You are on page 1of 283

Youth Employment

in Sub-Saharan Africa
Youth Employment
in Sub-Saharan Africa

Deon Filmer and Louise Fox


with
Karen Brooks, Aparajita Goyal,
Taye Mengistae, Patrick Premand, Dena Ringold,
Siddharth Sharma, and Sergiy Zorya

A copublication of the Agence Franaise de Dveloppement and the World Bank


2014 International Bank for Reconstruction and Development / The World Bank
1818 H Street NW, Washington DC 20433
Telephone: 202-473-1000; Internet: www.worldbank.org
Some rights reserved
1 2 3 4 17 16 15 14
This work is a product of the staff of The World Bank with external contributions. Note that
The World Bank and the Agence Franaise de Dveloppement do not necessarily own each
component of the content included in the work. The World Bank and the Agence Franaise
de Dveloppement therefore do not warrant that the use of the content contained in the work
will not infringe on the rights of third parties. The risk of claims resulting from such infringe-
ment rests solely with you.
The findings, interpretations, and conclusions expressed in this work do not necessarily
reflect the views of The World Bank, its Board of Executive Directors, or the governments
they represent, or the Agence Franaise de Dveloppement. The World Bank does not guar-
antee the accuracy of the data included in this work. The boundaries, colors, denominations,
and other information shown on any map in this work do not imply any judgment on the
part of The World Bank concerning the legal status of any territory or the endorsement or
acceptance of such boundaries.
Nothing herein shall constitute or be considered to be a limitation upon or waiver of
the privileges and immunities of The World Bank, all of which are specifically reserved.

Rights and Permissions

This work is available under the Creative Commons Attribution 3.0 Unported license
(CC BY 3.0) http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/3.0. Under the Creative Commons
Attribution license, you are free to copy, distribute, transmit, and adapt this work, including
for commercial purposes, under the following conditions:
AttributionPlease cite the work as follows: Filmer, Deon and Louise Fox. 2014. Youth
Employment in Sub-Saharan Africa. Africa Development Series. Washington, DC: World
Bank. doi:10.1596/978-1-4648-0107-5. License: Creative Commons Attribution CC
BY 3.0
TranslationsIf you create a translation of this work, please add the following disclaimer
along with the attribution: This translation was not created by The World Bank and should
not be considered an official World Bank translation. The World Bank shall not be liable for
any content or error in this translation.
All queries on rights and licenses should be addressed to World Bank Publications, The
World Bank Group, 1818 H Street NW, Washington, DC 20433, USA; fax: 202-522-2625;
e-mail: pubrights@worldbank.org.
ISBN (paper): 978-1-4648-0107-5
ISBN (electronic): 978-1-4648-0108-2
DOI:10.1596/978-1-4648-0107-5
Cover design: Critical Stages
Cover image: Corbis; permission required for further use.
Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data has been applied for.
The Africa Development Forum Series was created in 2009 to focus on issues of signifi-
cant relevance to Sub-Saharan Africas social and economic development. Its aim is both to
record the state of the art on a specific topic and to contribute to ongoing local, regional,
and global policy debates. It is designed specifically to provide practitioners, scholars,
and students with the most up-to-date research results while highlighting the promise,
challenges, and opportunities that exist on the continent.
The series is sponsored by the Agence Franaise de Dveloppement and the World Bank.
The manuscripts chosen for publication represent the highest quality in each institution
and have been selected for their relevance to the development agenda. Working together
with a shared sense of mission and interdisciplinary purpose, the two institutions are com-
mitted to a common search for new insights and new ways of analyzing the development
realities of the Sub-Saharan Africa region.

Advisory Committee Members

Agence Franaise de Dveloppement


Jean-Yves Grosclaude, Director of Strategy
Alain Henry, Director of Research
Philippe Cabin, Head of Research Publishing Division

World Bank
Francisco H. G. Ferreira, Chief Economist, Africa Region
Richard Damania, Lead Economist, Africa Region
Stephen McGroarty, Executive Editor, Publishing and Knowledge Division
Sub-Saharan Africa

CAPE MAURITANIA
VERDE NIGER
MALI SUDAN ERITREA
SENEGAL CHAD
THE GAMBIA
BURKINA FASO
GUINEA-BISSAU GUINEA BENIN
NIGERIA ETHIOPIA
CTE GHANA
SIERRA LEONE CENTRAL SOUTH
DIVOIRE SUDAN
AFRICAN REPUBLIC SOMALIA
LIBERIA TOGO CAMEROON

EQUATORIAL GUINEA
UGANDA KENYA
SO TOM AND PRNCIPE GABON CONGO
DEMOCRATIC RWANDA
REPUBLIC
OF CONGO BURUNDI
TANZANIA
SEYCHELLES

COMOROS
ANGOLA
MALAWI Mayotte
(Fr.)
ZAMBIA
MADAGASCAR
ZIMBABWE MOZAMBIQUE
MAURITIUS
NAMIBIA BOTSWANA Runion
(Fr.)

SWAZILAND

LESOTHO
SOUTH
AFRICA

Throughout this report, Africa is shorthand for Sub-Saharan Africa. In particular instances, Sub-Saharan Africa is
retained to clarify comparisons across regions or to indicate a specific data set.
ries

Africas Infrastructure: A Time for Transformation (2010) edited by Vivien Foster and
Cecilia Briceo-Garmendia
Gender Disparities in Africas Labor Market (2010) edited by Jorge Saba Arbache,
Alexandre Kolev, and Ewa Filipiak
Challenges for African Agriculture (2010) edited by Jean-Claude Deveze
Contemporary Migration to South Africa: A Regional Development Issue (2011)
edited by Aurelia Segatti and Loren Landau
Light Manufacturing in Africa: Targeted Policies to Enhance Private Investment and Create
Jobs (2012) by Hinh T. Dinh, Vincent Palmade, Vandana Chandra, and Frances Cossar
Informal Sector in Francophone Africa: Firm Size, Productivity, and Institutions (2012)
by Nancy Benjamin and Ahmadou Aly Mbaye
Financing Africas Cities: The Imperative of Local Investment (2012) by Thierry Paulais
Structural Transformation and Rural Change Revisited: Challenges for Late Developing
Countries in a Globalizing World (2012) by Bruno Losch, Sandrine Frguin-Gresh, and
Eric Thomas White
The Political Economy of Decentralization in Sub-Saharan Africa: A New Implementation
Model (2013) edited by Bernard Dafflon and Thierry Madis
Empowering Women: Legal Rights and Economic Opportunities in Africa (2013)
by Mary Hallward-Driemeier and Tazeen Hasan
Enterprising Women: Expanding Economic Opportunities in Africa (2013)
by Mary Hallward-Driemeier
Urban Labor Markets in Sub-Saharan Africa (2013) edited by Philippe De Vreyer and
Franois Roubaud
Securing Africas Land for Shared Prosperity: A Program to Scale Up Reforms and Investments
(2013) by Frank F. K. Byamugisha

All books in the Africa Development Forum series are available for free at
https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/handle/10986/2150
Foreword xix
Acknowledgments xxi
About the Authors xxiii
Acronyms and Abbreviations xxvii

Overview Youth Employment in Sub-Saharan Africa 1


Africas Large Youth Population 2
Growth, Jobs, and Africas Labor ForceNow and in the Future 3
Youths Transition to Productive Employment 6
Policy Priorities for Addressing Youth Employment 8
Human Capital: The Fundamental Role of Basic Education 10
Raising the Productivity of Smallholder Farmers 11
Increasing the Productivity of Nonfarm Household Enterprises 15
Improving Competitiveness to Boost Modern Sector Wage Jobs 18
Building an Effective Youth Employment Policy 21
Notes 22
References 22

1 Opportunities and Challenges for Youth Employment in Africa 25


Africas Working-Age Population: Very Young and Growing Rapidly 25
Can Africas Youth Bring an Economic Advantage? 26
What Is a Job, and Where Do Most Africans Find One? 28
Growth, Jobs, and Africas Labor ForceNow and in the Future 30
Framework of This Report 41
Notes 41
References 42

Focus Note 1 Jobs: More Than Just Income 43


The Value of Jobs 43
Jobs and Aspirations 44
ix
x Contents

Jobs and Development 45


References 47

2 Youth: A Time of Transitions 49


Youths Transition from School 50
Youths Transition to Work 53
The Parallel Transitions: Choices Influencing Health, Family Formation, and
Civic Engagement 60
Challenges for Females Transitioning to Work 62
Facilitating Transitions from School, to Work, and across Sectors of Employment 64
Notes 64
References 64

3 Skills for Productive Employment 67


Schooling, Educational Attainment, and Work 68
Building a Foundation: Cognitive, Socioemotional, and Behavioral Skills 75
Building Skills through Post-School Training 89
Government Interventions and the Post-school Training Market 94
Conclusion: A Skills Agenda for Youth 102
Notes 103
References 104

4 Agriculture as a Sector of Opportunity for Young Africans 113


Agriculture: Potential Opportunity, Room to Grow 114
Recognizing the Opportunity in Agriculture for Young People 117
Agricultural Career Paths for the Future 120
Lifting Key Constraints on Capital, Land, and Skills 123
Land Policies That Benefit the Young 127
Enhancing Skills and Building a Better Educational Foundation 130
Current Agricultural Programs Deliver Too Little, Too Slowly,
to Meet the Needs of Africas Young People 135
Harnessing Agricultures Youth Dividend 137
Notes 137
References 138

Focus Note 2 Safety Nets and Pathways to Productive Employment 142


Short-Term Benefits of Safety Net Programs 142
Safety Nets Plus Explicit Productive Components 143
Do Complementary Interventions Open Pathways toward Productive Employment
for Youth? 144
Contents xi

Safety Nets as Vehicles to Deliver Interventions Aimed at Improving Youth


Employment Outcomes 145
Notes 146
References 146

5 Creating Productive Employment for Youth in the Household Enterprise


Sector 149
The Household Enterprise Sector Today 152
The Business: Constraints and Opportunities 153
Constraints for Young People to Enter the HE Sector 157
Creating and Sustaining Productive Employment in Household Enterprises 159
What Should Governments Do to Help Equip Youth with Skills for the HE
Sector? 167
Market Access and Voice 174
Conclusion 177
Notes 178
References 180

Focus Note 3 Financial Inclusion and the Transition to Sustainable Livelihoods


for Young People 183
Gaps in Access to Savings and Credit 183
Formal Savings Services: Issues and Options 184
Formal Credit Services: Challenges in Expanding Options for Smallholders, Household
Enterprises, and Young People 188
Notes 194
References 195

6 Raising Productivity in Africas Modern Wage Enterprises to Foster Job Growth


for Youth 197
Africas Modern Enterprise Sector: An Overview 198
Modern Manufacturing Delivers Little Employment, Few Exports 199
How Competitive Is Modern Manufacturing in Africa? 200
Sources of Productivity Gaps in African Manufacturing 207
Making African Firms Competitive: Priorities for Improving the Business Climate and
Workforce Skills 212
Building Skills for the Modern Wage Sector 224
Many Options to Promote Competitive Modern Enterprises 231
Notes 232
References 233
xii Contents

Focus Note 4 Youth Unemployment in South Africa: Different Configuration,


Different Approaches 238
Conventional Perceptions of the Causes of Unemployment 238
The Real Unemployment Problem: Slow Growth 239
Inefficient Job Search and Matching Processes 240
Policies to Reduce Unemployment 240
References 241

7 Conclusion: Building an Effective Youth Employment Policy 243


A Programmatic Approach 243
Do Now for Now: Address the Constraints Facing Households and Firms 244
Do Now for Later: Take Action for Medium-Term Payoffs 246

Appendix A Note on Data 249


Standardized and Harmonized Household and Labor Force Data 249
Demographic and Health Survey Data 249

Boxes
O.1 What is a job? 4
O.2 The youth employment challenge in resource-rich and some middle-income countries
in Africa 6
O.3 What will happen to employment if light manufacturing increases dramatically
in Africa? 7
O.4 Youth employment versus overall employment 8
O.5 Framework for analyzing youth employment 9
O.6 Does labor need to move out of agriculture as productivity grows? 13
1.1 Youth versus overall employment 29
1.2 How are our employment estimates done? 32
1.3 The challenge of diversifying output and employment in resource-rich countries:
Examples from Central Africa 34
1.4 How are our employment projections done? 36
F1.1 Employment, conflict, and violence: Is there a link? 46
2.1 Child labor in Sub-Saharan Africa 51
2.2 Intergenerational transmission of occupations in Africa 54
3.1 Estimating the returns to education 74
3.2 A second chance at education for African youth 81
3.3 Northern Ghanas School for Life second-chance education program 82
3.4 Returns to behavioral skills in wage employment: Evidence from Peru 86
3.5 Developing socioemotional and behavioral skills in postconflict settings 87
3.6 Promoting socioemotional and behavioral skills 88
3.7 On-the-job training varies by country and type of firm, and it is not for everyone 95
Contents xiii

3.8 Kenyas Jua Kali voucher program 98


3.9 Can incentives improve training quality and participation? 100
3.10 Impact evaluation to build the evidence base on youth employment programs 101
4.1 Women and girls: A major force within Africas agricultural labor force 115
4.2 When agriculture is more productive, economies can grow 116
4.3 Compromising growth and job creation without improving long-term food
security 117
4.4 Producer organizations and the transition to modern supply chains 119
4.5 Options for establishing or leaving a farm in Kenya 119
4.6 High-value agriculture and opportunities for employment off the farm 123
4.7 Red Fox Ethiopia: More technically sophisticated wage work 124
4.8 Documenting land rights: Encouraging investment and reducing the cost of land
transfers 128
4.9 Mexicos program to speed intergenerational land transfers 129
4.10 Information and communication technologies: Altering the flow of agricultural
information 131
4.11 Vocational agricultural education: A poor substitute for general education 132
4.12 Innovations in agricultural extension: Relying on farmers to improve service
delivery 134
4.13 Overview of the Comprehensive African Agriculture Development Programme
(CAADP) 136
5.1 What is a household enterprise? 150
5.2 Why do females earn less? Occupational segregation in the household enterprise
sector 154
5.3 Small and medium enterprises are not the same as household enterprises 156
5.4 Informal training is normal for youths seeking to operate a household enterprise 158
5.5 Rwanda: Many programs to support household enterprises, but little information
on results 159
5.6 Need for a comprehensive approach 161
5.7 Ghanas integrated approach to HE development 162
5.8 Weakening the local economy by perpetuating the machinga cycle in
Dar es Salaam 164
5.9 Clustering household enterprises for the benefit of all 165
5.10 Sources of credit used by households to start a business in Tanzania 166
5.11 Rural enterprise projects bolster skills and business development in Ghana and
Senegal 172
5.12 Taking a household business to the international market: Gahaya Links and
Rwandas peace baskets 176
5.13 Reducing isolation and exploitation through self-help associations 177
F3.1 Rural banks in Ghana: Reaching clients who are underserved by other banks 185
F3.2 Use of technology: Bringing secure financial services to new markets in
Kenya and India 186
F3.3 Linking smallholders to supply chains to improve their access to financial services 189
xiv Contents

F3.4 Shifting from group to individual liability lending as a positive microfinance


innovation: Evidence from the Philippines 190
F3.5 ROSCAs, VSLAs, SHGs, and SACCOs: Examples of informal savings and credit
systems 191
F3.6 Village women in Mali: Achieving food and financial security through savings and
credit groups 194
6.1 Where do young people figure in Africas wage employment picture? 201
6.2 Measurement issues and other limitations of unit labor costs 203
6.3 Does Africa really have a labor cost advantage? 207
6.4 The high price of inefficiency at the port of Dar es Salaam 215
6.5 Improving land transportation through increased international cooperation and
comprehensive procedural reforms: The Malaba border-crossing pilot 217
6.6 Who must pay bribes? How much? And does it matter? 221
6.7 Knowledge, technology, and the emergence of successful enterprise clusters in
Africa 223
6.8 Why have special economic zones failed to thrive in Africa, and what are the lessons
for the future? 224
6.9 Reforming TVET systems in Africa 226
6.10 Does government have a role in on-the-job training? 228

Figures
O.1 The structure of Sub-Saharan Africas population is different than that in other
regions 3
O.2 Over the past two decades, agricultures share in GDP contracted in Africa, but
manufacturing did not replace it 4
O.3 Where are Africans working? 5
O.4 Informal will be normal in 2020 6
O.5 The transition from school to work in Sub-Saharan Africa is slow 8
O.6 Family formation starts earlier for young women than for young men 9
O.7 Education shapes opportunities 10
O.8 Young people are unlikely to own land 14
O.9 At the same level of income per capita, national policies can produce very different
levels of financial inclusion 17
O.10 The share of youth in wage employment tracks the share in the general
population 18
1.1 Africas population is young and will remain so 26
1.2 The structure of Sub-Saharan Africas population is different than that in other
regions 27
1.3 Unlike in other regions, the number of young people in Sub-Saharan Africa will
increase dramatically in the near future 27
1.4 In East Asia, the dependency ratio changed quickly; in Sub-Saharan Africa, it is
changing, but slowly 28
1.5 The reduction in the total fertility rate has stalled in several African countries 29
Contents xv

1.6 Africas growth miracle, 200512 30


1.7 Over the past two decades, agricultures share in GDP contracted in Africa, but
manufacturing did not replace it 31
1.8 Exports are a smaller share of GDP in Africa than in East Asia and a larger share
than in South Asia, but African countries, even richer ones, export commodities,
not manufactured goods 31
1.9 The majority of Sub-Saharan Africas workers in low- and lower-middle-income
countries work in agriculture and in nonfarm household enterprises 32
1.10 Growth has moved the structure of employment away from agriculture in some
countries, but not others 33
1.11 Most wage jobs are in the private sector (but not in resource-rich countries) 33
1.12 Industrial wage employment has not risen with GDP in Africa the way it has in
manufacturing exporters at similar income levels 35
1.13 Where will Africas 125 million new jobs be created? 39
1.14 Informal will remain normal in much of Sub-Saharan Africa 39
1.15 Even game-changing growth will have limited effects on the distribution of
employment in the near term 40
F1.1 Jobs and life satisfaction across regions 44
F1.2 Jobs drive development 45
2.1 Many 18-year-olds in Africa are still in school, but half of them are still in primary
school 50
B2.1.1 Percentage of children working 51
2.2 School and work are often combined 52
2.3 Most Sub-Saharan African youths start out working for their families and then
become self-employed 53
B2.2.1 Intergenerational transmission of employment sector in five African countries 54
2.4 Youths in urban Tanzania are unlikely to move between employment sectors
during their working lives 55
2.5 Youth transitions to sector of employment vary across urban and rural areas and
between male and female youths 56
2.6 Sectoral mobility among urban youth in Uganda 57
2.7 In Tanzania, many work in two or more activities 57
2.8 Younger people are most often engaged in casual wage employment 58
2.9 Personal networks are key to finding a job 58
2.10 Migration increases mobility across sectors of employment 60
2.11 Family formation starts earlier for young women than for young men 61
2.12 As they get older, young people increasingly engage as citizens 62
3.1 Primary school completion rates have risen substantially in Sub-Saharan Africa,
19902011 68
3.2 Africas young people have more education than ever before, but average education
attainment is still low 69
3.3 Educational attainment in Sub-Saharan Africa is projected to rise substantially 69
3.4 Schooling maps to sector of employment 70
xvi Contents

3.5 Wage workers with more schooling are more likely to work under contract 70
3.6 Relationships between schooling and work vary depending on gender and
urbanization 71
3.7 Education is associated with higher earnings in household enterprises 72
3.8 Education is associated with higher wages 73
3.9 The convex relationship between earnings and education: Schooling and earnings in
urban West Africa 75
3.10 The ability to read in early grades is alarmingly low 77
3.11 By the end of primary school, many students have not mastered even
basic competencies: 2007 SACMEQ results for math and reading proficiency 77
3.12 Secondary school students in Sub-Saharan Africa perform poorly on
internationally comparable assessments: TIMSS results for math proficiency, 2011 78
3.13 Learning trajectories by age are flat in Guinea-Bissau 78
3.14 Learning trajectories by grade are flat: Performance on test scores in selected
African countries, by educational achievement 79
B3.2.1 Proportion of 15- to 19-year-olds who have completed each grade 81
3.15 Cognitive skills increase slowly, especially for the poorest 83
3.16 Behavioral skills take longer to develop than cognitive skills 84
3.17 The returns to schooling are higher for those with greater ability: Returns of an
additional year of schooling by quantile 88
3.18 Many young people, especially in West Africa, have been an apprentice, whereas
experience with TVET is less prevalent 90
3.19 Apprenticeships are geared toward youths with lower levels of education 91
3.20 TVET is geared toward wage work, whereas apprenticeships lead to working in either a
household enterprise or wage work 92
3.21 Africa has a wide range of informal private training providers, 2009 93
B3.7.1 On-the-job training in African firms varies by country 95
B3.7.2 On-the-job training in African firms varies by firm size and export orientation,
2006 95
3.22 There are stark differences between rich and poor in experience with apprenticeships
and TVET 97
3.23 Men and women take up different types of vocational training in Kenya 97
3.24 Training costs and the price paid by participants vary by type of training in Kenya 99
B4.2.1 Higher total factor productivity helped U.S. farmers to compensate for declining
terms of trade, 19752009 116
4.1 The young do not typically own land 118
F2.1 Impacts of conditional cash transfers plus business grants or conditional cash transfers
plus skills training in Nicaragua 145
B5.1.1 Most people working in the HE sector are owners 150
B.5.1.2 Most HEs are family operations 150
5.1 Household enterprises are an important share of nonfarm employment in low- and
middle-income countries 151
5.2 In Africa, as labor moved out of agriculture, more people moved into the HE sector than
into private wage employment 151
Contents xvii

5.3 Most HEs are in the trading sector 152


B5.2.1 Earnings are higher in male-dominated subsectors than in female-dominated
subsectors 154
5.4 Younger HE owners tend to have more education than older ones 155
5.5 Household enterprise owners tend to be over 25 years of age 158
F3.1 Percentage of population ages 15 and older who reported saving any amount in the last
12 months, by savings mechanism 184
F3.2 Percentage of individuals with an account at a formal financial institution 188
6.1 Africa has less nonfarm wage employment than other regions 199
6.2 Wage employment is growing inconsistently across Africa 200
B6.1.1 The share of youth in wage employment tracks the share in the general population 201
6.3 Services form the largest share of nonfarm wage employment; within manufacturing,
the food and textile industries dominate 201
6.4 Africas modern wage manufacturing sector continues to have a small share in
employment 202
6.5 African firms export relatively little 203
6.6 Chinas unit labor costs have remained below those of other emerging economies 204
6.7 Growth in manufacturing wage employment has been inconsistent across African
countries 205
6.8 Based on unit labor costs, some African countries could become competitive with other
emerging economies 205
6.9 Africa does not have a uniform wage advantage over other developing regions 206
6.10 Labor productivity is particularly low in low-income African countries 208
6.11 African workers are not as well equipped with fixed capital as their counterparts
elsewhere in the world 208
6.12 African countries have lower productivity than other regions 209
6.13 Africa fares poorly in firm-reported indicators of transport, water, and electricity
supply 210
6.14 Decomposing textile industry productivity 211
6.15 Trading across borders is expensive and slow in Africa 212
6.16 African firms use relatively little bank financing 218
6.17 Coverage of credit bureaus is generally low in Africa 218
6.18 Africa has the highest formal costs of setting up a business 220
6.19 Business setup costs are higher in resource-rich African countries 220
F4.1 Patterns in economic and employment growth in South Africa 239

Tables
BO.6.1 Increase in crop area harvested, agricultural labor force, and output per worker in
Sub-Saharan Africa, 19602008 and 19902008 13
O.1 Priority actions to take now to address the youth employment challenge 22
1.1 African countries have less wage employment than high-growth comparator
countries 35
B1.4.1 Growth elasticities of employment 37
xviii Contents

1.2 Average annual growth, by sector and country income level, 200520 38
1.3 Framework of this report 41
B3.2.1 Costs per pupil in second-chance education programs and formal public schools 82
3.1 Developmental tasks, by age 84
4.1 Wholesale prices of unprocessed maize and rice in selected countries (average,
JanuaryApril 2012) 115
B4.2.1 Percentage change in prices of selected food products in the United States,
19602010 116
4.2 Pathways for agricultural employment and their requirements 120
B4.6.1 Employment in horticultural supply chains in Sub-Saharan Africa 123
5.1 Rural versus urban household enterprises 153
5.2 Sources of capital for household enterprises: Start-up and credit for operations 155
7.1 Priority actions to take now to address the youth employment challenge 245
A.1 Standardized and Harmonized Household and Labor Force Surveys used in report
analysis 250
A.2 Demographic and Health Survey Data Sets used in report analysis 251
Africa is now the worlds youngest continent. With its comprehensive analysis of youth
While national populations in most parts employment in Africa, this report updates how
of the world are aging, young people are now and where countries are creating jobs and
in the majority in many African countries. looks to the future of promising new direc-
Whether they live in the cities and towns of a tions for the continent. It focuses on how pol-
rapidly urbanizing Africa, or in rural villages icy makers can help young people walk
and settlements; whether they come from through the front door of the labor market and
middle-class backgrounds or from vulnerable into both fast-growing modern wage jobs as
families that are living in poverty, one thing is well as into other sustainable economic oppor-
certainthese young people have high expec- tunitiesimproving income by raising pro-
tations, and African policy makers are increas- ductivity in the informal sector, where many
ingly concerned about how to meet them. young people will work for the foreseeable
Today, jobs and opportunity for young peo- future.
ple are consistently at the top of the develop- Youth employment is not a one-dimen-
ment agenda in virtually every country on the sional challenge. Addressing it will require
continent. attention to the quality of basic education and
Although data on employment is patchy training to improve young peoples produc-
and not generally comparable across African tivity, while also removing current obstacles
countries, we can nonetheless learn much from that hinder progress in agriculture, household
the available evidence. Contrary to popular enterprises, and the modern wage sector.
perceptions, unemployment is but one of the If children do not know how to read or do
main problems facing low-income countries in basic mathematics at the end of their years in
Africa. Beyond simple unemployment, Africa is primary school, this basic skills gap has a pro-
challenged to address underemployment: in the found impact on productivity in adulthood.
absence of adequate social safety nets, young If young people have weak access to land and
people are compelled to take low-productivity, to credit, their dreams of becoming entrepre-
low-wage jobs for their very survival. neurs or working in high-paying, rewarding
While urban youth tend to be much more jobs will be dashed. If university graduates
vocal about their challenges and aspirations, acquire degrees and knowledge that have little
and highly visible in their job-seeking, millions practical application in Africas fast-changing
of young men and women in rural and semi- labor force, then their investment of time and
urban areas struggle to find better-paying jobs money will have been largely in vain, with
and opportunities to escape poverty for them- few prospects for strong careers in the private
selves and their families. sector.

xix
xx Foreword

I hope that this report will help African advantage of the opportunities that are
countries develop customized strategies to steadily growing across the continent whether
address youth employment and to invest in in export-oriented manufacturing, high-
better information on how well these strate- productivity agriculture and agribusinesses, or
gies are working. profitable small enterprises.
Collectively we must redouble our efforts Africas future will be profoundly shaped by
to meet the paramount challenge of youth how well it manages this challenge.
employment so that young people can take

Makhtar Diop

Vice President for Africa


The World Bank
This report was prepared by a core team led by Kadzamira. The report was edited by Kelly
Deon Filmer and Louise Fox and comprising Cassaday (overall) and Amy Gautam (who
Karen Brooks, Aparajita Goyal, Taye Mengis- had primary editing responsibility for chapter
tae, Patrick Premand, Dena Ringold, Siddharth 4). Several World Bank staff, as well as policy
Sharma, and Sergiy Zorya. Additional contri- makers, academics, and other stakeholders
butions were made by Shubha Chakravarty, provided comments at various stages of the
Florence Kondylis, Obert Pimhidzai, Raju development of this report. Richard Damania,
Singh, and Erik von Uexkull. The team was Mary Hallward-Driemeier, Margaret Grosh,
directed by Shantanayan Devarajan and Ritva and Ravi Kanbur provided careful peer review
Reinikka. Research assistance was provided by comments. Any errors or omissions are the
Jorge Munoz, Lena Nguyen, and Thokozani responsibility of the team.

xxi
Deon Filmer
Deon Filmer is a Lead Economist in the World Banks research department and the HD Econom-
ics Unit of the Human Development department of the World Banks Africa region. He works on
issues of youth employment and skills, service delivery, and impact evaluation of policies and pro-
grams to improve human development outcomes. He has spent many years in the World Banks
research department where his research has covered the areas of education, health, social protec-
tion, and poverty analysis. He has published numerous articles in top-ranked economics journals.
Recent work includes studies of the impact of demand-side programs on schooling outcomes;
of the roles of poverty, orphanhood, and disability in explaining education inequalities; of the
determinants of effective service delivery and the evaluation of interventions aimed at improving
it; of the determinants of fertility behavior, and on trends in adult mortality around the world. He
was a core team member of the World Development Report 1995: Workers in an Integrating World
and World Development Report 2004: Making Services Work for Poor People, and a contributor to
the World Development Report 2007: Development and the Next Generation. He holds PhD and MA
degrees from Brown University.

Louise Fox
Louise Fox was, until her recent retirement from the World Bank, a Lead Economist in the Africa
region of the World Bank. During her long career at the Bank, she worked on a wide range of
topics; her specialties included the analysis of employment and labor markets, poverty and
inequality, and the economics of social service delivery, with the overarching theme of the links
among policies, outcomes, and poverty reduction. Prior to her position in the Africa region, Dr.
Fox spent 13 years working on issues of labor market adjustment, poverty, and social protection
in transition economies, including China and Mongolia, the Baltic States, and Eastern Europe.
Before that she researched poverty, inequality, and macroeconomic adjustment in Latin America.
Her most recent published work has been on the topics of poverty reduction and inclusive growth,
the political economy of poverty reduction, and on employment, labor markets, and labor regula-
tion, all with respect to Sub-Saharan Africa. She has also published in the areas of pension reform,
reform of child welfare systems, social protection, public expenditures in the social sectors and
poverty reduction, female-headed households and child welfare, stabilization policies and poverty
reduction, the social costs of adjustment, and the economic history of poverty and inequality in
Brazil. Dr. Fox received a PhD from Vanderbilt University.

Karen Brooks
Karen Brooks is Director of the CGIAR research program on Policies, Institutions and Markets.
Brooks worked for the World Bank for 20 years. For the last 10 years of her tenure there, she
xxiii
xxiv About the Authors

managed analytical and operational programs in agriculture and rural development for the Africa
region. Brooks also worked extensively in both the Europe and Central Asia and Africa regions; in
the former on issues related to the transition from central planning, and in the latter on the invest-
ment and policy agenda associated with the renewed commitment to agricultural growth. Prior to
joining the World Bank, she was Associate Professor in the Department of Applied Economics at
the University of Minnesota. Brooks received both her PhD and MA degrees in Economics from
the University of Chicago, where she was a National Science Foundation Graduate Fellow.

Aparajita Goyal
Aparajita Goyal is an Economist with the Agriculture team of the Africa region of the World
Bank. Previously, she worked in the Banks Agriculture and Environment Services department, as
well as the Banks Development Research Group. Her work has focused on microeconomic issues
of development, with a particular emphasis on technological innovation in agriculture, access
to markets, and intellectual property rights. Her work has been published in leading academic
economics journals, and has also been featured in the popular press, including Frontline, The
Economist, and the Wall Street Journal. She has previously worked with ActionAid in London and
the Right to Food Campaign in India. She obtained a PhD in Economics from the University of
Maryland and an MSc degree in Development Studies from the London School of Economics.

Taye Mengistae
Taye Mengistae is a Senior Economist with the Finance and Private Sector Development, Eastern
and Southern Africa team of the World Banks Africa region. Previously he was with the Banks
Development Research Group. He has published numerous articles in leading academic economic
journals. His country work experience includes South Africa, Kenya, Ghana, Ethiopia, Zambia,
India, China, and Pakistan. His main areas of research interest include globalization, export com-
petitiveness, capital flows, innovation, and education. He holds a PhD from Oxford University
and an MA degree from the University of Leeds.

Patrick Premand
Patrick Premand is a Senior Economist in the HD Economics Unit of the Human Development
department of the World Banks Africa region. He works on issues of youth employment and
skills, early child nutrition and development, and the impact evaluation of policies and programs
to improve human development outcomes. He has previously held positions in the Office of the
Chief Economist for Human Development Department and in the Banks Latin America and
Caribbean regions Poverty team. He holds PhD and MSc degrees from Oxford University.

Dena Ringold
Dena Ringold is a Lead Economist in the Social Protection team of the World Banks Africa region,
with fifteen years experience working in Human Development at the World Bank. Her research
interests include social inclusion of minorities, safety nets, and governance. Prior to joining the
Africa region, she was a core team member of the World Development Report 2013: Jobs, and she
previously worked in the Office of the Chief Economist for Human Development. Dena began her
career at the Bank in the Europe and Central Asia (ECA) region, where she worked on operations
and analytical programs with a focus on social protection and local service delivery in Central and
Southeastern Europe. While in ECA she helped to initiate the Banks first qualitative and quantita-
tive analyses of the Roma minority and helped to set up the Roma Education Fund. She has also
worked on social protection in the Latin American and Caribbean (LAC) region. In 2005, Dena
was an Ian Axford Fellow in public policy based at the Ministry of Maori Development in Wel-
lington, New Zealand. She holds an MSc in Economics and Government from the London School
of Economics and a BA in History and Political Science from Swarthmore College.
About the Authors xxv

Siddharth Sharma
Siddharth Sharma is an Economist in the Finance and Private Sector team of the World Banks
Europe and Central Asia Region. He previously worked in the Social Protection team of the Africa
region and in the Poverty team of the Middle East and North Africa region. His research focus
has been on labor markets, productivity, and firms. He has published academic papers in leading
economics journals. He holds a PhD from Yale University, and an MA and BA from the University
of Delhi

Sergiy Zorya
Segiy Zorya is a Senior Economist in the Sustainable Development team of the World Banks East
Asia and Pacific Region. He was previously with the Banks Agriculture and Rural Development
(ARD) Department. He works on issues pertaining rural policies and strategies, food prices, man-
agement of public expenditure, and global food security. Prior to ARD, he worked in three Bank
regions: Europe and Central Asia, East Asia and Pacific, and Africa. His most recent work was in
South Sudan, Tanzania, Uganda, and Zambia. Sergiy holds an MA degree in Agricultural Econom-
ics from the Agricultural University of Zhytomyr, Ukraine, and a PhD in Agricultural Economics
from the Georg-August University of Goettingen, Germany.
AfDB African Development Bank FAO Food and Agriculture
ALPs accelerated learning programs Organization (United Nations)
BARA Bureau of Applied Research in FET further education and training
Anthropology G2P government to person
CAADP Comprehensive African GDP gross domestic product
Agriculture Development GNI gross national income
Programme GRADE Grupo de Anlisis para el
CECAM Caisses dEpargne et de Desarrollo
Crdit Agricole Mutuelles HE household enterprise
(Madagascar) HIV/AIDS human immunodeficiency
CEMAC Commission de la virus/acquired
Communaut Economique immunodeficiency syndrome
et Montaire de lAfrique ICT information and
Centrale (Economic and communication technology
Monetary Community of
IDS Institute of Development
Central Africa)
Studies
CFA Communaut Financire
IFAD International Fund for
dAfrique
Agricultural Development
COTVET Council for TVET (Ghana) IFC International Finance
CREATE Consortium for Research on Corporation (World Bank
Educational Access, Transitions, Group)
and Equity IFPRI International Food Policy
CREO Comprehensive Review of Research Institute
Education Outcomes IIEP International Institute for
CSAE Centre for the Study of African Educational Planning
Economies ILO International Labour
DFID Department for International Organization
Development (United Kingdom) IMF International Monetary Fund
DHS Demographic and Health IPA Innovations for Poverty Action
Surveys IPAR Institute of Policy Analysis and
EPAG Economic Empowerment of Research Rwanda
Adolescent Girls and Young IPPG Institutions and Pro-Poor
Women (Liberia) Growth
xxvii
xxviii Acronyms and Abbreviations

KEPSA Kenya Private Sector Alliance SEZ special economic zone


KYEP Kenya Youth Empowerment SfC Saving for Change
Project SfL School for Life
LISGIS Liberia Institute of Statistics SHG self-help group
and Geo-Information Services SHIP Survey-Based Harmonized
MFI microfinance institution Indicators Program
MICS Multiple Indicator Cluster SIEF Spanish Impact Evaluation
Survey Fund
MIJARC Mouvement International de SMEs small and medium enterprises
la Jeunesse Agricole et Rurale SPV special-purpose vehicle
Catholique
SSATP Sub-Saharan Africa Transport
MIX Microfinance Information Policy Program
Exchange
SUMATRA Surface and Marine Transport
MSME micro, small, and medium Authority (Tanzania)
enterprise
TESDA Technical Education and Skills
NBSSI National Board for Small Scale Development Authority (the
Industries (Ghana) Philippines)
NGO nongovernmental organization TEVETA Technical Education and
OECD Organisation for Economic Vocational Education and
Co-operation and Training Association (Malawi)
Development TFP total factor productivity
OHADA Organisation pour TICTS Tanzania International
lHarmonisation en Afrique Container Services
du Droit des Affaires
TIMSS Trends in Math and Science
(Organization for the
Study
Harmonization of Business
Law in Africa) TPA Tanzania Port Authority
OSBP one-stop border post TVET technical vocational education
and training
PMC project management consultant
TVVP Technical and Vocational
PROMER Promotion of Rural
Vouchers Program (Kenya)
Entrepreneurship (Senegal)
UEMOA Union Economique et
R&D research and development
Montaire Ouest Africaine
RCB rural and community bank (West African Economic and
RCT randomized controlled trial Monetary Union)
REP Rural Enterprise Project UNESCO United Nations Educational,
(Ghana) Scientific, and Cultural
ROSCA rotating savings and credit Organization
association UNICEF United Nations Childrens Fund
SACCO savings and credit cooperative UNIDO United Nations Industrial
SACMEQ Southern Africa Consortium Development Organization
for Measuring Educational USAID United States Agency for
Quality International Development
SEWA Self-Employed Womens VSLA village savings and loan
Association (India) association
Overview

Youth Employment
in Sub-Saharan Africa

S
ub-Saharan Africa has just experienced The incidence of poverty has fallen as Sub-
one of the best decades of growth since Saharan economies have expanded, yet overall
the 1960s. Between 2000 and 2012, gross growth in Sub-Saharan Africa has not been
domestic product (GDP) grew more than as pro-poor as growth in other regions. Each
4.5 percent a year on average, compared to 1 percent increase in average per capita con-
around 2 percent in the prior 20 years (World sumption has been associated with a reduction
Bank various years). In 2012, the regions GDP in poverty of 0.69 percent; elsewhere in the
growth was estimated at 4.7 percent5.8 per- world, that reduction has averaged just over
cent if South Africa is excluded (World Bank 2 percent (World Bank 2013). In part, Afri-
2013). About one-quarter of countries in the cas poverty reduction has been less marked
region grew at 7 percent or better, and several because in many countries the source of
African countries are among the fastest grow- growth is primarily oil, gas, and mineral extrac-
ing in the world. Medium-term growth pros- tion, not labor-intensive sectors such as agri-
pects remain strong and should be supported culture or manufacturing. Young people, who
by a rebounding global economy. have weaker links to the world of work than
At the same time, many Africans are dissat- the general population, are therefore doubly
isfied with this economic progress. According disadvantaged.
to the latest Afrobarometer data, 65 percent of Although the current generation of Africans
the surveyed population consider economic entering the labor force is the most educated
conditions in their country to be the same or ever, many are finding that their prospects for
worse than the year prior, 53 percent rate their employment and earnings differ very little
national economic condition as very bad or from those of their parents. In a few countries,
fairly bad, and 48 percent say the same about they are worse.
their personal economic condition (Afro- Youth in urban areas have been vocal about
barometer 201112. www.afrobarometer.org). their dissatisfaction. Urban demonstrations

1
2 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

consisting primarily of politically active and markets and can, in the longer term, stimu-
disaffected youth have become more common late economic growth and development
in African capitals. The causes of urban violence The role of mineral exportswhich have
undoubtedly include factors much broader shaped the structure of recent economic
than employment status (such as inequality and growth but failed to sufficiently increase
exclusion), yet dissatisfaction with opportuni- the number of wage jobs most desired by
ties, especially in relation to expectations, can youthand the prospects for reversing this
be a contributing factor. Understandably con- trend in the future
cerned, especially in light of the Arab Spring,
policy makers in Sub-Saharan Africa are mak-
The largely untapped reservoir of opportu-
nities in farming, at a time of high global
ing youth employment a high priority. Focusing prices for agricultural commodities and ris-
on urban youth, they are seeking policies and ing local and regional demand for food
programs that can ameliorate the dissatisfac-
tion of young people and ease their transition The massive expansion in access to educa-
tion, which is adding many years of school-
into adulthood by encouraging the creation of
ing, but much less learning, during child-
sustainable, productive employment.
hood and youth
But urban youth are only the most visible
and audible part of the employment problem. The aspirations of youth and policy mak-
The majority of young people still live in Afri- ers, which focus on the wage employment
cas rural areas and small towns. Poorer and less sector at the expense of more immediate
educated than their urban counterparts, they opportunities in family farming and house-
too struggle to find pathways to adulthood, hold enterprises.
especially to stable, remunerative employment Recognizing that it is the private sector that
that allows them to support a family. For young creates jobs, the report examines obstacles
women, the pathway can be especially treacher- faced by households and firms in meeting
ous. As they navigate the school-to-work tran- the youth employment challenge. It focuses
sition, their control over their own destiny and primarily on productivityin agriculture, in
their employment choices may be limited by nonfarm household enterprises (HEs), and in
social norms. the modern wage sectorbecause productivity
The challenge of youth employment in is the key to higher earnings as well as to more
Africa may appear daunting, yet Africas vibrant stable, less vulnerable, livelihoods. To respond
youth represent an enormous opportunity, to the policy makers dilemma, the report iden-
particularly now, when populations in much tifies specific areas where government interven-
of the world are aging rapidly. Youth not only tion can reduce those obstacles to productivity
need jobs, but also create them. Africas grow- for households and firms, leading to brighter
ing labor force can be an asset in the global employment prospects for youth, their parents,
marketplace. Realizing this brighter vision for and their own children.
Africas future, however, will require a clearer
understanding of how to benefit from this asset.
Meeting the youth employment challenge in all
Africas Large Youth Population
its dimensionsdemographic, economic, and
socialand understanding the forces that cre-
Sub-Saharan Africa today faces an unprec-
ated the challenge, can open potential pathways
edented opportunity. Half of the population is
toward a better life for young people and better
under 25 years of age. Each year between 2015
prospects for the countries where they live.
and 2035, there will be half a million more
This report begins by laying out the dynam-
15-year-olds than the year before. Meanwhile,
ics of the youth employment challenge in Sub-
the population in the rest of the world is, or will
Saharan Africa today:
soon be, aging (figure O.1).
The demographic transition, which created Africas youth bulge offers a range of oppor-
the youth bulge that is entering African labor tunities. First, the worlds goods and services
Overview 3

Figure O.1

a. Sub-Saharan Africa b. South Asia c. East Asia and Pacific

80+ 80+ 80+


7074 7074 7074
6064 6064 6064
Age group (years)

Age group (years)

Age group (years)


5054 5054 5054
4044 4044 4044
3034 3034 3034
2024 2024 2024
1014 1014 1014
04 04 04
100 80 60 40 20 0 20 40 60 80 100 100 80 60 40 20 0 20 40 60 80 100 160 120 80 40 0 40 80 120 160
Population (millions) Population (millions) Population (millions)

Male 2035 Male 2015 Female 2015 Female 2035


Source: Based on United Nations 2011.

cannot be produced without working- primary commodities for their exports. The
age labor. Sub-Saharan Africa, along with failure of this growth to reduce poverty is stark
South Asia, can be the main supplier of the in several countries, including oil-rich Angola,
worlds workforce, either by producing goods Gabon, and Nigeria, and noticeable in oth-
and services in the region or by sending work- ers, such as Mozambique and Zambia. Labor-
ers to regions with a shortage of workers. Sec- intensive manufactured exportsthe force
ond, manufacturing wages in other regions are behind employment and economic transfor-
rising. Africas labor force should compete for mation in East Asiaare far from taking off in
these jobs. Third, increasing concentrations of Africa. In fact, manufacturings share in GDP is
workers in urban areas can be a source of inno- lower in Sub-Saharan Africa today than it was
vation and rapid economic growth (World Bank in 1980; over the same period in Asia, it rose
2008). Young people will be at the forefront of in both lower- and middle-income countries
these developments. Finally, if fertility contin- (figure O.2).
ues to decline, rapid growth in Africas work- To understand the challenge of youth
force will mean that the number of working- employment in this context, we start with where
age adults relative to dependents will rise from Africans work today (see box O.1 for an expla-
just around 1 in 1985 to close to 1.7 in 2050, nation of how this report defines employment).
providing the space for savings, investment, Contrary to popular perceptions, measured
and sustained economic growth. Yet the demo- unemployment in low-income Africa is only
graphic transition is not automatic. A critical 3 percent.1 Even in lower-middle-income coun-
concern is that the decline in fertility rates has tries, unemployment is quite low (figure O.3).
stalledor not even startedin many African These low unemployment rates may seem
countries. But it is also a critical concern that counterintuitive, given widespread concern
those of working age are able to be productive. about unemployed youth, but most Africans
simply cannot afford to be idle. Very few fami-
lies can fully support a recent graduate while
Growth, Jobs, and Africas Labor he or she seeks a job. That the unemployment
ForceNow and in the Future rate is highest among university graduates
who mostly come from the top end of the
Despite 15 years of relatively rapid economic income distributionis no coincidence. Only
growth averaging more than 4.5 percent a year, in upper-income countries, with broader safety
almost all African countries still depend on nets, does substantial unemployment persist,
4 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Figure O.2 Over the past two decades, agricultures share in GDP contracted in Africa, but manufacturing did not replace it

a. Low-income countries b. Lower-middle-income countries


100 100
90 90
80 80
70 70
60 60
Percent

Percent
50 50
40 40
30 30
20 20
10 10
0 0
1990 2010 1990 2010 1990 2010 1990 2010 1990 2010 1990 2010
Sub-Saharan Africa South Asia East Asia and Pacific Sub-Saharan Africa South Asia East Asia and Pacific
Agriculture Industry (excluding manufacturing) Manufacturing Services

Source: World Bank various years.

Box O.1

What is a job?
In assessing the challenges of youth employment, it is impor- self-confidence; they can contribute to an individuals overall
tant to take stock of what it means to have a job and to have life satisfaction. Not all jobs contribute to these dimensions
employment. To some, having a job is synonymous with of well-being. The type of job, working conditions, contract,
having a wage or salaried position with an employer. Most benefits, and safety and security at work all matter. Beyond
work in Africa is not structured that way, however. This study personal life satisfaction, jobs also contribute to social cohe-
follows the approach adopted in the World Development sion through various channels: jobs can shape identities and
Report 2013: Jobs, which defines jobs as activities that gen- how individuals relate to one another, jobs can connect peo-
erate actual or imputed income, monetary or in kind, for- ple to one another through networks, and the distribution
mal or informal. That report also notes that not all forms of jobs within society and the perceptions about who has
or work can be considered jobsfor example, activities that access to opportunities, and why, can shape peoples expec-
are performed against the will of the worker or that violate tations and aspirations for the future, their sense of having a
basic human rights. stake in society, and their perceptions of fairness. All of these
Across countries, including those in Sub-Saharan Africa, intrinsic aspects of jobs are particularly important for youth.
people report that jobs have a broader importance than the
income they provide. Jobs can convey identity, status, and Source: World Bank 2012.

including among youth. Because the youth regular wage, sometimes with associated ben-
employment challenge is configured somewhat efits. In low-income countries, these jobs are
differently in Africas resource-rich countries divided roughly equally between the public
and some middle-income countries, they will and private sectors, although the private share
need to approach the challenge in somewhat grows with per capita income. The industrial
different ways (see box O.2). sector (mining, manufacturing, and construc-
Where do most Sub-Saharan Africans find tion) accounts for less than 20 percent of wage
employment? About 16 percent of those in the jobs (about 3 percent of total employment).
labor force have wage jobsjobs that pay a The remaining jobs are either on family farms
Overview 5

(62 percent) or in household enterprises (22 Figure O.3 Where are Africans working?
percent), which may be collectively described Estimated structure of employment in Sub-Saharan Africa by country type, 2010
as the informal sector (see box O.5 for a defi- 100
nition of household enterprises). These kinds
90
of jobsworking a small plot of land, selling
80
vegetables on the street, sewing clothes in ones
homeoften generate low earnings, partly 70

because the enterprises tend to be tiny, typi- 60

% of total
cally involving only the family. 50
Will this pattern of employment persist? 40
After all, countries that are not resource rich
30
are creating private wage jobs at a rapid clip
often faster than GDP is growing. The kinds of 20

jobs that are created will depend partly on the 10


structure of growth that Africa attains. Growth 0
and employment projections for this report Low-income Lower-middle- Resource-rich Upper-middle- Total
countries income countries income countries
assume that growth will remain strong (56 countries countries
percent a year) and will be fueled by Africas 183 40 150 21 395a
natural resourcesminerals and agriculture. Labor force (millions)
The mineral sector is not expected to create
Agriculture Household enterprises Wage services Wage industry Unemployed
very many jobs. Increases in wage employment
(as a share of total employment) will come Source: Fox et al. 2013.
from continued diversification of output and Note: On the horizontal axis, numbers show size of the labor force, ages 1564, in each group.
Resource-rich countries included are Angola, Chad, the Democratic Republic of Congo, Guinea,
exports and from increased domestic demand Nigeria, the Republic of Congo, Sudan and Republic of South Sudan, and Zambia.
a. Numbers do not add to total because of rounding.
for services as incomes grow. Since service
employment is projected to grow faster than
employment in industrial sectors, as it has in tivity of the almost 80 percent of the workforce
the past, most nonfarm employment will be who will be in the informal sectorthereby
created there. Based on these assumptions, the addressing the underemployment associated
number of industrial sector wage and salary with work in this sector. The size of the youth
jobs is projected to increase 55 percent over the bulge in Africa and the current structure of the
next 10 years. The problem is that this growth economy mean that the majority of this gen-
starts from such a small base that it does not erations workers will remain in the informal
even come close to absorbing the millions of sector for the duration of their working lives.
young people entering the labor force each To be sure, in the long run these workers (or
year. Because of the low base, the share of their children) will move to the formal sector,
industrial wage jobs in total employment will like their counterparts in East Asia and Latin
rise only from 3 to 4.5 percent in Sub-Saharan America.
Africa, still below the share in other developing This focus on raising productivity in the
regions. The share of wage jobs in the service informal sector may seem unusual, given the
sector is projected to rise from 13 to 22 percent. publicity around high unemployment among
In other words, over the next 10 years, at best university graduates and the recent emphasis
only one in four of Sub-Saharan Africas youth on creating jobs in the formal manufactur-
will find a wage job, and only a small fraction ing sector (Dinh et al. 2012). But university
of those jobs will be formal jobs in modern graduates still represent only a tiny fraction
enterprises. Most young people will end up (about 34 percent) of the labor force, come
working where their parents doin family from the richest households, and have the best
farms and household enterprises (figure O.4). job prospects. Creating jobs in the formal sec-
The employment challenge is therefore not tor is important and should be encouraged,
just to create jobs in the formal sector, impor- but the reality is that even if African countries
tant as that may be, but to increase the produc- were able to attract an extraordinary infusion
6 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box O.2

The youth employment challenge in resource-rich and some middle-income countries


in Africa
Resource-rich countries present particular challenges when it and Malaysia) or to non-resource-based primary commodities
comes to employment. Natural resource rents, if poorly man- (Chile)through sound macroeconomic policies, open trade
aged, lead to overvalued exchange rates and uncompetitive and investment policies, strategies to build human capital, and
real wages. Such conditions severely hamper job creation in a good business environment (Gelb and Grasmann 2010).
export-oriented sectors. At the same time, the few but highly Youth employment problems in some middle-income
paid employment opportunities in the natural resource sec- countries, such as Mauritius and South Africa, resemble the
tor encourage young people to wait for a jobbehavior crisis in youth unemployment occurring outside Sub-Saha-
that can distort educational choices and aggravate skill mis- ran Africa. Especially in South Africa, unemployment is high
matches in the labor market. Resource rents can also engen- (2540 percent, depending on the definition used), youth
der substantial governance problems that stifle growth in unemployment is even higher, and the informal sector is
employment. very small. The challenge is to reduce unemployment, which
If countries manage their natural resource endowments involves understanding its determinants. While the symp-
well, however, they can amass the financial resources to toms and some of the causes may differ (for instance, labor
support smart investments in human development, infra- regulations may play a significantly larger role in these more
structure, and the promotion of new sources of economic developed countries), some of the solutions proposed in this
growth. Resource-rich countries noted for successfully grow- report for other countries are quite similar to those needed
ing their economies, such as Chile, Indonesia, and Malaysia, in South Africafor example, steps to increase agricultural
have diversified economicallyto manufacturing (Indonesia productivity or improve workers foundational skills.

