Re- Mathematics and Mathematical Physics, vol. 20, no. 5, pp. 223228,
newable and Sustainable Energy Reviews, vol. 8, no. 4, pp. 365381, 1980.
2004.
[45] P. A. Samuelson, Some Implications of Linearity, The Review of
[33] S. Ahmad and R. M. Tahar, Selection of Renewable Energy Sources Economic Studies, vol. 15, no. 2, pp. p 8890, 1947.
for Sustainable Development of Electricity Generation System Using
[46] J. Carroll, S. Lyons, and E. Denny, Reducing Household Electricity
Analytic Hierarchy Process: A Case of Malaysia, Renewable Energy,
Demand Through Smart Metering: The Role of Improved Information
vol. 63, pp. 458466, 2014.
About Energy Saving, Energy Economics, vol. 45, pp. 234243,
[34] K. Smith Stegen and M. Palovic, Decision-Making for Supplying 2014.
Energy Projects: A Four-Dimensional Model, Energy Conversion
[47] J. Torriti, M. G. Hassan, and M. Leach, Demand Response Experi-
and Management, vol. 86, pp. 644652, 2014.
ence in Europe: Policies, Programmes and Implementation, Energy,
[35] J. Valenzuela, P. R. Thimmapuram, and J. Kim, Modeling and vol. 35, no. 4, pp. 15751583, 2010.
Simulation of Consumer Response to Dynamic Pricing with Enabled
[48] P. Warren, A Review of Demand-Side Management Policy in the
Technologies, Applied Energy, vol. 96, pp. 122132, 2012.
UK, Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews, vol. 29, pp. 941
[36] O. Erdinc, Economic Impacts of Small-Scale Own Generating and 951, 2014.
Storage Units, and Electric Vehicles under Different Demand Re-
[49] The Brattle Group, Freeman, Sullivan & Co, and Global Energy
sponse Strategies for Smart Households, Applied Energy, vol. 126,
Partners, LLC, A National Assessment of Demand Response
pp. 142150, 2014.
Potential: Staff Report, 2009. [Online]. Available: http://www.ferc.
[37] F. d. Ridder, M. Hommelberg, and E. Peeters, Four Potential Busi- gov/legal/staff-reports/06-09-demand-response.pdf
ness Cases for Demand Side Integration, in 2009 6th International
[50] Z. Ming, X. Song, M. Mingjuan, L. Lingyun, C. Min, and W. Yuejin,
Conference on the European Energy Market. IEEE, 2009, pp. 16.
Historical Review of Demand Side Management in China: Man-
[38] N. Mahmoudi, T. K. Saha, and M. Eghbal, A New Demand Response agement Content, Operation Mode, Results Assessment and Relative
Scheme for Electricity Retailers, Electric Power Systems Research, Incentives, Renewable and Sustainable Energy Reviews, vol. 25, pp.
vol. 108, pp. 144152, 2014. 470482, 2013.
[39] J. H. Yoon, R. Baldick, and A. Novoselac, Dynamic Demand Re- [51] P. Grunewald and J. Torriti, Demand Response from the Non-
sponse Controller Based on Real-Time Retail Price for Residential Domestic Sector: Early UK Experiences and Future Opportunities,
Buildings, IEEE Transactions on Smart Grid, vol. 5, no. 1, pp. 121 Energy Policy, vol. 61, pp. 423429, 2013.
129, 2014.

1019

You might also like