Figure O.4 Informal will be normal in 2020 pessimistic about Africas future? That we are
Jobs by sector
denying African workers the hope of emerging
from informal employment? On the contrary,
300
raising the productivity of smallholder farms
250 and household enterprises is precisely what will
enable the formal sector to develop and thrive.
Jobs (millions)

200
It was the key to structural transformation in
150
Asia and Latin America, and it is the key to
100 Africas future as well.
50

0
Agriculture Household Wage Wage Youths Transition to Productive
enterprise services industry
Employment
Jobs in 2010 New jobs in 2020

Source: Fox et al. 2013.


Transition is the defining feature of youth (see
Note: The projected number of new jobs added by 2020 will be World Bank 2006). The young leave school
125 million.
for work, eventually settling on a career. They
grapple with the many decisions that influ-
of private investment in very labor-intensive ence when they start a family and how health-
enterprises, the formal sector would draw only ily they live (including decisions to engage in
a small number of workers from the informal risky behaviors such as tobacco and alcohol
sector in the near future (see box O.3). use). Most young people also begin to engage
Even if it is realistic to emphasize the role of in the rights and duties of citizens, such as
the informal sector, does this mean that we are voting in elections. The question, therefore, is
Overview 7

Box O.3

What will happen to employment if light manufacturing increases dramatically


in Africa?
Some observers contend that the structure of employment cas low- and lower-middle-income countries. The average
could change more rapidly if Africa experienced a radical, annual growth of industrial wage employment would double
game-changing departure from its current growth path over the decade to 12 percent a year, and total wage employ-
(see Lin and Monga 2012; Dinh et al. 2012). What employ- ment would grow 6 percent a year.
ment prospects would open to youth by 2020 if African Ultimately, however, the structure of employment would
countries picked up manufacturing industries and jobs from change very little compared to today. Low-income countries
East Asia beginning in 2015, just as Asian countries such as could expect about 5 million more wage jobs a year, and
Bangladesh, Cambodia, and Vietnam picked up industries lower-middle-income countries could expect about 2 million
and jobs from Japan and the Republic of Korea in the 1980s new wage jobsa shift of 10 percent of total new jobs in
and 1990s? these countries, representing a small change in the pros-
To test the possibilities, we simulated this recent Asian pects for new entrants. These modest gains partly reflect the
experience in low-income and lower-middle-income coun- short period used for the projection (which covers 5 years,
tries of Africa.a For the simulation, the wage employment whereas the structural change in Vietnam unfolded over 20
elasticity rises to 1.2 to match the historical wage employ- years). They also reflect Africas larger labor force and the
ment elasticity estimated for Bangladesh, Cambodia, and lower base from which industrial development must start.
Vietnammeaning that employment in the industrial sec- Africa will need at least two decades to change the structure
tor would grow 20 percent faster than value added, which of employment sufficiently to offer dramatically different
implies very labor-intensive growth. The industrial growth prospects to its youth, which underscores the importance of
projection for low- and lower-middle-income countries is starting the change process now.
also revised upward to 10 percent a year over 201520.
This figure is slightly above the median and average indus-
try growth rate experienced by Bangladesh, Cambodia, and
Source: Fox et al. 2013.
Vietnam during the most recent decade (9.3 percent a year). a. Africas resource-rich countries are excluded from this simulation,
If this game-changing scenario could be realized, indus- because even resource-rich countries in East Asia did not achieve the
trial wage employment would grow much faster across Afri- transformation of employment simulated here.

how to help youth to make these transitions similar arrangements, but others do not. Evi-
in a way that puts them on a pathway to pro- dence from urban Tanzania (Bridges et al.
ductive employment. The particular challenges 2013) shows that some young people do odd
that young peopleespecially young women jobs and are supported by their families for as
or poorer youthencounter during these long as five years before they settle into wage
transitions increase the difficulty of finding a jobs or (mostly) self-employment. Moreover,
pathway to productive employment (although first-generation school leavers aspiring to be
securing productive employment is important wage workers lack a family history in formal
for all members of society, as box O.4 explains). employment. They may not have networks to
The transition from school to work as well help them to find jobs.
as between sectors of employment (between Young women may be particularly disad-
farming and a wage job, for example) is par- vantaged by other dimensions of the transi-
ticularly difficult for young Africans. Many tion, such as family formation, compared with
lack the means, skills, knowledge, or connec- young men (figure O.6). Social norms tend to
tions to translate their education into produc- enforce job segregation by gender. For instance,
tive employment. Nor is there a structured young women in the household enterprise sec-
path to follow. Many young people combine tor work mostly in narrowly defined fields such
school with work for many years (figure O.5). as dressmaking, even though a range of other
Some move straight into apprenticeships and occupations could be more lucrative.
8 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box O.4

Youth employment versus overall employment


A key part of improving employment opportunities for Afri- to help young people to enter agriculture or start household
cas youth is to understand and address Africas overall eco- enterprises do not generally reduce such opportunities for
nomic challenges. For that reason, much of the discussion in adults. But efforts to facilitate access of youth to the modern
this report focuses on identifying policies that can increase wage sector could potentially displace adults working in the
the productivity of all employmentin agriculture, nonfarm sector. On the one hand, assistance for young people might
household enterprises, and the modern wage sector. The have long-term benefits if it sets them on a productive path.
report also identifies promising policies that focus specifically On the other hand, older workers may have families and
on helping youth to transition more successfully to higher- other economic dependents who rely on their income. There
productivity work in each of those three sectors. is no clear argument that social welfare will be improved by
The focus on youth raises the question of whether it might favoring younger workers over older ones. This report advo-
be socially beneficial to support employment policies that cates seeking to increase the opportunities for all workers,
favor youth over other members of society. Special efforts while helping youth to overcome their particular constraints.

Figure O.5 The transition from school to work in Sub-Saharan Africa is slow

a. Rural b. Urban
100 100

80 80

60 60
Percent

Percent

40 40

20 20

0 0
15 18 21 24 27 30 33 15 18 21 24 27 30 33
Age (years) Age (years)

Working, not at school Both working and at school


At school, not working Not at school, not working, and looking for work

Source: Based on standardized and harmonized household and labor force surveys (see appendix).

Policy Priorities for Addressing that shape young peoples potential to find a
Youth Employment pathway to productive work in the three sec-
tors: human capital and the business environ-
To understand the challenges constraining ment. Box O.5 describes this framework more
productivity and earnings for youth and to fully.
orient how policies should be targeted, this On the human capital side, the role of basic
report considers the three main sectors where education dominates interventions in all three
people work: agriculture, nonfarm household sectors. As a complement, different approaches
enterprises, and modern wage employment. are needed to build post-school skills in agri-
It then distinguishes between two dimensions culture, household enterprises, and the modern
Overview 9

Figure O.6 Family formation starts earlier for young women than for young men

a. Females b. Males
100 100

80 80
% of age cohort

% of age cohort
60 60

40 40

20 20

0 0
15 20 25 30 35 15 20 25 30 35
Age (years) Age (years)

Ever had a child Ever married Ever had sexual intercourse

Source: Based on demographic and health survey data in 28 countries (see appendix).

Box O.5

Framework for analyzing youth employment


Three main sectors of employment: The modern wage sectorr includes small, medium, and
large firms that employ five or more workers on a continu-
Agriculture is where the vast majority of work takes place
ous basis. It also includes the public sector, which in some
in Sub-Saharan Africa. Agriculture occupies more than 70
countries is a large share of the modern wage sector. In the
percent of the labor force in Africas low-income countries
low- and lower-middle-income countries of Sub-Saharan
and more than 50 percent in its lower-middle-income coun- Africa, roughly half of wage employment is in the public sec-
tries. African farmers are predominantly smallholders who tor. In this report, we focus only on the private sector, where
consume a large share of what they produce. One recent the potential for job growth is the greatest.
collection of household surveys estimates that the share of
own-consumption is around 50 percent (versus 2030 per- Two dimensions that shape the pathways to productive work:
cent outside of Sub-Saharan Africa). Human capitalthel supply side, meaning the abilities, edu-
Household enterprisess are unincorporated, nonfarm busi- cation, skills, family connections, networks, and other char-
nesses owned by households. They include self-employed acteristics that are embedded in an individual and allow
people running businesses that may employ family mem- that person to find opportunities to be productive, increase
bers without pay, but may also employ less than five non- earnings, and achieve income security
family workers on a continuous basis. The vast majority Business environmentthe t factors outside the workers
(70 percent) of nonfarm enterprises today are pure self- immediate control that affect productivity (access to land,
employment: just the owner operating the HE. About 20 capital, and finance; infrastructure; technology; and mar-
percent of these enterprises include a family member in the kets), as well as the government policies, regulations, and
operation, and only 10 percent have hired someone outside programs that may affect the choice of economic activity
of the family. and how the activity is conducted.

wage sector. On the business environment side, structure services and access to finance as well
raising farm productivity requires enabling as a space to operate will play critical roles; to
farmers to gain access to finance and secure boost modern sector wage jobs, business regu-
land tenure; in the nonfarm HE sector, infra- lations and infrastructure will be important.
10 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Human Capital: The Fundamental complete primary school have low levels of
Role of Basic Education basic skills: among sixth-graders 43 percent in
Tanzania and 74 percent in Mozambique are
Sub-Saharan Africa has seen a rapid increase at or below the basic numeracy level, while
in the number of children who complete pri- 44 percent in Mozambique cannot read for
mary school, from about 50 percent in 1991 to meaning (Hungi et al. 2010). A few years of
70 percent in 2011. The average young Gha- low-quality basic education will not confer
naian or Zambian today has more schooling much of a gain in productivity if students never
than the average French or Italian citizen had master even basic literacy and numeracy
in 1960 (Pritchett 2013). The current cohort of although so-called second-chance education
youth in Sub-Saharan Africa will be the most approaches offer some potential for catching
schooled ever. up. For many, however, primary schooling is
Educational attainment shapes employment the highest level of schooling they will achieve.
opportunities, as reflected in the substantial These results are especially troubling because
variation in the educational profiles of young they suggest that school leavers have a fragile
workers in each sector (figure O.7). Interna- foundation on which to build more specialized
tionally benchmarked learning assessments skills.
suggest that many young people nevertheless Even students who make it to the second-
lack the skills to compete in a global market- ary levelthose who will most likely head
place. Schooling is not learning. Deep deficien- to the modern wage sectorare not globally
cies in the quality of education mean that the competitive. In the most recent internationally
effect of schooling on productivity is far below benchmarked assessment of eighth- and ninth-
its potential. The poor quality of education grade students, 79 percent of Ghanaians and 76
directly constrains productivity and hinders percent of South Africans do not surpass the
individuals from acquiring new skills. lowest measured level of math proficiency. For
Learning in primary school is often mini- comparison, the international mean is 25 per-
mal: 80 percent of Malian third-graders and cent, and the corresponding scores are 67 per-
more than 70 percent of Ugandan third-graders cent for Indonesian students and 45 percent
cannot read a single word (Cloutier, Rein- for Jordanian students.2 Beyond these cogni-
stadtler, and Beltran 2011). Even students who tive skills, many youth lack the behavioral and

Figure O.7 Education shapes opportunities

a. Ages 1524 b. Ages 2534


100 100

80 80

60 60
Percent

Percent

40 40

20 20

0 0
Agriculture Nonfarm Wage Wage Agriculture Nonfarm Wage Wage
household without with household without with
enterprise contract contract enterprise contract contract

No education Primary not completed Primary completed


Lower secondary completed Upper secondary completed Post-secondary

Source: Based on standardized and harmonized household and labor force surveys (see appendix).
Overview 11

socioemotional skills, sometimes called soft It has plentiful supplies of land and often of
skills, that are needed to get, keep, and be pro- water, unlike other regions. If young people can
ductive in a job. gain access to these resources and use them in
Addressing this lack of learning is not easy. conjunction with strategies to make agriculture
Surveys of schools reveal substantial failures more productive, the results could be transfor-
in service delivery. For example, absenteeism mative for livelihoods and economic growth.
among teachers is between 16 and 20 per- More than two-thirds of the young people who
cent on a given day in Kenya, Senegal, and work in rural areas already work in agriculture,
Tanzania, and primary school students in and most will remain there, even if the non-
those countries experience only about two farm sector develops extremely rapidly.
to three hours of learning a day.3 Reform- Although agriculture is the most immediate
ing the accountability framework that allows means of generating income and employment
such poor performance to persist is key. Bet- for large numbers of young people, efforts to
ter information on performance must be accelerate agricultural growth and improve
complemented by targeted approaches that food security in Africa have been conceptually
increase oversight by the people who are most separated from efforts to create jobs for young
affected: students and their parents. Steps to people. Yet these goals are highly complemen-
ensure that teachers are well prepared for tary. Increasing young peoples opportunities
teaching and supported in their tasks are crit- for productive work in rural areas is arguably
ical for creating a cadre of high-performing the most important catalyst for Africa to reap
professionals. The rise of private schools in its demographic dividend.
Africaschools that often deliver superior Low agricultural productivity is the primary
performance at lower costshould not be impediment to overcome. Agricultural produc-
stifled but should be encouraged and chan- tivity remains lower in Africa than in any other
neled to give larger numbers of students the region of the world, and agriculture is the least
opportunity to learn. productive sector in African economies. This is
Improvements in basic education will lay true, despite the fact that total factor productiv-
the foundation for improvements in produc- ity, as well as land and labor productivity, have
tivity. At the same time, to maximize young been increasing in African agriculture since the
peoples chances of transitioning successfully 1990s (Fuglie and Rada 2013; Nin-Pratt, John-
to remunerative employment, complemen- son, and Yu 2012). Productivity may increase
tary actions are required to improve the busi- further as food prices continue to rise, because
ness environment and develop human capital. the value of output for the same amount of
Those actions will vary by sector of employ- inputs will increase, but these productivity
ment, as discussed next. indicators are far below levels achieved in other
regions during their phases of rapid economic
growth. Indeed, African countries are not fol-
Raising the Productivity of lowing the trajectory of other regions in which
Smallholder Farmers productivity gains on farms, combined with
higher productivity and more opportunities off
Agriculture can and should be a sector of the farm, shifted labor rapidly out of agriculture.
opportunity for Sub-Saharan Africas youth. The effects of low agricultural productivity
The growing demand for food means that extend well beyond rural areas and farm house-
there is scope for supply to take advantage of a holds. An underappreciated result of low agri-
growing market. And growth in demand is not cultural productivity in Africa is high domestic
limited to Africas expanding domestic markets. food prices. Local prices are poorly correlated
Global food prices are at their highest point with global prices, especially in the interior.
in several decades, and they are expected to When domestic prices are high, this increases
remain high for at least the rest of the decade. the cost of food and pushes up wages, contrib-
Africa is well positioned to produce for this uting to Africas overall lack of competitiveness.
large and potentially lucrative global market. High domestic prices undermine real earnings
12 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

for everyone except those farmers who are net on regulatory and policy reform, and some
food sellers and whose production costs are attention to including young people, agricul-
relatively low. Greater agricultural productivity ture could absorb the large numbers of new job
will reduce the domestic cost of food and cre- seekers and offer meaningful work with large
ate more and better-paying nonfarm jobs for public and private benefits.
everyone, especially youth. Broadly speaking, three pathways are avail-
Understanding why the least productive able for rural youth in agriculture: (1) full-time
sector is also the largest may provide insight work on family farms, (2) part-time farm work,
into how farmworkers can increase their pro- combined with running a household enterprise,
ductivity. Small-scale farmers may be caught which can include the sale of farm services or
in a trap that prevents them from generating inputs, and (3) wage work. To increase the
sufficient earnings to invest in expanding pro- productivity of these pathways to agricultural
duction and productivity. The vast majority employment, constraints need to be relaxed in
of African farmers work on tiny plots of land, at least four areas: credit and financial services,
often under uncertain tenure arrangements. land policies, infrastructure, and skills.
They cannot take advantage of economies of
scale (where they exist), modern agricultural Credit and Financial Services
inputs, and mechanization. Poor rural infra- Because they work in a risky environment and
structure (transport, electricity, and irrigation) lack collateral, rural households face major
frustrates farmers efforts to obtain afford- constraints in obtaining capital and credit.
able inputs such as seed and fertilizer, market Traditional financial institutions do not find
their output profitably, or harness new land it profitable to provide agricultural credit.
for cultivation. The lack of irrigation makes Instead, various nongovernmental organiza-
agriculture more vulnerable to the vagaries of tions (NGOs) and banks have been innovating
weather. with new instruments and institutions, some
Low levels of education and pervasive health of which look promising. First started in Niger
problems (two outcomes of the poor delivery in 1991, village savings and loan associations
of services) prevent farmers from increasing (VSLAs)where members save on a regular
their own productivity, much less migrating to basis and lend money on terms determined by
areas where agriculture or some other occupa- the grouphave spread to 39, mostly African,
tion might be more productive. Rural youth countries. They hold great potential for assist-
have significantly lower levels of education ing young people to save the funds to invest in
than their urban counterparts. Many endemic a farm and to get access to credit, while also
diseases are not difficult to manage or cure, but benefiting from the mentoring and access to
these areas of health policy often receive little information that come from being a member.
attention despite their high cost to the rural VSLAs could help youth in rural areas to estab-
economy. Illness, apart from reducing the labor lish themselves in agriculture as well as in non-
available to farm households, can deplete sav- agriculture sectors.
ings through costly treatments and cause dis- Various institutional arrangements and
tress sales of assets. incentive schemes can also widen access to
For Africa to raise agricultural productiv- credit. Examples include different forms of
ity sufficiently to support overall growth and collateral (chattel mortgages and others), leas-
provide a remunerative livelihood for those ing (which requires no collateral, such as the
working in the sector, farming must shift rap- DFCU Leasing Company in Uganda), linking
idly from being an occupation of last resort and credit to extension services (thereby addressing
low productivity to one of technical dynamism multiple constraints simultaneously, because
and recognized opportunity (see box O.6 for a young people also need information), and con-
discussion of the link between productivity and tract farming (in which the wholesaler provides
jobs in agriculture). With much higher priority credit for inputs).
accorded to well-designed programs of public None of these innovations in rural finance
investment in agriculture, continued progress is exclusively for young people. Nor should
Overview 13

Box O.6

Does labor need to move out of agriculture as productivity grows?


If Africas farms get bigger as productivity grows, will work- in the developed world in favor of technology-intensive ser-
ers be pushed out of the sector and have nowhere to go? vices and products. The cost of capital in Africa remains high,
Some observers have raised this concern, and it is under- reflecting low saving rates, high costs of doing business,
standable. In other parts of the world, growth in produc- and rising demand for capital-intensive infrastructure invest-
tivity has been accompanied by an increase in farm size, ments. Agricultures share in African GDP (and ability to
a reduction in labor intensity, and the exit of labor from employ labor) therefore could remain steady or even grow,
agriculture. rather than shrink, with development. Reserves of good
Africas endowment of land and labor and its recent his-
tory offer perspectives to quell this concern. If land is avail- Table BO.6.1 Increase in crop area harvested, agricultural labor
able and crop area is still expanding, increased farm size force, and output per worker in Sub-Saharan Africa, 19602008
need not displace labor, especially where the cost of capital and 19902008
to invest in mechanization is high. As shown in table BO.6.1, % increase
between 1960 and 2008, crop area in Africa expanded, Indicator 19602008 19902008
the workforce in agriculture grew, and output per worker
Crop area harvested 42 20
increased despite the larger number of workers per hect-
are. During the later years, from 1990 to 2008, the pace of Agricultural labor force 125 21
growth in the labor force slowed relative to the expansion of Output per worker 21 9
land, and output per worker continued to increase. Source: Fuglie and Rada 2013.
Africas farms can grow in number, size, and productiv-
ity without displacing labor. The subcontinents experience land, abundant water, and an energetic young labor force
with structural change in the twenty-first century is not likely are tremendous assets at a time when the global economy
to replicate the experience in other regions in earlier times. urgently needs more food and fiber. Whether Africa can use
The current context is one of high global food prices, huge these assets productively depends on finding ways to ease
potential for growth in area and yield, few nontradable the constraints on access to land and address the barriers to
manufactured goods, and shifts in comparative advantage agricultural growth highlighted in this report.

young people be segregated as a group and The problem of insecure and unclear land
offered financial services designed specifically rights can be addressed by developing an inven-
for them. The risks of working with this cli- tory of registered land and improving land
ent base are high, and separating young people registration. Geographic information systems
from a larger pool for sharing risks would make have made this process increasingly practical.
them even less attractive to financial institu- Tenure security is also reinforced by improving
tions. A better approach is to support a range land titling procedures. When farmers know
of innovations in finance that facilitate out- that their land rights are secure, they are more
reach to small farmers and rural entrepreneurs. likely to invest in improving their land. A recent
When necessary, additional features should be impact evaluation of a land registration pilot
added to enhance the ability of these programs in Rwanda shows that more secure land tenure
to serve young people. increased investments in soil improvement by
9 percent among male farmers and 18 percent
Land Policies among female farmers (Ayalew Ali, Deininger,
Insecure and unclear land rights, as well as and Goldstein 2011).
constraints on renting or otherwise using land, Once land is registered and titled, land rental
pose problems for young people in agriculture. markets can develop. Land rental markets have
Some young people own land (albeit small been shown to promote commercial farming in
plots), but ownership is strongly concentrated Ghana and to encourage the transfer of land
among older adults (figure O.8). to smaller-scale farmers in Sudan. By contrast,
14 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Figure O.8 Young people are unlikely to own land 2008), but even here, investments should be
evaluated case by case and not accepted across
80
the board. For example, paved rural roads are
70 not always a good investment, especially in areas
% who own at least one plot of land

where motorized traffic is low. Paved roads are


60 more expensive to maintain, so maintenance is
50 often not funded; another issue is that roads are
prone to becoming tools of political patronage
40 (Raballand and Macchi 2009).
30
Skills
20
Given their low levels of formal education (fig-
10 ure O.7), youth in rural areas can increase their
productivity with more and better schooling.
0 In turn, higher productivity increases demand
1519 2024 2529 3034 3539 4044 4549 5054 5559 60+
for schooling, triggering a virtuous cycle. The
Age (years) evidence used to identify externalities in edu-
Tanzania Uganda Malawi cation usually comes from agriculture: farm-
ers learn from neighboring farmers, especially
Source: Based on data from the World Banks Living Standards Measurement Study, Integrated Surveys
for Agriculture (2011 in Malawi, 2010 in Tanzania and Uganda). more educated ones, who are also more likely
to adopt new technologies (Conley and Udry
2010; Rosenzweig 2012). All of these effects
apply more strongly to young farmers.
restrictions on land rental markets have inhib- In addition to basic education, high-
ited both the farm and nonfarm sectors, dis- productivity farming requires specific skills,
couraging people with land from taking jobs in such as skills in processing, marketing, machin-
the nonfarm sector for fear of losing their land. ery operation and repair, transport, logistics,
Agribusiness can increase productivity, and and quality control. In some countries, agri-
parts of Africa, especially the Guinea savannah, cultural vocational training institutes (some of
have huge potential for commercial agricul- which are associated with universities) tradi-
ture on both large and small farms (Morris, tionally have provided these skills. These insti-
Binswanger-Mkhize, and Byerlee 2009). Large tutes have a mixed track record, mostly owing
commercial landholdings and agribusiness to the disconnect between academic, lecture-
may prove politically contentious, however. style teaching and the need for on-the-ground,
How large farms are integrated into a diverse practical training.
farm structure and how smallholders are com- Agricultural extension programs have a dis-
pensated for land that they make available to appointing history in Africa, mainly because
large commercial operators are critical issues to of poor incentives and accountability. Better
resolve. Other ways of aggregating smallhold- results are coming from new programs that
ers, such as producer associations or contract empower farmers by giving them a choice of
farming, could also be practical approaches for providers and services from among a range of
improving productivity when increasing the public, private, and nongovernmental agen-
scale of production will contribute to lower cies. Another approach, farmer field schools,
costs. involves participatory methods of learning,
technology development, and dissemination
Infrastructure and appears to be especially successful in build-
In somebut not allcases, investments in ing womens skills. Business incubators and
rural infrastructure can have huge rates of rural alliances that bring together commercial
return. Typically such investments occur in buyers with producer organizations are further
more densely populated areas (World Bank ways of boosting agricultural incomes. In all
Overview 15

such efforts, the use of information and com- and imports. As a result, HEs that are involved
munication technology can benefit, and benefit in manufacturing do not persist as long as HEs
from, the participation of young people. that provide services.
Historically, HEs have tended to remain tiny
or to disappear; very few grow into even small
Increasing the Productivity of or medium enterprises. Data from West Africa
Nonfarm Household Enterprises show that, even after 10 years of operation,
the capital stock of these businesses remains
The majority of people who work outside the the same. Most enterprises never hire another
farm sector are engaged in informal, household worker. So the employment they provide,
enterprises. Often such an enterprise is one pil- including the employment for young people,
lar of a diversified livelihood strategy: Many comes from seizing a business opportunity and
households are engaged in the farm and non- starting a new enterprise.
farm sectors at the same time (3050 percent Despite their small scale, HEs are an instru-
of rural households have a nonfarm HE). In ment for reducing poverty in Africa, with the
urban areas, many households with an enter- potential for becoming an even more power-
prise have a family member earning a wage ful one. They tend to be found in richer areas.
income, a pattern that is likely to increase over Households with enterprises are less likely to
time (Fox and Sohnesen 2012). be poor and are clustered in the middle quin-
Although their productivity is relatively tiles of the income distribution. Rural house-
low, HEs provide earnings that are usually holds gain a higher hourly income from HEs
higher than anything their owners could than from agricultural work. In urban areas,
obtain in the agriculture sector. Most HEs have some HE owners make more money than they
no employees and are pure self-employment. would from a wage job. In fact, controlling for
Few include a family member as additional education and skills, the reported consumption
labor, and only 10 percent hire outside the of rural and urban households with an HE in
family. Some are started in response to a Africa is no different from that of households
local business opportunity (such as increased
in wage employment (Fox and Sohnesen 2012).
demand for a service), whereas others are
Indeed, they also report being happier (Falco
started because the household lacks alterna-
et al. 2013).
tive means to earn a living.
Most governments continue to ignore,
What do HEs do? They mostly sell services
neglect, or undermine the potential of this
(hairdressing, repairs) and internationally and
sector. Hawkers and sellers are regarded as an
locally produced consumer goods (used cloth-
ing, household supplies, vegetables, eggs). They unattractive annoyance to be chased out of the
also contribute to the industrial sector, trans- business districts in capital cities. Advocates
forming agricultural goods or natural resources of formal employment criticize HEs for not
into charcoal, bricks, iron work, or processed offering the benefits and security of a wage job.
grain. Some pursue artisanal activities such as Thinking that HEs can be transformed into
woodworking, dressmaking and tailoring, and small and medium enterprisesfor which they
construction. have a strategygovernments try to formalize
HEs sell low-cost goods and services mainly these informal enterprises. This transformation
for the local market, which lacks a modern rarely takes place, however, because this is not
service sector. In urban areas, the traders and the intention of the owners. Lacking support,
hawkers substitute for convenience stores and HEs just try to survive. In Tanzania, the law
shopping malls. The low-quality manufac- prohibits businesses from operating without
tured goods these enterprises produce, such fixed premises, but it does not stop the govern-
as homemade bricks and furniture, eventually ment from collecting taxes and fees from those
are replaced by higher-quality locally produced same enterprises. (This describes 80 percent
goods (made in brick and furniture factories) of HEs.)
16 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

By contrast, Ghana, a country with a rich cult to implement the lawif there is one. For
trading history dating to precolonial times, example, in Dar es Salaam, Tanzania, local gov-
explicitly incorporates HEs in its strategy doc- ernments are not empowered to decide whether
uments and the institutions that implement hawkers can use the land next to national roads.
them. In 2006 the government established an Just as land rental markets can facilitate access
objective to enhance productivity and income/ to agricultural land, they can facilitate access to
wages in all sectors of the economy, includ- space for HEs to do business.
ing the informal economy (Republic of Ghana In addition to secure space, HEs need ser-
2006). The Trade Union Congress supports the vices, such as security, sanitation, electricity,
development of HE organizations and their transport, and water supply. For the most part,
integration into the consultative mechanisms they are willing to pay for these services (and
between government and the private sector. do pay for them) through fees and taxes. In fact,
To realize the potential of the HE sector for HEs pay local business taxes at a higher rate
productive youth employment, national strat- than large businesses but often fail to receive
egies that recognize the sectors potential and any services. HEs have little leverage to improve
propose a supportive policy framework need this situation (Fox and Sohnesen 2012). Local
to be developed. Such strategies should endorse authorities are not accountable to HEs, because
the creation of independent HE associations to ineffective political decentralization and weak
reduce the costs of reaching individual enter- legal status deprive HEs of a voice in local
prises and to give this sector a voice in govern- governance.
ment decision making. Local interventions
need to address three key areas: the local busi- Credit and Financial Services
ness climate in urban areas, access to credit and Lacking access to formal sources of finance,
financial services, and skills. young people struggle to raise capital to start
and operate a business. The problem is exacer-
Urban Policy bated by the fact that business and household
One of the most frequently cited constraints finances are linked, so that lumpy household
on the productivity of urban HEs is the lack of expenditures (school fees, repairs, and so on)
access to space and sometimes outright harass- and external shocks (family illness) spill over
ment, legal and extralegal, by local authorities. to the business. Virtually all HEs in Africa
Insecurity of premises discourages entry (the today report that their own funds or loans
main form of growth in this sector) as well as from friends and relatives enabled them to
investment in the enterprise. Governments can start their businesses, and the overwhelming
help rather than hurt this sector by incorporat- majority of existing businesses report that they
ing the growth of HEs in planning processes. did not obtain any type of loan over the last 12
Without planning, traders and vendors crowd months. An expansion of credit cannot make
sidewalks and roads, leading to massive conges- up this gap and may even make it worse, as
tion. Usually the situation escalates to a crisis, recent experiences in India have shown. To use
and authorities use police or security forces credit effectively, a borrower has to be able to
to decongest the city. Because the eviction put aside money regularly to service the loan.
policy is rarely permanent, the cycle usually For this purpose, the establishment of a savings
resumes. If governments had planned for the mechanism is critical.
growth of HEs and provided adequate space for At the root of the credit problem for HEs is
them in the key areas of foot traffic in the city, the lack of financial inclusion among house-
employment growth and social stability would holds in Africa (World Bank 2014). Households
have followed. not only lack sources of credit but also have dif-
Alongside planning, national policy makers ficulty finding reliable places to safeguard their
can clarify land rights in urban jurisdictions, savings. As a result, it is challenging for them
giving local governments scope to provide HEs to accumulate the funds to start or expand a
with locations to operate. Overlapping land business. This problem is especially acute for
regulations and responsibilities make it diffi- youth and for females. Research has shown that
Overview 17

access to a secure place for savings is particularly develop low-cost products for small savers and
important for womens ability to build up sav- for households to use banks by channeling pay-
ings for a business (Dupas and Robinson 2013). ments to households through banks, including
The challenge of providing access to finan- microfinance banks with a client base among
cial services for poor people is a common one. lower-income households.4 Ghana developed
Because of economies of scale, the spread of a system of rural banks to process payments
formal banking services (banks, postal savings, to cocoa farmers; today these banks provide
formal savings institutions other than banks) low-cost accounts in rural areas. Ghana and
usually rises with income and urbanization Rwanda are both encouraging the spread of
banks go where the money is. But this is not mobile banking to further widen access to
the whole story in Africa. FINDEX data show financial services. Countries in the Western
that even at the same level of income per cap- and Central African monetary unions using
ita, national policies can produce very different the CFA currency (UEMOA and CEMAC) are
results (figure O.9). Low- and lower-middle- also changing their regulations to foster more
income countries such as Ghana, Kenya, and inclusion. Benin, which encouraged the estab-
Rwanda have achieved greater financial access lishment of microfinance institutions, was an
than other African and non-African countries early mover in this group.
at similar income levels. They have done so pri-
marily by reducing the costs of serving small Skills
savers and those in remote areas. Training can help to structure a pathway to
In Kenya, banking access increased through youth employment in HEs. Training pro-
the pioneering use of mobile banking technol- gramsboth for entry and for improving
ogy. By increasing branchless banking, mobile incomes and sustainabilityare the most com-
banking allows accounts to be maintained monly provided government and donor inter-
at relatively little cost to savers and borrow- vention to support HEs, whether or not they
ers. Today, about half of the adult population target youth. Programs provide (1) technical
of Kenya uses mobile banking. In Rwanda, training in a specific sector (such as tailoring,
government provided incentives for banks to metalworking, operating a bakery); (2) business

Figure O.9 At the same level of income per capita, national policies can produce very different levels of financial
inclusion
Individuals ages 25 and older with a bank account (%)

100

90

80 MUS
MNG
70 THA
CHN
60
ZWE RSA
50
AGO
40 RWA KEN IND EGY
NGA BWA
30 UGA SWZ
GHA
COM
BFA GAB
20

10 COG
SEN
NER MLI TKM
0
350 3,500

GDP per capita 2011 (current US$)

CFA countries Non-CFA Sub-Saharan African countries Rest of the world


Trend of CFA countries Trend of non-CFA Sub-Saharan African countries Trend of rest of the world
Source: Based on Global Financial Inclusion (Global Findex) Database, World Bank, Washington, DC, http://www.worldbank.org
/globalfinder
Note: The x axis of this figure is on a log scale.
18 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

skills or financial literacy (such as basic account- the engine for employment and growth in the
ing or money management); (3) behavioral and medium to long term for Africa. No country
life skills; or (4) a mix of these skills. Programs has developed without this sector coming to
specifically intended for youth focus primarily dominate employment. This is the sector that
on providing the skills needed to enter the HE can exploit economies of scale and produce
sector and have included all four types of train- for export. The multiplier effects to the house-
ing. Programs targeted at existing HEs tend to hold economy from the creation of wage jobs
focus more on business skills to strengthen or are strong. Most secondary-school graduates
expand HEs. aspire to work in this sector. When these aspi-
The good news for youth employment is rations are not fulfilled and graduates must
that programs designed to facilitate entry (ver- resort to working in the household enterprise
sus those focusing on productivity) appear to sector, for example, the risks for social insta-
have had some success, so positive models are bility and political violence are high. While
emerging. Apprenticeships and on-the-job Africas young people seem to have no spe-
training can help young people, provided that cial advantage or disadvantage when it comes
these programs are closely tied to market sig- to modern wage employment, they remain a
nals. For this reason, private providers, includ- consistent share of that employment when it
ing existing businesses, are often the best source grows (figure O.10).
for this training. Youth often face multiple The modern wage sector has been creat-
constraints in entering the HE sector, and the ing jobs at a fairly rapid pace in Sub-Saharan
most promising pilots are delivering interven- Africausually faster than GDP growth. The
tions that tackle multiple constraints (offering problem is that the sector has grown from such
behavioral, business, or technical skills training a small base that it still cannot absorb the mil-
together, or combining training with measures lions of young people entering the labor force
to tackle credit constraints through savings every year. To generate jobs at a rate that is
groups, grants, and other means). Many of these commensurate with growth in the labor force,
bundled interventions have been expensive, the export-oriented enterpriseswith their
however, and they are yet to scale up in Africa. potential to sell to global marketswill have
Overall, despite the large number of train-
ing programs, evidence of their effectiveness Figure O.10 The share of youth in wage employment
in the HE sector in Africa remains thin. More tracks the share in the general population
systematic use of careful evaluations is clearly
required, including impact evaluations that 100

measure outcomes among program partici-


Share of wage employment for population

90
pants and compare them to a relevant group 80
of nonparticipants. At the very minimum, gov-
70
ernments should encourage all programs to
ages 1534 (%)

track and report outcomes. At the same time, 60


governments should not attempt to deliver 50
training directly but rather focus their efforts 40
on market-enhancing programs that dissemi-
30
nate information about training opportunities
and enable disadvantaged youth to access train- 20
ing that is already available. 10

0
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
Improving Competitiveness to Share of wage employment for population
Boost Modern Sector Wage Jobs ages 1564 (%)
45 degree line
Although small (16 percent of the labor force), Source: Based on household and labor force surveys (most recent
the formal wage employment sector represents data available).
Overview 19

to be the engine for job creation in this sector. tion. Infrastructure policies and regulations
Since most African economies are small, access block firms access to infrastructure services,
to external markets is the key to unleashing and building infrastructure without improving
the modern wage sectors full potential. The policies and institutions is unlikely to solve the
scope for trade is wide. Even services are traded problem. Conversely, improving policies such
internationally, although these tend to call for as electricity and water tariffs or trucking regu-
relatively high-level skills still lacking in much lations can go a long way to improving services
of Sub-Saharan Africa. Moreover, the employ- and attracting the private sector.
ment effects of trade go beyond exporting Expensive or limited financing prevents
firms, as rising demand from the export sec- firms from investing to improve productivity
torfor inputs, consumer goods, and ser- and also keeps productive firms from grow-
vicesincreases opportunities in other parts ing. Banks in Africa set high collateral require-
of the economy. ments and high risk premiums partly because
What factors are constraining export- they lack the credit information systems that
oriented enterprises in Africa today? The main help lenders to evaluate prospective custom-
constraint on the growth of an export-oriented ers. This problem can be addressed by policy
sector in Africa is low productivity. and regulatory reform. Africa also needs bet-
The underlying causes are not identical ter, well-enforced creditor rights, which will
across the continent, even if they have similar ease lending by providing protection for lend-
effects. In some countries, the cost of comple- ers when borrowers default. Improved creditor
mentary inputs to labor (electricity, overland rights and contract enforcement will also allow
transport, and so on) is too high. Clearly, the borrowers to use a broader range of assets as
cost of transporting goods across borders is collateral.
prohibitively high in the region, and the need In developed economies, innovative new
for better transport infrastructure, simpler cus- firms are constantly emerging and growing,
toms procedures, and expedited inland border while unproductive incumbents are leaving.
crossings is acute. In other countries, bureau- This churning is a major source of aggregate
cratic red tape delays investors access to land productivity and employment growth in the
or permits. The high costs of financial interme- modern wage sector. In Africa, this process
diation are starving firms and entrepreneurs of is held back not only by financial constraints
the capital needed to implement good ideas. on entrepreneurs but also by difficult formal
In many countries, poor connectivity has frag- requirements for business entry or expansion.
mented local markets, suppressing competition Governance issues, such as corruption in the
and reducing the pressure to improve produc- granting of business licenses and other permits,
tivity. These business climate issues would be hamper this process as well.
a problem for productivity (and hence, youth In short, the constraints to Africas pro-
employment) even if firms only produced for ductivity are a combination of market and
domestic markets. government failures. Government failures in
What can be done to increase Africas low particular either have been difficult to rectify
labor productivity? The entire business climate especially when they require economywide pol-
comes into play here, with some exceptions. For icies such as deregulation or tariff reformor,
example, labor market regulationsconsid- when implemented, have not delivered results.
ered an important determinant of productivity Vested interests inside and outside government
elsewheredo not play a major role in Africa, can prevent reforms or their implementation.
except for South Africa. In many settings, reg- Analysis of Ethiopias light manufacturing sec-
ulations may exist on the books, but they are tor shows that the leather goods industry could
rarely enforced. create 90,000 jobs (it currently employs 5,000).
To unleash this potential, value-chain analy-
Infrastructure and the Business Climate sis shows that the government has to remove
Infrastructure is a major problem, but build- a series of policy-induced constraints, such as
ing new infrastructure may not be the solu- trade restrictions, anticompetitive practices,
20 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

and financial regulations that affect the sector important for all types of wage workers, partly
(Dinh et al. 2012). The scale of such a reform because they facilitate further training and on-
means that it could take some time. the-job learning in firms.
A complementary approach is to create a To avoid creating more unemployable uni-
localized environmentsay, a special economic versity graduates, higher education policies and
zone (SEZ), with the requisite infrastructure curriculums also need to be geared toward pri-
and deregulationin which industries that vate demand. Financing in public universities
could benefit from proximity can cluster and should include a private component (especially
flourish. The government provides land and for those who can pay), so that signals from the
functioning infrastructure services for the SEZ. private sector are received (Devarajan, Monga,
Although in China this approach attracted for- and Zongo 2011). Such a shift would improve
eign investment and know-how and helped equity in access to higher education as tuition
China to become an export manufacturing payments become means-tested rather than
powerhouse, it has not yet been implemented free across the board. Also, those who pay will
successfully in Africa. demand value for money.
Besides giving careful thought to the The Sub-Saharan African experience with
design and implementation of these interven- technical vocational education and training
tions, policy makers must evaluate each one (TVET) has been disappointing. Secondary
in terms of its susceptibility to political cap- and post-secondary vocational training costs
ture, which plagued industrial policy when it at least three times more than basic second-
was last attempted on a large scale in Africa. ary education, yet often provides no better
Any subsidy creates a rent. Politically powerful foundation for private sector jobs. Training in
interests, if they capture those rents, will resist government-run programs has not been geared
efforts to reduce them, even though that step to private sector needs.
is necessary for industries to compete in world Governments in Sub-Saharan Africa should
markets. focus on support for public goods in TVET
such as quality assurance and information. To
Skills promote access to training for poor and disad-
Is demand for secondary-school graduates vantaged youth, governments should provide
simply insufficient in Africas modern wage financial support for training in either the pub-
sector, or is there a skills mismatch? In fact, lic or the private sector. Information about the
both of these problems appear to be present. returns to alternative training options can help
Secondary and post-secondary graduates say to align young peoples training choices with the
they have trouble finding a job because of lack realities of the labor market. To the extent that
of demand. There is a much larger supply of governments support specific training options,
labor for unskilled (factory floor) jobs than for those options should emphasize portable skills
skilled jobs as mechanics and factory engineers rather than the firm- or job-specific skills that
or for office jobs as accountants and managers. employers should already have an incentive to
Meanwhile, employers are requesting permits provide. They should ensure that programs are
to import experienced skilled labor. Graduates closely linked to the private sector, potentially
at all levels without technical training and some through public-private partnerships. Programs
work experience (where they can acquire and for disadvantaged youth that integrate training
demonstrate the equally valuable soft skills) with internships show promise.
face an especially crowded job market, reflect- The visibly poor management practices
ing an aspirational mismatch as much as a in African firms suggest considerable scope
skills mismatch. for improving productivity by investing in
As with the farm and HE sectors, perhaps business and management skills training and
the most important step toward resolving these perhaps even in individualized management
problems in the modern wage sector is to get consulting. The evidence for such programs is
basic schooling right. Foundational skills are mixed but promising, and governments should
Overview 21

consider testing and refining them through It is equally urgent to undertake other
careful piloting. actions to address constraints that will only
yield payoffs in the medium term. For exam-
ple, improvements in basic education, the
Building an Effective Youth foundation for developing all other skills, will
Employment Policy take time to translate into higher productiv-
ity and better youth employment outcomes.
The challenge of youth employment in Africa Reforms to the business climate will require
is not amenable to simple solutions. It reflects sustained effort, and it may take time for
the challenges and opportunities of countries investors to respond. But policy makers must
themselves in a globalized world. The key rise to these urgent challenges. Failure to act
employment issue is that productivity, and now means that future cohorts of young peo-
therefore earnings, are low, while aspirations, ple may also lack clear pathways to productive
especially those of youth, are highand per- work.
haps higher than those of their parents. Despite These priorities are, of course, only a general
progress in many countries, most youth in guide. Addressing the challenge in any given
Africa today will not have an easy or structured country will require a country-specific analy-
path to a sustainable livelihood, one of the sis. The framework put forward in this report,
core aspects of adulthood. All stakeholders the general diagnostics that it provides, and the
governments, private firms, private and non- evidence that it marshals to illustrate successful
governmental training providers, and young or promising approaches provide a foundation
people themselveshave a role to play in sup- for such an analysis and indicate policy direc-
porting this transition. tions to pursue. But a country-based analysis
Progress requires a comprehensive approach is required to address the specific local issues
to relieve the constraints on human capital and surrounding the following questions: What is
the business environment that prevent the constraining earnings growth in agriculture,
private sector from seizing opportunities and HEs, and the modern wage sector? Why is it
increasing productivity in agriculture, HEs, and hard for youth to start HEs and work produc-
the modern wage sector. Governments need to tively in them? Why isnt private investment in
take a holistic view of how to address the situ- labor-intensive firms flowing in to increase the
ationthey need to own the whole problem. number of modern wage jobs on offer? What
A common tendency is to perceive can and should government, NGOs, and other
government-provided technical and vocational private sector actors do to ease the constraints
skills training as the key. But such action, by that youth face in making the transition to pro-
itself, will not address the more fundamental ductive employment?
problems. Government intervention should The basis for a successful country-specific
focus on public goodsthose things that will analysis will be more and better data on
support higher productivity in the economic employment; such data are currently sparse
activities of households and enterprises. Spe- and often of low quality (see the discussion in
cific actions can relieve the most pressing con- Fox and Pimhidzai 2013). The basis for build-
straints in the short term, such as increasing ing a much better evidence base of which
access to finance for HEs as well as modern approaches are potentially effective and cost-
firms; improving access to land and technol- effective will be more experimentation with
ogy for young people to expand earnings in promising interventionsand careful evalua-
agriculture; building supportive infrastructure tion of their impacts.
that enables all enterprises to be more produc- At its core, the youth employment challenge
tive; and opening access to regional markets is closely aligned with the challenge of pro-
so that firms can broaden the reach of their moting inclusive growth, defined not only as
products. Table O.1 summarizes the priority growth in which the poorest segments of soci-
actions. ety share but also as growth in which young
22 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Table O.1 Priority actions to take now to address the youth employment challenge
Do now for now: Do now for later:
Area for intervention Actions to affect the current cohort of youth Actions to affect future cohorts of youth
Agriculture 1. Enable rental markets for land 1. Establish effective land registration and transaction systems
2. Pilot intergenerational land transfer programs 2. Scale up intergenerational land transfer programs, based on
lessons from pilot programs
3. Support high-quality, demand-driven extension services (covering
information as well as skills) 3. Mainstream youth into smart interventions aimed at increasing
productivity (producer organizations, livestock development,
4. Link agricultural credit to extension services
irrigation, and others)
4. Build skills through rapid improvements in education systems in
rural areas
Agriculture and household 5. Promote rural village savings and loan associations and self-help
enterprises groups
6. Enable financial inclusion for households
7. Use safety net programs as a platform to deliver interventions to
disadvantaged youth
Household enterprises 8. Develop a national strategy for household enterprises that reflects 5. Build foundational skills through rapid improvements in education
the voice of their owners and youth systems
9. Ensure access to workspace and infrastructure for household 6. Address infrastructure needs of household enterprises in urban
enterprises through improved urban policy development planning
10. Leverage nongovernmental organizations to deliver interventions
that support disadvantaged youth to enter the sector by
addressing multiple constraints (building a range of skills together;
building skills along with providing access to finance)
Modern wage sector 11. Reduce the cost of infrastructure services by addressing quality 7. Increase the quantity of infrastructure services
and efficiency
8. Expand regional markets for products
12. Address logistics bottlenecks
9. Build foundational skills through rapid improvements in education
13. Reduce corruption and the cost of business start-up systems
14. Reform technical and vocational education and training and pursue 10. Improve access to credit through financial sector reform
public-private partnerships for delivering demand-driven training
Cross-cutting areas 15. Increase awareness of opportunities and pathways to self- 11. Promote early child development and nutrition to build a stronger
employment, especially for young women foundation for skills development
16. Consider second-chance education for basic skills 12. Build behavioral skills (consider reforms within the school system)
13. Reduce fertility rates to lower the size of future youth cohorts
(through more girls education, improved maternal and child
health, increased access to family planning)
14. Build better employment data and a stronger evidence base to
identify country constraints, priorities, and opportunities

peoples vitality is harnessed and rewarded. For References


African countries that meet this challenge, the Ayalew Ali, Daniel, Klaus Deininger, and Markus P.
benefits will build on each other. The demo- Goldstein. 2011. Environmental and Gender
graphic dividend will yield returns, and Africas Impacts of Land Tenure Regularization in Africa:
prosperity will grow and be shared. Pilot Evidence from Rwanda. Policy Research
Working Paper 5765, World Bank, Washington,
DC, August.
Notes
1. Defined as having no work at all in the last seven Bridges, Sarah, Louise Fox, Alessio Gaggero, and
days and actively looking for work (ILO 1982). Trudy Owens. 2013. Labour Market Entry and
2. In Botswana form-two and in South Africa Earnings: Evidence from Tanzanian Retrospec-
grade-nine students were tested, correspond- tive Data. Background paper presented at the
ing to nine years of schooling; in Ghana junior CSAE Conference on Economic Development in
high school form-two students were tested, Africa, Oxford University, March.
corresponding to eight years of schooling. Cloutier, Marie-Hlne, C. Reinstadtler, and Isa-
3. See www.sdindicators.org. bel Beltran. 2011. Making the Grade: Assessing
4. A similar approach was used in Mongolia. Literacy and Numeracy in African Countries.
Overview 23

DIME Brief, Washington, DC, World Bank. Commission. IMF Country Report 06/225, IMF,
http://go.worldbank.org/15Y7VXO7B0. Washington, DC, June.
Conley, Timothy, and Christopher Udry. 2010. Hungi, Njora, Demus Makuwa, Kenneth Ross,
Learning about a New Technology: Pineapple Mioko Saito, Stphanie Dolata, Frank van
in Ghana. American Economic Review 100 (1): Cappelle, Laura Paviot, and Jocelyne Vellien.
3569. 2010. SACMEQ III Project Results: Pupil
Devarajan, Shantayanan, Clestin Monga, and Achievement Levels in Reading and Mathe-
Tertius Zongo. 2011. Making Higher Educa- matics. Working Document 1, Southern
tion Finance Work for Africa. Journal of African Africa Consortium for Measuring Educational
Economiess 20 (supplement 3): iii13354. Quality (SACMEQ), Harare. http://www.
sacmeq.org/downloads/sacmeqIII/WD01_
Dinh, Hinh T., Vincent Palmade, Vandana Chandra, SACMEQ_III_Results_Pupil_Achievement.
and Frances Cossar. 2012. Light Manufacturing in pdf.
Africa: Targeted Policies to Enhance Private Invest-
ment and Create Jobs. Washington, DC: World ILO (International Labour Organization). 1982.
Bank. Resolution Concerning Statistics of the Eco-
nomically Active Population, Employment,
Dupas, Pascaline, and Jonathan Robinson. 2013. Unemployment, and Underemployment.
Savings Constraints and Microenterprise Devel- Adopted by the Thirteenth International
opment: Evidence from a Field Experiment in Conference of Labour Statisticians, Geneva.
Kenya. American Economic Journal: Applied
Economicss 5 (1): 16392. Lin, Justin Yifu, and Clestin Monga. 2012. Solving
the Mystery of African Governance. New Politi-
Falco, Paolo, William F. Maloney, Bob Rijkers, and cal Economyy 17 (5): 65966.
Mauricio Sarrias. 2013. Heterogeneity in Sub-
jective Well-Being: An Application to Occupa- Morris, Michael, Hans Binswanger-Mkhize, and
tional Allocation in Africa. Documento CEDE Derek Byerlee. 2009. Awakening Africas Sleeping
201301, Universidad de los Andes, Department Giant: Prospects for Commercial Agriculture in the
of Economics, Bogot. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ Guinea Savannah Zone and Beyond. Washington,
ssrn.2229328. DC: World Bank.
Fox, Louise, and Obert Pimhidzai. 2013. Different Nin-Pratt, Alejandro, Michael Johnson, and
Dreams, Same Bed: Collecting, Using, and Inter- Bingxin Yu. 2012. Improved Performance of
preting Employment Statistics in Sub-Saharan Agriculture in Africa South of the Sahara: Taking
Africa: The Case of Uganda. Policy Research Off or Bouncing Back?? IFPRI Discussion Paper
Working Paper 6436, World Bank, Washington, 01224. Washington, DC: International Food Pol-
DC. icy Research Institute.
Fox, Louise, and Thomas Pave Sohnesen. 2012. Pritchett, Lant. 2013. The Rebirth of Educa-
Household Enterprises in Sub-Saharan Africa: tion. Washington, DC: Center for Global
Why They Matter for Growth, Jobs, and Liveli- Development.
hoods. Policy Research Working Paper 6184, Raballand, Gal, and Patricia Macchi. 2009. Trans-
World Bank, Washington, DC. port Prices and Costs: The Need to Revisit
Fox, Louise, Alun Thomas, Cleary Haines, and Donors Policies in Transport in Africa. Working
Jorge Huerta Munoz. 2013. Africas Got Work to Paper 190, Bureau for Research and Economic
Do: Employment Prospects in the New Century. Analysis of Development, Duke University.
IMF Working Paper 13201, International Mon- http://ipl.econ.duke.edu/bread/papers/
etary Fund, Washington, DC. working/190.pdf.
Fuglie, Keith O., and Nicholas E. Rada. 2013. Rosenzweig, Mark R. 2012. Microeconomic
Resources, Policies, and Agricultural Productiv- Approaches to Development: Schooling, Learn-
ity in Sub-Saharan Africa. Economic Research ing, and Growth. Journal of Economic Perspec-
Report 145368, U.S. Department of Agriculture, tivess 24 (3): 8196.
Economic Research Service, Washington, DC. United Nations. 2011. World Population Prospects:
Gelb, Alan, and Sina Grasmann. 2010. How The 2010 Revision. New York: Department
Should Oil Exporters Spend Their Rents? Work- of Economic and Social Affairs, Population
ing Paper 221, Center for Global Development, Division. http://esa.un.org/wpp/Excel-Data/
Washington, DC. http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ population.htm.
ssrn.1660570. World Bank. 2006. World Development Report 2007:
Ghana, Republic of. 2006. Poverty Reduction Development and the Next Generation. New York:
Strategy Paper. National Development Planning Oxford University Press.
24 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

. 2008. World Development Report 2009: . 2014. Global Financial Development Report
Reshaping Economic Geography. New York: 2014: Financial Inclusion. Washington, DC:
Oxford University Press. World Bank.
. 2012. World Development Report 2013: . Various years. World Development Indica-
Jobs. New York: Oxford University Press. tors. Washington, DC: World Bank. http://wdi
. 2013. Africas Pulse: An Analysis of Issues .worldbank.org.
Shaping Africas Economic Future 7 (April).
Chapter

Opportunities and Challenges for


Youth Employment in Africa

Two trends are converging in Africa, with immediate attention, but it can be met. Indus-
potentially profound effects on how Africas tryespecially export manufacturinghas been
economy will grow and where it will create jobs. a vibrant source of wage jobs in other regions,
First, Africas economies, spurred by high prices most notably East Asia. In Africa, industry is in
for primary export commodities, are growing the very early stages of development. It needs time
again after a hiatus of many decades. Output is and the right policy environment to grow. Gov-
shifting out of agriculture and largely into ser- ernments must also focus on tapping the more
vices, and employment is shifting slowly toward immediate potential for productive employ-
services. The second trend is that Africas rapidly ment in agriculture and household enterprises.
growing population will constitute the worlds This report assesses the specific challenges and
largest reservoir of working-age individuals for opportunities related to youth employment on
generations to come, and the majority of this farms, in nonfarm household enterprises, and
population will be young. These trends mean in modern wage jobs. It examines these issues
that the structure of employment will continue and possible interventions in light of two types
to change in Africa, but the transformation will of binding constraints to higher productivity for
be slow. young people in those sectors: constraints related
Africa stands to gain economically, socially, to human capital and constraints related to the
and substantially from channeling the energy business environment.
of its young labor force into more productive
employment. The challenge is large and demands
Africas Working-Age Population:
Throughout this report, Africa is shorthand for Sub-
Very Young and Growing Rapidly
Saharan Africa. In particular instances, Sub-Saharan
Africa is retained to clarify comparisons across regions or The median person in Africa is 18 years old
to indicate a specific data set. 7 years younger than the median age in South

25
26 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Asia, which is the next youngest region (figure lion (figure 1.3). Each year between 2015 and
1.1). In other words, fully half of Africas popu- 2035, there will be half a million more 15-year-
lation is under 18 years old. Africa will remain olds than the year before. This rapid increase
the youngest region in the world in the decades contrasts starkly with the Middle East and
to come, and the age gap with other regions North Africa, where increases in the size of this
will increase. According to projections by the cohort have steadied, and even with East Asia,
United Nations, the median age in Africa will where numbers are dominated by China and
increase only to 21 in 2035 and to 24 in 2050. In the size of this cohort is expected to fall from
other regions of the world, the median person 350 million in 2010 to 225 million by 2050.1 In
in 2050 will be more than 35 years oldalmost South Asia, the size of the cohort is expected
45 in East Asia and the Pacific. to increase, and then begin to decline after
In Africa, the population structure resem- 2030.
bles an Egyptian pyramid, with a narrow top
and a wide base (figure 1.2). The wide base
is Africas youth bulgeAfrica has twice as Can Africas Youth Bring an
many 15-year-olds as 35-year-olds. In other Economic Advantage?
regions of the world, the structure is elongated,
reflecting a more even distribution across age Africas young and growing working-age popu-
groups. South Asias demographic profile is lation compels attention for many reasons, not
closest to Africas, whereas in East Asia and the least because a rapidly expanding working-
Pacific, the pyramid is inverted, with a greater age population spearheaded the economic
number of older than younger people. Projec- transformation that occurred in East Asia and
tions suggest that the shape of the pyramid in the Pacific between 1965 and 1990. Over that
Africa will remain as it is in the near future period, the working-age population in East
just with more people at each age. Asia and the Pacific rose by almost 500 million
These population trends suggest that the (from 541 million to 1.039 billion). More cru-
number of young people entering Africas cially, the number of dependents (ages 014
working-age population will be rising for years and 65 and over) increased by only 143 million
to come. The United Nations estimates that in (from 437 million to 580 million). The region
2015 Sub-Saharan Africa will have 193 million had just over one working-age adult for each
people between the ages of 15 and 24; by 2035, dependent in 1965, but by 1990 almost two
it will have 295 million, and by 2050, 362 mil- working-age adults supported each dependent
(figure 1.4). During those years, gross domes-
Figure 1.1 Africas population is young and will remain so tic product (GDP) per capita in East Asia and
the Pacific increased from around US$1,300 to
50
US$3,300. Based on cross-country analysis of
45 the relationship between growth rates and the
40 changing structure of the population, analysts
35 have attributed one-third to half of East Asias
Median age (years)

30 economic growth to changes in demography


25 (Bloom and Williamson 1998; Bloom, Can-
20
ning, and Malaney 2000).
15
East Asias demographic dividend is
argued to have transformed the economy
10
through two main channels. The first was the
5
increased availability of workers. More work-
0
Sub-Saharan South Middle East Latin America East Asia Europe and
ers mean more output, and if there are more
Africa Asia and and the and Pacific Central Asia workers relative to the population, then out-
North Africa Caribbean put per capita will rise. The second channel
2015 2035 2050 was the continued expansion of the working-
Source: Based on United Nations 2011. age population relative to the population as a
Opportunities and Challenges for Youth Employment in Africa 27

Figure 1.2

a. Sub-Saharan Africa b. South Asia c. East Asia and Pacific

80+ 80+ 80+


7074 7074 7074
6064 6064 6064
Age group (years)

Age group (years)

Age group (years)


5054 5054 5054
4044 4044 4044
3034 3034 3034
2024 2024 2024
1014 1014 1014
04 04 04
100 80 60 40 20 0 20 40 60 80 100 100 80 60 40 20 0 20 40 60 80 100 160 120 80 40 0 40 80 120 160
Population (millions) Population (millions) Population (millions)

Male 2035 Male 2015 Female 2015 Female 2035

Source: Based on United Nations 2011.

Figure 1.3 Unlike in other regions, the number of young people in Sub-Saharan Africa will increase dramatically in the near future

400

350
Population ages 1524 (millions)

300

250

200

150

100

50

0
1950 2010 2050 1950 2010 2050 1950 2010 2050 1950 2010 2050 1950 2010 2050 1950 2010 2050
East Asia and Pacific Europe and Central Asia Latin America Middle East and South Asia Sub-Saharan Africa
and the Caribbean North Africa
Source: Based on United Nations 2011.
Note: Each bar shows an estimate or a projection of the number of 15- to 24-year-olds for one year at five-year intervals.

whole, a result of the rapid decline in fertility. will not materialize. The rapid change in the
With fewer dependents, working-age adults can ratio between the two groups (illustrated in
increase their savingswhich can be converted figure 1.4) was critical for the boom in produc-
into productive investments, which further tivity in East Asia and the Pacific (Bloom and
stimulate economic growth. Williamson 1998).
For Africa to realize a demographic divi- Historically, declines in child mortality have
dend of its own, it is not enough to have a large preceded declines in fertilitya sequence that
working-age population; fertility rates need creates a true youth bulge (a bulge that is fol-
to fall. Unless the number of dependents per lowed by a decline in the youth population
working-age adult decreases rapidly, the poten- once the number of children born falls). In
tial benefits of a changing population structure Africa, child mortality has declined dramati-
28 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Figure 1.4 In East Asia, the dependency ratio changed quickly; in Sub-Saharan Two important differences help to explain
Africa, it is changing, but slowly why the changing population structure in
South Asia and Latin America has not trans-
2.5
lated into a demographic dividend. First, the
rate of increase has been much slower in those
non-working-age population

2.0 regions than in East Asia (where the ratio


Ratio of working-age to

increased from 1.1 in 1970 to 1.8 by 1990).


Second, as noted in the seminal analysis of the
1.5 demographic dividend, East Asians had the
social, economic, and political institutions and
policies that allowed them to realize the growth
1.0
potential created by the transition (Bloom and
Williamson 1998).
0.5
Recent analysis has pointed to the economic
1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2020 2030 2040 2050
threat posed in Africa by a growing population,
low savings rate, and low productivity, which
Sub-Saharan Africa Middle East and North Africa could mean a limited demographic dividend
Latin America and the Caribbean South Asia (Eastwood and Lipton 2011). An economic
East Asia and Pacific
environment that is conducive to investment
Source: Based on United Nations 2011. and growthinto which the population, with
Note: Working-age population is defined as individuals ages 1564; non-working-age population is
defined as individuals ages 014 and 65 and older. its large cohorts of young people, will arrive
and find productive employmentis vital for
Africas growing labor force to have a positive
cally in the past two decades, although some effect on economic and social development.
African countries still have the highest rates in The next section discusses in some detail the
the world. In the first decade or so of this cen- types of jobs that exist and are likely to exist in
tury, the under-5 mortality rate fell from 160 to Africa, because overall employment is a precon-
70 in Benin, 219 to 129 in Burkina Faso, 166 to dition of youth employment (see box 1.1). As
88 in Ethiopia, 189 to 112 in Malawi, 274 to 127 chapter 2 discusses, young people have unclear
in Niger, and 151 to 90 in Uganda.2 and constrained pathways to productive work,
Africas youth bulge will not taper off, how- and as the subsequent chapters in this report
ever, unless fertility rates decline much more show, a range of policies will be necessary to
rapidly and systematically. In the 1970s the fer- enhance those pathways.
tility rate in Asia and Latin America was iden-
tical to the rate in Africa today, but fertility is
falling much more slowly in Africa today than What Is a Job, and Where Do Most
in those regions at that time (Bongaarts and Africans Find One?
Casterline 2013). A more important consider-
ation may be that fertility rates have declined In assessing the challenges of youth employ-
inconsistently across Africa; in fact, the decline ment in Africa, it is important to take stock of
has stalled in several countries (figure 1.5). what it means to have a job and to have employ-
My father has
Even with a rapidly changing population ment. To many, having a job is synonymous
never worked. structure, the demographic dividend is not with having a wage or salaried position with
He has spent automatic. After all, as figure 1.4 shows, East an employer (see quote at left). The majority
his whole life Asia is not the only region where the population of work in Africa is not structured in such a
here in this structure has changed. In Latin America, the way, however. This study follows the approach
plantation which ratio of working-age population to dependents adopted in the World Development Report 2013:
he inherited. rose from 1.1 in 1970 to 1.9 in 2010. In South Jobs, which defines jobs as activities that gen-
Tanzania Asia, it rose from 1.2 in 1975 to 1.8 in 2010. erate actual or imputed income, monetary or in
Opportunities and Challenges for Youth Employment in Africa 29

kind, formal or informal (World Bank 2012e). Figure 1.5 The reduction in the total fertility rate has stalled in several African
This includes part- or full-time in-household countries
economic activities, such as subsistence farm- 9
ing, regardless of whether anything is ever sold.
That report also notes that not all forms of 8
work can be considered jobs. Examples include 7
activities that are performed against the will
of the worker and activities that violate basic 6

Total fertility rate


human rights. 5
In many countries, including in Africa,
people report that jobs have a broader impor- 4
tance beyond the income they provide (see 3
focus note 1). Jobs can convey identity, status,
and self-confidence; they can contribute to an 2
individuals overall life satisfaction. Some jobs 1
contribute to these dimensions of well-being
more than others. The type of job, working 0
195055 196065 197075 198085 199095 200005
conditions, contract, benefits, and safety and
security at work all matter. Jobs also influence Nigeria South Africa Botswana Sub-Saharan Africa

social cohesion by shaping individuals identi- Tanzania Niger Kenya

ties and relations to one another and bringing Source: United Nations 2011.
them together in networks. The distribution of
jobs within society and perceptions about who
has access to opportunities, and why, can shape Box 1.1
peoples expectations and aspirations for the
future, their sense of having a stake in society,
and their perceptions of fairness. All of these Youth versus overall employment
intrinsic aspects of jobs are particularly impor- A key part of improving employment opportunities for Africas youth
tant for youth. is to understand and address Africas overall economic challenges. For
In Africa, the vast majority of work takes that reason, much of the discussion in this report focuses on identify-
place in agriculture. Agriculture occupies more ing policies that can increase the productivity of all employmentin
than 70 percent of the labor force in Africas agriculture, nonfarm household enterprises, and the modern wage
low-income countries and more than 50 per- sector. The report also identifies promising policies that focus specifi-
cent in its lower-middle-income countries. cally on helping young people to make a more successful transition to
higher-productivity work in each of those three sectors.
African farmers are predominantly smallhold-
The focus on youth raises the question of whether it might be
ers who consume a large share of what they
socially beneficial to support employment policies that favor youth over
produce. Data from recently collected house- other members of society. Special efforts to help young people to enter
hold surveys indicate that the share consumed agriculture or start a household enterprise do not generally reduce such
is around 50 percent, compared with 2030 opportunities for adults, but targeted programs in the modern wage
percent outside of Africa (Losch, Freguin- sector could have a detrimental effect on adult employment in the sec-
Gresh, and White 2013). tor. On the one hand, assistance for young people might have long-
Others find employment in household term benefits if it sets them on a productive path. On the other hand,
enterprises (HEs), which are unincorporated, older workers may have families and other economic dependents who
nonfarm businesses owned by households. rely on their income. There is no clear argument that social welfare
will be improved by displacing these older workers to the benefit of
They include self-employed people who run
younger workers. Increasing the opportunities for all workers, while
a business that may employ family members
helping youth to overcome their particular constraints, is the strategy
without pay but also self-employed people that this report advocates.
who run a business that employs a small num-
ber of nonfamily workers on a casual basis.
30 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

We work mostly The vast majority (70 percent) of nonfarm (Chuhan-Pole and Angwafo 2011). The flow of
as subcontractors HEs today are pure self-employmentjust the private capital to Africa now exceeds the flow
owner operating the HE. About 20 percent of of foreign aid. As a result, the structure of out-
for the textile
these enterprises include a family member in put has changed: the share of GDP generated
factories. . . . the operation, and only 10 percent have hired by agriculture is falling, and the share gener-
The entire someone outside of the family. ated by industry and services is rising. By 2010,
village lives on The modern wage sector includes small, agricultures share in GDP had fallen to 30 per-
the income from medium, and large firms that employ five or cent in low-income countries and 16 percent
embroidery, more workers on a continuous basis. It also in lower-middle-income countries, while the
includes the public sector, which in some coun- share of the industrial and services sectors had
smocking, and
tries is a large share of the modern wage sector. increased.
agriculture, In the low- and lower-middle-income coun- The drivers of this growth were economic
which we do tries of Africa, roughly half of wage employ- policy reforms, which were necessitated by mis-
when we dont ment is in the public sector. This report focuses guided steps taken in the past, and higher com-
have work. only on the private sector, where the potential modity prices, which produced better terms of
Madagascar for job growth is greatest. trade (Devarajan and Fengler 2013). These two
factors allowed domestic demand, especially
for private sector services and construction, to
Growth, Jobs, and Africas Labor power growth. Africas impressive growth tra-
ForceNow and in the Future jectory has largely followed commodity prices,
however, and African exports are still concen-
Since 2000, Africa has seen more than a decade trated in primary commodities. In contrast,
of economic growth, the longest continuous it was the rapid rise in export manufacturing
expansion in more than 50 years. Until the that allowed East Asia to capture its demo-
200809 global economic crisis, Africas GDP graphic dividend. Over the past two decades,
grew relatively rapidly, averaging 5 percent a manufacturings share of GDP actually fell in
year, and growth had resumed by 2010 (figure Africa, while rising in Asias lower-income and
1.6). Between 1998 and 2008, mineral-exporting middle-income countries (figure 1.7). Today,
countries experienced an exceptionally steep the share of manufactured goods in merchan-
rise in GDP; 22 countries that are not oil pro- dise exports is 30 percent in Africa, compared
ducers averaged 4 percent growth or higher with 50 percent in Latin America (another
resource-rich region) and 60 percent in lower-
middle-income countries on average. Manu-
Figure 1.6 Africas growth miracle, 200512 factured exports have led growth in only one
country in Africa: Mauritius. Indeed, Africa is
8.0
so far behind East Asia that it will take some
7.0
time to catch up.
6.0
5.0
Real GDP growth (%)

The Structure of Employment in


4.0
African Countries
3.0
Africas dependence on commodity exports,
2.0 aid, and domestic demand as sources of
1.0 growth did not lead to a major transformation
0.0 in employment (figure 1.9; see box 1.2 for an
1.0 explanation of how employment estimates are
2.0 derived and countries are classified). Although
2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012
agricultures share in GDP fell substantially,
Developing (excluding China) Sub-Saharan Africa (excluding South Africa) almost 60 percent of Africas labor force in 2010
Sub-Saharan Africa
still reported that agriculture was their main
Source: World Bank 2012a. economic activity.
Opportunities and Challenges for Youth Employment in Africa 31

Figure 1.7 Over the past two decades, agricultures share in GDP contracted in Africa, but manufacturing did not replace it

a. Low-income countries b. Lower-middle-income countries


100 100
90 90
80 80
70 70
60 60
Percent

Percent
50 50
40 40
30 30
20 20
10 10
0 0
1990 2010 1990 2010 1990 2010 1990 2010 1990 2010 1990 2010
Sub-Saharan Africa South Asia East Asia and Pacific Sub-Saharan Africa South Asia East Asia and Pacific
Agriculture Industry (excluding manufacturing) Manufacturing Services
Source: World Bank various years.

Figure 1.8 Exports are a smaller share of GDP in Africa than in East Asia and a larger share than in South Asia, but African countries, even richer
ones, export commodities, not manufactured goods

Sub-Saharan Africa East Asia and Pacific South Asia


Exports of goods and services (% of GDP)

Exports of goods and services (% of GDP)

Exports of goods and services (% of GDP)


100 100 100
90 90 90
80 80 80
70 70 70
60 60 60
50 50 50
40 40 40
30 30 30
20 20 20
10 10 10
0 0 0
1990 1995 2001 2005 2011 1990 1995 2001 2005 2011 1990 1995 2001 2005 2011

Sub-Saharan Africa East Asia and Pacific South Asia

100 100 100


90 90 90
(% of merchandise exports)

(% of merchandise exports)

(% of merchandise exports)

80 80 80
Manufactures exports

Manufactures exports

Manufactures exports

70 70 70
60 60 60
50 50 50
40 40 40
30 30 30
20 20 20
10 10 10
0 0 0
1990 1995 2001 2005 2011 1990 1995 2001 2005 2011 1990 1995 2001 2005 2011

Low-income countries Lower-middle-income countries Upper-middle-income countries


Source: World Bank various years.
32 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Figure 1.9 The majority of Sub-Saharan Africas workers in low- and lower-middle- in agriculture combined with the persistently
income countries work in agriculture and in nonfarm household enterprises low growth in agricultural productivity help to
Estimated structure of employment in Sub-Saharan Africa by country type, 2010
explain the continued low incomes and poverty
100 in Africa. The data confirm that unemployment
90
remains low, except in upper-middle-income
countries and especially in South Africa, where
80
unemployment is stubbornly high (see focus
70 note 4).
60 Africas decade of growth was not jobless,
% of total

50 but patterns of employment growth differed


40
across countries. Growth moved away from
agriculture in some countries: for example,
30
Ghana, Nigeria, Rwanda, Tanzania, and Uganda
20 all experienced high growth in both wage
10 and HE employment (figure 1.10). Mineral-
0 exporting countries such as Cameroon and
Low-income Lower-middle- Resource-rich Upper-middle- Total Mozambique experienced job growth but saw
countries income countries income countries
countries countries little or no transformation of the employment
183 40 150 21 395a structure, although the creation of nonfarm
Labor force (millions) employment in Nigeria over the last decade
shows that diversification is possible in an Afri-
Agriculture Household enterprises Wage services Wage industry Unemployed
can oil-exporting country.
Source: Fox et al. 2013.
Note: On horizontal axis, numbers show size of labor force in each group. Country classification is
In rapidly growing countries where growth
based on per capita gross national income (GNI) in World Bank (various years). See box 1.2 for an did not depend significantly on mineral
explanation of how employment estimates are derived and countries are classified.
a. Numbers do not add to total because of rounding. resources, employment followed output in shift-
ing out of agriculturethe sector with the low-
est productivityand into higher-productivity
This result is not wholly unexpected: the industry and services. Those countries saw
transformation in labor always lags the trans- nonfarm wage and salary employment in the
formation in output (more capital per worker private sector advance at a rapid pace that
is needed to employ people in more produc- often surpassed growth in GDP. Most of the
tive jobs). Yet the large share of the labor force increase in wage employment (public and pri-

Box 1.2

How are our employment estimates done?


Data on the structure of employment in Africa are dif- of the labor force for each country was calculated by taking
ficult to obtain. Many countries do not collect these data the United Nations projection for the working-age popula-
frequently; often the data are not released until long after tion in each country and applying a labor force participation
they have been collected; and in some cases, only pub- rate. Countries were grouped according to income, with
lished tabulations are released. Regardless of how they low income set at gross national income (GNI) per capita
are released, the quality is often poor (Fox and Pimhidzai under US$1,000, lower-middle income at GNI per capita of
2013). For these estimates, all possible data sources were US$1,000US$4,000, and upper-middle income at GNI per
consulted to get at least one observation on the structure capita above US$3,000. Resource-rich countries were esti-
of employment for each country over the period 200010 mated as a separate group. Figure 1.9 shows the baseline
to form the baseline. We were able to do this for 28 of 47 distribution estimated using this method by country group
countries in Africa, covering 73 percent of the labor force. for 2010.
For the other countries, we imputed a distribution of the
labor force from the averages of similar countries. The size Source: Fox et al. 2013.
Opportunities and Challenges for Youth Employment in Africa 33

vate) occurred in the expanding services sector; Figure 1.10 Growth has moved the structure of employment away from agriculture
growth in labor-intensive industry was slow, in some countries, but not others
owing to the limited development of export 20
manufacturing. 15

Percentage point change in


By 2010, the private sector was creating 10

employment share
most of the wage jobs found in Africa (figure 5
1.11). Much of the increase in wage employ- 0
ment was in noncontract employment such as 5
day labor or temporary jobs. These jobs, often 10
called informal wage employment, represent 15
about half of all nonfarm wage jobs in Africa. 20
Despite the recent creation of private wage 25
jobs, the share of wage employment remains Nigeria Rwanda Ghana Uganda Tanzania Senegal Cte dIvoire

low throughout Africa, partly because the pub- Agriculture Private wage Household and medium-size enterprises
lic sector shed so many jobs in the 1980s and Source: Based on standardized and harmonized household and labor force surveys. See appendix A.
1990s (Fox and Gaal 2008). Although most
nonfarm wage employment was found in the
public sector in the 1960s and 1970s, this pat- Figure 1.11 Most wage jobs are in the private sector (but not in resource-rich
tern was reversed in nonresource-rich coun- countries)
tries during their recent growth spurt. In con-
100
trast, economies that grew through increased
90
mineral extraction maintained the pattern:
80
Public wage as a share of all

the state distributed part of the resource rents


wage employment (%)

in the form of public sector jobs. The pub- 70

lic sector continues to provide most of the 60

wage employment in resource-rich countries, 50


because incentives for the private sector to cre- 40
ate employment remain weak (box 1.3). 30
Private nonfarm employment grew the 20
most rapidly in the HE sector, as rural and 10
urban households used their extra income to 0
start businesses (figure 1.10). The data pre- Low-income Lower-middle- Resource-rich Upper-middle- Weighted
sented here are likely to understate growth in countries income countries countries income countries average
(including South Africa)
the HE sector, because they show only pri-
Source: Fox et al. 2013.
mary employment, when in fact a sizable share
of the labor forceup to 50 percent in some
countriesundertakes two or more economic agriculture, which is about the average for
activities (jobs) over a 12-month period. Par- Africas lower-middle-income countries (table
ticularly in rural areas, where the majority of 1.1). The difference is that these East Asian
Africas population still lives, a household is countries have higher agricultural productiv-
likely to report its HE as a secondary activity, ity, which has helped to reduce rural poverty
after farming (Fox and Sohnesen 2012). to levels well below those in Africa. Africa and
these East Asian countries may have the same
The Structure of Employment in Africa share of the labor force in agriculture, but the
Compared with Other Regions persistently low growth in agricultural produc-
The share of the labor force in agriculture is tivity in Africa prevents the African labor force
not unusually high in Africa, especially in its from reducing poverty to the same extent as
lower-income countries. In Vietnam and the their Asian counterparts (IMF 2012). The HE
Lao Peoples Democratic Republic, where per sector is also large in all of the lower-income
capita income just exceeds US$1,000, 50 per- comparator countries, especially in Bangla-
cent or more of the labor force still works in desh, the poorest of the comparators.
34 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box 1.3

The challenge of diversifying output and employment in resource-rich countries:


Examples from Central Africa
Debate remains lively on the existence and nature of the so- structure, and the promotion of new sources of economic
called resource curse, but few doubt that youth employ- growth. A central concern is to ensure coherence across
ment faces special challenges in countries with large endow- policies that promote human capital development, includ-
ments of mineral resources. Resource rents, if not carefully ing specific programs for youth employment, and those that
managed, lead to overvalued exchange rates and contribute promote public investment in infrastructure and productive
to noncompetitive wages. Both of these outcomes cripple sectors. In Central Africa, for example, public expenditure
the development of sectors that trade in goods other than reviews in Equatorial Guinea and Gabon found that pub-
mineral resources, particularly if a countrys human capital or lic spending has overemphasized investments in physical
productive infrastructure has not improved as a result of its infrastructure relative to human capital (World Bank 2010,
resource wealth. The traditional tradable sectors of the econ- 2012c). Despite high unemployment among well-educated
omy, including export-oriented agriculture, can shrink rap- youths, firms in newly emerging economic sectors have dif-
idly; at the same time, the industries based on extracting nat- ficulty finding qualified personnel, indicating that the skills
ural resources create few new wage-earning opportunities. taught by the education system are not adequately aligned
Most workers are left with few choices. They either revert with efforts to promote new economic activities (World
to low-productivity subsistence farming or migrate to urban Bank 2012d, 2013). Arbitrary limits on the employment of
areas, where they often remain underemployed. The few foreigners can also be a significant business constraint, and
opportunities for highly paid employmentin the natural even when expatriates are employed, all too little is done to
resource sector and the public sector (where growth is fed transfer their expertise to locals. Often foreign contractors
by resource rents)contribute to a pattern of youth unem- implement large-scale public investment projects that use
ployment in which young people simply opt to wait for a very little domestic labor, even for low-skilled activities that
job in those sectors and develop a motivational bias against could employ local youths in the short run. A review of youth
other forms of employment. The expectation of a public sec- employment programs in Cameroon found that they address
tor desk job distorts young peoples educational choices a wide range of specific problems but lack coherence and
and creates a large group of graduates whose skills are ill are not clearly integrated with broader policies to remove
matched to the needs of the private sector. binding constraints to growth and employment (World Bank
Often natural resource wealth goes hand in hand with 2012b).
significant deficits in the institutional environment that Successful resource-rich countries outside Africa, such
hamper growth in private sector employment. When natu- as Chile and Malaysia, have put skills and education at the
ral resource revenue is available, incentives for business cli- center of their diversification strategies (Gelb 2010). Rather
mate reforms are reduced, and the public sector assumes an than picking winners and subsidizing specific sectors, such
excessive role in economic activity. countries have used natural resource revenues strategically
The positive side of this story is that countries with exten- to identify and address constraints on skills in close coop-
sive natural resources have substantial financial resources eration with the private sector. This approach has effectively
at their disposal to invest in human development, infra- promoted economic diversification and youth employment.

The low share of the labor force in private manufacturing jobs. Clearly the importance of
industry is what makes the employment struc- mineral rents in raising per capita incomes in
ture so different in low-income and lower- Africas lower-middle-income countries con-
middle-income countries of Africa compared tributes to this discrepancy. Resource extrac-
to the rapidly growing countries of Asia or tion does not generate many jobs, and high
Latin America (table 1.1). All the comparator resource rents can create an economic structure
countries except Lao PDR and Mongolia have unfriendly to private, labor-intensive industry
a larger share of employment in industrial (Gelb 2010). The economies of Lao PDR and
wage jobs, because they have a high number of Mongolia, both mineral exporters in East Asia,
Opportunities and Challenges for Youth Employment in Africa 35

Table 1.1 African countries have less wage employment than high-growth comparator countries
% of employment
Wage job
Income level and
region or country All Industry Services HE Agriculture Total
Low income
Sub-Saharan Africa 12.3 2.3 10.0 18.3 69.4 100.0
Bangladesh 25.7 10.8 14.9 27.7 46.6 100.0
Cambodia 23.3 11.1 12.2 21.0 55.7 100.0
Low-middle income
Sub-Saharan Africa 13.9 2.0 11.9 31.1 55.1 100.0
Bolivia 43.0 12.6 30.4 28.1 28.9 100.0
Lao PDR 13.5 5.4 8.1 19.0 67.5 100.0
Mongolia 39.3 5.9 33.4 16.0 44.7 100.0
Nicaragua 43.9 13.3 30.6 22.9 33.2 100.0
Philippines 48.7 12.6 36.1 19.5 31.8 100.0
Vietnam 31.8 14.3 17.5 19.1 49.1 100.0
Source: Fox et al. 2013.

have structures similar to those in resource- stantial productivity growth seen in rapidly
rich African countries (figure 1.12). Even in this growing economies outside Africa. To create
case, African countries with high levels of min- more productive employment, Africa still faces
eral exports stand out, because they have even the dual challenge of increasing productivity in
less wage employment in industry than Lao agriculture and diversifying employment out of
PDR or Mongolia. Resources are not destiny, agriculture.
however, as Bolivias successful performance in
export-oriented manufacturing shows.
The lack of jobs in export-oriented manu- Figure 1.12 Industrial wage employment has not risen with GDP in Africa the way
it has in manufacturing exporters at similar income levels
facturing is not the only factor setting Africa
apart. As discussed, the labor force is grow- 20
Wage industry employment as a share of employment (%)

ing much faster in Africa than in Asia or


18 SWZ
Latin America, making it that much harder to
transform the structure of employment. For 16
VNM
example, because Vietnams labor force grew NIC
14
at only two-thirds of the pace of Senegals over BOL
the last decade (2.1 versus 3.1 percent a year), 12
KHM PHI
BGD
every dollar invested in creating labor-intensive 10
STP
manufacturing jobs will have a stronger effect
on the structure of employment (measured 8

as a share of the labor force) in Vietnam than 6 LAO KEN


LSO MNG
in Senegal. In other words, Senegal needs 50 MWI
RWA GHA
4 LBR COM
percent more investment in manufacturing SEN
CMR
than Vietnam needed, just to bring its share of 2 NGA COG AGO
COD TCD CIV
employment in industry to the level in Vietnam NER SLE BFA
0
in 2008. 0 500 1,000 1,500 2,000 2,500 3,000 3,500 4,000 4,500
In sum, after a decade of growth and job
GDP per capita, 2010 (current US$)
creation, the majority of Africas labor force
Sub-Saharan Africa, low- and low-middle-income countries Comparators
still works in its least productive sectoragri-
culturewhich has yet to experience the sub- Source: World Bank various years for GDP; Fox et al. (2013) for employment structure in 2010.
36 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

We both started What Can Africa Expect in the Future? Basic Scenario: Strong, Steady Growth
this profession Africas strong growth early in this decade Continues
[silk production has fueled expectations that by the end of the In this scenario, the main sources of growth
decade most of its population will live in coun- in Africa over the next decade are the same
and weaving]
tries with a per capita income (GNI) above as those in the last decade, resulting in steady
when we were US$1,000what the World Bank defines as growth across country groups (table 1.2). Agri-
eight years old. middle income (World Bank 2012a). Cur- cultural growth in lower-middle-income and
There was no rently almost 60 percent of the labor force low-income countries is projected to remain
other option for works in low-income countries, including strong at about 5 percent a year, driven by
us; this is our those classified as resource rich, so this shift increased factors of production (land and
heritage, and we would be significant. labor) and by increased labor productiv-
How might this continued strong growth ity (from increased input use and improved
proudly continue
influence the number and types of jobs avail- access to markets). This growth will cause real
this tradition. able to Africans by 2020? And what would incomes to rise for farmers, as demand for food
Madagascar happen to employment if growth were even crops from Africa is projected to remain high
stronger? We developed two sets of employ- regionally and internationally, keeping prices at
ment projections to explore those questions. current real levels. Projected industrial growth
First, we project what might happen if the in lower-middle-income and low-income
growth remains robust, following its present countries reflects a combination of new mining
course. Next, we project what might happen projects and higher manufacturing output to
to employment if Africa experiences a game- serve the domestic market, but no major gains
changing growth scenario, arising from a in manufacturing exports. Some countries with
surge in export-oriented manufacturing. (For mining projects are projected to have very high
background on the data and methods used industrial growth: Ghana at 19 percent a year,
to develop the employment projections, see as oil production comes on stream; Liberia at
box 1.4.) The sections that follow outline the 17 percent a year, from iron ore mining; and
assumptions behind these scenarios and the Sierra Leone, with an average industrial growth
resulting picture of employment. rate exceeding 50 percent, from iron ore min-

Box 1.4

How are our employment projections done?


For projecting the distribution of employment across sectors, the early 1990s through the late 2000s, and (3) computed
the first step was to develop economic growth projections estimates for African countries for which at least two high-
by sector for each country. These were made based on pro- quality employment and national accounts data points could
jections of area and yield for agricultural products and on be obtained. Using that data, we developed a set of median
projections of underlying sectoral benchmarks, such as elec- sector elasticities for each country grouping, sector, and
tricity usage, cement usage, road and rail transport, telecom- type of nonagricultural job (see table B1.4.1). The industry
munications, and hotel stays, for the other sectors. and services elasticities for the middle-income countries are
Then sectoral elasticities of employment with respect to comparable to the other estimates. For low-income coun-
growth were developed and applied. In developing the esti- tries, the industry elasticities are considerably lower in Africa
mates for employment growth between 2010 and 2020, we than in Asia (Bangladesh, Cambodia, and Vietnam), because
consulted (1) computed sectoral elasticity estimates for some industry growth has been much more labor intensive in the
African countries for the previous decade, (2) computed Asian countries. In contrast, the services employment elas-
estimates for selected Asian comparator countries from ticities are estimated to be slightly higher in Africa than in
Opportunities and Challenges for Youth Employment in Africa 37

Box 1.4

(continued)

Asia. The employment elasticity is much lower in industry income countries, because the explosive growth anticipated
for resource-rich countries than for low-income countries in this sector will come from increased extraction of iron ore,
because of the importance of mining in the former group which is not labor intensive. To close the model, the unem-
and the prevalence of labor-intensive production in the lat- ployment rate for low-income and lower-middle-income
ter group. The agricultural sector elasticities are negative countries was held constant, and all projected employment
for South Africa and the middle-income countries because not allocated to industry and services was assigned to agri-
they have been losing agricultural employment over the past culture. This feature of the model is consistent with agricul-
decade, in contrast to the earlier period (Kapsos 2005) and tures current function as the fallback economic activity for
to middle-income countries in Asia. most households, but it means that employment estimates
Finally, the elasticities of employment were applied to the for agriculture in low-income and lower-middle-income
projected growth rates to project employment by sector for countries are not based on growth elasticities. In middle-
each country to 2020. Since elasticity estimates vary consid- income countries, labor was allocated to each sector, with
erably across countries, the median estimate was adjusted in unemployment as the residual. The resulting baseline sce-
some countries based on the economic structure and pro- nario shows only a modest decline in unemployment in
jected future performance of the country. For example, the these countries. The detailed country employment estimates
employment elasticity of industrial sector growth in Sierra were aggregated back into the country groupings. The final
Leone was adjusted downward from the median for low- result is shown in figure 1.14.

Table B1.4.1 Growth elasticities of employment


a. Our elasticity parameters
Upper-middle
Lower-middle income (except
Sector Low income income Resource rich South Africa) South Africa
a
Agriculture 0.8 1.0
Wage industry 0.9 0.8 0.6 0.6 0.5
Nonwage industry 0.7 0.6 0.7 0.3 0.3
Wage services 0.8 0.8 0.8 0.7 0.5
Nonwage services 0.8 0.9 0.7 0.6 0.5

b. Comparators
Asia 19902010 ILO, SSA, 19902003b
Vietnam, Cambodia, Low- and lower- Upper-middle
Sector Bangladesh Indonesia, Philippines middle income income
Agriculture 0.3 0.3 0.7 0.1
Wage industry 1.2 0.4 0.6 0.8
Nonwage industry 1.1 0.4 0.6 0.8
Wage services 0.7 0.7 0.8 0.7
Nonwage services 0.7 0.7 0.8 0.7
a. Agricultural employment closes the model for low-income, low-middle income, and resource-rich countries.
b. Data from Kapsos 2005.

Source: Fox et al. 2013.


Note: Resource-rich countries are defined here as Angola, Chad, the Democratic Republic of Congo, Guinea, Nigeria, the Republic of Congo, Sudan
and Republic of South Sudan, and Zambia.
38 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Table 1.2 Average annual growth, by sector and country income level, 200520
percent
Actual Projected
200510 201015 201520
Country Real Agri- Real Agri- Real Agri-
group GDP culture Industry Services GDP culture Industry Services GDP culture Industry Services
Low income 6.5 4.8 6.6 7.7 6.2 5.0 7.9 6.2 6.4 5.8 7.3 6.2
Lower-middle
4.4 4.1 4.9 4.5 5.5 4.1 9.9 4.0 5.9 4.7 6.9 5.8
income
Lower-middle
income, except 3.3 3.9 3.4 3.2 4.9 4.3 6.6 4.4 5.8 4.9 7.1 5.4
Ghana
Resource rich 6.8 7.5 3.1 11.9 6.8 6.5 4.6 9.5 6.4 6.4 3.7 8.5
South Africa 3.6 2.5 2.3 4.1 3.1 2.1 2.2 3.5 3.2 3.2 1.3 3.8
Other upper-
3.0 1.5 1.5 4.8 4.6 3.2 4.7 5.1 4.5 4.7 4.1 4.9
middle income
Source: Fox et al. 2013.
Note: See box 1.4 for an explanation of how employment projections are derived and countries are classified.

ing. When those countries are excluded from the mining sector will not directly create very
their respective groups, a smoother pattern many jobs. By 2020, wage and salary jobs will
emerges for growth rates. Resource-rich coun- account for 29 percent of the net new jobs but
tries, whose main export is expected to remain only 25 percent of the total jobs taken by new
unprocessed minerals, will be distinguished by entrants (some new entrants will replace work-
higher growth in the services sectorr (public sec- ers leaving the labor force). In other words, at
tor growth funded by mineral rents). Upper- best one in four African youth will find a wage
middle-income countries are projected to job, and only a small fraction of such jobs will
continue recovering from the slump that fol- be formal jobs in modern enterprises. Unem-
lowed the financial crisis of 200708. They are ployment is assumed to remain low in the low-
expected to diversify their exports into services, income and lower-middle-income countries,
giving a boost to that sector. and we project that it will fall slightly in the
A key assumption behind this optimism is upper-middle-income countries if high growth
that Africa will not experience another major rates are realized.
economic shock from external or internal The HE sector is projected to create even
sources, such as another major global reces- more jobs than the wage sector, accounting for
sion that shatters demand for African exports, 45 percent of the net new jobs and employing
the outbreak of a regional conflict, or a pro- 37 percent of new entrants through the start-up
longed climatic disaster in the region. Without of new businesses. This sector feeds off demand
such shocks, African countries could realize for goods and services created by employment
10 years of growth averaging 4.56.0 percent a and earnings growth in the wage and agricul-
year, slightly above what was achieved during tural sectors, so balanced growth is necessary to
200510, which included the shock to world realize this part of the projection.
financial markets. Because the majority of new jobs will need
Figures 1.13 and 1.14 present initial answers to be created in countries currently classified as
to the questions about the number and types low income (such as the Democratic Republic
of jobs that this kind of growth might create. of Congo and Ethiopia), the agricultural sec-
Although industrial wage employment is pro- tor will remain important for creating employ-
jected to increase through continued modest ment. In agricultureunlike other sectors
diversification of output and exports, service the projection of new jobs (in low-income and
employment is projected to keep growing lower-middle-income countries) is not based on
faster than industrial employment because demand for labor in the sector. Instead it repre-
Opportunities and Challenges for Youth Employment in Africa 39

Figure 1.13 Where will Africas 125 million new jobs be created?

a. Jobs by sector b. Projected distribution of new entrants by sector, 201020


300 4% Wage industry
21%
250 Wage
services 37% Agriculture
Jobs (millions)

200

150

100

50
38%
0 Household
Agriculture Household Wage Wage enterprise
enterprise services industry

Jobs in 2010 New jobs in 2020


Source: Fox et al. 2013.
Note: See box 1.4 for an explanation of how employment projections are derived and countries are classified.

sents the labor force that does not find a wage Figure 1.14 Informal will remain normal in much of Sub-Saharan Africa
job or start a business (box 1.4). The absolute Projected structure of employment in Africa, by country type, 2020
number of people working in agriculture is pro- 100
jected to rise by about 33 million. Since about 70 90
percent of those who will exit the labor force are
80
now working in agriculture, the actual number
70
of new entrants that agriculture needs to absorb
is over 62 million, or about 38 percent of the 60
% of total

new entrants. Stronger growth in other sectors 50


could push this number down slightly, but it is 40
unlikely that the labor force in agriculture will
30
shrink over the next decadeyoung people
20
seeking jobs will simply have no other place to
go. If African agriculture realizes its potential, 10

however, agricultural jobs will be more produc- 0


Low-income Lower-middle- Resource-rich Upper-middle- All
tive, higher-earning jobs than they are today. countries income countries income countries
Although the projection implies high countries countries
growth in nonagricultural employment, the 248 52 200 23 523
projected structure of employment shown Labor force (millions)
in figure 1.14 is not much different from the Agriculture Household enterprise Wage industry Wage services Unemployed
current structure shown in figure 1.9. Agricul-
Source: Fox et al. 2013.
tural employment will decline in all country Note: See box 1.4 for an explanation of how employment projections are derived and countries are
groups, yet the share of industrial wage jobs in classified.

total employment will rise from 2.3 to only 3.2,


below other developing regions, because those
jobs are growing from such a small base. provided here30 million new wage jobs over
How do these estimates compare with others the coming decade? The main difference is that
in the literature? A recent McKinsey study con- we use Africa-specific data and projections to
tends that Africa will create about 122 million forecast the employment profile, whereas the
new jobs over the next 10 years and that almost McKinsey team uses data from fast-growing
half of them will be wage-paying jobs (Fine et developing and emerging market countries on
al. 2012). Why is McKinseys employment fore- other continents.3 That method clearly imparts
cast considerably more optimistic than the one an upward bias to McKinseys results.
40 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Game-Changer Scenario: A Surge in To test the possible implications of such a


Labor-Intensive Export Manufacturing game change for employment in Africa, we
Is there a better scenario for African jobs? The simulated this recent Asian experience for low-
scenario just presented is already optimistic in income and lower-middle-income countries of
the sense that it is based on sustained growth Africa.4 In this simulation, we raised the wage
across Africa, but it is not based on a radical, employment elasticity to 1.2 to match the his-
game-changing departure from Africas cur- torical wage employment elasticity estimated
rent growth path. Some observers contend that for Bangladesh, Cambodia, and Vietnam
if Africa increases output in export-oriented, meaning that employment in the industrial
labor-intensive light manufacturing as dramat- sector would grow 20 percent faster than value
ically as high-growth comparator countries in added, which implies very labor-intensive
Asia managed to do, the structure of employ- growth. The industrial growth projection for
ment could change more rapidly (Lin and low-income and lower-middle-income coun-
Monga 2012; Dinh et al. 2012). When growth tries was also revised upward to 10 percent a
in manufacturing employment was at its peak year over 201520. This figure is slightly above
in Bangladesh, Cambodia, and Vietnam, those the median and average industry growth rate
countries had annual growth rates of 10 per- experienced by Bangladesh, Cambodia, and
cent or more in their industrial sectors and Vietnam over the most recent decade (9.3 per-
were creating industrial wage jobs at an even cent a year). Figure 1.15 compares the structure
faster pace. of employment for the original and the alterna-
How would the structure of employment tive, game-changing scenario.
differ if low-income and lower-middle-income If the alternative scenario could be realized,
African countries changed their policies and industrial wage employment would grow much
investments to achieve a comparable perfor- faster across Africas low- and lower-middle-
mance? What employment prospects would be income countries, which would account for
open to youth in those countries in 201520 if almost 60 percent of Africas labor force in
Africa picks up manufacturing industries and 2020. The average annual growth of indus-
jobs from East Asia beginning in 2015, in much trial wage employment would double over
the same way that other East Asian countries the decade to 12 percent a year, and total wage
picked up industries and jobs from Japan and employment would grow 6 percent a year. Yet
the Republic of Korea in the 1980s and 1990s? even then the structure of employment would

Figure 1.15 Even game-changing growth will have limited effects on the distribution of employment in the near term

Original Alternative Original Alternative


scenario scenario scenario scenario
16 100
90
Wage industry jobs, 2020

14
80
12
70
% of total

10
(millions)

60
8 50
6 40
30
4
20
2 10
0 0
Low-income Lower-middle- 248 248 52 52
countries income countries Low-income Lower-middle-
countries income countries
Original Additional jobs under
scenario alternative scenario Labor force (millions)
Agriculture Household enterprise Wage services
Wage industry Unemployed
Source: Fox et al. forthcoming.
Note: See box 1.4 for an explanation of how employment projections are derived and countries are classified.
Opportunities and Challenges for Youth Employment in Africa 41

look about the same. Low-income countries Table 1.3 Framework of this report
could expect about 5 million more wage jobs Three sectors Two dimensions
a year, and lower-middle-income countries Agriculture Human capital
could expect about 2 million new wage jobs Nonfarm household Business environment
a shift of 10 percent of total new jobs in these enterprises
countries, representing a small change in the Modern wage employment
prospects for new entrants.
These modest gains partly reflect the short
period used for the projection, which covers productivity (access to land, capital, and
only five years, whereas the structural change finance; infrastructure; technology; and
in Vietnam took 20 years to unfold. They also markets), as well as the government policies,
reflect the larger labor force and the lower base regulations, and programs that may affect
from which industrial development would the choice of economic activity and how the
start. Africa will need at least two decades to activity is conducted.
change the structure of employment suffi-
ciently to offer dramatically different prospects Chapters 4, 5, and 6 address each sector
to its youth, which underscores the importance in turn (agriculture, HEs, and modern wage
of starting the change process now. employment in the private sector). They delve
into the particular ways that binding constraints
related to the business environment and human
Framework of This Report capital influence young peoples potential for
productive employment, and they describe how
Starting from the reality of youth in Africa those constraints might be relieved.
the size of the cohort and the events that shape To provide the context for those chapters,
their lives during the many transitions that chapter 2 discusses the transitions that char-
youth entailsthis report analyzes young peo- acterize youth, particularly the overlapping
ples employment prospects and experiences transitions from school and to work. Chapter
and examines how to create pathways leading 3 looks at skills, an issue that cuts across all
to productive work. Using a simple analytical sectors of employment, focusing on the skills
framework, the report develops a systematic that are critical for productive employment and
and detailed understanding of the challenges how they are acquired. The chapter assesses the
involved in improving the productivity, earn- role of schooling in producing education and
ings, and efficiency of the transitions of youth learning and describes the wide landscape of
as well as the various interventions that show apprenticeships and other forms of training
promise in addressing those challenges (table that develop skills outside of school.
1.3). We focus on the three sectors in which pro-
ductivity increases will be most critical: agricul- Notes
1. Excluding China, the estimates for East Asia and
ture, nonfarm HEs, and the modern wage sector.
the Pacific are 115 million youth ages 1524 in
We distinguish two types of constraints that
2015 and 101 million in 2050. The decline in the
limit young peoples potential for finding path- cohort size begins in 2010 (as it does for China).
ways to productive work in the three sectors: 2. Figures are based on Demographic and Health
1. Human capital. The supply side, or the abili- Surveys (DHS) final reports (www.measuredhs
.com).
ties, education, skills, family connections,
3. McKinsey based its estimate on data for the Arab
networks, beliefs, and other character traits
Republic of Egypt, Indonesia, Korea, Malaysia,
that are embedded in an individual and Mexico, Pakistan, the Philippines, Thailand, and
allow that person to find opportunities to be Turkey.
productive, increase earnings, and achieve 4. Africas resource-rich countries were excluded
income security from this simulation, because even the resource-
2. Business environment. The factors outside rich countries in East Asia did not achieve the type
a workers immediate control that affect of employment transformation simulated here.
42 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

References Policy Research Working Paper 6184, World


Bloom, David E., David Canning, and Pia N. Bank, Washington, DC.
Malaney. 2000. Population Dynamic and Eco- Fox, Louise, Alun Thomas, Cleary Haines, and
nomic Growth in Asia. Population and Develop- Jorge Huerta Munoz. 2013. Africas Got Work to
ment Review
w 26 (supplement): 25790. Do: Employment Prospects in the New Century.
Bloom, David E., and Jeffrey Williamson. 1998. IMF Working Paper, International Monetary
Demographic Transitions and Economic Mir- Fund, Washington, DC.
acles in Emerging Asia. World Bank Economic Gelb, A. 2010. Economic Diversification in
Revieww 12 (3): 41955. Resource-Rich Countries. Paper prepared for
Bongaarts, John, and John Casterline. 2013. Fertil- the conference on Natural Resources, Finance,
ity Transition: Is Sub-Saharan Africa Different? and Development: Confronting Old and New
Population and Development Review w 38 (supple- Challenges, Central Bank of Algeria and the IMF
ment 1): 15368. Institute, Algiers, November 45.
Chuhan-Pole, Punam, and Manka Angwafo, eds. IMF (International Monetary Fund). 2012.
2011. Yes Africa Can: Success Stories from a Regional Economic Outlook: Sub-Saharan
Dynamic Continent. Washington, DC: World Africa Sustaining Growth amid Global Uncer-
Bank. tainty. IMF, Washington, DC.
Devarajan, Shantayanan, and Wolfgang Fengler. Kapsos, Stephen. 2005. The Employment Intensity
2013. Africas Economic Boom: Why the Pessi- of Growth: Trends and Macroeconomic Deter-
mists and the Optimists Are Both Right. Foreign minants. Economic Strategy Paper 2005/12,
Affairss (MayJune): 6881. International Labour Organization, Geneva.
Lin, Justin Yifu, and Clestin Monga. 2012. Solving
De Wolf, Stefan, Yves Rolland Rakotoarisoa, Lau- the Mystery of African Governance. New Politi-
rence Vanpaeschen, and Honor Rabekoto. 2008. cal Economyy 17 (5): 65966.
Madagascar: Le Grand Livre des Petits Mtiers:
Portraits of Daily Life Professions. Belgium: Snoek Losch, Bruno, Sandrine Freguin-Gresh, and Eric
Publishers. Thomas White. 2013. Structural Transformation
and Rural Change Revisited. Washington, DC:
Dinh, Hinh T., Vincent Palmade, Vandana Chandra, World Bank.
and Frances Cossar. 2012. Light Manufacturing
in Africa: Targeted Policies to Enhance Private United Nations. 2011. World Population Prospects:
Investment and Create Jobs. Agence Franaise The 2010 Revision. New York: United Nations,
de Dveloppement and World Bank, Washing- Department of Economic and Social Affairs,
ton, DC. Population Division. http://esa.un.org/wpp/
Excel-Data/population.htm.
Eastwood, Robert, and Michael Lipton. 2011.
World Bank. 2010. Equatorial Guinea Public
Demographic Transition in Sub-Saharan Africa:
Expenditure Review. World Bank, Washington,
How Big Will the Economic Dividend Be? Popu-
DC.
lation Studiess 65 (1): 935.
. 2012a. Africas Pulsee 6 (October). World
Fine, David, Arend van Wamelen, Susan Lund, Bank, Washington, DC.
Armando Cabral, Mourad Taoufiki, Nor-
bert Drr, Acha Leke, Charles Roxburgh, Jrg . 2012b. Employment in Cameroon: Stock
Schubert, and Paul Cook. 2012. Africa at Work: Take of Programs, Assessment of Existing Gaps
Job Creation and Inclusive Growth. McKinsey and Opportunities, and Proposed Next Steps.
Global Institute, Washington, DC. World Bank, Washington, DC.
Fox, Louise, and Melissa S. Gaal. 2008. Working . 2012c. Gabon Public Expenditure Review:
out of Poverty: Job Creation and the Quality Better Management of Public Finance to Achieve
of Growth in Africa. World Bank, Washington, Millennium Development Goals. World Bank,
DC. Washington, DC.
. 2012d. Gabon: Rapport sur la croissance
Fox, Louise, and Obert Pimhidzai. 2013. Different et lemploi. World Bank, Washington, DC.
Dreams, Same Bed: Collecting, Using, and Inter-
preting Employment Statistics in Sub-Saharan . 2012e. World Development Report 2013:
Africa: The Case of Uganda. Policy Research Jobs. New York: Oxford University Press.
Working Paper 6436, World Bank, Washington, . 2013. Economic Growth in Equatorial
DC. Guinea: Paths to Inclusiveness and Sustainabil-
Fox, Louise, and Thomas Sohnesen. 2012. House- ity. World Bank, Washington, DC.
hold Enterprises in Sub-Saharan Africa: Why . Various years. World Development Indica-
They Matter for Growth, Jobs, and Livelihoods. tors. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Jobs: More Than Just Income FOCUS
NOTE 1

A
jobbe it for a wage or notis almost nic backgrounds in Rwandas coffee industry
always more than just an income. A job found that workplace interactions are associ-
affects a persons core sense of identity ated with better attitudes toward collabora-
and at the same time establishes how a person tion across ethnic boundaries and less distrust
is perceived by society. The kind of job that (Tobias and Boudreaux 2011).
people do exerts a powerful influence on their Jobs in agriculture, too, can connect peo-
social well-being and economic development. ple through networks. Studies in Ghana and
The World Development Report 2013: Jobs cov- Uganda illustrate how farmers connected
ers these themes in detail and serves as the basis through networks can obtain information [In my job] I
for the brief discussion that follows. and increase productivity. In Ghana, pine-
meet a lot of peo-
apple farmers adjusted their use of fertilizer
in response to the successful or unsuccessful ple, learn how to
The Value of Jobs experiences of their neighbors. Farmers just express myself
starting to cultivate pineapples are more likely and how to go
People throughout the world consider jobs to make changes based on information received about personal
to be more than a task or an income. Jobs say from other farmers, showing the potential of communication.
something about an individuals place and on-the-job interactions and learning from oth-
Ghana
identity in society and contribute to an individ- ers (Udry and Conley 2004). In rural Uganda,
uals satisfaction with life (World Bank 2012). a recent randomized experiment studied the
In a 2012 survey in Sierra Leone, 90 percent of productivity effect of networks by pairing cot-
respondents judged their job to be somewhat ton farmers to stimulate the exchange of infor-
or absolutely meaningful (Hatly et al. 2012). mation. The pairs were encouraged to discuss
Similarly, youths interviewed in a qualitative farming activities, problems, and solutions and
study in Ghana reported that they value jobs to set a target for increased cultivation. Farm-
that allow them to acquire new knowledge ers who participated in the project, especially
and skills or to connect with other people women, significantly increased their produc-
through social networks (Anarfi, Anyidoho, tivity. Connecting farmers with other farmers
and Verschoor 2008). The type of job, contract, outside their established social circles helped to
benefits, and safety and security at work all spread information that otherwise would not
influence such perceptions of well-being. This have been shared (Vasilaky 2010).
may explain why measures of job satisfaction While jobs can connect people through net-
are lower in Sub-Saharan Africa than in other works, they can also exclude. Across countries,
regions across all types of jobsagricultural, most people find their jobs through connec-
household enterprise, and modern wage (see tions with friends, relatives, and other acquain-
figure F1.1). tances. In the 2012 jobs survey in Sierra Leone,
In addition to their contribution to status, 75 percent of respondents reported that their
empowerment, identity, and well-being, jobs job is important for establishing contacts with
(including nonwage jobs) connect people others (Hatly et al. 2012). Yet networks may
through networks. Jobs connect people with have negative social consequences when they
othersof different backgrounds, ethnicities, exclude people and groups who lack such con-
and genderwith whom they would not oth- nections. A case study of a weaving cluster
erwise interact and with information, includ- in Ilorin, a city in the Yoruba Muslim part of
ing information about job opportunities. For western Nigeria, and a shoe and garment clus-
example, a study of workers from different eth- ter in Aba, a city in the Igbo Christian area of

43
44 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Figure F1.1 Jobs and life satisfaction across regions

50
45

40
35
30
Percent 25
20
15 High-income countries
Latin America and the Caribbean
10 Europe and Central Asia
5 East Asia and Pacific
Middle East and North Africa
0 South Asia
Wage
employed Self- Sub-Saharan Africa
employed, Self-
employed, Unemployed
non-farm
farm
Source: World Bank 2012, based on Gallup 2009, 2010.
Note: Figure shows the share of respondents who rate their present life at 7 or higher and who anticipate that their
life in five years will be at 8 or higher on a scale of 10.

eastern Nigeria, found that the greater inflow only consider jobs to be salaried employment,
of producers increased the reliance on connec- whereas other forms of livelihood and work
tions and social tensions. The poorest produc- activities do not qualify (World Bank 2013).
ers had no regular suppliers or credit networks, In a similar study in Sierra Leone, youth con-
but depended mainly on customers from their sidered employment to mean having a stable
own village (Meagher 2011). and salaried position. They held office jobs in
particular esteem. Such jobs are often referred
to as Englishman jobs. Positions in teaching
Jobs and Aspirations and nursing are also often treated with respect.
Young people refer to casual, informal jobs that
The distribution of jobs within a society can provide low levels of daily income as dishonor-
affect expectations and aspirations. As children able jobs.
and teenagers form goals for the future, their Wage jobs are not always the most coveted,
aspirations may be influenced by whether their however. The reality is more complex, based on
parents have jobs and the types of jobs their the context, available opportunities, and char-
parents have. Frustration and even social unrest acteristics of youth. In Ghana, wage work is not
may develop when education and effort are not necessarily preferred among different types of
rewarded or when people perceive the distribu- employment (Falco et al. 2012). In fact, owners
tion of jobs to be unfair. In many countries in of informal firms that employ others are sig-
Africa, the conventional wisdom suggests that nificantly happier than people working in the
people, and youth in particular, prefer wage formal private sector. Young people explained
employment to other types of jobs, including that status, autonomy, and income cause them
jobs in farming and household enterprises, to prefer self-employment. A 22-year-old stu-
and that the lack of wage jobs can provoke dent explained, Here in Ghana, you dont earn
social tensions. Wage employment, especially much by working for somebody. You are able
in urban areas, is perceived to be more lucra- to make more from your own business than
tive and secure and to have a higher status. from working for someone (Anarfi, Any-
For example, young people interviewed for a idoho, and Verschoor 2008). An unemployed
qualitative study in Liberia explained that they youth echoed that message: There is nothing
Focus Note 1 45

like doing [your own work], and it gives you Figure F1.2 Jobs drive development
the idea that, one day, I have to work hard and,
Jobs
if possible, establish my own company, employ connected to
people. Youth surveyed in Zambia expressed Jobs in global markets Jobs that are
functional environmentally
similar sentiments; those employed in wage cities benign
jobs noted that they have to supplement their
income with informal activities because of low DEVELOPMENT
pay as well as limited job security (PREM Pov-
erty Reduction Group 2008). Jobs for Jobs that give
the poor a sense
LIVING SOCIAL of fairness
PRODUCTIVITY
STANDARDS COHESION
Jobs and Development Jobs that
empower
Jobs that
link to
women networks
Jobs have three transformational dimen-
sions for individuals and society (World Bank Jobs that do not Jobs that
shift burden shape social
2012). The first one is living standards: poverty to others
JOBS identity
falls as people work their way out of hardship,
Source: World Bank 2012.
especially in countries where the scope for
redistribution is limited. The second is produc-
tivity: efficiency increases as workers get better
at what they do and move from less productive individual may have different effects on society.
jobs to more productive ones. The third is social Good jobs for development are those with the
cohesion: societies flourish as jobs create a sense highest value for society, taking into account
of opportunity and get people from different not only the value they have to the people who
ethnic and social backgrounds to work together. hold them, but also the potential spillovers on
When jobs are examined in light of their otherspositive or negative. Jobs that reduce
potential to contribute to those outcomes, poverty, connect the economy to global mar-
it becomes clear that some jobs do more for kets, or foster trust and civic engagement can
development than others (figure F1.2). For do more for development than others.
policy makers, therefore, it is not only the num- The particular jobs that are good for devel-
ber of jobs that matters, but their quality and opment will vary with each countrys level of
contribution to a countrys development. As development, demography, endowments, and
discussed, individuals value jobs for the earn- institutions. For example,
ings and benefits they provide, along with their
contributions to self-esteem and happiness. In agrarian countries, most people live in
But some jobs have broader effects on society. rural areas and their jobs are in agricul-
Jobs for women can change the way households ture. Making smallholder farming viable
invest in the education and health of children. is critical because poverty rates are high.
Jobs in cities support greater specialization and Higher agricultural productivity can help
the exchange of ideas, making other jobs more the development of off-farm employment.
productive. And in turbulent environments, At the same time, urban jobs connected to
jobs can contribute to peace and social cohe- world markets set the foundation for cities
sion (see box F1.1). to become dynamic.
Often the individual and social perspectives In conflict-affected countries, the most
on jobs coincide, but not always. Jobs with high immediate challenge is to support social
pay and benefits may be coveted by individuals, cohesion. Employment for former com-
but they may be less valuable to society if they batants or youths vulnerable to participa-
are supported through government transfers or tion in violence is particularly important.
restrictive regulations, undermining the earn- Construction can help, as it is labor inten-
ings or job opportunities of others. Because of sive and can thrive even in a poor business
gaps like these, jobs that look equivalent to an environment.
46 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box F1.1

Employment, conflict, and violence: Is there a link?


Dissatisfaction with the quality and availability of jobs among banis 2005; Urdal 2004). Other work fails to find empirical
youth in Africa has raised concerns in the media and in pub- evidence for the relationship between youth unemployment
lic debate about the risks of violence and social tensions. and armed conflict, however, so the evidence remains mixed
Across countries, however, the connections between jobs, (Cramer 2010).
conflict, and violence are not straightforward. Only limited Overall, where unemployment is high or employment
and contradictory evidence on those connections is available opportunities are poor, violence and tensions probably result
from developing countries. Generally, the literature suggests from accumulated risk factors, such as exclusion, perceptions
that relationships between conflict, violence, and employ- of opportunities, and family dynamics, rather than employ-
ment status are indirect and may operate through channels ment status alone. For example, young people may turn to
such as identity and social dynamics (Cramer 2010). gangs or other violent groups to compensate for the lack of
The literature linking crime to unemployment comes ties they have in economic and social life. A longitudinal study
mostly from developed countries, and it finds no consistent of youth in Ecuador found that members of gangs involved
link between unemployment and violent behavior. Studies with drugs and guns joined because they were searching for
from the United Kingdom and the United States have linked the support, trust, and cohesionsocial capitalthat they
youth unemployment to property crime, including burglaries maintained their families did not provide, as well as because
and vehicle break-ins (Bell and Blanchflower 2010). The evi- of the lack of opportunities in the local context (Moser
dence is weaker for violent crimes. The literature on unem- 2009). Similarly, analysis in the United States found that
ployment and conflict presents more consistent results, and gangs provide youth with the income, respect, and social ties
although causality is difficult to establish, there is evidence that they are unable to find in jobs, particularly given the lim-
that poor economic performance, including youth unem- ited opportunities available in cities such as Chicago and New
ployment, can be associated with conflict (Collier and Sam- York that have lost stable manufacturing jobs (Padilla 1992).

In urbanizing countries, productivity growth Fundamentals. Because jobs improve with


in agriculture frees people to work in cities. development, it is necessary to create a pol-
Jobs for women, typically in light manufac- icy framework that is conducive to growth.
turing, can benefit households. Avoiding That task requires attending to macroeco-
urban congestion and allowing the country nomic stability, an enabling business envi-
to move up the value-added ladder are top ronment, human capital accumulation,
priorities. and the rule of lawincluding respect for
In resource-rich countries foreign exchange rights.
earnings may be substantial, but the abun- Labor policies. Labor policy should avoid
dance may undermine the competitiveness the distortionary interventions that clog
of other activities and encourage the cre- the creation of jobs in cities and in global
ation of jobs supported through transfers. value chains and that lack mechanisms for
Jobs that lead to a diversification of exports giving voice and protection to the most vul-
can have large development payoffs. nerable workers, regardless of whether they
Ultimately the role of government is to are wage earners or not.
ensure that the conditions are in place for Priorities. Because some jobs do more for
strong private sectorled growth, to under- development than others, it is necessary to
stand why there are not more good jobs for understand where good jobs for develop-
development in a particular country, and to ment lie, given the country context. Policies
remove or mitigate the constraints that prevent should remove or offset the market imper-
the creation of more of these jobs. The World fections and institutional failures that pre-
Development Report 2013: Jobs outlines a three- vent the private sector from creating more
layered policy approach: good jobs for development.
Focus Note 1 47

References Moser, Caroline O. N. 2009. Ordinary Families,


Anarfi, John Kwasi, Nana Akua Anyidoho, and Extraordinary Lives: Assets and Poverty Reduc-
Arjan Verschoor. 2008. The Economic Empow- tion in Guayaquil, 19782004. Washington, DC:
erment of Young People in Ghana. Report pre- Brookings Institution Press.
pared for the World Bank, Washington, DC. Padilla, Felix M. 1992. The Gang as an American
Bell, David, and David Blanchflower. 2010. Youth Enterprise. Piscataway: Rutgers University Press.
Unemployment: Dj Vu? Discussion Paper PREM Poverty Reduction Group. 2008. The Eco-
Series 4705, Institute for the Study of Labor, nomic Empowerment of Young People in Zam-
Bonn. bia. Report 51431, World Bank, Washington,
Collier, Paul, and Nicholas Sambanis, eds. 2005. DC.
Understanding Civil War. Vol. 1: Africa. Washing- Tobias, Jutta M., and Karol C. Boudreaux. 2011.
ton, DC: World Bank. Entrepreneurship and Conflict Reduction in the
Cramer, Christopher. 2010. Unemployment and Post-Genocide Rwandan Coffee Industry. Jour-
Participation in Violence. Background paper for nal of Small Business & Entrepreneurship 24 (2).
World Development Report 2011: Conflict, Secu- Udry, Christopher, and Timothy G. Conley. 2004.
rity, and Development, World Bank, Washington, Social Networks in Ghana. Discussion Paper
DC. 888, Economic Growth Center, Yale University,
Falco, Paolo, William F. Maloney, Bob Rijkers, New Haven, CT.
and Mauricio Sarrias. 2012. Heterogeneity in Urdal, Henrik. 2004. The Devil in the Demograph-
Subjective Well-Being: An Application to Occu- ics: The Effect of Youth Bulges on Domestic
pational Allocation in Africa. Policy Research Armed Conflict, 19502000. Social Develop-
Working Paper 6244, World Bank, Washington, ment Paper 29740. World Bank, Washington,
DC. doi: 10.1596/1813-9450-6244. DC.
Hatly, Anne, Tewodros Kebede, Huafeng Zhang, Vasilaky, Kathryn. 2010. As Good as the Networks
and Ingunn Bjrkhaug. 2012. Perceptions of They Keep? Expanding Farmers Social Net-
Good Jobs: Port Loko and Freetown, Sierra works Using Randomized Encouragement in
Leone. Background paper for the World Devel- Rural Uganda. Yale University, New Haven, CT.
opment Report 2013, World Bank, Washington, Processed.
DC.
World Bank. 2012. World Development Report 2013:
Meagher, Kate. 2011. Informal Economies and Jobs. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Urban Governance in Nigeria: Popular Empow-
erment or Political Exclusion? African Studies . 2013. Understanding Youth Violence: Cases
Review
w 54 (2): 4772. from Liberia and Sierra Leone. Washington, DC:
World Bank.
Chapter

Youth: A Time of Transitions

By definition, youth is a time of many tran- Often womens opportunities are circumscribed
sitionsfrom school, to work, through risky by social norms related to family responsibility,
behaviors, to founding a family, and to exercising agency, and acceptable economic activities and
citizenship. These transitions, which are shaped by fears of harassment. Given these challenges,
by the opportunities available to each individual, the pertinent policy question is how to make the
as well as by social norms and aspirations devel- paths to employment easier for young people to
oped during childhood and adolescence, have find and navigate.
long-lasting consequences. For youths, the path
from school to a livelihood in agriculture, house- Different countries and different institu-
hold enterprise (HE), or wage employment can tions define youth differently. Broadly speaking,
be particularly long. Young people in rural areas the United Nations defines youth as ranging
may work on their parents farms for some time from ages 15 to 24, the African Union defines
prior to establishing their own farm or HE. In youth as ranging between ages 15 and 35, and
urban areas, they may exit the labor force for a many Sub-Saharan countries apply their own
year or two and then spend several years seek- definitions (such as ages 1540 in Mali or ages
ing but not finding a wage job. They may also 1530 in Kenya). For this report, we do not
work in the family business to gain experience define youth as a specific age range. Rather, we
and save money to start their own HE or invest focus on the fact that youth is a period of tran-
in a farm. Once young people start working in a sitionfrom school, to work, through risky
sectorwhether in agriculture, an HE, or a wage behaviors, to founding a family, and to exercis-
jobthey tend to stay there, although mobility ing citizenship (World Bank 2006). We present
across sectors is slightly higher in urban than data for the various age ranges during which
in rural areas. Migration can offer an opportu- these transitions occur (most commonly ages
nity to change these patterns and substantially 1524 and 2534). Generally we refer to the
increase earnings, but migration for employ- older group as young adults to distinguish
ment is (perhaps surprisingly) low in Africa. For them from the younger group.
young women, the transition from school to high- The transitions of youth have long-lasting
productivity work entails additional challenges. consequences. Clearly, the stage at which a young

49
50 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

person leaves the education system and starts are still in school, but half of them are still in
working is a key determinant of that persons primary school (figure 2.1). Of the 16 percent
skill level and career path, but an individuals of 24-year-olds who remain in school, nearly
stock of human capital is also formed through three-quarters are still in secondary or lower
early work experience. A prolonged period of levels. Thus, in addition to their many peers
initial unemployment or an initial job that offers who never attended school or left it at a pre-
no opportunities for learning and growth can mature age, many Africans leave school only
potentially hurt an individuals future produc- in their late teens or 20swithout having
tivity. Similarly, decisions regarding health and acquired much education.
family made during adolescence and early adult- For far too many young Africans, this mis-
hood can have long-term effects on an individ- match between age and academic level means
uals health and career. that years of childhood and adolescence that
Because adolescence is a critical period of should be spent learning in the classroom are
development, including for socioemotional being used inefficiently. A large part of early
skills, economic or health shocks occur- adulthood that should be invested in learning
ring during that time can have long-lasting on the job and gaining experience is instead
consequences. being used to finish school.
Work experience is important not only Aside from slow advancement through
because it is needed to master skills but because school, an unusually late start to school and
it affects adolescents expectations, goals, and interruptions to schooling combine to ensure
confidence. In some settings (primarily upper- much the same result. Young people graduate
income countries where a wage job is the norm at a late age, even though they have not spent
for first employment), prolonged unemploy- enough years in school. Understanding why
ment during youth can affect mental and these failures are endemic is essential to devis-
physical health, and it has been linked to stress, ing a supportive youth employment policy.
depression, and illness later in life (Lundberg Lengthy yet insufficient schooling may arise
and Wuermli 2012). from the same factors that prevent many chil-
Many types of market or government fail- dren from attending school in the first place or
ures could potentially constrain these transi- that force them to leave school at an early age,
tions. Examples include labor market rigidities
that lengthen the school-to-work transition,
inadequate information on the risks of certain
choices, and lack of access to finance for pursu- Figure 2.1 Many 18-year-olds in Africa are still in
ing higher education or starting a business. The school, but half of them are still in primary school
remainder of this report examines such failures
100
in depth. Enabling youth to manage these tran-
90
sitions betterin particular, to develop path-
% of age cohort still in school

80
ways to higher productivity and higher-earning
70
jobsis the central challenge for promoting
60
youth employment in Sub-Saharan Africa. 50
40
30
Youths Transition from School 20
10
More than 80 percent of 12-year-olds in the 0
developing world are going to school. As 12 15 20 25 30 34
expected, this number declines with age until, Age (years)
by the age of 24, few people remain in school. Primary or less Secondary Post-secondary
In Sub-Saharan Africa this transition is slow. Source: Based on standardized and harmonized household and
About 50 percent of 18-year-olds in Africa labor force surveys (see appendix).
Youth: A Time of Transitions 51

such as the poor quality of schooling, difficulty common in Africa (box 2.1), and strong evi-
of access, and lack of financial resources. dence indicates that it is associated with lower
Another key question is the extent to which school attendance and educational attainment.
lengthy yet insufficient schooling is caused by For some children, work marks a permanent
children or youths starting to work at an age end to schooling when they are still very young.
when they should be in school. Child labor is For other children or young people, the effects

Box 2.1

Child labor in Sub-Saharan Africa


Many African children ages 514 engage in some type of finance, land, or other resources require more work from
work. Compared to other regions, Sub-Saharan Africa has household members (World Bank 2012b).
the largest share of child labor (World Bank 2012b). Child labor is typically associated with delays in the accu-
The worst types of child labor are unambiguously harm- mulation of human capital, and it has been shown to reduce
ful to children and include all forms of slavery, bondage, school attainment and school attendance (Beegle, Dehejia,
military conscription, trafficking, and using, procuring, or and Gatti 2009). More limited evidence indicates that child
offering children for prostitution, pornography, or other labor leads to long-term scarring over and above its nega-
illicit activities. Extreme child labor leads to psychological tive impact on schooling. Yet the long-term implications
and physical scarring, which in turn affects learning capacity of child labor for young peoples ability to engage in more
and future earnings. For instance, in Uganda, child soldiering productive activities or for their welfare in general remain
had a corrosive effect on human capital by keeping children unclear. In Tanzania, working in childhood increased the
away from school and creating high levels of psychological probability that boys would be involved in farming 1013
distress, especially among those who experienced the most years later, and it also pushed girls toward domestic work
violence (Blattman and Annan 2010). and early marriage (Beegle et al. 2008). However, child
Most children are involved in other forms of labor, such labor was also associated with an increased likelihood of
as working on the farm while going to school (particularly wage work, which could be linked to higher living standards
in agricultural households) as well as performing domes- (Beegle, Dehejia, and Gatti 2009).
tic work, selling, begging, and engaging in some type of
manufacturing. The most recent round of the Multiple Indi- Figure B2.1.1
cator Cluster Survey (MICS) collected data on child work.
It defines child labor among 5- to 11-year-olds as being Cameroon
engaged in economic activities (working, paid or unpaid, for Chad
someone who is not a member of the household, or work-
ing in a family business, on the farm, or selling goods in the Congo, Dem. Rep.

street) for at least 1 hour in the 7 days prior to the survey Ethiopia
or being engaged in domestic activities (also described as
Guinea-Bissau
household chores) for at least 28 hours a week. Among 12-
to 14-year-olds, only those who engage in economic activ- Nigeria
ity for 14 hours or more or in domestic work for 28 hours Sierra Leone
or more in the 7 days prior to the survey were counted as
Swaziland
engaged in child labor. According to these definitions, child
labor among 5- to 11-year-olds is typically around 4060 Togo
percent; child labor among 12- to 14-year-olds is typically
0 20 40 60 80 100
closer to 20 percent (figure B2.1.1). In both age groups, the
Percent
results from these surveys show that the majority of children Ages 511 Ages 1214
work for the family business in either the farm or non-
Sources: Multiple Indicator Cluster Survey Reports (MICS), various
farm sector. years (circa 2010). Available at www.childinfo.org.
Child labor tends to be more prevalent among poor Note: Child labor is defined as follows: (a) for ages 511, as eco-
nomic activity for at least 1 hour a week or domestic work for at
households. Children in wealthier households may, in some least 28 hours a week; (b) for ages 1214, as economic activity for at
settings, engage in labor if household assets and access to least 14 hours a week or domestic work for at least 28 hours a week.
52 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Figure 2.2 School and work are often combined are already working exclusively (not counting
100
those who are at work and in school). The inci-
90
dence of exclusive work then rises rapidly. By
80
age 20, it is well above 50 percent, and by age
70
25, it is at 75 percent.

% of age cohort
60
Because a sizable number of those who
50
reach working age have worked while attend-
40
ing school, as many as 70 percent of African
30 youths complete the transition to work by the
20 time they are 18. With age, the ranks of work-
10 ing youth increasingly comprise those who are
0 exclusively at work.
15 20 25 30 34 The incidence of concurrent schooling and
Age (years) work is especially high in agriculture, where
Working and not in school Working and in school
almost 90 percent of such work involves youth
working on the family farm. In this context,
Source: Based on standardized and harmonized household and
labor force surveys (see appendix). young people may have fewer opportunities to
leave the farm sector.
At the other end of the spectrum, the transi-
of premature work may be less extreme but tion from school to work appears to be exces-
nonetheless limiting. Some children interrupt sively long for some young people. About 17
their schooling to perform intermittent work. percent of 26-year-olds and 10 percent of
Others engage in work that is light enough 34-year-olds are not working. This pattern does
to allow them to attend school but that delays not vary by gender, so lower female labor force
their progression through grades. Indeed, participation is an unlikely explanation. Some
household surveys indicate that a sizable per- of these people may be in a temporary phase
centage of young people are both at work and of unemployment between jobs. That, too, is
in school; as many as 45 percent of 15-year-olds unlikely to be the main explanation for their
may fall in this category (figure 2.2). This work- delayed transition to work, however, given the
school overlap becomes less common with age, low share of wage employment among youth.
declining to about 10 percent among 24-year- Identifying the groups most likely to experi-
olds, presumably because they switch to full- ence such difficulty in starting work should be
time work. a priority.
As this discussion shows, for many indi- Traditional policies related to the school-
viduals the transition from school to work is to-work transition often use informational
not a clearly demarcated progression from interventions and other strategies to link job
schooling to graduation and work. Often the seekers to employers, but their relevance in
transition is quite blurryschool and work Africa is limited. As the next section discusses
overlap, or schooling is interrupted for work in greater detail, even though most young peo-
and then resumedso policies that target ple are already working by the age of 20, most
only those who have just left school might have not yet left the family enterprise or farm.
not be enough. At 18 years of age, nearly 70 percent of work-
For many young people in Sub-Saharan ing youths are occupied in farming. At 24 years
Africa, the transition from school begins of age, nearly 60 percent of those working are
relatively early. Although in most developing still on the farm, and about 25 percent are in
countries this transition can begin at any time a nonfarm family enterprise or some form of
between the ages of 12 and 24, it picks up after self-employment. Only for cohorts in their
18 years of age, crossing the 50 percent mark mid-20s and onward does wage employment
only among those in their early 20s. In contrast, represent a notable share (more than 15 per-
more than 20 percent of 15-year-olds in Africa cent) of total employment.
Youth: A Time of Transitions 53

Traditional school-to-work transition poli- more than 60 percent of men and 70 percent
cies may, however, be more relevant to those in of women are working for themselves. Working
their mid-20s and early 30s who are yet to start for someone else increases modestly as people
working and are possibly looking for a wage age, reaching about 30 percent for men and
job. Evidence from firm surveys shows that the about 20 percent for women.
majority of such jobs are found through social Given the slow transformation of the struc-
networks, leaving those with weak networks at ture of employment, even after they become
a strong disadvantage (see the discussion of fig- economically independent from their parents
ure 2.9 later in this chapter). most people end up working in the same type
of economic activity as their parents (box 2.2).
In part because of the slow spread of educa-
Youths Transition to Work tion into rural areas and limited opportunities
to enter nonfarm sectors, males born to house-
As young people begin to work less for their holds where the father was a farmer tended to
families and more for themselves (figure 2.3), become farmers themselves. Those born into
they increasingly leave the family activity households where the father had nonfarm work
and strike out on their own. The vast major- tended to end up in the nonfarm sectorusu-
ity become self-employed. By their early 30s, ally because they grew up in an urban area and

Figure 2.3 Most Sub-Saharan African youths start out working for their families and then become self-employed

a. Male, rural b. Female, rural


100 100

80 80
% of age cohort

% of age cohort

60 60

40 40

20 20

0 0
15 20 25 30 34 15 20 25 30 34

c. Male, urban d. Female, urban


100 100

80 80
% of age cohort

% of age cohort

60 60

40 40

20 20

0 0
15 20 25 30 34 15 20 25 30 34

Worked for family (past 12 months) Worked for someone else (past 12 months) Worked for self (past 12 months)

Source: Based on Demographic and Health Survey (DHS) data in 35 countries for females and 28 countries for males (see appendix).
54 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box 2.2

Intergenerational transmission of occupations in Africa


The trend for young people to end up in the same activity in Cte dIvoire. In spite of the structural decline of agricul-
as their parents has deep roots. A study covering five Afri- tural employment, those numbers are not much lower than
can countries reveals strong patterns in the intergenerational for previous generations. The intergenerational transmission
transmission of occupations from fathers to sons. A farmers of nonfarm employment is also substantial (figure B2.2.1,
son is much more likely to become a farmer than to exit agri- panel b). In Cte dIvoire, 93 percent of the sons born in the
culture (figure B2.2.1, panel a). In Madagascar, 87 percent 1960s of nonfarmers end up being nonfarmers, compared
of farmers sons born in the 1960s are also farmers at the to 89 percent in Guinea, 73 percent in Ghana, 69 percent in
beginning of their working life, as are 72 percent in Uganda, Madagascar, and 61 percent in Uganda. Overall, these pat-
70 percent in Guinea, 69 percent in Ghana, and 64 percent terns reveal limited intergenerational mobility.

Figure B2.2.1 Intergenerational transmission of employment sector in five African countries

a. Probability that farmers sons stay farmers b. Probability that nonfarmers sons stay nonfarmers
100 100

80 80

60 60
Percent

Percent

40 40

20 20

0 0
Cte dIvoire Ghana Guinea Madagascar Uganda Cte dIvoire Ghana Guinea Madagascar Uganda

Son born in 193039 Son born in 194049 Son born in 195059 Son born in 196069
Source: Based on Bossuroy and Cogneau 2013.

encountered better opportunities for education over the two time periodsmainly because
and nonfarm employment. Data from urban they were more likely to stay in agriculture.1
areas in West Africa collected in 200102 show In urban Tanzania, labor force histories col-
that more than 60 percent of those who were lected from respondents who were 2039 in
self-employed had fathers who were also self- 2005 showed that among those whose first job
employed (Pasquier-Doumer 2013). was wage employment, only 20 percent ever
The limited longitudinal data available shifted into an HE (figure 2.4). The same sur-
from Uganda and urban Tanzaniasuggest vey reveals that those whose first job was in the
that once individuals enter a type of jobagri- HE sector (self-employment or family worker)
culture, household enterprise (HE), nonfarm also tended to stay in that sector. The transition
wagefew of them switch to another type of that determines what type of job a young per-
job. Nationally representative panel data from son will hold therefore occurs primarily when
Uganda suggest that, overall, 61 percent of that person exits school, not through subse-
youth ages 2029 in 2005 who were economi- quent mobility across employment sectors.2
cally active had the same type of employment
five years later, with an especially high persis- Moving into the Three Sectors of
tence in agriculture (73 percent). Persistence is Employment
lower in HEs and wage work, but nevertheless Given the relatively small amount of switching
high (at around 50 percent). Women were more between sectors, the transition to the first type
likely to stay in the same type of employment of work is key. But little is known about exactly
Youth: A Time of Transitions 55

how young people transition into the three main Figure 2.4 Youths in urban Tanzania are unlikely to move between employment
sectors of employment. The cross-sectional data sectors during their working lives
used in this report do not record individual his-
tories and thus hide variation between cohorts
as well as within cohorts on the timing and effi- 100
ciency of the transition. Longitudinal data from 90
Tanzania and Uganda provide some insights, as
80
they track individuals over time. Focus group
70
data collected from African youths help to fill

% of youths
out the picture. As noted, however, the under- 60
standing of how young people make key choices 50
leading to a transition to stable employment is 40
Wage
unclear. What is clear is that the pathways and 30 employed
constraints are different depending on the type Self-employed
20
of activity concerned and an individuals loca- Family worker
10
tion and gender.
0 Unemployed
As discussed, the transition into agriculture
Entry as
begins early. The vast majority of teenagers unemployed Entry as Out of labor force
who work are working in agriculture (figure family worker Entry as
self-employed Entry as
2.5). At age 15, of the 60 percent of those who wage employed
are working, almost 90 percent are working in
agriculture. The share working outside agricul-
ture increases steadily with age, largely because Source: Bridges et al. 2013.
Note: Sample includes youth ages 2039 and in the labor force in 2005.
young people who leave school at higher grades
enter other sectors. In rural areas, where lim-
ited educational opportunities prevent youths Like their adult counterparts, the young are
from staying in school for very long, agricul- more likely to work in an HE than in a wage job.
ture employs more than 90 percent of 15- and At age 19, just over 5 percent work in an HE,
16-year-olds, and about 80 percent of young while few work for a wage; by age 24, almost 20
people ages 24 and older remain in agriculture percent work in an HE, and just over 10 per-
(although some who report agriculture as their cent are in a wage job; and by age 34, almost 30
primary activity also have a nonfarm activity percent work in an HE, and the share in wage
as well). Women who work are more likely to work remains around 20 percent (figure 2.5).
work in agriculture than menand unlike As they leave school, women, like men, who are
men their probability of working in agriculture not in agriculture are substantially more likely
does not decrease much with age. One reason to work in an HE than to obtain wage employ-
why so many women remain in agriculture is ment. Longitudinal data from urban Tanzania
that they leave school sooner, so employment suggest that many women enter this sector by
opportunities are set much earlier for females helping out in a family business and then tran-
than for males. sitioning to their own HE. The same data also
Although agriculture is primarily a rural show that other women enter the HE sector
activity, young people and adults in second- only after a long period of searching for a wage
ary cities and periurban areas report working job or failing to find one to their liking or with
in agriculture as well. For example, almost 50 remuneration as high as they could earn in the
percent of youth ages 2029 in urban Uganda HE sector (Falco et al. 2012).
in 2010 reported working in agriculture as their Because it is based on primary occupation,
primary job, and at least 60 percent of those which shows substantial persistence, this gen-
had entered the sector five years before. Young eral picture conceals changes happening below
people in urban areas are less likely to stay in the surface. Within the HE sector and agricul-
agriculture, however; it is often a stepping stone ture alike, young people may start working with
to starting a nonfarm business (figure 2.6). their parents and then acquire their own plot of
56 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Figure 2.5 Youth transitions to sector of employment vary across urban and rural areas and between male and
female youths
a. Overall
100
90
80
70

% of age cohort
60
50
40
30
20
10
0
15 18 21 24 27 30 33

b. Rural c. Urban
100 100
90 90
80 80
70 70
% of age cohort

% of age cohort
60 60
50 50
40 40
30 30
20 20
10 10
0 0
15 18 21 24 27 30 33 15 18 21 24 27 30 33

d. Female e. Male
100 100
90 90
80 80
70 70
% of age cohort

% of age cohort

60 60
50 50
40 40
30 30
20 20
10 10
0 0
15 18 21 24 27 30 33 15 18 21 24 27 30 33

Agriculture Household enterprise Wage

Source: Based on standardized and harmonized household and labor force surveys (see appendix).

land or start their own business. In both rural save enough money to start their own busi-
and urban areas, multiple jobs are common. A ness. Labor force survey data from Tanzania
young person may start out in agriculture but indicate that by age 25 about half of those who
add nonfarm work as a second job. Even young had employment also pursued a secondary
people with a wage job may start out in casual economic activity (figure 2.7). The probability
labor but move to a more stable wage job or of having multiple sources of employment is
Youth: A Time of Transitions 57

Figure 2.6 Sectoral mobility among urban youth in Uganda


Sector of employment in 2010 by sector of employment in 2005
70

60

50

40
Percent

30

20

10

0
Agriculture, Household enterprise owner, Family worker Wage employed, Unemployed or out of labor force,
2005 (33%) 2005 (17%) (household enterprise), 2005 (22%) 2005 (13%)
2005 (15%)

Agriculture, Household enterprise owner, Family worker (household enterprise), Wage employed, Unemployed or out of labor force,
2010 2010 2010 2010 2010
Source: Based on standardized and harmonized Uganda panel survey (see appendix).

much higher in rural areas. Having multiple Figure 2.7 In Tanzania, many work in two or more
jobs helps the worker to minimize the risks activities
associated with operating a farm or HE and to
% of age cohort holding multiple jobs

60
cope with seasonal variation in employment
opportunities and income. The higher prob- 50

ability of having multiple sources of employ- 40


ment in rural areas also suggests that mobility
30
may be higher in rural areas than the data on
primary economic activity indicate. 20
Young people find it particularly challeng- 10
ing to enter into modern wage employment.
Employment histories of urban Tanzanian 0
15 20 25 30 34
youths suggest that most did not enter directly
Age (years)
into a wage job (20 percent; figure 2.4). How-
ever, 69 percent of those who entered a wage Urban All Rural

job remained in wage employment26 per- Source: Based on standardized and harmonized Tanzania labor
force survey, 2005 (see appendix).
cent became self-employed, and 4 percent
became unemployed. Among the few young
people who work for wages, less than half have
a contract. Only around 20 percent of African ing experienced long periods out of the labor
teenagers with wage employment have a con- force or in unemployment before entering into
tract; this rate increases to around 50 percent stable employment. In the longitudinal data,
for those in their mid-20s and around 60 per- the average age of leaving school was two years
cent for 30-year-olds (figure 2.8). Young people less than the average age of entering the labor
are most often engaged in casual wage employ- force, suggesting that even those who did not
ment, which can take the form of part-time or report entering the labor force as unemployed
seasonal wage work. These arrangements are (for example, searching for a wage job) spent
often verbal and of very short duration. time idle or doing odd jobs of very short dura-
The desire for a wage job can lead urban tion (Bridges et al. 2013). Most of those who
youth to search a long time, without success. reported a significant period of unemploy-
In urban Tanzania, young people reported hav- ment (not working and looking for a job) did
58 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Figure 2.8 Younger people are most often engaged getting information on the work-related char-
in casual wage employment acteristics of youth and the need to have a trust-
100
worthy workforce, employers prefer to rely on
contacts to attract new entrants. Urban youths

% of wage-employed youth
80 who participated in focus group discussions in
Kenya complained that either a personal con-
with contract
60 tact from the same ethnic group or a bribe or
40
both were required simply to get anyone in a
private firm to look at their rsum, even for
20 those with postsecondary education (World
Bank 2012a). As long as firms have an ample
0 supply of entry-level candidates, this behavior
15 20 25 30 34
is not likely to change.
Age (years)
Networks are important beyond the wage
Source: Based on standardized and harmonized household and sector. In a survey in Ghana, most youths cited
labor force surveys (see appendix).
networks as important for getting any type
of work. Young men mentioned that friends
would tell them about work opportunities,
not end up getting a wage job. Only 25 percent especially in petty trading, street vending,
of those who were no longer unemployed at farming and fishing, and construction. Young
the time of the survey had found a wage job; women tended to get referrals from family
the rest went into the HE sector (family or self- members for jobs in an HE, in many cases with
employment). The average duration of unem- other family members.
ployment before becoming self-employed was
close to 4.5 years. Moving into Employment through
If a young person is hoping for a wage job Migration
but ultimately settles for self-employment, 4.5 Urbanization is fundamentally altering Africa.
years is a long time to search for work before Even though the share of the population liv-
realizing that informal is normal. The aver- ing in urban areas remains well below the share
age duration of unemployment for those who in the rest of the world, in Africa urbanization
entered the labor force as unemployed but has accelerated over the past couple of decades.
managed to find a wage job in the end was 5.5
years. Youth entering as unemployed generally Figure 2.9 Personal networks are key to finding a job
have higher education and come from wealth-
ier families. Individuals who went through long Family/friends
spells of unemployment did not suffer an earn- Public announcement/
ings penalty. If one makes it into wage employ- advertisement
ment, even a long job search can pay off, but Private placement office
the odds of finding a wage job are low (Bridges Public placement office
et al. 2013).
School-related network
The importance of networks and contacts is
one reason why the search for a wage job can Applicant walked in
be frustrating for youth. Across countries, most Other
people get their jobs through contacts from
family and friends, especially in the case of 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70
% of employers who filled most
modern wage jobs. Almost 60 percent of enter- recent position with each method
prises surveyed in 14 countries report that their
Source: Based on World Bank enterprise surveys (aggregated
most recent position was filled through con- from surveys conducted in Angola, Botswana, Burundi, Camer-
tacts with family or friends (figure 2.9). For oon, the Democratic Republic of Congo, The Gambia, Guinea,
Mauritania, Namibia, Niger, Rwanda, Swaziland, Tanzania, and
a variety of reasons, including the difficulty of Uganda in 200607).
Youth: A Time of Transitions 59

Census data from 42 Sub-Saharan African place between urban areas or between rural
countries show that by 2010 two-fifths of areas. Seasonal migration between rural areas
Africas urban population already lived in a big is common in some countries, Niger for exam-
city (with a population of 1 million or more), ple, where it can involve up to one-third of the
while two-fifths lived in a small town (with population (Simkins 2013).
less than 250,000 people; Dorosh and Thurlow A snapshot of migration patterns and their
2013). The share of the population living in an implications for employment mobility is pro-
urban area is expected to rise from 39 percent vided by a recent study from Kegera, Tanzania.
in 2010 to 57 percent in 2060 (Simkins 2013). The study followed individuals from the pre-
Contrary to popular belief, fertilitynot dominantly rural region of Kagera in Tanza-
migrationstill drives most urban population nia who were 011 years old in 199194 (De
growth in Africa. After slowing from the 1960s Weerdt and Kutka 2013). Two decades later, in
to the 1990s, migration to urban areas has risen 2010, 56 percent of those individuals lived in
in recent years, but it is expected to constitute the same or a neighboring village, 18 percent
only about 30 percent of urban population had moved to a village in the same region, 9
growth between 2010 and 2060 (Simkins 2013). percent had moved to an urban area in the same
Urbanization can be beneficial if it creates region, and 8 percent had moved to another
agglomeration effects that can be a source of region. The main reason that young people had
long-term growth and structural transforma- migrated was marriage (35 percent), followed
tion. Africas urbanization has not yet delivered by attending school (16 percent), looking for
many of these beneficial effects. One reason is work (15 percent), and working (10 percent).
discussed in chapter 1: the lack of a manufac- Migration was associated with a substantial
turing sector. The beneficial effects of agglom- amount of employment mobility. Although
eration are more often seen in lower-income 57 percent of youths ages 1832 in 2010 who
countries with the development of industy, not stayed in the village remained in agriculture,
services, but the economy of African cities is only 30 percent of those moving to a nearby
dominated by services. Where agglomeration town, and 3 percent of those moving to a city,
benefits occur in service clusters, the sectors, were still working in agriculture (figure 2.10).
such as information technology, tend to require Young people in cities were over three times
higher levels of education than most countries more likely to be working for a wage and nearly
in Africa have. As a result, agglomeration forces twice as likely to be in nonfarm self-employ-
are weak, and Africa remains a low-density ment. These moves were associated with large
continent (see World Bank 2008). At the same increases in measured consumption. Young
time, urban growth rates in some capital cities people who stayed in the village or moved to a
are very high and difficult to manage. local town saw incomes increase by 70 and 91
Africans tend to migrate within their percent, respectively, between 1991 and 2010;
country of origin (Sander and Maimbo 2003; those moving to a regional town had incomes
McKenzie 2007; Simkins 2013). Few migrants 150 percent higher; and those who moved to a
come to Sub-Saharan Africa from outside the city had income gains of around 300 percent
region, and international migration within (De Weerdt and Kutka 2013). Most of these
the region is limited to a handful of mag- gains were associated with the move outside of
net countries, such as Kenya, Nigeria, and agriculture.
South Africa (Simkins 2013). Most migration Clearly, urban growth and migration from
within countries occurs for purposes that are rural to urban areas can be a powerful engine
not directly related to employment, includ- for transforming the structure of employment.
ing education, marriage, or avoiding conflict To ensure that the economic infrastructure can
or insecurity. Local moves in particular are support both indigenous population growth
often motivated by marriage. Longer moves, and migrants, however, forward-looking urban
out of district boundaries, are more likely to be planning and investments are required as part
related to work. Much of the migration takes of an overall development strategy.
60 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Figure 2.10 Migration increases mobility across sectors of employment Human immunodeficiency virus/acquired
immune deficiency syndrome (HIV/AIDS) and
Employment status in 2010, by location
60 teenage pregnancy are the two biggest dangers
% of individuals who were age 011
in 199194 in Kagera, Tanzania

50
associated with teenage sexual activity, and
both loom large in Africa. Sub-Saharan Africa
40 is the region most severely affected by HIV.
30 According to survey data collected between
2006 and 2011, the age-specific fertility rate
20
for young women ages 1519 (births per 1,000
10 women) was above 100 in all Sub-Saharan
countries except Rwanda, and it surpassed 150
0
in Chad, Guinea, Lesotho, Madagascar, Malawi,
School Agriculture Self-employed Casual wage Employed Not employed
work Mali, Mozambique, and Zambiarates that are
at the higher end compared to rates in other
Village Town City
developing regions (United Nations 2007).
De Weerdt and Kutka 2013. In thinking about policies to prevent risky
teenage behavior, it is important to consider
how such behaviors are connected with the
other youth transitions. For example, given the
The Parallel Transitions: Choices evidence that stress and mental health prob-
Influencing Health, Family lems are associated with risky sexual activity
Formation, and Civic Engagement and substance abuse among young people, the
stress from idleness or job dissatisfaction could
Certain decisions taken and habits formed dur- increase the chances of engaging in risky behav-
ing adolescence have lifelong consequences. ior. Another example is the rising evidence that
Adolescence is when most individuals begin school attendance lowers teenage sexual activ-
to have control over their own decisions and ity and pregnancy. A conditional cash transfer
behaviors. It is also a period of experimenta- targeting young Malawian women (1322 years
tion, when youth start engaging in risky activi- of age) provided incentives to current stu-
ties such as smoking and consuming alcohol. dents and dropouts to attend school and led to
Youth is also the period in which sexual activ- large increases in school enrollment as well as
ity is initiated, family formation begins (figure declines in early marriage, teenage pregnancy,
2.11) (see de Walque 2014). This is also the sexual activity, and risky sexual behavior (Baird
time when people begin to engage with society et al. 2010). Similarly, a study in Kenya finds that
as citizens. reducing the cost of schooling (by paying for
uniforms) reduced dropout rates, teen marriage,
Taking Health Risks and childbearing (Duflo et al. 2006). Schooling
Smoking is one of the leading preventable is not the only determinant, however. In the
causes of death worldwide, and youth is when it Malawi study, girls who received an uncondi-
is most likely to develop into a habit. Less than tionall cash transfera transfer not linked to
10 percent of boys ages 1315 smoke cigarettes school participation and performancealso
in most of Africa, except the southern tip had large reductions in sexual activity, teenage
Botswana, Namibia, and South Africa (Warren pregnancy, and marriage (Baird et al. 2011).
et al. 2009). This rate of tobacco use is one of
the lowest in the developing world, but even so, Starting a Family
the potential for damage should not be under- Along with starting work, starting a fam-
estimated. As countries grow richer, they tend ily is one of the biggest decisions taken dur-
to pass through a cycle of tobacco prevalence ing youth. By the age of 25, nearly 80 percent
(Eriksen, Mackay, and Ross 2012). The second of women in Africa have married and given
stage of this cycle is when smoking prevalence birth (figure 2.11).3 This transition happens
tends to rise sharply. later among men. While more than half of
Youth: A Time of Transitions 61

Figure 2.11

a. Females b. Males
100 100

80 80
% of age cohort

% of age cohort
60 60

40 40

20 20

0 0
15 20 25 30 35 15 20 25 30 35
Age (years) Age (years)

Ever had a child Ever married Ever had sexual intercourse


Source: Analysis of DHS data for 28 countries (see appendix).

all women are married by the age of 20, the health of both child and mother, should be
majority of men are likely to remain unmar- of particular concern to policy makers. How
ried before the age of 25 and to marry only in young parents invest in their children will have
their late 20s or early 30s. a large impact on the well-being of future gen-
Decisions about employment and family for- erations. Evidence is growing on the range of
mation are linked. The decision to start a family is interventions that could prepare youth for this
often taken after securing the means to support a transition (summarized in World Bank 2003).
family, which could be the reason why most men For instance, micronutrient supplementation
marry late. The linkages are particularly salient and food fortification for children and for
for women. Economically active women may young women before and during pregnancy
decide to postpone marriage, schedule births are known to improve birth weight and sub-
later in life, and have fewer children on average sequent child development, as are conditional
than women who are not economically active. cash transfers for the use of preventive health
For example, in Asia and Latin America, wom- services. Other interventions, such as informa-
ens employment in the garment sector has been tion campaigns on reproductive health, safe
linked to later age at marriage and lower fertility motherhood, and child health, look promising.
(Amin et al. 1998; McLeod et al. 2005). In the
other direction, there is evidencealbeit mostly Exercising Citizenship
from developed countriesthat childbearing Along with participating in the civic discourse
lowers female labor force participation (Bloom on important social, economic, and other
et al. 2009). In Africa, where most employment issues, citizenship means having certain rights
is with the family farm or enterprise, the nature and obligations, such as the right to vote, which
of the relationship between work and family African youths exercise in large numbers (fig-
formation may be different. Early marriage or ure 2.12). Youth is also when individuals begin
childbearing may not prevent work so much as to express themselves as citizens in other ways,
trap young women in low-productivity activities such as attending community meetings, join-
performed in the household. ing with others to raise issues, or taking part
While the main drivers of fertility are largely in demonstrations. Survey data from 2008
economic, public policy has a role in support- indicate that in the past year between 60 and
ing healthier family formation, as financial or 70 percent of African youth ages 2030 had
informational constraints may lead young par- engaged in at least one of those activities.4
ents in Africa to underinvest in family planning Civic engagement is necessary for govern-
or maternal health services. Early pregnancy, ments to take young peoples ideas and aspira-
which can have a large adverse impact on the tions into account effectively when formulating
62 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Figure 2.12 As they get older, young people agriculture, and they are also less likely to gain
increasingly engage as citizens wage employment. Womens employment
100 opportunities are constrained not only by the
fact that they tend to exit school earlier, but

% of cohort who voted in


most recent election
80
also by gender-specific constraints associated
60 with marriage and fertility choices. Womens
employment opportunities are also more likely
40
to be constrained by occupational segregation,
20 social norms, or the fear of sexual harassment.
0
Many young women in Africa have to decide
18 20 22 24 26 28 30 32 34 at the same time whether and how to enter the
Age (years) labor market and whether and when to have
Source: Afrobarometer 2008. children. For some women, marrying and hav-
ing children (or marrying early) can be a means
to escape from poverty by relying on men for
policy. Such engagement is particularly relevant economic support. Although recent analy-
for policy to reflect an understanding of the sis suggests that young women in Africa are
types of work to which the young aspire and delaying having children in comparison with
perhaps even to inform those aspirations. The previous generations, fertility rates for young
common perception that the young are simply women remain much higher in Africa than in
waiting for prized jobs in firms may have some other regions (Sneeringer 2009). Across Africa,
truth, but it is unlikely to be relevant to most 25 percent of females ages 1519 have already
young people in Africa, who are predominantly had their first child or are pregnant.5 By the
rural and have little education. Some studies time they reach age 20, the average age at first
find that young people in low-income countries job, they are already caring for young children.
are concerned mainly about jobs that guarantee Once faced with responsibility for child care,
at least basic incomes and job security (Wietzke young women are constrained in their employ-
and McLeod 2012). But others suggest that the ment choices. They may choose not to work,
labor market aspirations of African youth are they may work fewer hours than they otherwise
more heterogeneous. This complexity makes would, or they may choose occupations that
it all the more important to facilitate the civic offer flexible schedules and home-based work.
channels through which the young can express In Liberia, 41 percent of young women, com-
themselves. If the young cannot engage as citi- pared to 31 percent of adult women and just 11
zens, their frustrations about not being heard percent of young males, reported family respon-
could foment economic and social instability. sibilities as a reason for inactivity (Ruiz Abril
Civic organizations can also broaden access 2008). A time-use study in Guinea concluded
to economic opportunities for youth by pro- that women, in particular, cannot increase the
viding better information and facilitating net- number of hours devoted to paid work because
works. This kind of action may be particularly of their care duties (Bardasi and Wodon 2009).
important to previously excluded groups (such Where care options are limited, the need for
as women) and to youth from disadvantaged flexible work arrangements pushes women
backgrounds. from formal into informal work that can be
combined with child care, such as HEs. The
experience from developed countries suggests
Challenges for Females that while part-time work is often a good option
Transitioning to Work for women seeking flexibility, it can often trap
them in low-quality jobs even after that flexibil-
Employment opportunities are more con- ity is no longer needed (World Bank 2011).
strained for young women than for young Gender segregation in jobs is evident
men. Women are less likely to be able to leave throughout Sub-Saharan Africa, as in other
Youth: A Time of Transitions 63

developing regions. Men are concentrated in South Africa. In that village, another explains, For women,
manufacturing, construction, mining, and My parents would never allow me to go to distance becomes
transportation, while women are concentrated other places. They think I will fall pregnant and
a barrier because
in retail trade, education, health, and social bring shame upon the family name (Petesch
work. Gender segregation has potentially large and Rodrguez Caillava 2012). A young woman of lack of bicycles
effects on overall productivity and economic who is well educated might be able to take a and a bad eye
growth by allocating labor in a less than opti- distant jobfor instance, as a teacher. on women who
mal way. Labor force surveys in Africa con- Sexual harassment may also affect womens ride bicycles.
sistently find that women are concentrated in employment options. Nationally represen- Tanzania
sectors with low wages and low productivity. tative statistics on the prevalence of sexual
For example, the 2010 Liberia labor force sur- harassment are hard to find, but smaller sur-
vey found that women are underrepresented in veys have found that the perceived risk of
the growth sectors of mining, manufacturing, harassment from bosses and other authority
construction, and services (LISGIS 2011). Even figures factors highly into a womans choice of
though women have made strides in entering work. In qualitative assessments conducted in
the services sector in the past 20 years, they Liberia and Rwanda in advance of job training
continue to lag in industry (ILO 2012). When programs, young women reported a preference When I was
women strike out on their own as entrepre- for self-employment or female-dominated
looking for
neurs, they still tend to work in less productive, industries because of the threat of sexual
female-dominated sectors. In agriculture, plots harassment.6 Surveys have found similar sen- (secretarial)
controlled by women are much more likely to timents among female entrepreneurs in Tanza- work here in
be used for less profitable staple food crops, nia (Holla, Leonard, and Wilson 2010). Nega- Mombasa, I
while male-controlled plots are used for cash tive experiences with teachers in school (for went to a certain
crops (see World Bank 2011, ch. 5). These pat- example, teachers trading sex for grades) can company, and
terns are reinforced by the fact that training reduce the willingness of prospective trainees
when I showed
for women is often concentrated in less lucra- to participate in training programs. Risks of
tive female-dominated trades, such as arts and harassment are particularly high for women that boss my
crafts, tailoring, and hairdressing (discussed in who work in other peoples homes, where the papers he said it
chapter 3; Fox et al. 2011). isolation of the work and the dependence on was OK, but then
Social norms strongly shape womens the employer for housing and food can make I had to give
employment opportunities. Expectations with workers especially vulnerable to physical and him a date first.
respect to child care duties, mobility and trans- sexual violence, nonpayment of wages, limi-
Kenya
port, and occupational choice all play a role. tations on mobility, and (in extreme cases)
When women do choose to work outside of the forced labor.
home, they often spend more time traveling on Cross-border traders are particularly vulner-
slower modes of transport; as a result, they are able. A recent survey of traders on the border
limited to employment options closer to home between Rwanda and the Democratic Repub-
(Uteng 2011). Lack of agency also restricts their lic of Congo documented high rates of threats,
options. In a focus group in Bombouaka, Togo, harassment, and violence such as beatings,
young women said that a husband would likely stripping, and even rape among the predomi-
veto a job that requires a woman to travel out- nantly female traders (Brenton et al. 2011). A
side the village (Petesch and Rodrguez Caillava survey of Liberian female cross-border traders
2012). in 2007 revealed that, in addition to traditional
Domestic and child care responsibilities and challenges such as high duties, lack of market
concerns about their reputations and safety information, and lack of capital, women also
make it much harder for women to travel: If reported high rates of sexual harassment and
a woman is gone for a few days, people would rape. The survey also found that women were
start making up all sorts of bad stories about more likely than men to join or to form groups
her. The norm is that a woman should stay at to jointly transport goods to reduce costs,
home and raise her children and look after the improve safety, and collectively resolve disputes
home, says a young woman from Ezinyathini, with border authorities (UNWomen 2012).
64 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Facilitating Transitions from Nigeria, Senegal, South Africa, Tanzania,


Uganda, Zambia, and Zimbabwe.
School, to Work, and across
5. Average across the most recent demographic
Sectors of Employment and health surveys in Sub-Saharan Africa for
which this indicator is available. Based on cal-
In all likelihood, most young people who enter culations using DHS StatCompiler.
into employment over the next 10 years in Sub- 6. In Liberia, 20 percent of those who reported
Saharan Africa will continue to work in the a preference for self-employment mentioned
same sectors as the previous generation, with avoiding sexual harassment as a reason for their
some expansion into the HE sector, especially preference (Ruiz Abril 2008).
in market towns and rural areas near popula-
tion centers. The transition from school to work References
will continue to be unstructured and often slow Afrobarometer. 2008. Abrobarmeter Surveys Round
for these youths. Agriculture is the gateway to 4. http://www.afrobarometer.org/.
work and, for many, will become the sector of Amin, Sajeda, Ian Diamond, Ruchira T. Naved, and
lifetime employment. If productivity and earn- Margaret Newby. 1998. Transition to Adult-
hood of Female Garment-Factory Workers in
ings in agriculture do not improve, the wider
Bangladesh. Studies in Family Planning 29 (2):
economy in rural areas, where the majority of 185200.
the population still lives, will be depressed, and
Baird, Sarah, Ephraim Chirwa, Craig McIntosh,
the options for youth will shrink. and Berk zler. 2010. The Short-Term Impacts
Once youth start workingwhether in of a Schooling Conditional Cash Transfer Pro-
agriculture, HEs, or wage jobsthey tend to gram on the Sexual Behavior of Young Women.
stay in the same sector, with mobility across Health Economicss 19 (1): 5568. doi: 10.1002/
sectors being slightly higher in urban than in hec.1569.
rural areas. Migration offers an opportunity to . 2011. Cash or Condition? Evidence from
change these patterns and substantially increase a Cash Transfer Experiment. Quarterly Journal
of Economicss 126 (4): 170953.
earnings. For young women, the transition
from school to high-productivity work entails Bardasi, Elena, and Quentin Wodon. 2009. Work-
ing Long Hours and Having No Choice: Time
additional challenges. The remainder of this Poverty in Guinea. Policy Research Working
report identifies ways to support young people Paper 4961, World Bank, Washington, DC.
in making these transitions, by equipping them Beegle, Kathleen, Rajeev H. Dehejia, and Roberta
with the skills that will be needed wherever they Gatti. 2009. Why Should We Care about Child
work (chapter 3) and by ensuring that the busi- Labor? The Education, Labor Market, and Health
ness environment and their human capital are Consequences of Child Labor. Journal of Human
conducive to high productivity in agriculture Resourcess 44 (4): 87189.
(chapter 4), HEs (chapter 5), and the modern Beegle, Kathleen, Rajeev H. Dehejia, Roberta Gatti,
wage sector (chapter 6). and Sofya Krutikova. 2008. The Consequences
of Child Labor: Evidence from Longitudinal
Data in Rural Tanzania. Policy Research Work-
Notes ing Paper 4677, World Bank, Washington, DC.
1. Based on analysis of Uganda national panel sur- doi: 10.1596/1813-9450-4677.
vey data. Blattman, Chistopher, and Jeannie Annan. 2010.
2. The study is based on the Tanzania household The Consequences of Child Soldiering. Review
urban panel survey, which collects retrospec- of Economics and Statisticss 92 (4): 88298.
tive information on previous jobs (Bridges et al. Bloom, David E., David Canning, Gnther Fink,
2013). and Jocelyn E. Finlay. 2009. Fertility, Female
3. The percentage of women who have given birth Labor Force Participation, and the Demographic
can include unmarried women. Dividend. Journal of Economic Growth 14 (2):
4. Based on analysis of Afrobarometer round 4 79101.
surveys (Afrobarometer 2008) in 20 African Bossuroy, Thomas, and Denis Cogneau.2013.
countries: Benin, Botswana, Burkina Faso, Cape Social Mobility in Five African Countries.
Verde, Ghana, Kenya, Lesotho, Liberia, Mada- Review of Income and Wealth 59: s84110. doi:
gascar, Malawi, Mali, Mozambique, Namibia, 10.1111/roiw.12037
Youth: A Time of Transitions 65

Brenton, Paul, Celestin Bashinge Bucekuderhwa, Lundberg, Mattias, and Alice Wuermli, eds. 2012.
Caroline Hossein, Shiho Nagaki, and Jean Bap- Children and Youth in Crisis: Protecting and Pro-
tiste Ntagoma. 2011. Risky Business: Poor moting Human Development in Times of Eco-
Women Cross-Border Traders in the Great Lakes nomic Shocks. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Region of Africa. Africa Trade Policy Notes 11, McKenzie, David. 2007. A Profile of the Worlds
World Bank, Washington, DC. Young Developing Country Migrants. IZA
Bridges, Sarah, Louise Fox, Alessio Gaggero, and Discussion Paper 2948, Institute for the Study of
Trudy Owens. 2013. Labour Market Entry and Labor, Bonn.
Earnings: Evidence from Tanzanian Retrospec- McLeod, D., R. Ramirez, M. Davalos, and W. Gru-
tive Data. Background paper presented at the ben. 2005. Apparel Jobs: Ladder Up or Poverty
CSAE Conference on Economic Development in Trap? Paper presented at the 2005 meeting of
Africa, Oxford University, March. the Latin America and Caribbean Economics
de Walque, Damien, ed. 2014. Risking Your Health: Association, Paris, October 2729.
Causes, Consequences, and Interventions to Pre- Pasquier-Doumer, Laure. 2013. Intergenerational
vent Risky Behaviors. Washington, DC: World Transmission of Self-Employed Status in the
Bank. Informal Sector: A Constrained Choice or Bet-
De Weerdt, Joachim, and Andreas Kutka. 2013. ter Income Prospects? Evidence from Seven West
Urbanisation and Youth Employment in Tan- African Countries. Journal of African Economies
zania: Preliminary Analysis. Background paper, 22 (1): 73111. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/
World Bank, Washington, DC. jae/ejs017.
Dorosh, Paul, and James Thurlow. 2013. Agri- Petesch, P., and Rodrguez Caillava, I. 2012. Voices
culture and Small Towns in Africa. Agricul- of Young Villagers in Sub-Saharan Africa. Back-
tural Economicss 44 (4-5): 44959. doi: 10.1111/ ground paper, World Bank, Washington, DC.
agec.12027. Ruiz Abril, Maria Elena. 2008. Liberia: Girls Vul-
Duflo, Esther, Pascaline Dupas, Michael Kremer, nerability Assessment. Government of Liberia,
and Samuel Sinei. 2006. Education and HIV/ Nike Foundation, and World Bank, Washington,
AIDS Prevention: Evidence from a Randomized DC. https://docs.google.com/document/d/1FvEg
Evaluation in Western Kenya. Policy Research QNMsZHVfMLYxfp62DUly8nY1850lh2v
Working Paper 4024, World Bank, Washington, GmiYHk_0/edit?hl=en_US&pli=1.
DC. Sander, Cerstin, and Samuel Munzele Maimbo.
Eriksen, Michael, Judith Mackay, and Hana Ross. 2003. Migrant Labor Remittances in Africa:
2012. The Tobacco Atlas. 4th ed. Atlanta: Ameri- Reducing Obstacles to Developmental Contribu-
can Cancer Society. tions. Africa Region Working Paper 64, World
Falco, Paolo, William F. Maloney, Bob Rijkers, Bank, Washington, DC.
and Mauricio Sarrias. 2012. Heterogeneity in Simkins, Charles. 2013. Urbanization in Africa
Subjective Well-Being: An Application to Occu- and Its Relation to the Demographic Dividend.
pational Allocation in Africa. Policy Research Background paper for the Africa Regional Study
Working Paper 6244, World Bank, Washington, on the Demographic Dividend, World Bank,
DC. doi: 10.1596/1813-9450-6244. Washington, DC.
Fox, Louise, Katie Kibbuka, Jorge Huerta Munoz, Sneeringer, Stacy E. 2009. Fertility Transition in
and Thomas Pave Sohnesen. 2011. Small Is Big: Sub-Saharan Africa: A Comparative Analysis
Development of the Household Enterprise Sec- of Trends in 30 Countries. DHS Comparative
tor in Ghana; a Quantitative Look at Household Reports 23, ICR Macro, Calverton, MD.
Enterprises. World Bank, Washington, DC. United Nations. 2007. Age-Specific Fertility Rate.
Holla, Alaka, Sibomana Leonard, and Wema Wil- United Nations, Statistics Division, New York.
son. 2010. The Secret Lives of Economically http://data.un.org/Data.aspx?d=GenderStat&
Empowered Women: Qualitative Evidence on f=inID%3A13.
Sensitive Issues from Female Entrepreneurs in UNWomen. 2012. Breaking the Cycle of Violence
Dar es Salaam. World Bank, Washington, DC. and HIV in Liberia. http://www.unwomen.org/
ILO (International Labour Organization). 2012. en/news/stories/2012/7/breaking-the-cycle-of-
Global Employment Trends for Women, 2012. violence-and-hiv-in-liberia/.
Geneva: ILO. Uteng, Tanu Priya. 2011. Gender and Mobility
LISGIS (Liberia Institute of Statistics and Geo- in the Developing World. Background paper
Information Services). 2011. Report on the for the World Development Report 2012: Gender
Liberia Labor Force Survey 2010. LISGIS, Equality and Development,t World Bank, Wash-
Monrovia. ington, DC.
66 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Warren, Charles W., Samira Asma, Juliette Lee, . 2006. World Development Report 2007:
Veronica Lea, and Judith Mackay. 2009. Global Development and the Next Generation. New York:
Tobacco Surveillance System: The GTSS Atlas. Oxford University Press.
Atlanta, GA: CDC Foundation. . 2008. World Development Report 2009:
Wietzke, Frank-Borge, and Catriona McLeod. 2012. Reshaping Economic Geography. New York:
Jobs, Well-Being, and Social Cohesion: Evidence Oxford University Press.
from Value and Perception Surveys. Background . 2011. World Development Report 2012:
paper for World Development Report 2013, World Gender Equality and Development. New York:
Bank, Washington, DC. https://openknowledge. Oxford University Press.
worldbank.org/bitstream/handle/10986/12138/
WDR2013_bp_Jobs_Wellbeing_SocialCohesion. . 2012a. Kenya at Work: Energizing the
pdf?sequence=1. Economy and Creating Jobs. Kenya Economic
Updatee 7 (December).
World Bank. 2003. World Development Report 2004:
Making Services Work for Poor People. New York: . 2012b. World Development Report 2013:
Oxford University Press. Jobs. New York: Oxford University Press.
Chapter

Skills for Productive Employment

A critical part of the policy agenda for youth the skills demanded by employers, and to build
employment in Africa is to strengthen human the evidence needed to guide specific programs
capital. Although training alone will not deliver to improve skills for youth employment. Govern-
more and better jobs for youthmuch also ments must also bear in mind that a dynamic
depends on policies to strengthen the business private market exists for training and avoid
environment, as discussed elsewhere in this introducing undue distortions in this market.
reportthe education that young people receive Priority areas for government intervention are to
and the skills they acquire can expand the spec- provide information and facilitate access to exist-
trum of employment opportunities they can ing training for disadvantaged youths (such as
access and the earnings they are likely to com- young women or the poorest) as well as to ensure
mand. Skills strongly influence where people the availability of better-quality training options.
work and how much they earn. A key problem is In the presence of active training markets, public
that across Africa rapid increases in school par- interventions need to be selective, performance
ticipation and educational attainment have come driven, and evidence based.
at the cost of quality, contributing to a serious
shortfall in the skills for productive employment. Low educational achievement and limited
Those skills include basic and higher-order cogni- skills contribute to difficult transitions into
tive skills, behavioral and socioemotional skills, work and limited employment mobility among
technical or vocational skills, and business skills. African youth. Education and skills open path-
To facilitate entry, improve productivity, and ways into productive employment. Schooling
raise earnings across the range of employment is a good predictor of an individuals eventual
in agriculture, household enterprises (HEs), and occupation, but the quality of education also
the modern wage sector, the most pressing pri- matters for productivity. In Africa more chil-
ority is to increase the quality of schooling and dren attend school than ever before. Yet the
ensure that it delivers actual learning and skills. generally poor quality of the education they
Other important priorities are to identify and receive means that schooling has relatively small
directly build the socioemotional and behavioral effects on productivity, earnings, and poverty
skills that contribute to productivity, including reduction. Rapid improvements in the quality

67
68 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Figure 3.1 of learning provided in school are critical


Africa, 19902011 to increase the productivity and earnings of
Africas youth.
Guinea-Bissau
Mali
Guinea
Schooling, Educational
Chad
Niger
Attainment, and Work
Burkina Faso
Measured against the objective set by the Mil-
Benin
lennium Development Goal for education
Ethiopia
ensure that all boys and girls complete a full
Mozambique
course of primary schoolingSub-Saharan
Malawi Africa has made remarkable progress. Across
Mauritania the region, the share of children completing
Central African Republic primary school rose from 51 percent in 1990
Angola to 70 percent in 2011. Some countries made
Madagascar exceptional progress (figure 3.1). Burkina Faso,
Togo Chad, Ethiopia, Madagascar, Malawi, Mau-
Cte dIvoire ritania, Mozambique, and Niger more than
Gambia, The doubledd their primary completion rates; Benin,
Burundi Guinea, Guinea-Bissau, and Mali more than
Senegal tripled theirs. These achievements rival those
Uganda of countries with the best historical increases,
Rwanda such as the Republic of Korea, and far exceed
Congo, Dem. Rep. those typical of most developing countries
Tanzania since 1960 (Clemens 2004). An average young
Equatorial Guinea
Ghanaian or Zambian today has more school-
Cameroon
ing than an average French or Italian person in
1960 (Pritchett 2013).
Cape Verde
Nevertheless, these improvements started
Lesotho
from a very low base, and Sub-Saharan Africa
Congo, Rep.
lags behind other world regions in primary
Ghana
school completion. The young people enter-
Swaziland
ing Africas labor force right now have more
Namibia
schooling than any previous generation, but
South Africa they still have little overall schooling. Nearly
Zambia 60 percent of 15- to 24-year-olds have com-
Kenya pleted only primary school (figure 3.2). Among
Botswana the group that is most likely to have exited
school for goodthose who are 2534 years
Sub-Saharan Africa old30 percent have no education, 21 percent
South Asia have completed only some primary schooling,
Middle East and North Africa and 14 percent have completed only primary
Latin America and the Caribbean education. About 35 percent have continued
East Asia and Pacific beyond primary school, and 19 percent have
gone beyond lower-secondary school. Edu-
0 20 40 60 80 100
cational attainment is higher in urban areas,
Percent
although more than 40 percent of 25- to
1990 2011 34-year-olds in those areas have not completed
Source: World Bank various years. lower-secondary school.
Skills for Productive Employment 69

Figure 3.2 Africas young people have more education than ever before, but average education attainment is
still low

a. Ages 1524 b. Ages 2534


100 100

80 80

60 60
Percent

Percent
40 40

20 20

0 0
All Female Male Rural Urban All Female Male Rural Urban

No education Primary incomplete Primary complete


Secondary incomplete Secondary complete Higher education

Source: Based on demographic and health surveys in 30 countries (see appendix).

Figure 3.3 Educational attainment in Sub-Saharan Africa is projected to rise substantially

a. Male b. Female
100 100

80 80

60 60
Percent

Percent

40 40

20 20

0 0
2010 2015 2020 2025 2030 2010 2015 2020 2025 2030

No education Primary education Secondary education Tertiary education

Source: Based on International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis data.

Younger generations are likely to do better. ing has come at the cost of learning outcomes,
Thanks to recent progress in getting children as discussed later.
into school, incoming cohorts should have sub-
stantially higher levels of education than past Schooling and Sector of Employment
cohortsin fact, they will be the most highly The links between educational attainment and
educated cohort ever in Africa. By 2020, more sector of employment are very clear. Most peo-
than half of men ages 1524 are projected to ple who never finish primary school work in
have attained secondary education; women agriculture. Those with a primary or lower-sec-
will cross that threshold in 2025 (figure 3.3). Of ondary education work in nonfarm household
course these projections depend on policies to enterprises (HEs), whereas those with higher
come, and they are only a rough guide to actual levels of education are more likely to enter the
outcomes. Moreover, greater access to school- modern wage sector.
70 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Figure 3.4 Schooling maps to sector of employment

a. Ages 1524 b. Ages 2534


100 100

80 80

60 60
Percent

Percent
40 40

20 20

0 0
Agriculture Nonfarm Wage Agriculture Nonfarm Wage
household household
enterprise enterprise
No education Primary incomplete Primary complete
Lower secondary complete Upper secondary complete Post-secondary
Source: Based on standardized and harmonized household and labor force surveys (see appendix).

Since schooling strongly influences the sector of youths and young adults who work in HEs is
in which people work, the educational profile of only somewhat better, but about half have not
wage earners is very different from that of work- completed even primary schooling.
ers in the agricultural and HE sectors in Africa. Completion of primary or additional edu-
The great majority of youths and young adults cation becomes the norm only among young
working in agriculture never completed pri- adults in the wage sector. Almost 65 percent of
mary school. Close to 80 percent of those ages 15- to 24-year-olds who work for wages have
2534 who work in agriculture have primary completed primary school. Because youths who
schooling or less; 40 percent have no education transition out of school later are more likely to
at all (figure 3.4). The educational attainment enter the wage sector, the share of young adults
(2534) who finished primary school and are
employed in that sector increases to over 80
Figure 3.5 Wage workers with more schooling are more likely to work under
percent. Wage employees are significantly more
contract
likely to have a secondary or a tertiary education:
100 among 25- to 34-year-olds, wage employees are
more than twice as likely as the self-employed to
80 have completed secondary schooling.
Wage workers with more schooling are also
60 more likely to work under contractan indi-
Percent

cator that they perform more formal modern


40 wage work (figure 3.5). Close to 70 percent of
wage employees without primary schooling
20 lack a contract, compared to less than 40 per-
cent of those with upper-secondary schooling.
0 The relationships between schooling and
No education Primary Primary Secondary Secondary Post- work in each sector are broadly similar across
incomplete complete incomplete complete secondary
various subgroups of the population, with two
No contract Contract main distinctions. First, women are substan-
Source: Based on standardized and harmonized household and labor force surveys (see appendix). tially more likely to work in the nonfarm HE
Skills for Productive Employment 71

Figure 3.6 Relationships between schooling and work vary depending on gender and urbanization

a. By gender b. By urban/rural
70 70

60 60

50 50

Percent
40
Percent

40

30 30

20 20

10 10

0 0
No Primary Primary Low Upper Post- No Primary Primary Low Upper Post-
education incomplete complete secondary secondary secondary education incomplete complete secondary secondary secondary
complete complete complete complete
Female wage Rural wage
Male wage Urban wage
Male nonfarm household enterprise Rural nonfarm household enterprise
Female nonfarm household enterprise Urban nonfarm household enterprise

Source: Based on standardized and harmonized household and labor force surveys (see appendix).

sector as their educational attainment rises, modern wage sector cannot absorb the incom-
suggesting that education facilitates womens ing cohorts of youth. The majority of young
transition out of agriculture (figure 3.6). Sec- people will still create their own livelihoods.
ond, participation in the wage sector begins at As a result, a growing share of workers in agri-
lower levels of educational attainment in urban culture and nonfarm HEs will probably have
areas, reflecting the larger pool of educated higher levels of schooling.
youth in urban areas as well as the greater avail- Shifts in employment patterns will not occur
ability of jobs for relatively unskilled workers in automatically. Additional years of schooling Education
the modern wage sector. that impart actual competencies will be needed
for young people to develop the skills that can
guarantees a
Will Workers Increasing Educational promote such a shift. Research has suggested better job and a
Attainment Change Employment that higher levels of educational achievement stable life.
Patterns? and cognitive skills are associated with overall Togo
There is potential for employment patterns to economic growth (Hanushek and Woessmann
shift, if current patterns in educational attain- 2012) as well as with the employment of a
ment and sector of work persist in Africa and larger share of youth in modern wage jobs out-
if educational attainment improves as pro- side of agriculture (Lee and Newhouse 2012).
jected. Africa is positioned for a large shift of If increases in educational attainment are not
workers out of the farm sector and into HEs, associated with a greater accumulation of skills,
along with an increase in modern wage sector schooling will have a limited effect on overall
employment. growth and composition of employment. Then
Analysis of past trends in four countries there is the demand side of the labor market
(Al-Samarrai and Bennell 2007) suggests that to consider. The economy will need to generate
increasing shares of secondary school gradu- new employment opportunities to make use of
ates are working in self-employment (Malawi, the learning and skills acquired by young peo-
Tanzania, and Zimbabwe, for example), except ple. As discussed throughout this report, poli-
where economic growth has led to the creation cies to address human capital are not sufficient
of substantially more self-employment and in themselves to address the youth employment
wage jobs (Uganda). The employment projec- challenge; improvements in the business envi-
tions in chapter 1 suggest that even a growing ronment are needed as well.
72 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

I have always Schooling Increases Productivity and farmers are more likely to adopt new agricul-
been limited Earnings tural technologies first, either because they ini-
Schooling is associated not only with the sec- tially have more information about the tech-
by not being
tor in which youthand older workerswork, nology or because they are able to learn more
schooled . . . . than less educated farmers exposed to the same
but also with greater productivity and earnings.
I dont want Therefore, in addition to facilitating entry into information. Schooling enhances the capacity
my children to nonfarm HEs and modern wage jobs, educa- to learn throughout life. The introduction of
have the same tion is also essential to tackle the policy chal- new technologies is a learning opportunity
experience lenge of increasing workers productivity across that reveals the complementarity between
the spectrum of employment. schooling and the adoption of profitable new
I had.
The education level of household members technology.
Madagascar Outside of agriculture, in the HE and wage
is a strong determinant of standards of living.
Households where adults have attained higher sectors, the link between education and earn-
levels of schooling have substantially higher ings is strong. Figure 3.7 shows that higher levels
consumption levels per capita than households of education among HE owners are associated
where members have less schooling. This dif- with higher earnings in Ghana, Rwanda, Tan-
ference partly reflects the selection of workers zania, and Uganda. Figure 3.8 shows the aver-
into sectors described previously. age wage increment associated with increasing
Considerable research in the agricultural levels of education by comparing wage workers
sector indicates that farmers with primary at each education level to uneducated workers
schooling tend to have higher profits than in a sample of nine African countries. In both
farmers without schooling, even for those figures, earnings differentials are adjusted for
holding similar assets. Educated farmers gen- the age, gender, and rural or urban location of
erally are the first to adopt new seeds, tillage the worker. The figures should not be under-
practices, fertilizer, and animal breeds (see, for stood as indicating returns to education. They
example, Welch 1970; Huffman 1977; Besley merely capture an association between educa-
and Case 1993; Foster and Rosenzweig 1995; tion and earnings and may not fully control
Abdulai and Huffman 2005). The benefit of for factors that confound the analysis (box 3.1
education is particularly pronounced in envi- discusses the challenges in estimating returns
ronments undergoing rapid technical change to education).
(Foster and Rosenzweig 2010). More educated
Earnings Tend to Increase Little with
Only a Few Years of Primary Schooling
Figure 3.7 Education is associated with higher earnings in household enterprises A review of rates of return to education across
several developing countries finds that the
180 mean rate of return to an additional year of
160 education is almost 9 percent (Banerjee and
140 Duflo 2005). In other words, six years of pri-
Percentage increment

120 mary schooling yield an increment of almost


100 70 percent. Although figures 3.7 and 3.8 do
80 not necessarily represent estimates of rates of
60
return to education (box 3.1), they illustrate an
40
association between earnings and education
that is substantially lower than the link docu-
20
mented in other developing countries. A few
0
years of basic education appear to yield much
Ghana Rwanda Tanzania Uganda
lower productivity gains in Africa than in other
Primary incomplete Primary Lower secondary Upper secondary Post-secondary
regions.
Source: Based on standardized and harmonized household and labor force surveys (see appendix). For instance, owners of HEs who have not
Note: Figure displays net average earnings (sales minus expenditures per month) for a sample of self-
employed owners of HEs by level of education (relative to HE owners without education). completed primary education do not earn sig-
Skills for Productive Employment 73

nificantly more than owners of HEs without Figure 3.8 Education is associated with higher wages
any educationsuggesting that minimal pro-
250
ductivity gains are associated with a few years
of primary school (figure 3.7).1 200
In contrast, HE owners who have com-

Percentage increment
150
pleted primary education earn significantly
more than HE owners who have no education. 100
The earnings increment associated with pri-
mary school completion ranges from 25 per- 50
cent in Ghana to 46 percent in Rwanda. Low
0
earnings differentials at low levels of education
Cameroon Cte Ghana Kenya Malawi Mozam- Rwanda Sierra Uganda
are a serious issue, because most young people dIvoire bique Leone
in the HE sector have not completed primary
Primary incomplete Primary complete
school.2 Lower secondary complete, upper secondary incomplete Upper secondary complete
In the wage sector, workers with incom- Post-secondary
plete primary schooling earn a modest pre- Source: Based on standardized and harmonized household and labor force surveys (see appendix).
mium (1025 percent on average) compared Note: Based on a regression of hourly wages (in logs) by education level, adjusted for age, gender, and
whether the workplace is urban or rural. Figure displays hourly wages among wage workers by level
to workers with no education, and often the of education (relative to workers without education). The dependent variable is ln (wage/hours) using
difference is not even statistically significant information from the last seven days. Wages were adjusted for local consumer price index (2005 =
100) and purchasing power parity. This dependent variable was run against the dummy level of educa-
(Ghana, Mozambique, and Sierra Leone).3 In tion variables listed above, and the no education dummy was excluded. As the mean wage among
contrast, wage workers who have completed those with no education is normalized to zero, the wages shown are not absolute but are depicted in
comparison to workers with no education. Workers are ages 2064.
primary education earn consistently more
than uneducated wage workers. The wages of
primary school completers typically are more
than 20 percent higher than the wages of work- analysis of seven cities in West Africa found
ers without education; the gap reaches as much evidence of strong associations between edu-
as 52 percent in Cameroon. Wage workers with cation and earnings in HEs as well as evidence
upper-secondary education typically earn of an increase in the earnings premium across
wages that are 100150 percent higher than education levels (figure 3.9; Kuepie, Nordman,
those without education. and Roubaud 2009). In particular, the study
found that marginal returns for an additional
Earnings Increase Faster with Education year of postprimary education are higher than
beyond Primary School marginal returns associated with an additional
In contrast with the limited earnings gains asso- year of primary education.
ciated with a few years of basic education, earn- As seen in figure 3.8, individuals in the wage
ings and wages increase faster when education sector who have completed upper-secondary
extends beyond primary school. For owners of school earn 30155 percent more than individ-
HEs, the increment in earnings associated with uals without any schooling. Postsecondary edu-
completing lower-secondary education ranges cation is associated with a premium of 70200
from around 35 percent in Ghana and Tanzania percent over no schooling. As in the HE sec-
to around 60 percent in Rwanda and Uganda. tor, the increment in earnings is substantially
Upper-secondary and postsecondary education higher at higher levels of education (Teal 2010;
are associated with even higher increments to Sderbom, Teal, and Harding 2006; Bigsten et
earnings, although few individuals in the HE al. 2000). Each additional year of schooling in
sector acquire that much education.4 Kenya, for example, is estimated to increase
These descriptive patterns are consistent earnings by 3 percent among those with only
with more robust econometric evidence tack- 17 years of schooling, 9 percent among those
ling the selection issues involved in estimating with 811 years, and 24 percent among those
returns to education (Fasih et al. 2012), par- with 12 years or more (Sderbom, Teal, and
ticularly in Africa and in the HE sector.5 An Harding 2006). A review of studies concludes
74 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box 3.1

Estimating the returns to education


When the more educated differ inherently from the less supply-side factors have influenced levels of schooling inde-
educated, the relationship observed between earnings pendently of confounding factors such as ability. A surpris-
and education levels ceases to be a reliable guide to the ing finding is that the estimates of the returns to school-
causal impact of schooling on earnings and productivity. ing from such natural experiments are not much lower than
For instance, when the more educated are of higher-than- unadjusted estimates. Although quasi-experimental meth-
average innate ability, the earnings gap observed between ods relying on natural experiments or other econometric
individuals with high and low levels of education partly techniques cannot eliminate all bias resulting from omitted
reflects the higher-than-average ability of the more edu- variables, the typically high estimates emerging from these
cated group. An individual of average ability and an indi- careful studies make it much harder to reject the idea that
vidual of above-average ability should not expect the same schooling leads to substantial earnings gains.
outcome from the same education. If those who are more Developed countries have produced a vast body of evi-
educated are also more likely to come from advantaged dence on the adjusted returns to schooling. The studies use a
backgrounds, then the measured returns to education range of econometric techniques to correct for the problems
would be overstated, since they include returns to family just mentioned. Estimates from studies in developing coun-
background. In the wage sector, they can also reflect con- tries tend to be higher than those from developed coun-
nections in labor markets, particularly because job referrals tries, but developing countries rarely provide opportunities
from family members appear to be particularly important in to use panel data or natural experiments to identify causal
developing countries. effects. One of the best-cited examples concerns the impact
Concerns about bias arising from omitted factors or of a program to build schools in Indonesia (Duflo 2001). The
selection effects have motivated an entire field of research study benefited from the fact that the program, launched
focused on correctly measuring the causal impact of educa- in 1974, differentially increased school opportunities among
tion on earnings. One approach is to adjust the estimates children from different cohorts and different regions. Look-
for omitted factors by including their proxy measures in a ing at wages in 1995, the study found returns to education
regression analysis (for example, by using measures of cogni- in the range of 6.810.6 percent, approximately similar to
tive skills to proxy for innate ability). However, this approach returns found in previous studies. A recent review of rates of
may not correct for all omitted factors. For that reason, some return to education across multiple countries found that the
of the best-regarded studies have chosen to take advantage mean rate of return to an additional year of education was
of natural experimentsinstances in which policies or almost 9 percent (Banerjee and Duflo 2005).

that while the wage gains associated with an often accompanied by a decline in the earnings
additional year of secondary or higher edu- increment associated with being a primary or
cation are in the 1015 percent range, gains secondary school graduate. In India in 1994,
associated with an additional year of primary for example, the wage increment for a primary
schooling are only 310 percent (Bigsten et school graduate versus someone with no edu-
al. 2000; Schultz 2004). Here again, patterns cation was 50 percent, but by 2010 it had fallen
are consistent with more robust economet- to 30 percent. The wage increment for a univer-
ric results of increasing returns to education, sity graduate versus an upper-secondary gradu-
including evidence from urban West Africa ate was 10 percent in 1994, but had risen to 36
(figure 3.9). percent by 2010. Similar changes occurred in
other South Asian countries (Nayar et al. 2012).
Returns to Education Change with In Latin America between the mid-1990s and
Educational Attainment the late 2000s, the wage increment associated
Returns to education change over time as the with completing secondary relative to primary
relative shares of the population with no, pri- schooling declined systematicallyfor exam-
mary, and secondary schooling change. In ple, from around 40 percent to about 30 per-
other regions of the world, these shifts were cent in Brazil and Peruwhile the increment
Skills for Productive Employment 75

Figure 3.9 The convex relationship between earnings and education: Schooling and earnings in urban West Africa

a. Household enterprises b. Private wage employment


1,200 2,500

1,000
2,000
Hourly earnings (CFA)

Hourly earnings (CFA)


800
1,500
600
1,000
400

500
200

0 0
0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16 18
Years of schooling Years of schooling

Lom Ouagadougou Cotonou Niamey Bamako Abidjan Dakar


Source: Kuepie, Nordman, and Roubaud 2009, based on 1-2-3 surveys on employment and earnings in urban West Africa. Reproduced
with permission of the authors.
Note: In the study, household enterprises are defined as production units with no fiscal or statistical identity or without any formal
accountancy and labeled as informal sector by the authors. We use the term household enterprises for consistency with terminology
used in this report.

associated with being a tertiary graduate rose emotional and behavioral skills. These short-
(Aedo and Walker 2012). falls can prevent youth from reaching their
All else being equal, the rising share of full potential. Cognitive, socioemotional, and
Africas population with completed primary behavioral skills create the foundation for
schooling should put downward pressure on acquiring higher-order cognitive and technical
the earnings increment to schooling. However, skills, whether through more formal education,
all else is not necessarily equal. The returns to training, or on-the-job learning. Improvements
schooling depend on the quality of schooling in the quality of basic education are urgently
and the skills it supplies, as discussed in the required to ensure that incoming youth acquire
remainder of this chapter. Returns also depend the necessary foundational skills.
on the demand side of the labor market. The Schooling aims to develop an assortment of
productivity of the work done by individuals skills, including literacy and numeracy as well
with a given level of schooling, in the particu- as higher-order cognitive, socioemotional, and
lar economic environment where they put their behavioral skills. The skills shaped by the edu-
skills to work, will determine how effectively cation system explain part of the gains in earn-
their schooling turns into earnings. Chapters 4, ings that are associated with more schooling.
5, and 6 elaborate on how to improve employ- The fact that a few years of education confer
ment opportunities and the business environ- only a small increase in earnings is related to
ment on the demand side of the labor market. the low quality of basic education in Africa
as well as other economywide factors beyond
the education system. Moreover, the pattern
Building a Foundation: Cognitive, of increasing marginal returns to education
Socioemotional, and Behavioral in Africa suggests that productivity increases
Skills faster at higher levels of educationconsistent
with the notion that skills can complement one
Many types of skills are needed for produc- another and that skills produced at one stage
tive employment. Weak education systems are raise the productivity of investment at subse-
contributing to a critical shortfall in two key quent stages (Cunha and Heckman 2007).
sets of skillscognitive skills as well as socio- The fundamental issue is that many African
76 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

children never acquire the skills that are the requirement for professors and scientists, but
foundation for a productive life because of the less so for entry-level or semi-skilled workers.
low quality of basic education systems. Technical and vocational skills matter in tech-
This section discusses how skills are built nical occupations. Other characteristics of per-
through the education system, in early child- sonality, such as openness to experience and
hood, and through other avenues for learning. agreeableness, have been shown to matter for
Productivity-enhancing skills can be catego- particular career paths (Cobb-Clark and Tan
rized as follows:6 2010). Still, the first step is a basic education
of sufficient quality that lays the foundations
Basic cognitive skills, such as numeracy and
for young people to acquire a range of relevant
literacy
skills later in lifethrough additional formal
Higher-order cognitive skills, such as prob- education, training, on-the-job learning, or
lem solving and critical analysis other means.
Behavioral and socioemotional skills (also
called soft skills or life skills), includ- Education Systems in Africa Are Failing
ing a broad range of skills, such as social to Produce Critical Foundational Skills
skills, self-regulation, self-confidence, and Rapid increases in school participation and
conscientiousness educational attainment have undoubtedly
Technical or vocational skills, often specific come at the cost of quality. Empirical evidence
to each occupation confirms that poor learning outcomesa few
years of low-quality education, producing indi-
Business skills, such as entrepreneurship
skills, managerial skills, and financial viduals who are barely literate and numerate
literacy. are hampering the potential for education to
increase productivity, even in African econo-
The track record of the education system in mies that have been performing well. Learning
producing these skills, including basic cognitive assessments in Africa show that most primary
skills, has been abysmal in Africa. If the quality students still lack basic proficiency in reading
of education does not improve rapidly, produc- at the end of second or third grade. In several
tivity and earnings are likely to remain lowa countries, a very large proportion of primary
problem that will only become more acute as school students are illiterate. For example,
new generations of Africans enter and graduate more than 80 percent of Malian third-graders
from school in larger numbers. Without sub- and more than 70 percent of Ugandan third-
stantial improvements in quality, the rewards graders cannot read a single word (figure 3.10).
that graduates of primary and lower-secondary Household surveys that measure numeracy
school can expect to reap in the labor market will and literacy are consistent with these trou-
surely fall as more graduates enter the workforce. bling results. In Tanzania, for example, a 2011
To some extent, such outcomes can be mitigated assessment of childrens abilities revealed that
by urgent improvements in the education sys- 70 percent of students complete standard two
tem that enable young people to develop more without meeting the numeracy standards of
productivity-enhancing skills. Of course, educa- that level (Uwezo Tanzania 2011). Assessments
tion is only a starting point; graduates will also in Kenya and Uganda revealed similar shortfalls
need an economic and business environment in students cognitive skills.
where they can use their skills productively. Even children who complete primary school
The relevance of the range of productivity- have low levels of basic skills. In the regionally
enhancing skills can vary by sector of employ- benchmarked Southern Africa Consortium for
ment as well as across occupations. For Measuring Educational Quality (SACMEQ) in
instance, the mix of skills required for pro- 2007, 43 percent of sixth-graders in Tanzania
ductivity in wage employment will depend on and 74 percent in Mozambique did not get
the complexity of the job. Higher-order cog- beyond the basic numeracy level, while 44
nitive skills matter more when jobs are more percent in Mozambique could not read for
complex. Analytical thinking is an absolute meaning (figure 3.11). The results from an
Skills for Productive Employment 77

Figure 3.10

a. Students who cannot read a single b. Students who cannot read at least
word of a simple paragraph 45 words per minute
90 90
80 80
70 70
60 60
Percent

Percent
50 50
40 40
30 30
20 20
10 10
0 0
Ghana Kenya Liberia Mali Senegal Senegal The Uganda Ghana Liberia Senegal The Gambia
Gambia

Grade 3 End grade 2 End grade 3 Grade 5 Grade 6


Sources: Cloutier, Reinstadtler, and Beltran 2011; Gove and Cvelich 2010.
Note: These findings refer only to students who have stayed in school. Those who have dropped outwho would have scored even lower
on these assessmentsare excluded from these calculations. The many primary school dropouts who lack the most basic skills, including
simple numeracy or literacy, are largely young people who will find work in agriculture and HEs.

Figure 3.11 By the end of primary school, many students have not mastered even basic competencies:
2007 SACMEQ results for math and reading proficiency

a. Math b. Reading
All All
Zambia Malawi
Malawi Zambia
Namibia Lesotho
Lesotho South Africa
Uganda Uganda
Mozambique Mozambique
Zanzibar Namibia
South Africa Zimbabwe
Zimbabwe Botswana
Botswana Seychelles
Swaziland Zanzibar
Tanzania Mauritius
Seychelles Kenya
Kenya Tanzania
Mauritius Swaziland

100 80 60 40 20 0 20 40 60 80 100 100 80 60 40 20 0 20 40 60 80 100


Percent Percent

Pre-, emergent, and basic numeracy (levels 1, 2, and 3) Pre-, emergent, and basic reading (levels 1, 2, and 3)
Beginning numeracy (level 4) Reading for meaning (level 4)
Competent and above (levels 5, 6, 7, and 8) Interpretive and above (levels 5, 6, 7, and 8)
Source: Hungi et al. 2010.

earlier round of SACMEQ (in 2003) were gen- est round (in 2011) of globally benchmarked
erally similar. learning assessments, the Trends in Math and
Beyond primary school, learning outcomes Science Study (TIMSS). Among the eighth-
remain a cause for concern. Botswana, Ghana, grade (Ghana) and ninth-grade (Botswana
and South Africa all participated in the lat- and South Africa) students tested, 79 percent
78 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Figure 3.12 Secondary school students in Sub-Saharan especially given the grade in which this test is
Africa perform poorly on internationally comparable administered. (The international mean was
assessments: TIMSS results for math proficiency, 2011
25 percent; the result was 67 percent for Indo-
nesian students and 45 percent for Jordanian
Korea, Rep.
students.)
International
average School-age children are building skills too
Malaysia slowly. The amount of learning that takes place
in schools from one year to the next is very
Chile
low. Household surveys that include the same
Jordan measures of skills for all children, regardless
Botswana of the grade they are attending, illustrate this
phenomenon. Learning trajectories demon-
Indonesia
strate just how slowly school-age children are
South Africa acquiring skills. A study from Guinea-Bissau
Ghana that mapped performance in basic literacy
and numeracy by childrens ages (figure 3.13)
100 80 60 40 20 0 20 40 60 80 100 shows that only half of 8-year-olds recognize
% of students single digits, while less than half of 9-year-olds
< 400 (low) 400625 (intermediate high) recognize letters of the alphabet (Boone et al.
> 625 (advanced) 2013). Literacy and numeracy performance
Source: Mullis et al. 2012.
improves only very slowly with age. An average
Note: Students tested in grade eight in Ghana and grade nine in 16-year-old still cannot read a paragraph and
Botswana and South Africa.
cannot subtract a single-digit number from a
two-digit number. These low learning trajecto-
of Ghanaians and 76 percent of South Afri- ries are widespread: 351 schools were visited as
cans did not surpass the lowest benchmarked part of the Guinea-Bissau study, but in only 6
level of mathematics proficiency (figure 3.12).7 of them could an average student read a para-
In other words, all of those students failed to graph. In none of the schools could an average
meet the proficiency criterion for this level student multiply or divide.
for example, students have some knowledge Learning trajectories are flat not only for
of whole numbers and decimals, operations, basic literacy or numeracy but for a range of
and basic graphswhich is a low threshold, other cognitive skills, such as language, math-

Figure 3.13 Learning trajectories by age are flat in Guinea-Bissau

a. Literacy b. Numeracy
8 An average An average 12 An average
An average
An average 14-year-old sixteen-year-old An average 14-year-old can sixteen-year-old
7
11-year-old can recognize can recognize and 10 11-year-old add two single cant subtract a
6 can recognize words, but comprehend words, cant add digits but cannot single digit from
Numeracy test score
Literacy test score

letters but not has trouble but cannot read a 8 two single add two-digit a two-digit
5 words comprehending paragraph digits numbers to a number
them single digit
4 Less than 6 Only half of
eight-year- number
half of nine-
3 year-olds can olds can
4
recognize letters recognize
2 of the alphabet single digits
2
1

0 0
7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17
Age (years) Age (years)
Source: Boone et al. 2013. Reproduced with permission of the authors.
Skills for Productive Employment 79

Figure 3.14 Learning trajectories by grade are flat: Performance on test scores in selected African countries,
by educational achievement

a. Ghana b. Malawi
Normalized test score (standard deviations)

Normalized test score (standard deviations)


2.0 2.0

1.5 1.5

1.0 1.0

0.5 0.5

0.0 0.0

0.5 0.5

1.0 1.0

1.5 1.5
None Some Primary Lower Upper Tertiary None Primary Lower Upper
primary secondary secondary secondary secondary

25th percentile 50th percentile 75th percentile

c. South Africa
Normalized test score (standard deviations)

2.0

1.5

1.0

0.5

0.0

0.5

1.0

1.5
5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12
Grade

Level 2/3 Level 3/4 (anchored to grade 8)

Sources: Calculations from Ghana 2004 living standards survey, Malawi Zomba Pilot control group, and South Africa 2008 national income
dynamics study survey.
Note: Standardized score tests are different and cannot be compared across countries. In South Africa, different tests were administered at
different grades; scores on the two tests have been anchored at grade eight.

ematics, and problem solving. Figure 3.14 another analysis using TIMMS data to infer
illustrates how problem-solving skills are asso- learning trajectories, which shows that they
ciated with education in samples from Ghana, are very flat in Ghana (Pritchett 2013). The
Malawi, and South Africa. Learning trajecto- learning trajectories for problem-solving skills
ries from Ghana show that the median level of in Malawi or South Africa are likewise very flat
problem-solving skills is higher for individuals (figure 3.14). Overall, students at each level
who have completed more schooling. Never- vary greatly in their problem-solving skills, but
theless, the increases are very slow. The poorest- across levels of schooling, the accumulation of
performing students in lower-secondary skills varies little around a generally low level.
school (the twenty-fifth percentile) perform Africas schools are not effectively imparting
roughly the same as the median performer basic numeracy or literacy skills, nor are they
among those with incomplete primary school. imparting other cognitive skills such as prob-
This finding is consistent with the results of lem solving or critical analysis.
80 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Poor Cognitive Skills Contribute to Poor learning a day.10 Reforming the accountability
Employment Outcomes framework that allows such poor performance
Because returns to schooling depend consider- to persist is key (World Bank 2003; Bruns,
ably on the quality of education (Card 1999), Filmer, and Patrinos 2011). Better informa-
returns to basic education will remain low as tion on performance must be complemented
long as new cohorts of young people enter the by targeted approaches that increase oversight
labor force with more schooling but limited by the people who are most affected: students
skills. Studies seeking to disentangle the returns and their parents. Steps to ensure that teachers
to cognitive skills from other effects that school- are well prepared for teaching and supported
ing might have on earnings have demonstrated in their tasks are critical for creating a cadre of
a strong associationincluding in Africa.8 For high-performing professionals. What teachers
example, one careful study of wage earners in know and what they do is the cornerstone of
Ghana found that cognitive skills have signifi- good teaching and learning. The rise of private
cant positive effects on wages. An earlier study schools in Africaschools that deliver supe-
of urban wage earners in Kenya and Tanzania rior performance often at lower costsshould
produced similar findings (Glewwe 2002). not be stifled; rather they should be encour-
Recent evidence from Kenya documents the aged and channeled to give more students the
chain of causation from schooling to cogni- opportunity to learn. Such strategies would
tive skills to employment outcomes.9 Second- need to be undertaken in tandem with efforts
ary school graduates were shown to perform to ensure that children are prepared for learn-
significantly better than comparable non- ing when they attend school.
graduates on vocabulary and reasoning tests
in adulthood. Test scores were higher by 0.6 Children Acquire Limited Cognitive and
standard deviation, which is a large effect. By Socioemotional Skills before Entering
their mid-20s, school completers had a roughly School
50 percent lower probability of low-skilled There are strong signs of cognitive delays
self-employment compared to noncompleters. among African children even before they enter
They were about 30 percentage points more school. Data from the Democratic Republic of
likely to be in formal employment. Congo, Nigeria, Sierra Leone, and Togo show
How can African countries overcome the that young children acquire cognitive skills
problem of limited accumulation of cognitive more slowly than expected (figure 3.15). Signs
skills? For those who have already dropped of delays are already apparent at age 36 months
out, especially younger workers, one option is and get worse as children grow older (Naudeau
to expand access to second-chance education. et al. 2010). Some children acquire skills faster
Second-chance education is an option to assist than others, however. For instance, the accu-
the large stock of young workers who have mulation of cognitive skills in early childhood
already dropped out of school, but it is poten- is associated with household socioeconomic
tially expensive and has had mixed success (see status. Children from poorer households score
boxes 3.2 and 3.3). worse on measures of cognitive skills such as
For current and future schoolchildren to receptive language or memory than children in
become productively employed, however, an better-off households. In addition, the gap in
immediate priority is to address the lack of cognitive skills between the poor and nonpoor
learning in basic education. Improving the widens with age. These results are consistent
quality of basic education will not be easy. Sur- across the region, including detailed studies in
veys of schools reveal substantial failures in ser- Madagascar and Mozambique as well as other
vice delivery. For example, absenteeism among parts of the world.11 Delays in early childhood
teachers is on the order of 16 to 20 percent on development can affect children throughout
a given day in Kenya, Senegal, and Tanzania; their lives, limit school readiness, and contrib-
primary school students in those countries ute to the slow accumulation of skills in school
experience only about two to three hours of (Shonkoff and Phillips 2000).
Skills for Productive Employment 81

Box 3.2

A second chance at education for African youth


Many young people in Africa have not completed basic educa- Accelerated learning programs (ALPs) give children and
tion and lack numeracy and literacy skills. In the school year youth an opportunity to catch up on missed education in
ending in 2010, it is estimated that 23 percent (31 million) of a short period (Mattero 2010). They use intensive, flexible
132 million primary schoolage children (514 years) in Sub- methods or schedules to complete the curriculum faster than
Saharan Africa were out of school or not enrolled.a A large pro- in traditional education and help youth to reenter the for-
portion of children never attend school (28 percent of young mal primary or secondary school system. Such programs are
people ages 2534 never started school). Many who manage common in countries where childrens schooling was inter-
to start school drop out after just a few years (figure B3.2.1). rupted by armed conflict or other kinds of social upheaval:
As learning achievement tests demonstrate, when the quality
Republic of South Sudan. ALPs provide basic education to
of education is poor, even formal schooling is no guarantee
those who missed the opportunity during the civil war. The
that students will master basic literacy and numeracy skills.
eight primary grades are reduced to four years of learning.
The programs are part of a broader alternative education
Figure B3.2.1 Proportion of 15- to 19-year-olds who have system that reaches more than 165,000 students (mostly
completed each grade
ages 1218), roughly equal to the number of fourth-grade
100 students in primary schools nationwide (Government of
South Sudan 2011).
Sierra Leone. The Complementary Rapid Education Pro-
80
gramme for Schools, implemented in three districts,
reduced the traditional curriculum and introduced teach-
Percentage

60
ing strategies, thereby shortening the six-year primary
cycle to three years.
40 Northern Ghana. The School for Life Program, described
in box 3.3, was implemented to address a shortage of
20 teachers in areas where literacy among 12- to 18-year-
olds was only 5 percent. The program recruited volunteer
0 teachers with some secondary education and gave them
0 2 4 6 8 10 modest incentives along with a short induction training to
Grade teach out-of-school youth.

Burkina Faso Senegal Ethiopia Nonformal education programs provide youth with instruc-
Congo, Dem. Rep. Malawi Uganda tion equivalent to formal education, focusing on essential
learning needs and basic skills such as literacy, oral expres-
Source: Based on demographic and health survey data, except for the Demo-
cratic Republic of Congo, which is from the Multiple Indicator Cluster Survey.
sion, numeracy, and problem-solving skills (Delors 1996).
Data are for 2010 or 2011 (http://econ.worldbank.org/projects/edattain). Most nonformal education courses range from a few
months to years and can be offered on a part-time or full-
Second-chance education programs have the potential to time basis. They are normally delivered face-to-face in formal
bring school-age children back to school as well as to equip school facilities and learning centers but can also be pro-
youth with the basic literacy and numeracy skills needed for vided through e-learning and radio. Community schools are
productive employment. They enable individuals to complete a well-known example of nonformal education programs in
general primary or secondary education, either by substitut- Africa. In Zambia, community schools enroll individuals who
ing for formal education or by offering bridges to return to are 14 and older and are vulnerable, orphaned, or unable
the formal education system (Mattero 2010). The main types to meet the costs associated with formal schooling. In Mali,
of second-chance programs are (1) accelerated learning pro- community schools originally designed for adults have been
grams, (2) nonformal education programs, and (3) education extended to rural children, offering primary school educa-
equivalency programs. Although adult nonformal education tion up to sixth grade. In Eritrea, to ensure basic education
as well as programs providing technical, vocational, and life for all (especially girls), a UNICEF-supported Complementary
skills are sometimes referred to as second-chance education Elementary Education Program provided nonformal educa-
programs, this report considers them separately. tion to children and young adults (ages 1014 years old)

(continued)
82 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box 3.2

(continued)

who missed an opportunity to complete a five-year primary proficiency tests compared with students in public schools.
school curriculum. Students who attended community schools in Mali outper-
Equivalency degree programs are nonformal education formed their public school counterparts in school completion
programs leading to qualifications equivalent to those gained examinations (DeStefano et al. 2006).
through formal education programs. Equivalency degree Studies suggest that the costs per learner can be higher
programs target primary or secondary school dropouts and in second-chance programs than in traditional public schools
provide corresponding degrees, signaling that the recipient (table B3.2.1), but the limited information on the ultimate
has demonstrated the ability to read, write, think, and com- outcomes of interest makes it hard to evaluate their cost-
pute at the level for which the degree was offered (Boesel, effectiveness. Much more data are needed to understand
Alsalam, and Smith 1998). Equivalency programs vary in how these programs can cost-effectively build skills and
terms of admission, age, place, and pace, and they are deliv- increase youth productivity and earnings.
ered either via face-to-face learning or distance education.
Systematic evidence on the effectiveness of second-
chance programs is quite limited and mixed. In Sierra Leone, Table B3.2.1 Costs per pupil in second-chance education
programs and formal public schools
students in ALPs performed consistently better than stu-
dents in traditional schools, with a 91 percent passing rate Annual cost
on primary school achievement tests. Students progressed Country and type of education per pupil (US$)
to secondary schooling at similar rates (Nicholson 2006). For Ghana
students in Ghanas School for Life, the transition back into School for Life 39
the formal system is close to 90 percent (DeStefano et al.
Public 27
2006). However, in the Republic of South Sudan the dropout
rates for ALPs during the 201011 school year were 52 per- Mali
cent for females compared to around 20 percent in formal Community schools 47
schools (Government of South Sudan 2011). Results are bet- Public 30
ter for males; only 5 percent dropped out of the ALP versus
Zambia
around 25 percent in formal schools. In Zambia students in
community schools performed well on math and English Community schools 39
Public 67
a. UNESCO 2012. Source: DeStefano et al. 2006.

Box 3.3

Northern Ghanas School for Life second-chance education program


School for Life (SfL) offers a nine-month literacy cycle in the children to maintain daily duties; and training takes place in
mother tongue for children ages 814. The curriculum aims primary school classrooms after school, which provides a link
to meet the first three years of the formal school systems with formal education.
requirements and transition participants into the formal sys- The programs reach is broad and growing. Approxi-
tem on graduation. Facilitatorsvolunteers selected by the mately 800 facilitators served 20,000 learners in 17 districts
communityreceive an initial three-week intensive training, in 201213, up from 10,000 in 9 districts the previous year.
supplemented with follow-up workshops and training. Com- The vast majority complete the programthe graduation
munities provide their own teachers or facilitators, who are rate was 97 percent in 201112and most join the formal
literate in the communitys language; the mother tongue is schooling system. As many as 90 percent of the 201112
both the language of literacy and the medium of instruction; cohort entered primary school on leaving SfL.
the community is actively involved; the school calendar and
hours are flexible and adapted to local conditions, allowing Sources: CREATE 2010; DFID 2012.
Skills for Productive Employment 83

Figure 3.15 Cognitive skills increase slowly, especially for the poorest

a. Democratic Republic of Congo b. Nigeria


100 100

80 80

60 60
Percent

Percent
40 40

20 20

0 0
35 40 45 50 55 60 35 40 45 50 55 60
Age (months) Age (months)

c. Sierra Leone d. Togo


100 100

80 80

60 60
Percent

Percent

40 40

20 20

0 0
35 40 45 50 55 60 35 40 45 50 55 60
Age (months) Age (months)

Poorest 40% Richest 20%


Source: Based on Multiple Indicator Cluster Survey 4 data.
Note: Graphs show the proportion of respondents who can perform two of the following three tasks: identify or name at least 10 letters
of the alphabet; read at least four simple, popular words; know the name and recognize the symbols of all numbers from 1 to 10.

Multiple factors contribute to the slow acqui- to gains in school readiness and improvements
sition of skills in early childhood. Nutrition is in a range of cognitive skills. Similar effects on
one factor, but parenting practices and stimula- skills in early childhood have been found in
tion also matter greatly. Poor nutrition in early other developing countries for interventions
childhood can hinder the accumulation of focusing on improving parenting practices and
cognitive skills12 and affect reading or problem- stimulation through home visits, community-
solving skills in adulthood (Maluccio et al. based centers, or preschools.13
2009). Parenting practices and psychosocial Early childhood is also a critical window
stimulation also shape cognitive and socioemo- for the development of socioemotional and
tional skills. Programs that encourage stimula- behavioral skills, including skills involved in
tion as well as nutrition have been shown to forming relationships, communication or
be more effective than programs that only socialization, and self-regulation of behav-
aim to improve nutrition. They increase skills iors and emotions (table 3.1; Lundberg and
as well as earnings in adulthood (Grantham- Wuermli 2012; Tubbs and McCoy 2012; Aber
McGregor et al. 2007; Gertler et al. 2013). In and Jones 1997). Stressful experiences such as
Mozambique, a recent preschool program led conflicts or other shocks can trigger behavioral
84 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Table 3.1 Developmental tasks, by age by the time individuals are 15 years old,
Age Period of life Developmental task whereas many behavioral skills are acquired
01 Early childhood Establishing (secure) attachment relationships between the ages of 15 and 30 (figure 3.16).
13 Early childhood Learning to explore and communicate
Psychology has a long history of studying
domains of human functioning. In practice,
35 Early childhood Learning to self-regulate thoughts, behaviors, and
emotions socioemotional and behavioral skills are often
612 Middle childhood Learning and reasoning, developing interpersonal
taken to encompass a broad set of soft skills or
and social problem-solving skills life skills, which have come to include a mix
13+ Adolescence and emerging adulthood Establishing autonomy (renegotiating relationships), of skills and less well-defined individual char-
forming identity, setting and achieving goals acteristics such as social skills, self-regulation,
Source: Wuermli et al. 2012. goal-setting behavior, personal initiative,
achievement orientation, proactivity, action
problems and affect socioemotional devel- planning, deliberate practice, or self-confidence.
opment through depression, anxiety, or Sometimes behavioral skills also include life
self-esteem. Parenting practices and psycho- skills linked with avoiding risky behavior or
social stimulation contribute to shaping these more general measures of psychological well-
socioemotional skillsas shown recently in being, attitudes, or aspirations. They are some-
Mozambique, where children participating times linked to personality characteristics such
in a preschool program showed improved as the big five: extraversion, emotional stabil-
emotional maturity, including self-regulation ity, agreeableness, conscientiousness, and open-
(Martinez, Naudeau, and Pereira 2012). ness to experience. These traits can continue to
change in adulthood (Roberts and Mroczek
Socioemotional and Behavioral Skills 2008).
Are a Neglected Part of the Skill Set for Socioemotional and behavioral skills such as
Productivity self-regulation have been linked to educational
Socioemotional and behavioral skills comple- achievement and those such as self-confidence,
ment and extend cognitive skills to improve social skills, or emotional stability have been
productivity, but they are often neglected. shown to affect employment outcomes (Heck-
Socioemotional skills develop through early man, Stixrud, and Urzua 2006). In fact, em-
and middle childhood. Social competen- ployer surveys and qualitative research from
cies are consolidated through increasing
interactions and socialization in school and
in communities (Lundberg and Wuermli Figure 3.16 Behavioral skills take longer to develop
than cognitive skills
2012). As children reach adolescence, they
further hone their social skills, become 70
increasingly autonomous, and forge a sense
of identity (see chapter 2). Depending on 60
% scoring at mean adult level

the context in which they live, including the 50


social expectations surrounding them, ado-
40
lescents shape aspirations and set goals for
themselves. Concurrently, they experience 30
deep socioemotional changes that can chal- 20
lenge their self-confidence or self-regulatory
skills and make them vulnerable to depres- 10

sion, anxiety, or risky behaviors (Lundberg and 0


Wuermli 2012). Long after cognitive skills have 1011 1213 1415 1617 1821 2225 2630
been acquired, socioemotional and behavioral Age (years)
skills remain malleable, reflecting the many Cognitive skills Psychosocial maturity
changes and transitions characteristic of ado- Source: Steinberg et al. 2009. Reproduced with permission of the
lescence. Cognitive skills are largely acquired authors.
Skills for Productive Employment 85

various African countries suggest that employ- different behavioral skills are required for dif-
ers are looking for soft skills in young hires. ferent occupations and sectors. New research
In Botswana, employers report that they seek from the United States suggests that not all
workers with skills such as honesty, commit- behavioral skills matter in the same way across
ment and hard work, reliability and punctual- different types of work or even across relatively
ity, communication, and team working skills unskilled tasks. For example, sociability (or
(World Bank 2012a). In Lesotho, employers extraversion) has higher returns in the ser-
rate soft skills (the appropriate personal char- vice sectorspecifically in sales jobsthan in
acteristics) as among the hardest to find in unskilled manual work (Almlund et al. 2011;
prospective employees. Of the soft skills they Fletcher 2012).
seek when recruiting professionals or skilled The relative importance of behavioral and
workers, employers rate punctuality and reli- cognitive skills is also not well established.
ability and honesty and trustworthiness as Fundamentally, many behavioral and cognitive
the most important.14 In Sierra Leone, focus skills are interconnected. For instance, the abil-
group discussions revealed that the young are ity to regulate ones behavior or emotions also
perceived to lack work attitudes appropri- depends on cognitive abilities. Research sug-
ate for formal jobs, such as punctuality and gests that for less complex tasks, such as those
the ability to follow instructions (Peeters et al. required for relatively unskilled work, the role
2009). of behavioral skills can be relatively larger. For
Behavioral skills also matter for HEs for more complex tasks, the contribution of cogni-
many reasons, including the firms dependence tive skills can be relatively higher, although soft
on the skills of the owner, who is often the skills matter there as well (Almlund et al. 2011).
sole worker (chapter 5). In South Africa and For wage jobs, two personality characteristics,
Zimbabwe, for example, the owners entre- in particular, seem to have strong predictive
preneurial orientationmeasured by per- power for job performance and wages: con-
sonal initiative (proactivity and persistence) scientiousness (the tendency to be organized,
and achievement orientation (taking respon- responsible, and hardworking) and emotional
sibility for ones own performance, taking on stability. Almost all such evidence comes from
challenges, and setting high goals for one- developed countries, although similar findings
self)are positively associated with success are emerging from developing countries. A
in operating a small business.15 A similar link
recent study in Peru shows that cognitive skills
between personal initiative and business suc-
and perseverancea behavioral skillhave
cess was found in Uganda (Koop, De Reu, and
similar effects on earnings in wage employment
Frese 2000, quoted in Krauss et al. 2005). Other
(box 3.4).
work has emphasized how the deliberateness
Overall, socioemotional and behavioral
of business owners is linked to success. Exam-
skills matter for productivity. Such skills can be
ples include the role of elaborate and proac-
shaped through experience in early childhood,
tive planning skills in Namibia, South Africa,
through education, as well as through a range
and Zimbabwe (Frese et al. 2007) and deliber-
ate practice (self-regulated and effortful activ- of experiences and programs in adolescence
ities showing a willingness to learn) in South and adulthood. The relative effectiveness of dif-
Africa (Unger et al. 2009). Self-control ferent approaches to building these skills needs
a behavioral skill that builds on cognitive to be better understood, and this is an area that
capacityalso appears to be an important warrants policy attention.
influence on the savings and investment
behavior of HE owners in Kenya (Dupas and Schooling Can Contribute to Building
Robinson 2013). Socioemotional and Behavioral Skills
Despite the recognized importance of The link between education and behav-
behavioral skills, it is not yet well understood ioral skills is complex. Part of the association
which ones matter most or the extent to which between behavioral skills and employment
86 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box 3.4

Returns to behavioral skills in wage employment: Evidence from Peru


A survey of micro and small enterprises in Peru found that topics, including a range of other individual and household
employers seek workers with a range of skills. About half of characteristics.
the firms said that the main problem in hiring suitable work- Analysis of those data reveals that measures of cogni-
ers is the lack of qualified or competent workers (in this case, tive skills correlate with higher earnings. An increase of 1
qualifications and competence reflect perceived cogni- standard deviation in receptive language, numeracy, work-
tive and technical skills). At the same time, about 40 percent ing memory, or verbal fluency was associated with 918
cited the lack of skills such as a strong work ethic,
c ability to percent higher hourly earnings. Behavioral skills were also
work in teams, persistence, adaptability, initiative, and other associated with higher earnings. Workers scoring 1 standard
socioemotional skills. Other data from the national public deviation higher in the perseverance facet of grit earned 13
employment service show that, in addition to cognitive skills, percent more; those scoring 1 standard deviation higher in
employers seek employees with traits related to work ethic, three of the big-five scores (extraversion, emotional stability,
reliability, and interpersonal relationsregardless of formal and openness to experience) earned 8 percent more. Not all
schooling. Moreover, the results also suggest that behavioral behavioral skills necessarily correlate positively with earnings.
skills may be more important for the less educated. A score for agreeableness-cooperation that was 1 stan-
The study also set out to measure the supply of skills dard deviation higher was associated with 10 percent lower
directly. In addition to traditional measures such as years of earnings.
education, the study applied a range of standardized and spe- Schooling, cognitive skills, and behavioral skills affect
cifically designed instruments. The Peabody Picture Vocabu- earnings through multiple pathways, both direct and indi-
lary Test was used to measure receptive vocabularythe rect. When the role of each factor is evaluated while con-
ability to comprehend specific words. Additional cognitive trolling for the other factors, years of schooling, years of
tests were designed to measure verbal ability, working mem- work experience, and cognitive skills all have significantly
ory, and numeracy or problem-solving skills. Socioemotional positive effects. This finding suggests that measured cogni-
skills were measured with self-reported tests for personal- tive skills affect earnings over and above years of schooling
ity characteristics related to behaviors. They were measured alone, suggesting that what is learned d in school matters. The
with scales of the big-five personality factors (openness to behavioral skills that significantly affect earnings (even after
experience, conscientiousness, extraversion, agreeableness, accounting for schooling, experience, and cognitive skills)
emotional stability), factors that are considered in psychol- are emotional stability and perseverance. Perseverance mat-
ogy as characterizing differences in broad personality traits ters as much as cognitive skills. A score that is 1 standard
(and associated behaviors), and grit, a narrower trait cap- deviation higher on either the cognitive skill or the persever-
turing a persons inclination and motivation to achieve long- ance scale led to a similar increase in earnings (of 8 and 9
term goals (through perseverance of effort and consistency percent, respectively).
of interest). The study measured these skills in the context of
a household survey that collected information on multiple Source: World Bank 2011b.

outcomes stems from their effect on higher Education systems have scope for develop-
educational achievementand the cognitive ing skills other than cognitive skills. Research
skills that underlie higher educational achieve- in the United States suggests that elementary
ment. Behavioral skills such as perseverance or even preschool programs that enrich the
or personal initiative are correlated with suc- early learning environment can have lasting
cess in school. It could be that people who are effects on later-life outcomes through posi-
inherently more conscientious both acquire tive impacts on behavioral and socioemotional
more schooling and perform better at work skills (Almlund et al. 2011). Increased attention
(Almlund et al. 2011). Recent work on China to imparting behavioral skills through school-
found a positive association between behav- ing may take several forms, including modes of
ioral skills and educational achievement, even instruction as well as the modeling of appropri-
after accounting for cognitive skills (Glewwe, ate behaviors, including teachers behavior, in
Huang, and Park 2011). the school environment.
Skills for Productive Employment 87

Schooling imparts behavioral skills in sev- behaviormight also contribute to improving


eral ways. First, school success itself increases students behavioral skills through their dem-
self-esteem and confers a greater sense of self- onstration effect. Teaching approaches that are
determination, as shown in research among more interactive and group based may facilitate
high school and college graduates in the United the acquisition of both cognitive and behav-
States.16 Second, the way that teaching and ioral skills, for instance. Curricular reforms
learning are delivered may influence behav- that explicitly seek to improve behavioral skills
ioral skills. Teaching approaches that encourage may also be considered. However, such reforms
participation, group activities, and exploration may entail a trade-off requiring a decision
instill different mind-sets among students than about what to prioritize. Curriculum reforms
approaches that emphasize rote learning. Third, introducing behavioral skills should not come
the experience of education and the habits at the cost of neglecting urgent improvements
learned in school matter. Teacher absenteeism in the acquisition of basic literacy and numer-
on the order of 20 percent, with little or no con- acy skills. Reforms might be more relevant for
sequence to teachers, has been documented in higher grades where potential trade-offs with
several African countries (World Bank 2003).17 other teaching may be more limited. Given the
Students exposure to such an environment will limited evidence on the effectiveness of such
likely instill a sense that punctuality (one of the approaches and the importance of their devel-
skills that some employers say they are seeking) opment in local contexts, they should be intro-
is not important. duced in an experimental setup and rigorously
There are little data on the extent to which tested before being rolled out widely.
education builds socioemotional and behav- Beyond education, other more focused
ioral skills, including the soft skills demanded approaches are showing promise in reaching
by employers. The education system could be youths and building behavioral skills. They
leveraged to build further behavioral skills and include targeted interventions in postconflict
reach a large number of children and young settings (box 3.5). Programs that integrate
people. Policies that aim to improve the qual- behavioral skills into more comprehensive
ity of educationfor instance, by decreasing youth employment programs can also improve
teachers absenteeism and improving their behavioral skills (box 3.6). Chapter 5 (for the

Box 3.5

Developing socioemotional and behavioral skills in postconflict settings


Children exposed to violence such as rape or killing can ful integration into educational or livelihoods initiatives, and
develop conditions such as depression or anxiety that might positive peer, family, and community relationships.
lead to behavioral problems. In Sierra Leone, where the The Sierra Leone pilot intervention was developed
long civil war has had deep psychosocial consequences, a through an approach building on rigorous use of qualitative
Youth Readiness Intervention has focused on rebuilding methods to ensure that the training modules and interven-
skills related to anger management, interpersonal relations, tion strategy were culturally appropriate and could be deliv-
and goal setting. The intervention is delivered to groups of ered by local providers. A randomized control trial is under
young people. The groups meet for weekly sessions over way to test the interventions effectiveness. Such pilots have
two months. The intervention seeks to increase adaptive yet to be tested at scale, and the employment outcomes
coping, health-promoting behavior, and the development remain to be documented. Still, this type of well-designed
of life skills, such as goal setting and positive self-efficacy; model to foster socioemotional and behavioral skills is an
decrease maladaptive coping strategies, such as high-risk example of potential interventions that could be integrated
sexual behavior and substance use; decrease trauma-related more systematically into youth employment programs.
distress, including aggression, depressive symptoms, social
isolation, and poor interpersonal skills; [and] increase proso- Source: Draws from FXB Center for Health and Human Rights 2012,
cial behavior, including community involvement and success- including quoted material.
88 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box 3.6
higher abilitywith the pattern being starkest
in Kenya and Tanzania. This finding suggests
that education has the greatest benefit among
Promoting socioemotional and behavioral skills people who start with greater ability or better
foundational skills.
Employment programs in Malawi and Uganda that focused on female
Basic cognitive skills also underlie the devel-
empowerment and life skills improved psychosocial well-being and
opment of business skills, which are often par-
reduced risky behaviors (Bandiera et al. 2013; Cho et al. 2013). A pro-
gram integrating training in technical and life skills in Uganda resulted
ticularly low for young people and women (Xu
in a self-reported increase in routine condom use of almost 50 percent and Zia 2012). A study of small HEs in Ghana
and a 29 percent reduction in the likelihood of becoming a mother found that owners with more schooling are
(Bandiera et al. 2013). Positive impacts on behaviors was seen in pro- more likely to keep written records: Only 23
grams in Tanzania and Uganda aiming to increase personal initiative percent of HE owners who had not completed
and develop a more entrepreneurial mind-set (Glaub 2009; Berge et basic education kept accounts, compared to 52
al. 2011). These results are consistent with others outside of Africa. percent of owners who had completed basic
Programs in countries as diverse as Chile, Jordan, Nicaragua, and Peru education (Fafchamps et al. 2011). Low busi-
have produced graduates who have greater self-esteem, measured ness skills are observed even among more for-
empowerment, mental health, or positive attitudes about the future
mal firms. In a survey of owners of small and
(Carneiro, Galasso, and Ginja 2010; Valdivia 2011; Macours, Premand,
medium enterprises in Ghana, only 27 percent
and Vakis 2013; Premand et al. 2012; Groh et al. 2012).a
of owners were found to keep business records
a. These effects are corroborated by an ongoing evaluation of a comprehensive (Mano et al. 2012). Throughout the world,
youth training programJuventud y Empleoin the Dominican Republic. Prelimi- financial literacy is associated with higher edu-
nary evidence indicates significant effects on future expectations, job satisfaction,
and job search attitudes.
cational attainment (Xu and Zia 2012).
Another study from Ghana measured a
range of business practices among HE own-
ers, such as whether the owner keeps writ-
HE sector) and chapter 6 (for the modern wage ten business records, has a written budget, has
sector) discuss the extent to which programs a sales target, visits competitors business to
aiming to shape behavioral skills are effective observe prices, asks existing customers if they
in improving employment outcomes. had interest in other products. The number of
management practices adopted by the owners
Skills Build on Each Other of micro and small enterprises was found to
A growing body of research documents how
cognitive and socioemotional skills build on Figure 3.17 The returns to schooling are higher for
each other, starting in early childhood (Helm- those with greater ability: Returns of an additional
ers and Patnam 2011). Cognitive skills such as year of schooling by quantile
literacy and numeracy form the foundation for
22
acquiring higher-order and technical skills later 20
in life, whether through more formal education, 18
16
training, or on-the-job learning. Basic cognitive 14
skills are necessary for learning more advanced
% return

12
concepts, and better foundational skills lower 10
8
the costs of any additional investments. 6
One way to understand how skills build on 4
2
each other is to observe that the productivity 0
returns to investments in further schooling are Q10 Q25 Q50 Q75 Q90
higher when foundational skills are stronger. Quantile
Figure 3.17 presents an example from Ghana, Kenya Tanzania
Kenya, South Africa, and Tanzania. Returns Ghana South Africa
to schooling tend to be lower for individu- Source: Fasih et al. 2012. Reproduced with permission from the
als with lower ability compared to those with authors.
Skills for Productive Employment 89

vary substantially. In addition, these business In Tunisia, a middle-income country, entrepre-


practice scores also predicted business perfor- neurship training was introduced in the univer-
mance (Fafchamps and Woodruff 2012). The sity curriculum and led to changes in behavioral
adoption of better management practices was skills (Premand et al. 2012). Initial evidence on
significantly higher among respondents who a pilot financial education program provided
scored better on various cognitive tests. through the schools in Brazil suggests some
Although business skills are not taught in positive impacts: 59 percent of students who
school, they are correlated with education, benefited from the program saved, compared
because they are rarely acquired without basic to 55 percent among the control group, and
cognitive skills. A more direct measure of this knowledge about savings increased (Bruhn et
effect, however, is the interaction between edu- al. 2013). Similar efforts are under way in some
cation and the effectiveness of interventions African countries (for example, in secondary
to build business skills. A program to provide education in Uganda). An important challenge
business training to small-scale entrepreneurs is that soft skills for self-employment and wage
in Tanzania found larger impacts among par- employment may differ, requiring careful atten-
ticipants with higher initial cognitive (math) tion to curriculum development and program
test scores (Bjorvatn and Tungodden 2010). effectiveness.
Basic cognitive skills also complement on-
the-job learning for wage workers, includ-
ing learning through the use of instructions.
Building Skills through
Although literate workers can be trained in job
specifications and procedures partly through Post-School Training
detailed and complex written instructions, such
training is rare in Africa, where literacy is low. A wide array of institutions throughout Africa
Among firms surveyed in Ghana, Kenya, and offer skills training for nonfarm employment.
Zimbabwe, 80 percent said that they rarely use This array of institutions and programs can be
technical documentation or procedural manu- described as a market, since it involves those
als (Biggs, Shah, and Srivastava 1995). A recent who supply training coming together with
study in Ghana found that, in a job involving those who demand training. Informal training
the handling of money, more educated workers is normal. Most training is offered by private
were more likely to pick up math skills while providers, and the offerings vary in price and
working (Aslam and Lehrer 2012). Perhaps quality. The rationale for public investment in
because of the complementarity between basic training needs to be made in the context of this
education and on-the-job learning, firms in existing market, based on careful analysis of its
Africa (as in other parts of the world) are more added value and cost-effectiveness.
likely to provide formal on-the-job training to
more educated workers (Rosholm, Nielsen, and Pathways from Training to Sectors of
Dabalen 2007). Employment
Beyond the complementarities between Four main kinds of youth training provide
basic skills and business skills, there may be skills for employment outside agriculture:
potential for incorporating entrepreneurship apprenticeships, public formal technical voca-
education or financial literacy education into tional education and training (TVET), private
school curricula. Yet it remains unclear whether formal and informal TVET (formal mean-
the education system can provide such skills ing integrated into the formal education sys-
effectively. Some developed countries have tem; informal meaning outside of the formal
attempted to include entrepreneurship training education system), and stand-alone programs.
at the primary and tertiary level (see Rosendahl Training is delivered through a mix of private
Huber, Sloof, and van Praag 2012 for efforts in and public institutions, and each type of train-
primary school; Oosterbeek, van Praag, and Ijs- ing tends to lead to a different type of work
selstein 2008 for efforts in tertiary education). (nonfarm HE or modern wage sector).
90 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Figure 3.18 Many young people, especially in West Africa, have been an apprentice, whereas experience with
TVET is less prevalent

a. Ever been an apprentice b. Ever attended a TVET institute


Cameroon
Cte dIvoire
Cte dIvoire
Ghana Ghana

Mozambique
Rwanda
Malawi

Sierra Leone Rwanda

Senegal
Tanzania
Sierra Leone

Uganda Tanzania

Uganda
Average
Average

0 10 20 30 40 0 10 20 30 40
Share (%) Share (%)
Source: Based on standardized and harmonized household and labor force surveys, latest data available (see appendix).

Two of the most common forms of train- Apprenticeship was by far the most common
ing pursued by young people are apprentice- form (55 percent had been an apprentice), fol-
ships and TVET. Apprenticeships are the more lowed by on-the-job formal training in a firm
prevalent type of training, particularly in West (25 percent), and formal vocational training (16
Africa. Detailed survey data on apprenticeship percent). An earlier study estimated that tradi-
are limited, but in five countries with compara- tional or informal apprenticeships supply 8090
ble data, 20 percent of young adults ages 2435 percent of all basic skills training in Ghana,
have had experience as an apprentice (figure while public training institutions supply 510
3.18), although there is variation across coun- percent (Atchoarena and Delluc 2001). Ghana
tries, from 6 percent in Uganda to 35 percent may have as many as four informal apprentices
in Ghana. for every trainee in either a formal public or a
Enrollment in formal TVET, delivered in the private training center (Darvas 2012; Haan and
classroom and leading to a formal degree after Serrire 2002; Monk, Sandefur, and Teal 2008).
two to three years, is low throughout Africa. Apprenticeships are widespread elsewhere in
Overall, around 4 percent of young people West Africa as well, including in Benin and Cte
between 25 and 34 have ever attended formal dIvoire (AfDB and OECD 2008).
TVET,18 and only 1 percent currently attend.19 Traditional apprenticeship can also be the
Because most TVET requires some secondary dominant form of training for nonfarm occu-
schooling, the majority of young people lack pations in East Africa. In Kenya, enrollment in
the general qualifications even to enroll in a traditional apprenticeships delivered by master
technical or vocational institute. craftsmen is much higher than enrollment in
The prevalence of apprenticeship in Ghana formal TVET.20 A small survey of 350 informal
is well documented (for example, see Atcho- enterprises in Dar es Salaam found that more
arena and Delluc 2001; Frazer 2006; Monk, than half of the operators had apprentices, on
Sandefur, and Teal 2008). A 2006 urban labor average about two per firm (Nell and Shapiro
market survey found that one-third of respon- 1999).
dents between ages 16 and 65 had some form Beyond the more traditional apprenticeship
of training (Monk, Sandefur, and Teal 2008). and formal TVET models, a broad range of
Skills for Productive Employment 91

private providers offers various types of skills individuals who have completed primary
training. Private providers of informal voca- school or less, while formal TVET is geared
tional training (in other words, training outside toward individuals with at least some sec-
the formal education system) include for-profit ondary schooling (figure 3.19). For example,
private institutes and firms, nongovernmental among young adults ages 2534 in Uganda
organizations (NGOs), and community orga- who had done an apprenticeship, 95 percent
nizations. While the distinction with master had no more than a primary education. A
craftsmen providing apprenticeships can be study in Ghana found that apprenticeships are
fuzzy, the vast majority of providers of informal undertaken primarily by persons with a junior
vocational training are self-financing and oper- high school or lower level of education (Monk,
ate with little government oversight or support. Sandefur, and Teal 2008). Among those who
Many informal private providers are not reg- had entered a TVET program, almost all had
istered (World Bank 2003). Many operate at a some education beyond primary.
very small scale; these micro training provid- The type of training pursued maps closely to
ers provide short, intensive training based on the subsequent sector of employment. Appren-
a curriculum of their own design and may ticeship is mainly a pathway to work in an HE,
offer certificates (Johanson and Gakuba 2011). since apprentices are most likely to become
Assessing their reach is challenging. Household self-employed. By contrast, formal TVET is
surveys rarely ask respondents about training mostly a pathway to wage employment.
other than apprenticeships, on-the-job train- As a result, the training experience of work-
ing, or formal TVET. A recent tracer study of ers in different sectors is quite different. For
cohorts of secondary and university graduates young adults ages 2534 working in the HE
suggests that the use of private post-school sector, apprenticeships are the most common
training may be rising (Al-Samarrai and Ben- form of post-school training: 32 percent have
nell 2007). been an apprentice at some point, compared
Apprenticeships (as well as other types of to 30 percent of young adults in the modern
informal training) are typically geared toward wage sector and 13 percent in the agricultural

Figure 3.19 Apprenticeships are geared toward youths with lower levels of education

a. Past apprentices b. TVET graduates

Cte dIvoire Cte dIvoire

Ghana Ghana

Rwanda Rwanda

Sierra Leone Sierra Leone

Tanzania Tanzania

Uganda Uganda

Average Average

0 20 40 60 80 100 0 20 40 60 80 100
Percentage Percentage

Less than primary Primary Lower secondary Secondary or higher


Source: Based on standardized and harmonized household and labor force surveys, latest data available (see appendix).
92 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Figure 3.20
enterprise or wage work

a. Apprenticeship b. TVET

Cte dIvoire Cte dIvoire

Ghana Ghana

Rwanda Rwanda

Sierra Leone Sierra Leone

Tanzania Tanzania

Uganda Uganda

Average Average

0 10 20 30 40 50 60 0 10 20 30 40 50 60
Percentage Percentage

Agriculture Household enterprise Wage


Source: Based on standardized and harmonized household and labor force surveys, latest data available (see appendix).

sector (figure 3.20).21 Returns to apprentice- provides practical training in the workplace
ships may be particularly high in HEs. A study over a period of a few weeks or months to as
from Ghana found that former apprentices much as three or four years. Many apprentice-
earn about 49 percent more a year being self- ships build technical skills in a narrow range
employed than working as a wage worker, of traditional vocations or crafts, such as met-
despite having slightly fewer years of school- alworking, carpentry, mechanics, or tailor-
ing and being slightly younger.22 Relatively ing. Some offer certification, but most do not.
few young workers enter the HE sector after Apprenticeships can be offered in return for a
obtaining formal technical or vocational train- fee or reduced earnings while learning.
ing. Only 6 percent of individuals between 25 In an apprenticeship program in Malawi,
and 34 in the HE sector have attended a formal master craftsmen were primarily in carpentry
TVET institution (figure 3.20). The share of and joinery (19 percent), tailoring (18 percent),
workers in the wage sector who have attended auto mechanics (11 percent), and fabrication
formal TVET is much higher (17 percent). and welding (11 percent). A large share of the
observed apprenticeship training in Rwanda
Apprenticeships and Informal Private was concentrated in tailoring (Johanson and
Training Gakuba 2011).
The distinction between apprenticeship and The duration of apprenticeships can vary
informal private training (two of the most greatly. Many youths only spend a few months
prevalent forms of youth training) is fuzzy. as an apprentice. In Rwanda, 56 percent of
Both types of training encompass a range of HE owners with experience as an apprentice
offerings delivered by private providers. reported that their apprenticeship lasted less
Apprenticeships in Africa overwhelmingly than a month (Johanson and Gakuba 2011). In
occur in small informal firms with a mas- Malawi, participants in an apprenticeship pro-
ter craftsman. They are private arrangements gram reported that apprenticeships lasted on
between an apprentice and a master craftsper- average 3.3 months; training for auto mechan-
son or another relatively skilled person, who ics spanned more than three months, whereas
Skills for Productive Employment 93

training for hairdressers lasted only three weeks ing vouchers in Kenya, for example, enrolled For many
(Cho et al. 2013). By contrast, in countries such mainly in informal training in tailoring (37 long years, I
as Cte dIvoire or Ghana, where the institution percent), mechanics (18 percent), hairdressing
worked as an
of apprenticeship is more established, appren- (9 percent), driving (7 percent), and masonry
ticeships can last several years and can be hard (6 percent; Hicks et al. 2011). In northern apprentice and
to leave. Uganda, youth groups eligible for cash grants had to follow
The range of private informal training in chose training heavily concentrated in a few the masons . . . .
Africa is quite wide. Many micro training pro- trades: tailoring (38 percent), carpentry (24 It wasnt until I
viders develop their own teaching programs, percent), metalwork (13 percent), hairdress- turned 30 that
market their services, and deliver a mix of ing (8 percent), and business or management
I got my license.
theoretical and applied training to individu- (5 percent).24
als in small groups. For example, in Rwanda, The duration of informal training can be Madagascar
97 percent of all training providers are private, quite short. In Northern Uganda, where youths
and they account for 90 percent of enrollment engaged in informal training for an average of
(figure 3.21; Johanson and Gakuba 2011). about 321 hours over two years, they increased
Individuals own about half of all private train- their investment in training to 560 hours after
ing enterprises, and associations and coopera- receiving a cash grant. When grant recipients
tives own the other half. Just over half of all enrolled with private formal TVET providers,
providers are micro training providers, such as the training was substantially longer, ranging
associations, cooperatives, or training centers, up to two years (Hicks et al. 2011).
enrolling 12 or fewer trainees. Micro train-
ing providers enroll only 8 percent of private Formal TVET
trainees, but total enrollment in micro training Formal TVET runs parallel to general school-
still exceeds enrollment in all public, formal ing at the secondary or tertiary level and meets
vocational training in Rwanda (figure 3.21). In the need for intermediate or advanced techni-
Tanzania, private training institutions, includ- cal skills. Entry requirements often include hav-
ing faith-based organizations and NGOs, ing completed primary or secondary school.
produce about three-fourths of all vocational Therefore, participants in formal TVET have
graduates, even though most of those insti- substantially more schooling than participants
tutions do not operate at capacity (Cojocaru in other forms of post-school training.
2011).23 In Nigeria, technical colleges at the sec-
Like apprenticeships, informal training ondary level produce craftsmen and master
programs are often concentrated in a limited craftsmen, focusing on traditional technical
set of areas. Youth eligible for vocational train- vocations (electricians, vehicle mechanics, and

Figure 3.21 Africa has a wide range of informal private training providers, 2009

a. Training institutions, Rwanda b. Enrollment in vocational training, Rwanda


Micro private
Public Public
training providers
Semi-public
Micro private Semi-public
training providers

Large private Large private


training training
providers providers

Source: Johanson and Gakuba 2011.


94 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

masons). At the tertiary level, vocational insti- often those with larger populations and greater
tutions (polytechnics) produce technicians, demand for training (Ghana and Zambia are
professionals, and engineers. Business-oriented examples).
vocational training is prevalent. Nearly half of Besides pre-employment TVET, post-
all polytechnic graduates pursue qualifications employment formal training paid for by employ-
in accounting, business studies, marketing, ers can also be a source of technical or vocational
and banking and finance (World Bank 2011a). skills. About 30 percent of African firms provide
In Rwanda, technical secondary schools pre- formal on-the-job training, a rate comparable to
pare students for entering the labor market at other developing regions (box 3.7).
roughly the same level as an upper-secondary
school graduate. Vocational training centers
prepare basic education graduates or dropouts Government Interventions and
to enter the labor market (World Bank 2011a). the Post-school Training Market
Several types of nongovernmental entities
also provide technical and vocational training, Governments the world over are active in
including for-profit private institutes and firms skills development, but before designing pub-
as well as NGOs. However, data on the extent lic policy, it is essential to assess the rationale
to which the private sector provides formal for government intervention. Given the large
TVET are scarce; household surveys rarely ask array of training already provided by the pri-
respondents to identify whether they attended vate sector, the rationale for governments to
a public or a private TVET institute.25 Never- invest in specific programs is not obvious. As a
theless, studies suggest that the private sector general principle, public interventions need to
is a large and increasingly important provider be based on clearly identified market failures
of pre-employment TVET. In some countries, and weighted against government failures.
the majority of trainees are enrolled in nongov- Market failures for skills development take
ernmental institutions. Examples include Mali specific formsall of which can lead to under-
(where nongovernmental training accounts investment in training (see the discussion in
for two-thirds of all TVET), Tanzania (90 per- Almeida, Behrman, and Robalino 2012; World
cent), and Zambia (82 percent). Private techni- Bank 2011a). These failures can be grouped
cal institutes in Ghana enroll about six times as into four main categories:
many trainees as public institutes (Haan 2001
1. Imperfections in labor markets, such as
for Tanzania; Atchoarena and Esquieu 2002 for
poaching externalities, whereby the firm
Mali; Kitaev 2003 for Ghana and Zambia). A
that trains an employee loses the benefits of
recent study in Ethiopia estimates that 3050
that training if the worker moves to another
percent of TVET students are enrolled in pri-
firm, or information and signaling failures,
vate institutions (Shaorshadze and Krishnan
whereby a potential worker cannot effec-
2013). A recent World Bank report, using sta-
tively show her level of skills to a potential
tistics from 33 countries in the region, found
employer
that the private sector currently accounts for
about 35 percent of formal TVET enrollment 2. Imperfections in credit markets, whereby it is
(Mingat, Ledoux, and Rakotomalala 2010). hard to get financing to pay for training
Compared with public institutes, private 3. Coordination failures, occurring, for exam-
training providers tend to focus on light ple, when workers and firms need to make
vocational skills such as business, commercial, investments, but those investments pay off
and service skills, possibly owing to the high only if both parties invest, which can lead to
fixed costs of providing more industry-oriented neither side making the first move
sorts of skills. Private providers in Uganda, for 4. Limited information at the individual level,
instance, focus on office qualifications and var- which can lead to too little or too much
ious business skills that require only a limited investment in particular types of skills
investment (Haan 2001). Private providers also development
tend to be concentrated in specific regions
Skills for Productive Employment 95

Box 3.7

On-the-job training varies by country and type of firm, and it is not for everyone
In the United States, one-quarter to half of human capital between 15 and 30 percent in most countries, but in some
accumulation occurs through on-the-job training (Heck- (such as Botswana, Malawi, and Rwanda), the incidence is as
man, Lochner, and Taber 1998). Even in developing countries high as 50 percent.
(including African countries), many firms provide training to Variations in the rates of on-the-job training across
their workers. Estimates from the World Banks enterprise Africa do not appear to be related to per capita income
surveys indicate that, on average, about 30 percent of formal levels. Since firm surveys tend to focus on formal, officially
firms in Africa provide training (figure B3.7.1), only slightly registered firms and often miss unregistered firms, some
below the average for low- and middle-income countries. of the variation might arise from differences in the share
In Africa, the percentage of firms training workers varies of firms that are registered. In most countries around the
world, the incidence of training in firms is strongly related
Figure B3.7.1 On-the-job training in African firms varies to firm characteristics such as size and export orientation.
by country Smaller firms are less likely to provide formal training to
employees. So are nonexporters. This pattern is borne out
Congo, in Africa as well (figure B3.7.2). Thus African countries with
Dem. Rep.
Liberia larger, more outwardly oriented firms may have more on-
Eritrea
the-job training.

Niger
Central African Figure B3.7.2 On-the-job training in African firms varies
Republic by firm size and export orientation, 2006
Sierra Leone
Malawi 80
% firms offering formal training

Madagascar
60
Togo
Mali
40
Burkina Faso
Rwanda
20
Chad
Lesotho
0
Benin All Exporter Non- Large Medium Small
Cte dIvoire exporter (100+) (2099) (519)

Cameroon Firms
Cape Verde Source: World Bank enterprise surveys (average for African countries sur-
veyed in 2006).
Congo, Rep.
Angola
Mauritius
Firms providing on-the-job training do not train all of
their workers. As figure B3.7.2 suggests, African firms that
Botswana
provide on-the-job training rarely provide it to more than
Gabon half of the workforce, perhaps because levels of education
Sub-Saharan are low. As in the rest of the world, in Africa workers with
Africa
All more education and skills are much more likely to receive
formal training on the job. A 1980 survey of formal train-
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 ing in enterprises in Dar es Salaam, Tanzania, and Nairobi,
Percent
Kenya, found that unskilled and semi-skilled manual workers
Workers offered formal training Firms offering formal training are significantly less likely to have received formal training
Source: Based on World Bank enterprise surveys. from their current employer than skilled production, cleri-
Note: Countries ordered by GDP per capita.

(continued)
96 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box 3.7

(continued)

cal, and supervisory workers (De Beyer 1990). Surveys con- partly specific to their current firm. On-the-job training is also
ducted in Kenya and Zambia in 1995 found that workers specific to the technology used in the firm.
with no formal education do not receive on-the-job training The typical worker is more likely to get training through
(Rosholm, Nielsen, and Dabalen 2007). on-the-job learning than from classroom training paid for by
There are scarce data on the content of on-the-job train- employers. Firm surveys in Kenya and Zambia found that,
ing in African firms or on how it may differ from the training in the 12 months prior to the survey, the most common
that a young job seeker might receive at a training institute. forms of learning among employees were instructions from
It is likely that the content of on-the-job training has an ele- a supervisor or coworker and watching others or learn-
ment of firm-specificity. In Dar es Salaam workers who had ing on your own (Rosholm, Nielsen, and Dabalen 2007).
previously been in another firm were almost as likely to get Courses paid for by the employer were less common and
formal on-the-job training as those who were on their first about as likely as training at a school or technical or voca-
job (De Beyer 1990), suggesting that the training was at least tional institute.

These various forms of market failure pro- Existing forms of training are not equally
vide general rationales for government inter- available to everyone (figure 3.22). Patterns
vention, but their prevalence needs to be care- of training across income groups suggest that
fully assessed in specific country contexts. They financial constraints reduce access to training
also provide guidance as to the range of activi- among the poorest households. Among youth
ties that the public sector might want to sup- from households in the top income quintile,
port. For example, credit constraints may pro- 11 percent have ever enrolled in TVET and 2.7
vide a rationale for policies to improve access to percent are currently enrolled. By contrast, in
training. Limited or inaccurate information at the bottom income quintile, only 1.6 percent
the individual level has also led to underinvest- have ever enrolled in TVET and 0.1 percent are
ment in training or suboptimal choice of train- currently enrolled. This inequality in access to
ing and can provide a case for public interven- training holds not only for formal vocational
tion. Governments need to recognize that there training but also for informal apprenticeships:
is a market for training and avoid introducing 25 percent of youth in the top quintile have
undue distortions in this market. Overall, there taken an apprenticeship and 7.6 percent are
are two broad areas for government interven- currently in an apprenticeship, compared with
tion: (1) providing information and facilitat- 7.3 and 2.5 percent, respectively, of youth in the
ing access to training and (2) intervening to bottom quintile.
ensure the availability of better-quality train- Women also have limited access to train-
ing options. Those two areas are discussed next. ing opportunities, and when they do receive
training, it often focuses on a limited range of
Facilitating Access to Training occupations. Women are less likely than men
Public policy should facilitate access to existing to be enrolled in formal TVET or apprentice-
training opportunities, including those avail- ships (see also Atchoarena and Delluc 2002).
able in the private market. One strategy, for Across the region, 18 percent of individuals
example, is to provide information or incen- ages 1534 have ever been an apprentice, but
tives to young people who have the least access only 12 percent of women.26 Women who
to training, starting with individuals from the manage to pursue informal technical training
poorest households, women, and individuals or apprenticeships tend to end up in heavily
in rural areas. Better provision of information concentrated sectors with limited demand,
about employment and training opportunities such as tailoring or hairdressing. In Uganda,
can start in school. 91 percent of training hours taken by females
Skills for Productive Employment 97

who were not involved in the Youth Oppor- Figure 3.22 There are stark differences between rich and poor in experience with
tunities Program were in tailoring (Blattman, apprenticeships and TVET
Fiala, and Martinez 2011). In Kenya, the most 30
popular courses for women were tailoring,
hairdressing, and computer packages, whereas 25
men preferred training to become mechanics,

Percentage of youths
20
drivers, or masons (figure 3.23).

(ages 1534)
Youths in rural areas also have less access 15
to training, since more training providers are
located in urban areas and distance to training 10
centers is a constraint for access. Across Sub-
5
Saharan Africa, 25 percent of 15- to 34-year-
olds living in an urban area have ever been an 0
apprentice, compared with only 11 percent of Currently Currently an Ever enrolled in TVET Ever an apprentice
those living in a rural area. In Kenya, women enrolled in TVET apprentice

were significantly more likely than men to cite Quintiles


1st (poorest) 2nd 3rd 4th 5th (richest)
proximity to training opportunities as a deter-
Source: Based on standardized and harmonized household and labor force surveys (see appendix).
mining factor (50 and 43 percent, respectively),
suggesting that female participants are more
geographically constrained than their male
Figure 3.23 Men and women take up different types of vocational training in Kenya
peers (Hicks et al. 2011).
In the presence of financial and other con- 60
straints on access to training, there is scope for
50
policies to facilitate access to training among
Percentage of youths

youth, particularly women and the poor. Inter- 40


(ages 1534)

ventions that provide targeted financial incen-


tives to increase participation in training have 30
been shown to help. In northern Uganda, a
20
program providing large cash grants to self-
created groups increased the proportion of 10
youth enrolled in vocational training from 15
to 74 percent, and recipients also engaged in 0
Tailoring Vehicle related Computers Beauty Business skills Other
more intensive training. Some training oppor-
tunities were already available in the commu- Male Female
nity, but the young people participating in the Source: Hicks et al. 2011.
project had not purchased much of this train-
ing before. Although youths in the program did
not havee to buy training, most chose to spend a young people vouchers worth approximately
large part of their cash grants on training prior US$460 to encourage them to enroll (Hicks
to starting a business. This finding suggests that et al. 2011). Voucher winners who were closer
programs that help to finance access to training to private schools were more likely to take up
might be effective. Among those who did not training compared to winners who were far-
get a grant (the control group), some partici- ther away. Among voucher winners, a random
pants did acquire training on their own, but it half received a voucher that could be used only
was of much shorter duration. Of the 15 per- in a public (government) vocational institu-
cent of individuals who took training without tion, while the other half received a voucher
the program, only 6 percent paid for it. that could be used in either a private or a pub-
Voucher programs can be effective when lic school.27 The broader choice and access to
recipients have the option to choose a pri- private providers increased the use of training:
vate training provider. In Kenya, the Techni- 69 percent of individuals who were awarded the
cal and Vocational Vouchers Program offered restricted vouchers attended vocational train-
98 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

ing, compared with 79 percent of individuals There might also be scope for interventions
who were awarded unrestricted vouchers. Win- that provide information on employment and
ners of unrestricted vouchers were also more training opportunities to help young people to
likely to complete training. decide which training to undertake. Research in
Voucher programs can also have an effect on Kenya has shown that young people have inac-
skill providers and stimulate the supply of train- curate perceptions about the returns to voca-
ing available. In Kenya, a large program that tional training (including misconceptions about
provided vouchers to workers in the informal which trades provide the highest earnings) and
sector (called Jua Kali) not only increased access that their perceptions have a strong gender bias
to training but also led to the emergence of new (Hicks et al. 2011). In such a context, there is a
training providers relevant for the HE sector, role for interventions to increase participation
such as master craftsmen (see box 3.8; Adams in training by providing information to better
2001; Johanson and Adams 2004). Evidence match trainees to training. In Kenya, young peo-
from a smaller-scale pilot of training vouchers ple changed their training choices after receiving
in Kenya suggests that programs or schools that information on actual labor market returns
received voucher students were significantly including differences in expected earnings for
more likely to expand their course offerings trades dominated by men (such as electrician)
(Hicks et al. 2011). Although such programs and women (such as seamstress)and viewing
have not been scaled up yet and would likely inspirational videos about successful female car
require some prior identification of eligible mechanics. In particular, the provision of infor-
providers, they have the potential to be effective, mation caused more women, especially young
given the vast diversity of existing providers. and more educated girls, to take up training in
male-dominated trades.
Such information failures have long been
recognized, but public policy has rarely been
Box 3.8 able to address the issue successfully at scale.
Many employment programs aim to improve
information on the labor market, but most
Kenyas Jua Kali voucher program focus almost exclusively on formal training
In the mid-1990s, Kenyas Jua Kali Program (Kiswahili for work under
providers and wage employment. Despite the
the hot sun) offered training vouchers to HEs operating small fabrica- lack of evidence and thorough testing of such
tion or repair workshops. Eligible participants had to pay 10 percent approaches, the cost of providing information
of the training cost and received vouchers to cover the remainder. is low and the potential for impact is high. Gov-
The vouchers produced a positive supply response, predominantly ernments could systematically disseminate and
from NGOs and master craftsmen in the informal sector. These suppli- communicate data on labor market earnings
ers developed new programs tailored to the needs of voucher recipi- or training options collected through house-
ents and offered the programs at times that suited participants work hold surveys or surveys of training providers.
schedules. Public institutions showed little interest in adapting their Schools could also provide information on
traditional programs to respond to this new source of demand (Adams
employment and training opportunities.
2001). In its pilot stage, the Jua Kali Program successfully expanded
the supply and reduced the cost of training for workers in the informal
sector. There is evidence that the training had a positive effect on par-
Intervening to Ensure Better Training
ticipants earnings and strengthened the capacity of the local Jua Kali Options
associations responsible for distributing the vouchers. When the pro- Given that governments have often stumbled
gram was scaled up, problems in governance led to high administra- in their efforts to promote skills development,
tive costs (Adams 2001; Riley and Steel 2000). Ghana offered a similar interventions to address market failures must
voucher program targeted at informal sector enterprises in the early be assessed against the risks of government
1990s, but it failed largely because of flaws related to the marketing failures in the provision of training or training
and distribution of vouchers (Johanson and Adams 2004). subsidies. Inefficiencies in public interventions
Source: Reproduced from Adams, Johanson de Silva, and Razmara 2013.
usually involve challenges in the policy-making
process, governance, and institutional arrange-
mentsespecially as they relate to accountabil-
Skills for Productive Employment 99

ityand mismatches between the rationale for Figure 3.24 Training costs and the price paid by
government intervention and the ways gov- participants vary by type of training in Kenya
ernments actually intervene (such as limited
attempts to incorporate the role of information
in an effective way). Examples of wasteful insti- Apprenticeship

tutions abound. Training is often provided in a


fragmented way by a large number of ministries
Informal skills training
with limited accountability, creating substantial
inefficiencies and distortions. Many TVET sys-
tems are inefficient and create distortions by
Faith-based institutions
subsidizing the supply of technical training of
similar or inferior quality to the types of train-
Formal
ing widely delivered by the private sector. Given post-secondary
this experience, public intervention should not TVET
only be based on a clear understanding of mar-
Formal
ket failures but also emphasize efficiency and post-secondary TVET
quality service delivery. Whenever public pro- (National Youth Service)
vision or financing is considered, the efficiency Formal
of the institutions involved and the quality of post-primary TVET
(Youth Polytechnics)
service delivered require careful attention.
Given the large number of training institu-
Youth Empowerment
tions and wide range of private providers, the Program on-the-
training available to Africas young people var- job training
ies greatly in price and quality. In the presence 0 500 1,000 1,500 2,000 2,500
of active training markets, public interventions Cost (US$)
need to be selective, performance driven, and
Cost range Price range
evidence based.
Source: Franz 2011.
Note: Approximate training cost and price in U.S. dollars.
Measuring the Cost of Training
Large variations in training costs, as well as in
the share of costs borne by participants, pre- fully) cover tuition costs for both government
vail across types of trainingalthough sys- and private vocational programs (Hicks et al.
tematic data are hard to come by. Data from 2011).
Kenya, illustrated in figure 3.24, give some idea The data from Kenya reflect three patterns
of patterns in training costs.28 The data include in training costs that appear to be common in
formal TVET (postsecondary TVET, postsec- other countries:
ondary National Youth Service, and postpri-
mary youth polytechnics) as well as informal Formal TVET is very expensive. In Ghana,
training delivered through faith-based insti- the cost of TVET per pupil is about five
Even if training
tutions, private TVET providers, or appren- times the cost of primary education and
almost three times the cost of senior sec- was available for
ticeships. Training costs range from US$113
for the cheapest private TVET to US$204 for ondary education, in line with international free, it would be
apprenticeships, US$1,942 for National Youth averages, in which TVET costs range from hardly possible
Service, and US$1,704 for the most expensive two to three times the cost of secondary for me to get
private TVET. The share paid by participants education (Adams et al. 2009). In Mozam- time to attend,
ranges from all (in private TVET or appren- bique, TVET costs four times more than
lest I lose the
ticeships) to nothing (National Youth Service). secondary school (Fox et al. 2012).
little income that
The vouchers supplied in the Technical and The cost of private training varies substan-
I get daily in
Vocational Vouchers Program were approxi- tially. The median cost of private training in
mately US$460, which the program designers northern Uganda, for example, ranges from order to survive.
calculated was sufficient to fully (or almost US$24 to US$444, depending on the type Tanzania
100 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

of training (Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez more likely to have flush toilets and electricity
2011). than their public, rural, and informal counter-
Informal apprenticeship is often among the parts, but they had comparable instructional
cheaper training options. Sometimes pay- capital per student.
ment is not even required. Among Rwan- Systematic evidence on the quality of
dan owners of HEs who have been trained TVET institutions is hard to compile. Key
through apprenticeships, only 40 percent indicators of the quality of training are atten-
paid for the apprenticeship (Johanson and dance, dropout rates, and graduation rates.
Gakuba 2011). Better attendance leads to better learning
(Bjorvatn and Tungodden 2010), and high-
quality programs have fewer dropouts. Many
Measuring the Quality and providers do not track the percentage of par-
Effectiveness of Training ticipants who complete training, however;
The quality of various training providers is when data are available, it is common to find
rarely measured directly. A survey of training that 2550 percent of participants do not
providers in Kenya found few differences in complete training. Yet high dropout rates are
observable quality between public, private for- not inevitable (box 3.9).
mal, and private informal training providers The share of enrollees who graduate from
(Hicks et al. 2011). When young people were a training program (in other words, complete
offered vouchers to take vocational training, and pass the final exam) is often reported to
they had a slight preference for public train- be very low. For example, the pass rates for the
ing centers (56 percent) compared to private Malawi craft and advanced craft examinations
providers (44 percent). Instructors in public are less than 70 percent. For the trades, the pass
institutions were more likely to have taken the rate is closer to 50 percent, and it is even lower
secondary school exam and completed college, (on the order of 1020 percent) in the trades
yet the profiles of instructors in all institutions for which delivery is more complex, such as the
were similar in many respects (they had the electrical and mechanical trades (World Bank
same practical experience, for example). Dif- 2013). Moreover, the constraints facing young
ferences in infrastructure also appear limited. women tend to lead to even higher dropout
Urban and formal private institutions were rates for them (Cho et. al. 2013).

Box 3.9

Can incentives improve training quality and participation?


Beneficiary assessments consistently highlight serious issues trainees participated in a variety of contests and competi-
with the quality of training. For example, a qualitative assess- tions. All of the measures contributed to a retention rate sur-
ment of the Youth Empowerment Project in Kenya found passing 95 percent and an attendance rate of 90 percent.
that the implementation of various training modules varied Incentives to provide good-quality training can also
substantially in quality, and those variations played a key role improve attendance. In a business skills program in Tanzania,
in participants evaluation of the modules and decisions to attendance, subjective evaluations of course quality, and self-
drop out (KEPSA 2012). reported knowledge were higher when professional trainers
Dropout rates can be limited by motivating training partic- did the teaching (Berge et al. 2011). A qualitative assessment
ipants as well as providers. In Liberia, the Economic Empow- of training in life skills under the Liberia Youth Employment
erment of Adolescent Girls and Young Women (EPAG) Pro- Project found large variations in quality among community
gram used innovative strategies to ensure high participation trainers (World Bank and Republic of Liberia 2012). In the
and training quality (Word Bank 2012b). Participants signed EPAG Program, training providers were incentivized through
commitment forms, received small stipends contingent on performance bonuses, and frequent and unannounced visits
attendance, were offered free child care, and were assigned to monitor the quality of training also helped to make the
to small teams with mentors. In addition to those incentives, training program effective (World Bank 2012b)
Skills for Productive Employment 101

Box 3.10

Impact evaluation to build the evidence base on youth employment programs


Impact evaluations provide rigorous evidence of a programs Impact evaluations are often implemented at the scale
effectiveness by estimating the programs effects on final of pilots, with the result that the scalability and ultimate
outcomes, based on an estimate of the counterfactual (the affordability of the evaluated programs remain a matter of
outcomes that would have prevailed for program beneficia- debate, even when the results are positive. Moreover, it may
ries if they had not participated in the program; see Gertler not always be possible to achieve similar positive results in
et al. 2010). The hallmark of sound impact evaluations is other contexts. Despite these caveats, impact evaluations
that they ensure that the counterfactual is crediblethat provide critical information about whether a program can
the only difference between treatment and control groups is work. When scaled-up programs are evaluated rigorously,
participation in the program. the results provide evidence on their effectiveness in real-
Randomized assignment is the gold standard for impact world conditions.
evaluation. It generates fully comparable treatment and Few interventions to support young workers in Africa
comparison groups by assigning program benefits randomly have been subject to impact evaluations over the years (Bet-
(for example, by lottery) among equally eligible individuals, cherman, Olivas, and Dar 2004; Cho and Honorati 2012).
households, or communities. Impact evaluations can rely on The impacts of a small number of programs targeting the
other methods, although those methods typically require self-employed were evaluated between 2002 and 2012, and
additional (often untestable) assumptions. Most impact eval- recent studies add somewhat to this tally, but more high-
uations require baseline data as well as a solid compari- quality impact evaluations are greatly needed. Such studies
son group, and they are best designed before a program is would specifically evaluate the best ways of designing youth
implemented, to ensure that baseline data are collected and employment programs (including the best components to
valid comparison groups identified. package together), the cost-effectiveness of those programs
at scale, and their general equilibrium effects.

Another indicator of quality is the prob- evaluations are required to compare employ-
ability of securing a job after graduation. A ment outcomes among graduates to counter-
2008 study from Nigeria (Billetoft 2010), for factual employment outcomes, as well as to
example, estimates that less than 30 percent of assess cost-effectiveness by comparing mea-
polytechnic graduates secure a paid job within sured impacts to costs. Overall, the evidence
their area of competence after completing their from Africa to guide specific programs for
education. Polytechnic graduates with techni- improving skills remains thin. Building that
cal or scientific training do better, however, evidence base is an urgent priority for action
than those with more general training oriented (box 3.10).
toward white-collar jobs. A study of public Given the large array of skills training avail-
TVET graduates in Tanzania in 1996 found that able in the private sector, public financing or
only 14 percent had found work upon gradua- direct provision of training needs to be selec-
tion (Fluitman 2001). Studies in the mid-1990s tive, performance driven, and evidence based.
in Mali and Madagascar estimated employ- Governments need to have rationales for the
ment rates of 44 and 45 percent, respectively, value-added of public intervention in the mar-
one to three years after graduation (Johanson ket for skills, and they must be sure not to dis-
and Adams 2004). In Uganda, although two- place privately provided training. In addition,
thirds of TVET graduates were working, only the objectives of funding or providing training
31 percent had a permanent job (Johanson need to be clear; it is particularly important to
and Adams 2004). clarify whether such training aims to provide
Aside from tracking employment outcomes pathways to productive employment in HEs or
among graduates more systematically, impact wage employment.
102 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Conclusion: A Skills Agenda promising and worthy of public investment.


for Youth More evidence on what works in improving
employment outcomes among youth, includ-
This chapter has reviewed aspects of the skills ing careful evaluations, is clearly needed across
agenda that cut across the three sectors of the board.
employment: agriculture, HEs, and the modern Chapter 4 discusses the scope and priori-
wage sector. The most urgent policy action is to ties for skills training in the agricultural sector.
ensure that children and youths acquire foun- Traditional agricultural TVET and extension
dational skills through quality basic education. have had a mixed record. However, new models
The abysmal performance of education systems of service delivery that empower farmers and
throughout Africa results in low worker pro- allow them to choose across a range of provid-
ductivity, and the lack of foundational skills ers appear promising. These models include
prevents youths from acquiring additional participatory farmer field schools as well as
skills and reaching their full potential. It is a beneficiary-driven models to deliver extension
pressing priority to improve substantially the services, build skills, and facilitate access to
quality of schooling so that it results in actual information among young people.
learning and skills acquisition for the growing Chapter 5 reviews the evidence on the effec-
cohorts of youth who will enter the labor force tiveness of training for the HE sector. Young
in the next 10 years. Early childhood develop- people often face multiple constraints in start-
ment and nutrition must also be promoted ing a business. Programs attempting to build
actively to ensure that children are more ready one skill at a time (such as technical skills,
to learn when they enter school. business skills, or behavioral skills alone) have
Having a range of skills, beyond cognitive had limited impacts. Integrated interventions
and technical skills, matters for productive that build a range of complementary skills
employment. Behavioral and socioemotional together are more promising. Especially prom-
skills are often a neglected skill set. More atten- ising are bundled interventions that deliver
tion is required to identify and build the behav- integrated skills training along with assistance
ioral skills that contribute to productivity with accessing start-up capital. Finally, infor-
including the skills that employers demand. mal training delivered by private providers is
There is room to leverage education systems to normal in the HE sector, so there is scope for
impart behavioral skills as well as to consider governments to leverage NGOs and private
including a behavioral skills component in providers to support youth through demand-
youth employment programs. driven, performance-based models.
Skills markets are active in Africa, operat- Chapter 6 outlines specific policy recom-
ing through the private provision of appren- mendations to build skills for the modern wage
ticeships in the HE sector, on-the-job training sector. Overall, the experience with TVET has
in the modern wage sector, and other channels. been disappointing. Governments in Africa
In this context, there is a role for governments should focus on support for public goods in
to provide information to youth about training TVET, such as quality assurance and infor-
and occupational choices as well as to facilitate mation, and they should facilitate access to
greater access to existing training opportunities training for poor and disadvantaged youths.
among disadvantaged groups, such as women Post-school vocational training should only be
and the poor. provided selectively, based on careful targeting
The scope for direct government interven- and demand-driven models that link employ-
tion in the skills market is more limited. It ers and training providers. To the extent that
needs to be well motivated by clearly identify- governments support specific training options,
ing the rationale for public sector engagement, those options should emphasize portable skills
and it needs to be evidence based. Chapters 46 rather than the firm- or job-specific skills that
review the evidence for each sector and iden- employers should already have an incentive to
tify interventions and approaches that are more provide. Programs for disadvantaged youths
Skills for Productive Employment 103

that integrate training with internships show been concentrated at lower levels of education.
promisebut the challenge is to make them As Teal (2010) finds, Returns to education,
cost-effective. measured both by macro production functions
Overall, education and skills matter. The and by micro earning functions, are highest
starting point in meeting the youth employ- for those with higher levels of education. He
argues, Growth has been more closely linked to
ment challenge is to improve human capital
investment in physical capital than in education,
by providing education and allowing youths to
and this may well reflect the fact that education
acquire the skills needed for productive work. is most valuable when it is linked to technol-
At the same time, it is only the starting point. ogy which requires higher skills. See also Moll
Governments cannot solely train their way (1996); Appleton, Hoddinott, and Krishnan
to more and better jobs for youth. Policies (1999); Schultz (2004); and Lassibille and Tan
addressing the economic and business envi- (2005).
ronment have a critical role to play, and chap- 6. This categorization is only indicative, and many
ters 46 examine the relative roles of policies skills are interconnected. For instance, self-
that promote skills and those that promote the control is a behavioral skill that also builds on
business environment for the agricultural sec- cognitive ability.
tor, the HE sector, and the modern wage sector. 7. In Botswana form-two and in South Africa
grade-nine students were tested, corresponding
Notes to nine years of schooling; in Ghana form-two
1. Only in Ghana do self-employed workers with students were tested, corresponding to eight
incomplete primary education earn significantly years of schooling.
more (20 percent) than self-employed workers 8. Other studies find that differences in a range
without education. of cognitive skills explain part of the earnings.
2. Low differentials in earnings premiums can- See, for example, Glewwe (1991) in Ghana; Moll
not be explained by the recent surge in primary (1998) for computational skills in South Africa;
school enrollment and completion in Africa. Denny, Harmon, and OSullivan (2003) for
Most of that surge happened in the late 2000s, functional literacy; Boissiere, Knight, and Sabot
when the cohorts benefiting from increased (1985) in Kenya and Tanzania; Heckman and
enrollment had not reached the labor force. Vytlacil (2000) in the United States; or Azam,
3. In Ghana, the mean wage for workers with Chin, and Prakash (2010) in India.
incomplete primary schooling was lower than 9. Ozier (2010) is based on the fact that in Kenya
the mean wage of workers without any edu- the probability of admission to a government
cation, but the difference was not statistically secondary school rises sharply at a score close
significant. to the national mean on a standardized eighth-
4. The general patterns for earnings increments grade examination. The causal effect of school-
hold for both men and women, as well as across ing is estimated by comparing those who score
urban and rural areas. In Rwanda, Tanzania, and just below the national mean to those who score
Uganda, earnings differentials tend on average just above it.
to be higher and steeper for women. In Rwanda 10. See www.sdindicators.org.
and Uganda, earnings differentials are higher in 11. For Madagascar, see Fernald et al. (2011); for
urban areas, while in Ghana and Tanzania, dif- Mozambique, see Naudeau et al. (2010); for
ferentials are higher in rural areas. other parts of the world, see Paxson and Schady
5. See Aromolaran (2006); Rankin, Sandefur, and (2007); Case, Lubotsky, and Paxson (2002).
Teal (2010). For example, Rankin, Sandefur, and 12. Walker et al. (2007); Engle et al. (2007). See also
Teal (2010) find clear evidence of convexity in the Maternal and Child Undernutrition Series
the returns to education for the self-employed of The Lancet,t http://www.thelancet.com/series/
in urban Ghana and Tanzania, along with low maternal-and-child-undernutrition.
average returns. Sderbom, Teal, and Hard- 13. For home visits, see Attanasio et al. forthcoming;
ing (2006) find convex earnings functions in Macours et al. forthcoming. For community-
both Ghana and Tanzania. They suggest that based centers, see Martinez, Naudeau, and
convexity may be part of the explanation as Pereira (2012). For preschools, see Attanasio
to how rapid expansion of education in Africa and Vera-Hernndez (2004); Behrman, Cheng,
has generated so little growth if expansion has and Todd (2004); Berlinski, Galiani, and Gertler
104 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

(2006); Berlinski, Galiani, and Manacorda individuals are willing to fund apprenticeships
(2008). because they can reap the returns to the specific
14. Based on World Bank, Lesotho skills and training if they manage to acquire the capital to
employment survey, 2011. start their own firm and replicate the technology
15. See Krauss et al. (2005), who study a sample of and business practice of the apprenticeship firm.
owners of firms employing seven persons on Apprentices are constrained only by capital from
average. All had been active for more than a year, becoming apprenticed entrepreneurs.
and half had started with less than US$1,000; 37 23. In northern Uganda, when youth groups were
percent of the firms were informal. Krauss and provided cash to pay for training as part of
her co-authors measure business success as busi- the Youth Opportunities Program, 33 percent
ness growth or number of employees. They find chose to obtain training from local artisans and
that other skills (learning orientation, autonomy 32 percent chose to obtain it from informal
orientation, competitive aggressiveness, innova- training institutions. In Nigeria, the volume
tive orientation, risk-taking orientation) are less of informal training far exceeds that of formal
strongly associated with business success than TVET. Despite being short and of varying qual-
entrepreneurial and achievement orientation. ity, informal training is in great demand (Bil-
16. Heckman, Stixrud, and Urzua (2006). The Rot- letoft 2010, 185). Kenya also has a remarkably
ter Scale measures the degree of control that large, diverse array of private training providers
individuals feel they possess over their lives. (Hicks et al. 2011; Franz 2011).
17. www.sdindicators.org. 24. Youths who did not receive cash grants chose a
18. The remainder of this discussion focuses on slightly different mix of training. Short courses
young adults ages 2534, because younger indi- on business and management (27 percent) or
viduals may still be in school, and results includ- agribusiness and farming (7 percent) were more
ing them would not reflect the apprenticeship or common.
TVET experience accurately. 25. In the statistics based on household surveys used
19. In Ghana, only 12.7 percent of students who in this chapter, for example, it is not possible to
advance beyond lower-secondary education apportion TVET enrollment between public
enroll in a TVET institution (World Bank 2009). and private providers or even to know with cer-
Low enrollment partly reflects limited capacity; tainty whether the numbers correspond to both
only 5 percent of junior secondary students public and private TVET or to public TVET
could have expected to obtain a place in a pub- alone.
lic TVET institution. If private TVET capacity 26. A recent review of training in Malawi estimates
is included, the percentage rises to 7.2 percent. that, over the past 10 years, female enrollment
In Nigeria, less than 1 percent of university in apprenticeships was 2135 percent of male
enrollment is in a technical college and about enrollment (World Bank 2013).
20 percent is in a more advanced polytechnic 27. While the program was mainly for industrial
(World Bank 2011b). Rwandas vocational train- courses, it also allowed students to enroll in
ing centers enroll just over 10,000 trainees; of more academic courses (for example, computer
these, about 4,700 are enrolled in a public train- training) and to cover fees up to the level of the
ing centera modest number compared to the average two-year industrial course.
roughly 260,000 students enrolled at the second- 28. These costs exclude opportunity costs, which
can be large for training of long duration.
ary level (World Bank 2011a).
20. An estimated 100,000 youths are enrolled in
formal TVET, compared with 150,000 in tradi- References
tional apprenticeships (Franz 2011). Abdulai, Awudu, and Wallace E. Huffman. 2005.
21. Other studies point to similar patterns. In Nige- The Diffusion of New Agricultural Technolo-
gies: The Case of Crossbreeding Technology in
ria, it is estimated that more than half of small
Tanzania. American Journal of Agricultural Eco-
business operators acquired their skills in the nomics 87 (3): 64559.
informal sector from master craftsmen or mas-
ter trainers (Billetoft 2010). In Rwanda, 25 per- Aber, Lawrence, and Stephanie Jones. 1997. Indi-
cators of Positive Development in Early Child-
cent of HE owners report having been trained as hood: Improving Concepts and Measures. In
an apprentice (Johanson and Gakuba 2011). Indicators of Childrens Well-being,
g edited by
22. Frazer (2006) finds that apprenticeship train- Robert Hauser, Brett Brown, and William
ing increases an individuals productivity in Prosser, 395427. New York: Russell Sage
the current firm but not in any other firm. Still, Foundation.
Skills for Productive Employment 105

Adams, Arvil V. 2001. Assessment of the Jua Kali tional Institute for Educational Planning (IIEP)
Pilot Voucher Program. World Bank, Washing- and the United Nations Educational, Scientific,
ton, DC. and Cultural Organization (UNESCO), Paris.
Adams, Arvil V., Sara Johansson de Silva, and Atchoarena, David, and Paul Esquieu. 2002. Pri-
Setareh Razmara. 2013. Improving Skills Develop- vate Technical and Vocational Education in Sub-
ment in the Informal Sector: Strategies for Sub- Saharan Africa: Provision Patterns and Policy
Saharan Africa. Direction in Development Series. Issues. International Institute for Educational
Washington, DC: World Bank. Planning (IIEP) and the United Nations Edu-
Adams, Arvil V., Harold Coulombe, Quentin cational, Scientific, and Cultural Organization
Wodon, and Setarah Razmara. 2009. Education, (UNESCO), Paris.
Employment, and Earnings in Ghana. In Ghana: Attanasio, Orazio, Emla Fitzsimons, Sally
Job Creation and Skills Development, Vol. 2. Grantham-McGregor, Costas Meghir, and Marta
Washington, DC: World Bank. Rubio-Codina. Forthcoming. Stimulation and
Aedo, Christian, and Ian Walker. 2012. Skills Childhood Development in Colombia: The
for the 21st Century in Latin America and the Impact of a Scalable Intervention. Institute for
Caribbean. Washington, DC: World Bank. doi: Fiscal Studies, University College, London.
10.1596/978-0-8213-8971-3. Attanasio, Orazio, and Marcos Vera-Hernndez.
AfDB (African Development Bank) and OECD 2004. Medium- and Long-Run Effects of Nutri-
(Organisation for Economic Co-operation and tion and Child Care: Evaluation of a Community
Development). 2008. African Economic Out- Nursery Program in Rural Colombia. Working
look 2008. Paris: AfDB and OECD. doi: 10.1787/ Paper EWP04/06, Institute for Fiscal Studies,
aeo-2008-en. University College, London.
Al-Samarrai, Samer, and Paul Bennell. 2007. Azam, Mehtabul, Aimee Chin, and Nishith Prakash.
Where Has All the Education Gone in Sub- 2010. The Returns to English-Language Skills in
Saharan Africa? Employment and Other Out- India. IZA Discussion Paper 4802, Institute for
comes among Secondary School and University the Study of Labor, Bonn.
Leavers. Journal of Development Studiess 43 (7): Bandiera, Oriana, Robin Burgess, Narayam Das,
1270300. Selim Gulesci, Imran Rasul, and Munshi Sulai-
Almeida, Rita, Jere Behrman, and David Robalino, man. 2013. Can Basic Entrepreneurship Trans-
eds. 2012. The Right Skills for the Jobs? Rethinking form the Economic Lives of the Poor? IZA
Training Policies for Workers. Washington, DC: Discussion Paper 7386, Institute for the Study of
World Bank. Labor, Bonn.
Almlund, Mathilde, Angela Lee Duckworth, James Banerjee, Abhijit V., and Esther Duflo. 2005.
J. Heckman, and Tim Kautz. 2011. Personal- Growth Theory through the Lens of Develop-
ity Psychology and Economics. IZA Discussion ment Economics. In Handbook of Economic
Paper 5500, Institute for the Study of Labor, Growth, edited by Philippe Aghion and Steven N.
Bonn. Durlauf, 47352. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Appleton, Simon, John Hoddinott, and Pramila Behrman, Jere, Yingmei Cheng, and Petra Todd.
Krishnan. 1999. The Gender Wage Gap in Three 2004. Evaluating Preschool Programs When
African Countries. Economic Development and Length of Exposure to the Program Varies: A
Cultural Changee 47 (2): 289313. Nonparametric Approach. Review of Economics
Aromolaran, Adebayo B. 2006. Estimates of and Statistics 86 (1): 10832.
Mincerian Returns to Schooling in Nigeria. Berge, Lars Ivar Oppedal, Kjetil Bjorvatn, and
Oxford Development Studiess 34 (2): 26592. Bertil Tungodden. 2011. Human and Financial
Aslam, Monazza, and Kim Lehrer. 2012. Learn- Capital for Microenterprise Development: Evi-
ing by Doing: Skills and Jobs in Urban Ghana. dence from a Field and Lab Experiment. NHH
CSAE Working Paper 2012-15, Centre for the Department of Economics Discussion Paper
Study of African Economies (CSAE), Oxford. 1/2011, Chr. Michelsen Institute (CMI), Bergen.
Atchoarena, David, and Andre Delluc. 2001. Revis- Berlinski, Samuel, Sebastian Galiani, and Paul
iting Technical and Vocational Education in Gertler. 2006. The Effect of Pre-Primary Educa-
Sub-Saharan Africa. Report for the World Bank, tion on Primary School Performance. Working
International Institute for Educational Planning, Paper WP06/04, Institute for Fiscal Studies, Uni-
Paris. versity College, London.
. 2002. Revisiting Technical and Vocational Berlinski, Samuel, Sebastian Galiani, and Marco
Education in Sub-Saharan Africa: An Update on Manacorda. 2008. Giving Children a Better Start
Trends, Innovations, and Challenges. Interna- in Life: Preschool Attendance and School-Age
106 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Profiles. Journal of Public Economics 92 (56): Financial Education and Behavior Formation:
141640. Large-Scale Experimental Evidence from Brazil.
Besley, Timothy, and Anne Case. 1993. Modeling World Bank, Washington, DC.
Technology Adoption in Developing Countries. Bruns, Barbara, Deon Filmer, and Harry Anthony
American Economic Revieww 83 (2): 396402. Patrinos. 2011. Making Schools Work: New Evi-
Betcherman, Gordon, Karina Olivas, and Amit Dar. dence on Accountability Reforms.
2004. Active Labor Market Programs: New Evi- Washington, DC: World Bank. doi:
dence from Evaluations with Particular Attention 10.1596/978-0-8213-8679-8.
to Developing and Transition Countries. Social Card, David. 1999. The Causal Effect of Education
Protection Discussion Paper 04012, World Bank, on Earnings. In Handbook of Labor Economics,
Washington, DC. Vol. 3, edited by Orley Ashenfelter and David
Biggs, Tyler, Manju Shah, and Pradeep Srivastava. Card, 180259. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
1995. Technological Capabilities and Learn-
Carneiro, Pedro, Emanuela Galasso, and Rita Ginja.
ing in African Enterprises. Technical Paper 288,
2010. The Impact of Providing Psycho-Social
World Bank, Washington, DC.
Support to Indigent Families and Increasing
Bigsten, Arne, Anders Isaksson, Mans Soderbom, Their Access to Social Services: Evaluating Chile
Paul Collier, Albert Zeufack, Stefan Dercon, Mar- Solidario. Evaluation report, University College,
cel Fafchamps, and Jan Willem. 2000. Rates of London.
Return on Physical and Human Capital in Afri-
cas Manufacturing Sector. Economic Develop- Case, Anne, Darren Lubotsky, and Christina Pax-
ment and Cultural Changee 48 (4): 80127. son. 2002. Economic Status and Health in
Childhood: The Origins of the Gradient. Ameri-
Billetoft, Jorgen. 2010. Labor Market Trends and can Economic Review
w 92 (5): 130834.
Skills Development. In Putting Nigeria to Work:
A Strategy for Employment and Growth, edited Cho, Yoonyoung, and Maddalena Honorati. 2012.
by Volker Treichel, 167202. Washington, DC: Entrepreneurship Programs in Developing
World Bank. Countries: A Meta Regression Analysis. Policy
Research Working Paper 6202, World Bank,
Bjorvatn, Kjetil, and Bertil Tungodden. 2010.
Teaching Business in Tanzania: Evaluating Par- Washington, DC.
ticipation and Performance. Journal of the Euro- Cho, Yoonyoung, Davie Kalomba, Ahmed Mushfiq,
pean Economic Association 8 (23): 56170. and Victor Orozco. 2013. Gender Differences in
Blattman, Christopher, Nathan Fiala, and Sebastian the Effects of Vocational Training: Constraints
Martinez. 2011. Can Employment Programs on Women and Drop-Out Behavior. Policy
Reduce Poverty and Social Instability? Experi- Research Working Paper 6545, World Bank,
mental Evidence from a Ugandan Aid Program. Washington, DC.
Columbia University, New York. Clemens, Michael. 2004. The Long Walk to School:
Boesel, David, Nabeel Alsalam, and Thomas M. International Education Goals in Historical Per-
Smith. 1998. Research Synthesis: Education and spective. CGD Working Paper 37, Center for
Labor Market Performance of GED Recipients. Global Development, Washington, DC.
Washington, DC: U.S. Department of Education, Cloutier, Marie-Hlne, C. Reinstadtler, and Isa-
January. bel Beltran. 2011. Making the Grade: Assessing
Boissiere, M., J. B. Knight, and R. H. Sabot. 1985. Literacy and Numeracy in African Countries.
Earnings, Schooling, Ability, and Cogni- DIME Brief, World Bank, Washington, DC.
tive Skills. American Economic Review w 75 (5): http://go.worldbank.org/15Y7VXO7B0.
101630.
Cobb-Clark, Deborah A., and Michelle Tan. 2010.
Boone, Peter, Ila Fazzio, Kameshwari Jandhyala, Noncognitive skills, occupational attainment,
Chitra Jayanty, Gangadhar Jayanty, Simon and relative wages Labour Economics 18 (1):
Johnson, Vimala Ramachandrin, Filipa Silva, 123.
and Zhaoguo Zhan. 2013. The Surprisingly
Dire Situation of Childrens Education in Rural Cojocaru, Alexandru. 2011. Tanzania: Skills and the
West Africa: Results from the CREO Study in Informal Sector. World Bank, Washington, DC.
Guinea-Bissau (Comprehensive Review of Edu- CREATE (Consortium for Research on Educational
cation Outcomes). NBER Working Paper 18971, Access, Transitions, and Equity). 2010. Com-
National Bureau of Economic Research, Cam- plementary Education and Access to Primary
bridge, MA. Schooling in Northern Ghana. CREATE Ghana
Bruhn, Miriam, Luciana de Souza Leo, Arianna Policy Brief 2, September. http://www.create-rpc.
Legovini, Rogelio Marchetti, and Bilal Zia. 2013. org/pdf_documents/Ghana_Policy_Brief_2.pdf.
Skills for Productive Employment 107

Cunha, Flavio, and James Heckman. 2007. The Experiment in Ghana. CSAE Working Paper
Technology of Skill Formation. American Eco- 2011-11, Centre for the Study of African Econo-
nomic Revieww 97 (2): 3147. mies, Oxford.
Darvas, Peter. 2012. Demand and Supply of Tech- Fafchamps, Marcel, and Christopher Woodruff.
nical and Vocational Skills in Ghana. World 2012. Identifying and Relaxing Constraints to
Bank, Washington, DC. Employment Generation in Small-Scale African
De Beyer, Joy. 1990. The Incidence and Impact on Enterprises. University of Oxford.
Earnings of Formal Training Provided by Enter- Fasih, Tazeen, Geeta Kingdon, Harry Anthony
prises in Kenya and Tanzania. Economics of Edu- Patrinos, Chris Sakellariou, and Mans Soderbom.
cation Review 9 (4): 32130. 2012. Heterogeneous Returns to Education in
the Labor Market. Policy Research Working
Delors, Jacques. 1996. Learning: The Treasure
Paper 6170, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Within. Report to UNESCO of the International
Commission on Education for the Twenty-first Fernald, Lia C. H., Ann Weber, Emanuela Galasso,
Century. Paris: United Nations Educational, Sci- and Lisy Ratsifandrihamanana. 2011. Socioeco-
entific, and Cultural Organization. nomic Gradients and Child Development in a Very
Low Income Population: Evidence from Madagas-
Denny, Kevin J., Colm P. Harmon, and Vincent
car. Developmental Science 14 (4): 83247.
OSullivan. 2003. Functional Literacy, Edu-
cational Attainment, and Earnings: A Multi- Fletcher, Jason M. 2012. The Effects of Personality
Country Comparison. School of Economics, Traits on Adult Labor Market Outcomes: Evi-
University College, Dublin. dence from Siblings. IZA Discussion Paper 6391,
Institute for the Study of Labor, Bonn.
DeStefano, Joseph, Audrey-Marie Schuh Moore,
David Balwanz, and Ash Harwell. 2006. Meet- Fluitman, Fred. 2001. Working, But Not Well:
ing EFA: Reaching the Underserved through Notes on the Nature and Extent of Employment
Complementary Models of Effective Schooling. Problems in Sub-Sahara Africa. ITC Occasional
EQUIP 2 Working Paper, U.S. Agency for Inter- Paper, International Training Centre, Interna-
national Development and Academy for Educa- tional Labour Organization, Turin.
tion Development, Washington, DC. Foster, Andrew D., and Mark R. Rosenzweig. 1995.
De Wolf, Stefan, Yves Rolland Rakotoarisoa, Lau- Learning by Doing and Learning from Others:
rence Vanpaeschen, and Honor Rabekoto. 2008. Human Capital and Technical Change in Agri-
Madagascar: Le Grand Livre des Petits Mtiers: culture. Journal of Political Economyy 103 (6):
Portraits of Daily Life Professions. Belgium: Snoek 1176209.
Publishers. . 2010. Microeconomics of Technology
DFID (Department for International Develop- Adoption. Yale University, Economic Growth
ment, UK). 2012. School for Life Literacy for Center, New Haven, CT.
Change. DFID Annual Review w (December). Fox, Louise, Lucrecia Santibaez, Vy Nguyen,
Duflo, Esther. 2001. Schooling and Labor Market and Pierre Andr. 2012. Education Reform in
Consequences of School Construction in Indone- Mozambique: Lessons and Challenges. World
sia: Evidence from an Unusual Policy Experiment. Bank, Washington, DC.
American Economic Review w 91 (4): 795813. Franz, Jutta. 2011. Realizing the Youth Dividend
Dupas, Pascaline, and Jonathan Robinson. 2013. in Kenya through Skills for the Informal Sector:
Savings Constraints and Microenterprise Devel- Institutional Assessment of Skills Development
opment: Evidence from a Field Experiment in and Youth Employment Promotion Programmes
Kenya. American Economic Journal: Applied Eco- and Projects. World Bank, Washington, DC.
nomicss 5 (1): 16392. Frazer, Garth. 2006. Learning the Masters Trade:
Engle, Patrice, Maureen Black, Jere Behrman, Apprenticeship and Human Capital in Ghana.
Meena Cabral de Mello, Paul Gertler, Lydia Journal of Development Economicss 81 (2): 25998.
Kapiriri, Reynaldo Martorell, Mary Young, and Frese, Michael, Stephanie I. Krauss, Nina Keith,
the International Child Development Steer- Susanne Escher, Rafal Grabarkiewicz, Siv Tonje,
ing Group. 2007. Strategies to Avoid the Loss T. Luneng, Constanze Heers, Jens Unger, and
of Developmental Potential in More Than 200 Christian Friedrich. 2007. Business Owners
Million Children in the Developing World. The Action Planning and Its Relationship to Business
Lancet 369 (9557): 22942. Success in Three African Countries. Journal of
Fafchamps, Marcel, David McKenzie, Simon Applied Psychologyy 92 (6): 148198.
Quinn, and Christopher Woodruff. 2011. When FXB Center for Health and Human Rights. 2012.
Is Capital Enough to Get Female Microenter- Building Youth Readiness: An Integrated
prises Growing? Evidence from a Randomized Approach to Promoting Healthy Functioning
108 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

among War-Affected Youth in Sierra Leone. Haan, Hans Christian, and Nicholas Serrire. 2002.
Harvard University, Cambridge, MA. Training for Work in the Informal Sector: Fresh
Evidence from West and Central Africa. Inter-
Gertler, Paul, James Heckman, Rodrigo Pinto,
national Training Centre, International Labor
Arianna Zanolini, Christel Vermeersch, Susan
Organization, Turin.
Walker, Susan M. Chang, and Sally Grantham-
McGregor. 2013. Labor Market Returns to Early Hanushek, Eric A., and Ludger Woessmann. 2012.
Childhood Stimulation: A 20-Year Follow-up to Do Better Schools Lead to More Growth?
an Experimental Intervention in Jamaica. NBER Cognitive Skills, Economic Outcomes, and
Working Paper 19185, National Bureau of Eco- Causation. Journal of Economic Growth 17 (4):
nomic Research Cambridge, MA. 267321.
Gertler, Paul, Sebastian Martinez, Patrick Premand, Heckman, J., L. Lochner, and J. Taber. 1998.
Laura B. Rawlings, and Christel M. J. Vermeersch. Explaining Rising Wage Inequality: Explora-
2010. Impact Evaluation in Practice. Washington, tions with a Dynamic General Equilibrium
DC: World Bank. Model of Earnings with Heterogeneous Agents.
Review of Economic Dynamics 1 (1): 158.
Glaub, Matthias E. 2009. Training Personal Initiative
to Business Owners in Developing Countries: A Heckman, James A., Jora Stixrud, and Sergio Urzua.
Theoretically Derived Intervention and Its Evalu- 2006. The Effects of Cognitive and Noncogni-
ation. Ph.D. thesis, Justus-Liebig University, tive Abilities on Labor Market Outcomes and
Social Behavior. Journal of Labor Economicss 24
Giessen.
(3): 41182.
Glewwe, Paul. 1991. Schooling, Skills, and the
Heckman, James, and Edward Vytlacil. 2000. Iden-
Returns to Government Investment in Educa-
tifying the Role of Cognitive Ability in Explain-
tion: An Exploration Using Data from Ghana.
ing the Level of and Change in the Return to
Living Standards Measurement LSM76, World Schooling. Review of Economics and Statisticss 83
Bank, Washington, DC. (1): 112.
. 2002. Schools and Skills in Developing Helmers, Christian, and Manasa Patnam. 2011.
Countries: Education Policies and Socioeco- The Formation and Evolution of Childhood
nomic Outcomes. Journal of Economic Literature Skill Acquisition: Evidence from India. Journal
40 (2): 43682. of Development Economics 95 (2): 25266.
Glewwe, Paul, Qiuqiong Huang, and Albert Park. Hicks, Joan Hamory, Michael Kremer, Isaac Mbit,
2011. Cognitive Skills, Non-Cognitive Skills, and Edward Miguel. 2011. Vocational Education
and the Employment and Wages of Young Adults Voucher Delivery and Labor Market Returns: A
in Rural China. Paper presented at the annual Randomized Evaluation among Kenyan Youth.
meeting of the Agricultural and Applied Eco- Report for Spanish Impact Evaluation Fund
nomics Association, July 2426, Pittsburgh. (SIEF) Phase II, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Gove, Amber, and Peter Cvelich. 2010. Early Read- Huffman, Wallace E. 1977. Allocative Efficiency:
ing: Igniting Education for All: A Report by the The Role of Human Capital. Quarterly Journal
Early Grade Learning Community of Practice. of Economicss 91 (February): 5979.
Research Triangle Institute, Research Triangle Hungi, Njora, Demus Makuwa, Kenneth Ross,
Park, NC. Mioko Saito, Stphanie Dolata, Frank van Cap-
Grantham-McGregor, Sally, Yin Bun Cheung, San- pelle, Laura Paviot, and Jocelyne Vellien. 2010.
tiago Cueto, Paul Glewwe, Linda Richter, and SACMEQ III Project Results: Pupil Achieve-
Barbara Strupp. 2007. Developmental Potential ment Levels in Reading and Mathematics.
in the First Five Years for Children in Developing Working Document 1, Southern Africa Con-
Countries. The Lancet 369 (9555): 6070. sortium for Measuring Educational Quality
(SACMEQ), Harare. http://www.sacmeq.org/
Groh, Matthew, Nandini Krishnan, David McKen-
downloads/sacmeqIII/WD01_SACMEQ_III_
zie, and Tara Vishwanath. 2012. Soft Skills or Results_Pupil_Achievement.pdf.
Hard Cash? The Impact of Training and Wage
Subsidy Programs on Female Youth Employment Johanson, Richard K., and Avril V. Adams. 2004.
in Jordan. Policy Research Working Paper 6141, Skills Development in Sub-Saharan Africa. Wash-
World Bank, Washington, DC. ington, DC: World Bank.
Haan, Hans Christian. 2001. Training for Work in Johanson, Richard, and Theogene Kayiranga
the Informal Sector: Fresh Evidence from East- Gakuba. 2011. Rwanda: Training for the Infor-
ern and Southern Africa. International Train- mal Sector. World Bank, Washington, DC.
ing Centre, International Labour Organization, KEPSA (Kenya Private Sector Alliance). 2012. Ben-
Turin. eficiary Assessment of Kenya Youth Empower-
Skills for Productive Employment 109

ment Project (KYEP) Training and Internship Mano, Yukichi, Alhassan Iddrisu, Yutaka Yoshino,
Component. KEPSA, March. and Tetsushi Sonobe. 2011. How Can Micro and
Kitaev, Igor, with contributions from J. Glover, A. Small Enterprises in Sub-Saharan Africa Become
More Productive? The Impacts of Experimental
Melomey, Th. Coleman, and B. Kaluba. 2003.
Basic Managerial Training. World Development
Phase II: Synthesis of Main Findings from Two
40(3):45868.
Case Studies Carried out in Ghana and Zambia
on Private Technical and Vocational Education Martinez, Sebastian, Sophie Naudeau, and Victor
and Training (TVET). International Institute Pereira. 2012. The Promise of Preschool in
for Educational Planning (IIEP) and UNESCO, Africa: A Randomized Impact Evaluation of
Paris. Early Childhood Development in Rural Mozam-
bique. World Bank and Save the Children,
Koop, Sabine, Tamara De Reu, and Michael Frese. Washington, DC.
2000. Sociodemographic Factors, Entrepreneur-
ial Orientation, Personal Initiative, and Envi- Mattero, Minna. 2010. Second Chance Education
ronmental Problems in Uganda. In Success and for Out-of-School Youth: A Conceptual Frame-
Failure of Microbusiness Owners in Africa: A Psy- work and Review of Programs. World Bank,
chological Approach, edited by M. Frese, 5576. Washington, DC.
Westport, CT: Quorum. Mingat, Alain, Blandine Ledoux, and Ramahatra
Krauss, Stefanie I., Michael Frese, Christian Fried- Rakotomalala. 2010. Developing Post-Primary
rich, and Jens M. Unger. 2005. Entrepreneurial Education in Sub-Saharan Africa: Assessing the
Orientation: A Psychological Model of Success Financial Sustainability of Alternative Pathways.
among Southern African Small Business Own- Washington, DC: World Bank.
ers. European Journal of Work and Organiza- Moll, Peter G. 1996. The Collapse of Primary
tional Psychology 14 (3): 31544. Schooling Returns in South Africa, 196090.
Kuepie, Mathias, Christophe J. Nordman, and Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statisticss 58 (1):
185209.
Francois Roubaud. 2009. Education and Earn-
ings in Urban West Africa. Journal of Compara- . 1998. Primary Schooling, Cognitive Skills,
tive Economicss 37 (3): 491515. and Wages in South Africa. Economica 65 (258):
26384.
Lassibille, Gerard, and Jee-Peng Tan. 2005. The
Returns to Education in Rwanda. Journal of Monk, Courtney, Justin Sandefur, and Francis Teal.
African Economiess 14 (1): 92116. 2008. Does Doing an Apprenticeship Pay Off?
Evidence from Ghana. CSAE Working Paper
Lee, Jean N., and David Newhouse. 2012. Cogni-
2008-08, Centre for the Study of African Econo-
tive Skills and Youth Labor Market Outcomes. mies, Oxford.
Background paper for World Development Report
2013: Jobs. World Bank, Washington, DC. Mullis, Ina V.S., Michael O. Martin, Pierre Foy,
and Alka Arora. 2012. TIMSS 2011 International
Lundberg, Mattias, and Alice Wuermli, eds. 2012. Results in Mathematics. TIMSS & PIRLS Inter-
Children and Youth in Crisis: Protecting and Pro- national Study Center, Lynch School of Educa-
moting Human Development in Times of Eco- tion, Boston College, Chestnut Hill, MA, and
nomic Shocks. Washington, DC: World Bank. doi: International Association for the Evaluation of
10.1596/978-0-8213-9547-9. Educational Achievement (IEA) IEA Secretariat,
Macours, Karen, Patrick Premand, Norbert Schady, Amsterdam, the Netherlands.
and Renos Vakis. Forthcoming. Experimental Naudeau, Sophie, Sebastian Martinez, Patrick Pre-
Evidence from an Early Childhood Parenting mand, and Deon Filmer. 2010. Cognitive Devel-
Intervention in Nicaragua. World Bank, Wash- opment among Young Children in Developing
ington, DC. Countries. In No Small Matter: The Impact of
Macours, Karen, Patrick Premand, and Renos Vakis. Poverty, Shocks, and Human Capital Investment in
2013. Demand Versus Returns? Pro-Poor Tar- Early Childhood Development,
t edited by Harold
geting of Business Grants and Vocational Skills Alderman, 950. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Training. Policy Research Working Paper 6389, Nayar, Reema, Pablo Gottret, Mitra Pradeep, Gor-
World Bank, Washington, DC. don Betcherman, Yue Man Lee, Indhira Santos,
Maluccio, John A., John Hoddinott, Jere R. Mahesh Dahal, and Maheshwor Shrestha. 2012.
Behrman, Reynaldo Martorell, Agnes R. More and Better Jobs in South Asia. South
Quisumbing, and Aryeh D. Stein. 2009. The Asia Development Matters Report 66229, World
Impact of Improving Nutrition during Early Bank, Washington, DC.
Childhood on Education among Guatemalan Nell, Marian, and Janet Shapiro. 1999. Traditional
Adults. Economic Journall 119 (537): 73463. Apprenticeship Practice in Dar es Salaam: A
110 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Study. Consultancy report prepared for GTZ/ sion Paper 6512, Institute for the Study of Labor,
VETA, GTZ/VETA, Dar es Salaam. Bonn.
Nicholson, Sue. 2006. Accelerated Learning Pro- Rosholm, Michael, Helena Skyt Nielsen, and
grams in Post Conflict Settings: A Discussion Andrew Dabalen. 2007. Evaluation of Training
Paper. Save the Children US, Westport, CT. in African Enterprises. Journal of Development
Oosterbeek, Hessel, Mirjam van Praag, and Auke Economicss 84 (1): 31029.
Ijsselstein. 2008. The Impact of Entrepreneur- Schultz, T. Paul. 2004. Evidence of Returns to
ship Education on Entrepreneurship Competen- Schooling in Africa from Household Surveys:
cies and Intentions: An Evaluation of the Junior Monitoring and Restructuring the Market for
Achievement Student Mini-Company Program. Education. Journal of African Economiess 13
IZA Discussion Paper 3641, Institute for the (supplement 2): ii95148.
Study of Labor, Bonn. Shaorshadze, Irina, and Pramila Krishnan. 2013.
Ozier, Owen. 2010. The Impact of Secondary Technical and Vocational Education and Train-
Schooling in Kenya: A Regression Discontinuity ing in Ethiopia. Working Paper, International
Analysis. Development Research Group, World Growth Centre, London School of Economics,
Bank, Washington, DC. February.
Paxson, Christina, and Norbert Schady. 2007. Cog- Shonkoff, Jack P., and Deborah Phillips, eds. 2000.
nitive Development among Young Children From Neurons to Neighborhoods: The Science of
in Ecuador: The Roles of Wealth, Health, and Early Childhood Development. Washington, DC:
Parenting. Journal of Human Resourcess 42 (1): National Academy Press.
4984. Sderbom, Mns, Francis Teal, and Alan Harding.
Peeters, Pia, Wendy Cunningham, Gayatri Acharya, 2006. The Determinants of Survival among
and Arvil Van Adams. 2009. Youth Employment African Manufacturing Firms. Economic Devel-
in Sierra Leone: Sustainable Livelihood Oppor- opment and Cultural Changee 54 (3): 53355.
tunities in a Post-Conflict Setting. World Bank, South Sudan, Government of, Ministry of General
Washington, DC. Education and Instruction. 2011. Education Sta-
Premand, Patrick, Stefanie Brodmann, Rita tistics for the Republic of South Sudan: National
Almeida, Rebekka Grun, and Mahdi Barouni. Statistical Booklet, 2011. Juba.
2012. Entrepreneurship Training and Self- Steinberg, Laurence, Elizabeth Cauffman, Jennifer
Employment among University Graduates: Woolard, Sandra Graham, and Marie Banich.
Evidence from a Randomized Trial in Tunisia. 2009. Are Adolescents Less Mature Than Adults?
Policy Research Working Paper 6285, World Minors Access to Abortion, the Juvenile Death
Bank, Washington, DC. Penalty, and the Alleged Apa Flip-Flop. Ameri-
Pritchett, Lant. 2013. The Rebirth of Education: can Psychologist 64 (7): 58394.
From 19th-Century Schooling to 21st-Century Teal, Francis. 2010. Higher Education and Eco-
Learning. Washington, DC: Brookings Institu- nomic Development in Africa: A Review of
tion Press. Channels and Interactions. CSAE Working
Rankin, Neil, Justin Sandefur, and Francis Teal. Paper 2010-25, Centre for the Study of African
2010. Learning and Earning in Africa: Where Economies, Oxford.
Are the Returns to Education High? CSAE Tubbs, Carly, and Dana Charles McCoy. 2012.
Working Paper 2010-02, Centre for the Study of Early Childhood Development: An Introduc-
African Economies, Oxford. tion. In Children and Youth in Crisis: Protecting
Riley, Thyra A., and William F. Steel. 2000. Kenya and Promoting Human Development in Times
Voucher Programme for Training and Business of Economic Shocks, edited by Mattias Lundberg
Development Services. In Business Development and Alice Wuermli, 10615. Washington, DC:
Services: A Review of International Experience, World Bank.
edited by Jacob Levitsky, ch. 12. London: Inter- UNESCO (United Nations Educational, Scientific
mediate Technology Publications. and Cultural Organization). 2012. EFA Global
Roberts, Brent W., and Daniel Mroczek. 2008. Per- Monitoring Report: Youth and Skills: Putting
sonality Trait Change in Adulthood. Current Education to Work. Paris: UNESCO.
Directions in Psychological Sciencee 17 (1): 3135. Unger, Jens M., Nina Keith, Christine Hilling,
Rosendahl Huber, Laura, Randolph Sloof, and Michael M. Gielnik, and Michael Frese. 2009.
Mirjam van Praag. 2012. The Effect of Early Deliberate Practice among South African Small
Entrepreneurship Education: Evidence from a Business Owners: Relationships with Education,
Randomized Field Experiment. IZA Discus- Cognitive Ability, Knowledge, and Success. Jour-
Skills for Productive Employment 111

nal of Occupational and Organizational Psychol- Country Study, Policy Note, World Bank, Wash-
ogyy 82 (1): 2144. ington, DC.
Uwezo Tanzania. 2011. Are Our Children Learn- . 2012a. Botswana: Policy Note 2: Labor
ing? Annual Learning Assessment Report. Market Signals on Demand for Skills. World
Uwezo Tanzania, Dar es Salaam. http://www. Bank, Africa Region, Human Development
uwezo.net/wp-content/uploads/2012/08/ Department, Washington, DC.
TZ_2011_AnnualAssessment-Report.pdf. . 2012b. Preliminary EPAG Midline Report:
Valdivia, Martin. 2011. Training or Technical Assis- Economic Empowerment of Adolescent Girls
tance? A Field Experiment to Learn What Works and Young Women (EPAG) Project in Liberia.
to Increase Managerial Capital for Female Micro- World Bank, Washington, DC.
entrepreneurs. Grupo de Anlisis para el Desar- . 2013. The Skills Development System in
rollo (GRADE), Lima. Malawi. World Bank, Washington, DC.
Walker, Susan P., Theodore D. Wachs, Julie Meeks . Various years. World Development Indica-
Gardner, Betsy Lozoff, Gail A. Wasserman, tors. Washington, DC: World Bank. http://wdi.
Ernesto Pollitt, and Julie A. Carter. 2007. Child worldbank.org.
Development: Risk Factors for Adverse Out-
World Bank and Republic of Liberia. 2012. Com-
comes in Developing Countries. The Lancett 369
munity Works Life Skills Training Assessment:
(9556): 14557. Youth, Employment, Skills Project Mid-Term
Welch, F. 1970. Education in Production. Journal Review. World Bank, Washington, DC.
of Political Economyy 78 (1): 3559. Wuermli, Alice, Rainer K. Silbereisen, Mattias
World Bank. 2003. World Development Report 2004: Lundberg, Michele Lamont, Jere R. Behrman,
Making Services Work for Poor People. New York: and Larry Aber. 2012. A Conceptual Frame-
Oxford University Press. work. In Children and Youth in Crisis: Protecting
and Promoting Human Development in Times
. 2009. Ghana: Job Creation and Skills Devel-
of Economic Shocks, edited by Mattias Lundberg
opment. Vol. 1: Main Report. Washington, DC:
and Alice Wuermli, 29102. Washington, DC:
World Bank.
World Bank.
. 2011a. Challenges and Options for Tech-
Xu, Lisa, and Bilal Zia. 2012. Financial Literacy
nical and Post-Basic Education in South Africa. around the World: An Overview of the Evidence
World Bank, Washington, DC. with Practical Suggestions for the Way Forward.
. 2011b. Raising Productivity and Reduc- Policy Research Working Paper 6107, World
ing the Risk of Household Enterprises. Ghana Bank, Washington, DC.
Chapter

Agriculture as a Sector of Opportunity


for Young Africans

Efforts to accelerate agricultural growth and technology, and connections through trade that
improve food security have often been sepa- spurred diversification and structural change.
rated conceptually from efforts to create jobs for Faster growth in nonagricultural sectors has
young people. This damaging compartmental- drawn enough labor out of agriculture to cause
ization, if it persists, will limit Africas ability the share of employment in agriculture to fall.
to reap the benefits of its youth dividend. Agri- Labor shifted out of agriculture because pro-
culture, already Africas largest employer, is the ductivity gains on the farm saved labor (push
most immediate means of catalyzing economic factors), and higher productivity and earnings
growth and employment for young people. To opportunities off the farm attracted labor (pull
realize this potential, farming must shift rapidly factors).1
from its present status as occupation of last resort Africa is not following that trajectory. In
and low productivity to one of technical dyna- many African countries, income generated
mism and recognized opportunity. With higher through the extraction of natural resources
priority accorded to accelerated implementation and urban construction and services has raised
of well-designed programs of public investment gross domestic product (GDP) without draw-
in agriculture, continued progress on regulatory ing significant numbers of workers out of agri-
and policy reform, and further specific measures culture. Even under optimistic assumptions,
to include young people, agriculture will absorb the cohort of young Africans now entering
the large numbers of new job seekers and offer the labor force is likely to exceed the number
meaningful work with large public and private that can be absorbed into jobs in manufactur-
benefits. ing and services (see chapter 1). Over the next
few decades, young people will continue to
Agricultureonce the predominant sector apply their energies and talents to agriculture,
in most of the worlds economieshas histori- on or near the farmstead of their birth (Proc-
cally played a lesser role as economies devel- tor and Lucchesi 2012). The critical question
oped the accumulated wealth, innovations in is how African youths and their countries can

113
114 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

benefit from agricultural employment. The US$313 billion in 2010 to US$1 trillion in 2030
answer depends on whether governments take (World Bank 2013). Food imports surged ahead
the policy and investment decisions that will of exports as recently as 2003, and they have
lift the constraints on agricultural productivity. continued to climb. The growth in imports
The reasons for Africas slow growth in agri- has been variously attributed to the failure
cultural productivity are known. Cropping sys- of agricultural production to keep up with
tems based on wheat and irrigated rice, which population growth (which is incorrect, as per
registered spectacular productivity gains in capita production has risen over this period),
South and East Asia, are not suited for most climate change, and other supply-side factors.
environments south of the Sahara. Africas Supply matters, but the fundamental point
complex agro-ecologies and highly diverse is that rapid growth in population, incomes,
production systems demand a level of original and urbanization is increasing the demand for
research comparable to that undertaken else- imported food faster than the supply of domes-
where in the world, but Africa is only begin- tically produced substitutes is growing.
ning to reverse decades of neglect and under- Rapidly growing demand creates oppor-
investment in agricultural research. It will take tunities for suppliers. For example, urbaniza-
time for the benefits to be felt in earnest. The tion could be good news for local agriculture.
effects of low productivity in African agricul- The denser patterns of settlement seen as rural
ture are also well known. Low productivity is communities grow and merge3 can reduce
partially responsible for the high food prices marketing costs for agricultural producers in
prevalent in much of Africa, where expendi- the hinterlands and raise the returns to invest-
tures on primary food products can account ments in processing raw products. Nor is
for as much as half of consumers expenditures growth in demand limited to Africas expand-
(OECD and FAO 2012). High food prices also ing domestic markets. Global food prices are
curtail competitiveness by increasing the cost at their highest point in several decades, and,
of labor. barring significant changes in policies related
In the interim and until research specific to biofuels, food prices are expected to remain
to Africas environments is available, growth high for at least the rest of the decade.
in agricultural productivity will need to come The opportunities presented by this grow-
from wider use of superior technologies that ing local and international demand for food
have worked elsewhereimproved seeds, are likely to be as varied as African agriculture
breeds, cropping methods, conservation prac- itself. On average agriculture is a sector of low
tices, and equipment. Over the past decade, labor productivity and high employment, but
more farmers across Africa have started to in reality it is exceptionally heterogeneous.
adopt such technologies,2 although not as rap- Even in developed countries, agriculture is suf-
idly as farmers in other regions. Recent invest- ficiently heterogeneous to raise questions about
ments and policy reform may catalyze more what constitutes a farm. In Africa every farm
rapid adoption, but the levels of investment, lies somewhere along wide continuums of farm
pace of implementation, and quality of pro- size, capital intensity, use of mechanical and
grams in Africa have not yet sufficed to deliver biological technology, and degree of commer-
a large shift in productivity. cialization. The first requirement for creating
good opportunities for young people in African
agriculture is to gain a detailed understanding
Agriculture: Potential of the sector by peeling back the averages to
Opportunity, Room to Grow reveal the dispersion of participants activi-
ties, command of assets, and use of skills. This
The opportunity that farming represents in task demands close, continuous attention to
Sub-Saharan Africa is clearly evident in the gender issues, given the importance of women
regions trade accounts. The value of Africas and girls in Africas agricultural labor force
food markets is projected to increase from (box 4.1).
Agriculture as a Sector of Opportunity for Young Africans 115

New opportunities for African agriculture to Box 4.1


benefit from changes in local and national mar-
kets will emerge from segments of the farming
structure that have been underdeveloped in the Women and girls: A major force within
past but now have room to grow. For example, Africas agricultural labor force
in many African capitals, rice is twice as expen-
sive as it is in Asian exporting countries. The African women and girls work in agriculture as farmers on their own
price of maize, the main food staple in Eastern land, as unpaid workers on family farms, and as paid laborers on
other farms and in agricultural enterprises. They are involved in both
and Southern Africa, is 3040 percent above
crop and livestock production at subsistence and commercial levels.
export prices in South Africa, the United States,
Across developing countries, women comprise 43 percent of the
and the Black Sea region (table 4.1). If local agricultural labor force, on average; this figure ranges from around
producers become more competitive, they can 20 percent in Latin America to 50 percent in parts of Africa and Asia.
capture thriving domestic and regional mar- Some Sub-Saharan African countries have seen womens share of the
kets. Measures that reduce the costs of produc- agricultural labor force rise significantly in recent decades due to con-
tion (such as the dissemination of improved flict, the human immunodeficiency virus/acquired immune deficiency
technology) and marketing (such as invest- syndrome (HIV/AIDS), migration, and livelihood diversification, but
ments in transportation and infrastructure) regional data conceal wide differences. The share of women in the
can increase profitability and reduce food costs. agricultural labor force ranges from 36 percent in Cte dIvoire and
Even in countries that are relatively well linked Niger to more than 60 percent in Lesotho, Mozambique, and Sierra
Leone (FAO 2011). Nevertheless, one regional trend is clearit is usu-
to world markets, increased local production
ally the male member of the agricultural household who moves into a
can lower food prices, because international
nonfarm activity first (Fox and Sohnesen 2012).
prices do not translate directly into local mar-
ket prices (Minot 2011). Lower food prices not
only help consumers but also temper demands
for higher wages in the nonfarm sector, which How countries choose to increase agricul-
attracts new investment in manufacturing and tural productivity will influence whether this
services. New investment creates new jobs, fuel- virtuous cycle is sustained, with benefits to
ing a virtuous cycle (box 4.2). young people and the economy as a whole, or

Table 4.1 Wholesale prices of unprocessed maize and rice in selected countries (average, JanuaryApril 2012)
Maize Rice
Wholesale price Wholesale price
Market (US$ per ton) Market (US$ per ton)
Africa
Ethiopia 390 Benin 1,055
Kenya 393 Burkina Faso 738
Malawi 400 Madagascar 593
Mozambique 378 Mali 690
Rwanda 318 Mozambique 865

South Africa 293 Niger 850


Tanzania 334 Senegal 810
Togo 453 Togo 1,097
Uganda 334 Uganda 1,368
Zimbabwe 300 International benchmark
International benchmark India 378
Black Sea region 267 Thailand 556
United States 276 Vietnam 434
Source: FAO Global Information and Early Warning System.
116 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box 4.2

When agriculture is more productive, economies can grow


Despite differences in the global context and national eco- Figure B4.2.1 Higher total factor productivity helped U.S.
nomic circumstances, the effects of agriculture on the U.S. farmers to compensate for declining terms of trade, 19752009
economy over the past 45 years may provide useful lessons
1.8
for Africa at this juncture, when so many young people
1.6
are poised to enter the agricultural workforce. From 1960 1.4
to 2005, the United States produced more agricultural 1.2
commodities more cheaply than ever. The real prices of 1.0

Index
most agricultural commodities declined 2050 percent 0.8
(see table B4.2.1). Even though the cost of food was ris- 0.6
ing throughout the world, most food prices were still lower 0.4
in 2010 (in constant U.S. dollars) than they were in 1960. 0.2
0.0
For the economy as a whole, low prices of primary food
1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010
products meant that it was much cheaper to process food
into an array of consumer products (an activity that gener- Total factor productivity (1992=1)

ated new jobs). The low prices enabled consumers to spend Terms of trade (prices of farm outputs/prices
of farm inputs) (199092=1)
more money on items other than food. Higher agricultural
productivity contributed to broad-based income growth in Source: Executive Office of the President 2011.

the United States.


Even while the prices of commodities they produced
declined, farmers and other agricultural workers preserved
Table B4.2.1 Percentage change in prices of selected food their livelihoods. As real agricultural prices fell and the cost
products in the United States, 19602010
of inputs and factors of production rose, farmers in the
Period Wheat Maize Sugar Beef United States and other developed countries still managed
19602005 43 52 19 23 to profit (and so did agricultural wage earners) by increas-
ing their productivity. They used inputs more efficiently and
20062010 8 41 50 22
changed their mix of outputs. In the United States between
19602010 24 18 24 10 1975 and 2010, total factor productivity rose 2.2 percent a
Source: World Bank Pink Sheets. year, which was low by historic standards but sufficient to
maintain profitability (see figure B4.2.1).

whether it is short-lived. As demand for food African leaders who are framing strategies
rises, growth in total factor productivity will be for agriculture now should be aware that the
necessary to keep real food prices in check and circumstances they face are quite different
maintain the capacity to create jobs.4 Unless from those that shaped traditional experiences
serious attention is paid to interventions that of development and structural change. African
can truly sustain productivity, such as agri- agriculture is developing in a context of high
cultural research, the development of farm- global food prices, potential for growth in
ing skills, and the adoption of new and better area and yield, few nontradable manufactured
varieties, growth in output will come through goods, and shifts in comparative advantage in
increased use of purchased inputs such as fertil- the developed world in favor of technology-
izer and agro-chemicals. The resulting growth intensive services and products (Losch,
in output may be rapid for a short period if Frguin-Gresh, and White 2012). In this con-
the inputs boost yields, but it will be costly, text, if African farmers change the technology
increase the real price of food, and ultimately they use and the mix of commodities they pro-
erode potential gains to producers, consumers, duce, agricultures share in African GDP could
and society at large (box 4.3). remain larger than has historically been the case
Agriculture as a Sector of Opportunity for Young Africans 117

or even grow with development. Furthermore, Box 4.3


the cost of withdrawing labor from agriculture
seems to have increased over time around the
world, and this is another factor arguing that Compromising growth and job creation
Africas experience may be different (Timmer without improving long-term food security
and Akkus 2008). Over the past 50 years, the
point at which wages in agriculture converge Since 2008, several African countries have introduced subsidy pro-
with those in nonagricultural jobs has been grams that encourage farmers to use fertilizer on staple crops without
supporting the use of more productive varieties and better manage-
reached at later and later stages in the transfor-
ment practices. As a result, farmers have devoted much of their land
mation of successful economies, perhaps sug-
to staple crops, crowding out higher-value, more labor-intensive crops
gesting that globally industry is becoming less and slowing the pace at which agriculture creates jobs and expands
and less able to absorb labor. productivity. In some cases, the production of staple crops surged
Recent cautiously optimistic trends suggest briefly, only to drop off sharply once the expensive (and often politi-
that the sources of agricultural growth in Africa cized) distribution of subsidized fertilizer came to an end. Early evi-
may be changing. Between 1960 and 2008, dence suggests that, even while the subsidies were in place, the yield
cultivated area grew faster than yields (Fuglie response of varieties in use was considerably less than anticipated.
2011). About 40 percent of the growth in yield Much can be done to improve the production of staple food crops
came from greater use of purchased inputs and without compromising growth and job creation in this way. The les-
60 percent from changes in total factor pro- son is that fertilizer use should be one part of a broader program
to promote gains in productivity and encourage diversification into
ductivity. Between 2006 and 2008, when Afri-
higher-valued and more labor-intensive products.
can governments began to give greater atten-
tion to agriculture,5 yield growth dominated
area growth, and total factor productivity rose.
These recent developments suggest that if gov-
ernments would intensify and sustain their livelihood, and their perceptions varied widely Farming is a
efforts to raise factor productivity, they could across Africa. Within three broad categories of good job because
secure lower prices for consumers, higher earn- jobs (nonfarm wage, nonfarm nonwage, and
it is where I can
ings for farmers, and good opportunities for agriculture), family farming was the desirable
young people to enter farming. job named most often. Yet with the exception of get food to eat
a womens group in North Darfur, none of the and live well.
focus groups from South Africa, Sudan, or Togo Liberia
Recognizing the Opportunity in mentioned any farming activities as a good job
Agriculture for Young People (Petesch and Caillava 2012). Within the same
broad categories, farming followed only illegal
Many young people know little of the oppor- and antisocial jobs as the worst job. Focus
tunities and dynamism possible in farming group interviews with urban young people sug-
today. When young rural Africans in 32 focus gest that agriculture virtually disappears from
groups were asked about the best and worst mention as the best job. To attract young peo-
ways to earn a living in their community, they ple, agriculture will need to be more dynamic
rarely mentioned agriculture as the best job and appealing than it is now, and young people
(although it was not considered the worst). will need to view the sector more positively (IDS
Participants described good jobs as those that 2012). The farms that offer attractive opportu-
command good pay and respect, two features nities will have to be quite different from those
not typically associated with farming under that most young Africans know.
the conditions most familiar to young Afri-
cans. They described bad jobs as those that Patterns of Land Use, Farm Size, and
offer poor, insecure returns and are physically Profitability
damaging or demanding or illegal. The farms that many young Africans know
Even so, the focus groups gave mixed mes- from childhood are small and worked with
sages regarding the desirability of farming as a back-breaking labor and little mechanization.
118 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Figure 4.1 The young do not typically own land sible to farm larger areas, but trypanosomiasis
80
and other animal diseases constrain the use of
draft animals in many parts of Africa.
70 Alternatively, land may be abundant but vir-
% who own at least one plot of land

tually impossible to acquire because of ambi-


60
guities in the transactability of land through
50 purchase, sale, leasing, inheritance, assignment
under traditional rules, and mortgage (World
40
Bank 2012b). When constraints on the opera-
30 tion of land markets raise the cost of accessing
new land, a young person reaching adulthood
20 may simply farm a portion of the familys origi-
nal holding rather than secure a new allotment.
10
It is not unusual for the continuous fragmenta-
0 tion of small holdings to persist alongside the
1519 2024 2529 3034 3539 4044 4549 5054 5559 60+ acquisition of large tracts by outside investors,
Age (years) whether domestic or foreign.
Tanzania Uganda Malawi A third consideration is that small, labor-
Source: Based on data from the Living Standards Measurement StudyIntegrated Survey on intensive farms can be economically appro-
Agriculture. priate, efficient, and profitable under certain
conditions. Recent evidence based on a geo-
Holdings of 1 to 2 hectares predominate, and graphically wide and heterogeneous set of data
the most common implements are the hand confirms an inverse relationship between maize
hoe and machete (Nagayets 2005). According to yield and farm size, supporting the premise
World Bank data from three countries, owned documented in earlier studies that small farms
land increases with age of the farmer (figure are often productive in the African context
4.1)the average plot size, even for older farm- and that smallholders do not necessarily forgo
ers, often remains well under 1 hectare. economies of scale (Larson et al. 2012). His-
This pattern of land use is seen whether torically, primary production of staple com-
land is scarce or abundant, although for differ- modities has not exhibited increasing returns
ent reasons. Where settlement is dense and land to scale, and smallholders who voluntarily form
If you have only is scarce, as in Rwanda and Malawi, holdings producer groups can capture scale economies
a small parcel per household and per worker are small and where they do existfor example, in the mar-
for eight people, shrinking with population growth. Under these keting of their produce and access to informa-
circumstances, investments in irrigation, appli- tion (see box 4.4; Morris, Binswanger-Mkhize,
not everyone can cation of purchased inputs, improved varieties, and Byerlee 2009).
eat. Madagascar high-valued crops, double and triple cropping, The most desirable farm size, however, is an
terracing, and other practices can increase the economic issue and not a matter of principle
productivity of land and incomes. Investments or ideology. Where relevant costs of produc-
that make it easier to reach markets increase the tion are readily divisible, smallholders will do
demand for agricultural products and reduce as well as or better than others. Where costs are
the cost of transporting them. The returns to not divisible for whatever reason, smallholders
intensification rise, and more such investments will be at a disadvantage but will still be very
take place. numerous. In that case, programs that facilitate
But why are farms so small in areas where adjustments in farm size or address the indivis-
land is abundant, as in much of Africa? Farm ible costs will be constructive.
size is often limited to the amount of land that a
household can farm manually, because machin- Getting Young Africans the Farms
ery is expensive, cannot be purchased without They Need
financing, and can be challenging to own and Even where small farms are demonstrably effi-
use collectively. Animal traction makes it pos- cient, agricultural productivity cannot grow
Agriculture as a Sector of Opportunity for Young Africans 119

if more family labor crowds onto them. The Box 4.4


income that 1 or 2 hectares can generate is
rarely sufficient to pull all members of a house-
hold out of poverty. For agricultural produc- Producer organizations and the transition to
tivity and incomes to grow, young people will modern supply chains
need to be able to acquire more land, and young
workers will need to be able to leave the farm Rural productive alliances can bring producer organizations and
of their birth for other forms of employment. commercial buyers together to increase income and employment
via participation in modern supply chains. These alliances have been
Since mobility out of farming has been
shown to bring about higher agricultural incomes and increased rural
low in Africa, much of the land is now held
employment, especially for agricultural workers and women working
by aging farmers despite the large cohort of in postharvest activities (World Bank 2012a). Farmers have also ben-
potential new entrants. Constraints to inter- efited from employment opportunities generated by public-private
generational transfers of land are particularly partnerships that enhance agricultural productivity. For example, a
costly when land is scarce or young people have successful model in Latin America that sought to increase competi-
difficulty acquiring holdings to start farming tiveness along the entire value chain for cassava (production, process-
on their own. Where old-age pensions do not ing, and utilization) worked with farmer groups and cooperatives
exist and rental markets are poorly developed, (among many others) and ultimately expanded training and jobs for
elderly farmers often retain control over hold- farmers in cassava-based agro-industries.
ings that would be managed more efficiently by
Source: World Bank 2012a.
younger, more innovative, and energetic farm-
ers (box 4.5).
More fluid land markets would create bet-
ter opportunities for young people to practice
more productive and managerially demanding Box 4.5
agriculture. As processors and urban consum-
ers demand quality and traceability in agricul-
tural produce and as changing weather patterns Options for establishing or leaving a farm
undermine the validity of traditional rules of in Kenya
thumb for the agricultural cycle, agriculture
Kenyas young people have great difficulty establishing themselves
requires a more sophisticated level of manage- as farm operators. According to a large national sample drawn from
ment. Young people are well suited to acquire participants in the Kenya Agricultural Productivity and Agribusiness
and exercise managerial expertise, and they can Project, people whose primary economic occupation is farming are
do so in many ways, but the managerial acu- in their late 50s, on average. In most cases, these people are also the
men of an individual farmer is as indivisible as principal decision makers on the farm.
a tractor. Each creates economic pressures to Men who identify themselves primarily as farmers usually farm as
amalgamate very small farms into larger units their first occupation; they have a spouse who works in the household
or develop new networks of producers to share and on the farm but does not earn significant outside wages. Women
costs. For this reason, increased fluidity of land who identify themselves primarily as farmers may or may not have an
adult male in the household contributing wage earnings to the house-
markets, in particular through land rentals, is
hold income. Women farmers with wage-earning adult males in their
essential for a new generation of African farm-
household do very well in farmingin most cases, better than men.
ers to take advantage of opportunities emerg- In contrast, single women who manage farms are, on average, about
ing in agriculture. Producer organizations may 10 years older than other farmers, and their earnings are the lowest.
need to innovate in the delivery of managerial These women probably retain control of land because the cost of hold-
services, an area in which they have not been ing it is low in the absence of land tax, and they have no other way
active in the past. to feed themselves as they age. This information suggests that elderly
When factor endowments and the charac- women and land-hungry young farmers could benefit from participat-
teristics of technology and markets imply that ing in a program that eases intergenerational land transfers while pro-
the optimal farm size is larger than what is viding some kind of social safety net for elderly landholders.
observed, constraints on capital and land mar-
Source: Torkelsson 2012.
kets impose a high burden of inefficiency on
rural people. Although smallholders may not
120 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

have the skills or appetite for risk to manage gering the change. The conditions in Africa
as much as 100 hectares, many could prob- offer ample opportunities for simultaneous
ably handle 510 hectares if they had access increases in average farm size and in employ-
to machinery to work it, particularly if public ment. The fact that average farm size in Africa
investments were made in infrastructure that is now declining is a worrisome indicator that
would make farming more profitable. The constraints on land markets are already damag-
incentives for young people to remain in school ing the prospects for young people and becom-
and acquire basic numeracy and literacy skills ing stronger (Djurfeldt and Jirstrm 2013).
would increase if intermediate-size farms were
among the possible options and were known to
require those basic skills for successful opera- Agricultural Career Paths for
tion. Intermediate-size farms can emerge only the Future
if land markets are more active.
One concern is that an expansion of farm The young people who will look to agriculture
size in Africa could displace labor precisely for employment are familiar with traditional
when demography requires agriculture to agriculture, but given the changes under way
absorb labor. In parts of the world where farms in the sector, they are likely to experience their
have expanded from very small (2 hectares and working years in ways different from their par-
less) to mid-size holdings (5100 hectares), ents. They will also have different requirements
labor has often been displaced. This displace- for support if they are to succeed. Young farm-
ment need not occur in Africa because under- ers will face four generic paths to agricultural
used land can be brought into production employment: continuing on the family plot but
Africa can still expand at the extensive margins with a different mix of enterprises; establishing
of farming without compromising forest area. their own operations on new land; combining
Larger farms need not be less labor intensive farming with part-time other work; or taking
than small ones when both area and employ- wage work on large or mid-size commercial
ment can expand simultaneously. However, if holdings. Although these four basic paths cover
farm size grows through consolidation on land many options, the diversity of African agricul-
that is already farmed and is accompanied by a ture ensures that some young people will face
capital subsidy that reduces the cost of mecha- other choices. For example, young people in
nization, as occurred in Brazil, then bigger pastoral areas confront a different set of chal-
farms could be expected to displace labor. If lenges and opportunities.
the change is occasioned by shifts in technol- The four basic pathways to employment in
ogy and markets that require greater manage- agriculture vary in their requirements for land,
rial skill, formerly independent farm operators capital, and skills (table 4.2). The first two
might become hired workers or outgrowers full-time employment on the family farm and
on larger, technically more sophisticated hold- full-time farming on a new holdingare the
ings. Thus the effects of changing farm size on most prevalent. Among households surveyed
employment are specific to the factor endow- in nine African countries in 2008, 51 percent
ment in a given market and to the forces trig- reported that inheriting land already under
cultivation was the most common means for
young people to obtain land, while 16 percent
Table 4.2 Pathways for agricultural employment and their requirements
would be allocated land not previously culti-
Need for Need for Need for vated, 9 percent would rent or borrow land,
Type of employment land capital skills
and 12 percent would buy land (Proctor and
Full-time on existing family holding None Medium Medium
Lucchesi 2012).
Full-time on new holding High High High
For each pathway to become a more produc-
Part-time combined with household enterprise tive source of employment, policy makers will
Low Medium High
(processing, trading, sales of services)
need to use a range of approaches to improve
Wage work off the family farm None None Medium or high
young peoples acquisition of land, capital, and
Agriculture as a Sector of Opportunity for Young Africans 121

skills. Evidence from various African countries household with several young adults should be Two [of our
suggests some approaches that show promise. able to undertake the required work. children]
Thus even if young people are absorbed have become
Pathway 1: Full-Time Employment on into the farm of their birth as a young adult,
a change in management of the household
farmers as well
an Existing Family Holding
enterprise could make this absorption more . . . the others
For young people with no other options, the
default outcome is to remain on the family rewarding for the individuals and the family. took another
holding and simply farm a portion, essentially A combination of pooled off-farm earnings, a direction. It is
subdividing an already small parcel. Others shift in farming technology to higher-value and best that we are
choose not to leave. Eventually many can expect more commercial products, and aggregation of not in the same
to inherit a portion of the land, but if siblings household labor at peak periods could allow
small farms to absorb young adults construc-
profession; that
are in the same position, the holding will be
tively. An emphasis on extension programs that way we can help
small. These youths need capital and skills to
make the most of their small holdings through focus on the household as an enterprise and do out one another.
higher-value agriculture. Young people who not just offer technical and economic advice on Madagascar
foresee this as their future, however, may have crops or livestock could help this group.
little incentive to invest in skills, since they will The view sketched above of the small house-
not have the power to use them as long as the hold farm evolving as young adults become
parental generation retains recognized rights of economically active provides an important
decision. perspective on the conceptual understanding
Families in this situation may find them- of youth employment. A young person in, for
selves in increasingly difficult circumstances, example, northern Uganda who is a member
with alienated young people resentful of their of such a household and has also benefited
elders continued control over resources. With from the Youth Opportunities Program of the
some guidance and mentoring, however, fami- northern Uganda Social Action Fund might
lies could turn this situation to advantage by have acquired vocational skills as a hairdresser
managing the household as an enterprise with (see discussion in chapter 3). She might see her
a portfolio of activities. Many households primary occupation as hairdresser, but she
already support small natural resourcebased would also be an equity holder in a small farm
enterprises (selling eggs and poultry, process- enterprise (if her earnings were applied in part
ing cassava or grain, collecting reeds, making to investment on the farm) and an occasional
bricks) as adjuncts to their primary farm- laborer at times of peak demand. Her economic
ing enterprise. The difference here is that the security would come from the farm earnings
household takes a strategic approach enabling as well as from her trade. To create space for
the small household farm to evolve and sup- the contributions of young people like this, the
port multiple generations and families. In this parental generation would need to view the
way, pathway 1 resembles pathway 3, but the farm as an enterprise.
emphasis is on full-time agriculture as part of a
diversified, multigenerational family business. Pathway 2: Full-Time Employment on
In this pathway, the skills and labor of mul- New Farm Starts
tiple young adults in the household could allow A second group of young people will succeed
for specialization. If there is demand for their in leaving the farm of their childhood and
labor, those capable of earning off-farm wages establishing a new and separate holding, ide-
could do so, thus easing the households capital ally larger than the parcel they left. Those more
constraints. Those with sufficient skill to man- likely to succeed in such an undertaking would
age higher-value agriculture could sharpen the probably be relatively experienced in farming
specific skills required through short courses and hence on the older end of the age range
or focused training. Some superior technolo- for youth. They would also have the high-
gies, such as conservation tillage, require high est potential returns in the form of increased
investment of labor at peak periods, and a productivity. These young farmers would
122 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

have the greatest need for land, start-up capi- mechanized field operations, and advice can be
tal, and advisory services or training to assist met by young men and women with the capital
with technical and managerial challenges. Few and skills to start a small business. These young
young farmers will be able to assemble the ele- people may not have the capital to acquire a full
ments required to establish a new farm without array of farm machinery, but they could offer
assistance. services on a paid basis by purchasing or leasing
New holdings may be in the localities where a limited selection of equipment. Young people
young people already live and on land newly would also need the particular skills to deliver
available for cultivation through clarification the services and maintain the machinery.
of ownership, conversion of marginal or graz-
ing land, or public investment in irrigation and Pathway 4: Wage Work off the
improvement. Alternatively, new holdings may Family Farm
be farther away, in which case establishing the The seasonal nature of agriculture creates
new farmstead will require relocation. demand for part-time wage work at peak peri-
Resettlement is often controversial. Experi- ods even on small farms. In a heterogeneous
ence globally and in Africa attests to the impor- farm structure with significant numbers of
tance of strict adherence to voluntary decision large holdings, wage work on a regular basis is
making on the part of participants, careful also observed. Most of this work pays relatively
selection, full information for all stakehold- little and requires very little skill, and few young
ers, effective support services for new arrivals, people aspire to be low-skilled day laborers. For
and adequate investment in infrastructure. An the very poorest, however, paid work, even if
assessment of several decades of public sup- undesirable, is a better option than no work.
port for resettlement in Indonesia found mixed Therefore, it is anticipated that a fourth group
results tending toward the negative. Improve- of young people will take wage work, whether
ments in the incomes and access to public ser- formal or informal, on large commercial farms
vices of settlers were offset by disappointing or in the processing and service sectors. These
outcomes in agricultural production, environ- young people need skills to handle a range of
mental degradation, and resentment against tasks and equipment. At a minimum, for the
newcomers on the part of indigenous inhabit- most basic low-skilled work, they need good
ants (World Bank 2012a). Preliminary results health to withstand often grueling working con-
regarding a program of market-assisted land ditions. Such wage work could fit into the liveli-
reform in Malawi, in contrast, indicate more hood strategies described above in combination
positive outcomes (Chirwaa 2008). If local with other activities, or it could be a temporary
My first job was young people can secure access to land in or option until better opportunities appear.
a contract job near their community, this approach is clearly Not all wage work is poorly paid or low
that paid 300 simpler. If relocation is required, lessons of past skilled. Some very large enterprises, both in
experience should be fully weighed. primary production and in processing, require
[Liberian] dollars
per day . . . I a range of skills depending on the technical
Pathway 3: Part-Time Farming and sophistication of the production process and
didnt enjoy it. I Household Enterprises types of machinery used. Drivers, machine
just did it for the A third group of young people may be indepen- operators, mechanics, quality testing techni-
money, worked dent part-time farmers, either managing their cians, and others will be required in increas-
on someone elses own holdings or contributing to family opera- ing numbers in the future, and these jobs are
farm . . . I just tions described under pathway 1, with enough often better paid than unskilled day labor. For
forced myself capital to establish themselves as a seller of ser- example, Red Fox Ethiopia, a floriculture firm
vices, a trader, or an occasional wage worker. located outside of Addis Ababa, draws labor
because of food Higher-value agriculture will use services more from the surrounding rural areas and towns
. . . Im still doing intensively and create employment for those and offers employer-provided transport to
it. It was my first who can provide them (box 4.6). Demand for work, life and health insurance, and a subsi-
job. Liberia transport, plant protection, veterinary services, dized cafeteria (box 4.7).
Agriculture as a Sector of Opportunity for Young Africans 123

Box 4.6

High-value agriculture and opportunities for employment off the farm


The labor market effects of high-value agriculture are docu- Processing food for local markets is another growth area
mented in several countries in Africa. In 1985, just 14 per- for rural employment. As new towns proliferate through in
cent of the agricultural and food exports from African coun- situ urbanization, demand for processed foods increases,
tries consisted of high-value agricultural products; by 2005, along with investment in processing. Greater attention to
the share had risen to 30 percent, with many jobs created food safety in public policy will improve conditions within
along the way. In Madagascar, the export of vegetables has processing plants, since the conditions that assure safe
relied on about 10,000 smallholders contracted for procure- products also contribute to improved hygiene and safety for
ment of primary produce. In other instances, production of workers. The regulatory bar for wages and working condi-
primary produce has been vertically integrated with large tions cannot be set so high that it stifles investment, elimi-
estate farms, as is the case with tomato and bean exports in nates jobs, and depresses demand for primary production.
Senegal; the jobs created are for wage earners in processing The surge in food imports in Africa since 2003 reflects the
units and pack houses. Table B4.6.1 gives several examples underdevelopment of local food-processing capacity. Rem-
of employment created in export horticulture chains. Hor- edying this underdevelopment will create jobs and raise
ticultural work is generally labor intensive and effective at returns to investments in primary agriculture.
alleviating poverty, especially among women.

Table B4.6.1 Employment in horticultural supply chains in Sub-Saharan Africa


Number of employees
in the fresh fruit and Percentage of
Country Commodity Year of survey vegetable agro-industry female employees
Cameroon Bananas 2003 10,000
Cte dIvoire Bananas and pineapples 2002 35,000
Kenya Flowers 2002 40,00070,000 75
Fruits and vegetables 2002 2,000,000
Senegal Cherry tomatoes 2006 3,000 60
French beans 2005 12,000 90
South Africa Deciduous fruit 1994 283,000 53
Uganda Flowers 1998 3,300 75
Zambia Flowers 200203 2,500 35
Vegetables 200203 7,500 65
Source: Maertens, Minten, and Swinnen 2009.
Note: = not available.

Lifting Key Constraints on Capital, agricultural research and infrastructure to the


Land, and Skills weak rural investment climateis also integral
to raising agricultural productivity and creat-
Constraints on the acquisition of capital, land, ing jobs, but those constraints are not specific
and skills block young peoples progress along to opportunities for young people and are not
the four basic pathways to employment in addressed here.
agriculture. To create opportunities commen-
surate with the number of young people who Financial Services
will need employment, those constraints must Access to capital and credit for smallholders has
be removed or relieved, as discussed next. The been a perennial problem and the subject of
removal of other constraintsfrom the lack of analysis for decades.6 Small farmers in Africa,
124 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box 4.7

Red Fox Ethiopia: More technically sophisticated wage work


Red Fox Ethiopia was established in 2003 by a German Red Fox controls the end-to-end supply chain by having
entrepreneur with long experience in the flower business. its own importing company, transportation services, and dis-
Red Fox Ethiopia produces and exports more than 150 vari- tribution networks in the international market. The company
eties of unrooted young plants, mainly to France, Germany, imports its fertilizer and other agro-chemicals and sources
Italy, and the United States. In 2009, it exported 127 million packaging materials and plastic bags locally. The presence
cuttings valued at US$10 million. of a well-established customer network enables the firm to
The firm started on 8 hectares in Koka, 95 kilometers book orders in advance and produce accordingly, resulting in
from Addis Ababa. The factorys area increased incremen- minimal wastage and risks of price fluctuations.
tally to 35 hectares in 2009, and the firm is acquiring Red Fox plans to strengthen its market leadership and
additional land to bring its area to 65 hectares. The firm consolidate its special expertise in producing unrooted young
has 1,300 employees, 450 of whom are hired on a sea- plants. In addition, it plans to diversify into fruit production,
sonal basis for three to four months at a time. Expatriate in partnership with another firm that has knowledge and
professionals currently run the operation, but the own- experience of the sector.
ers plan to replace them slowly and smoothly with local
professionals. Source: Sutton and Kellow 2010.

like their counterparts elsewhere, work in risky attention nonetheless to identify, replicate, and
environments that are expensive for financial scale up the successful approaches.
institutions to serve. Most such farmers have
little or no usable collateral and little experi- Institutions and Organizations
ence with financial services. A history of pub- Various actors offer financial services, includ-
lic intervention in credit markets has created ing bank and nonbank financial institutions,
expectations that defaults on agricultural loans insurers, and payment service providers. As
will carry little penalty to the borrower. All of commercial banks tend to limit their outreach
these challenges for financial institutions seek- in rural areas, alternative institutions such as
ing to serve smallholders are relevant for young self-help groups, savings and credit associa-
farmers and compounded by their lack of tions, and cooperatives have emerged to fill the
experience. Not everyone will be able to access gap and to address both credit risk (usually
credit, although many farmers can benefit higher in agriculture than in other sectors) and
You may have from a wider array of financial services such as covariant risks specific to agricultureweather
innovative insurance and money transfer. Yet small farm- and other climatic risks, pest and disease epi-
ideas, but there ers, particularly if they are young, need capital demics, and so on (see focus note 3).
is nothing you to adopt the technologies and secure the land
and equipment that will allow them to become Access to Credit
can do if you more commercially active. Because finance is Allowing alternative forms of collateral, such
cant afford to so important and the potential client base is as chattel mortgages, warehouse receipts, and
get a loan from so large, banks and nongovernmental organi- the future harvest, can ease the credit market.
the bank. It is zations (NGOs) continue to experiment with The OHADA7 Uniform Act on Secured Trans-
difficult getting innovations to overcome the barriers to provid- actions, in effect in 17 Sub-Saharan African
a loan from the ing sustainable financial services to large num- countries, was amended at the end of 2010 to
bers of smallholders. A brief review of some of allow borrowers to use a wide range of assets
bank, as you these new products and services follows. Many as collateral, including warehouse receipts and
have to have of the innovations discussed are still being movable property such as machinery, equip-
security. Its tested; their performance and sustainability on ment, and receivables that remain in the hands
hard. Rwanda a large scale are unknown. They warrant close of the debtor (AgriFin 2012). Even where the
Agriculture as a Sector of Opportunity for Young Africans 125

regulatory framework allows collateralization, Many governments and development partners


however, assets may not be attractive for vari- use matching grants in a variety of schemes,
ous reasons, and banking practices require time including efforts to promote improved tech-
for adjustment. nologies, empower farmers to hire service pro-
Leasing also offers young farmers some viders, strengthen linkages with private firms
relief, as it requires either no or less collateral through productive partnerships, and provide
than typically required by loans. Most rural rural infrastructure for common use (AgriFin
leases are financial (unlike operating leases); 2012). Grant schemes carry well-known risks
the price of the asset is amortized, and the les- of diversion and elite capture, and their success
see can purchase the asset at the end of the lease depends crucially on their design, including
period for a small price (IFPRI and World Bank transparent rules for participation, checks and
2010, brief 6). A notable example is DFCU balances in monitoring at the local level, and
Leasing in Uganda, which provided more than clear expectations regarding accounting and
US$4 million in farm equipment leases in 2002 auditing. The expectation and encouragement
for items such as rice hullers, dairy process- of savings should be a key feature of grants to
ing equipment, and maize milling equipment. individual beneficiaries. Africa has widespread
CECAM in Madagascar8 leased more than experience with grant programs, yet few have
US$2.8 million in 200203 to rural microen- focused specifically on the needs of young
terprises, with an average US$945 per lease participants. In Sri Lanka, the Gemi Diriya
(Kloeppinger-Todd, Nair, and Mulder 2004). Program allocates a portion of its Livelihood
Individuals in pathways 2 and 3, who may need Fund for one-time grants of US$46US$92 to
new equipment to start their venture, would generate income and help clients to start an
particularly benefit from leasing. Despite leas- economic activity without incurring the risk of
ings clear potential to relieve constraints on a loan (World Bank 2007b). Young people are
access to mechanical technology, few firms have one of the programs target groups. Just over
chosen to enter this business. 10 percent of participants are destitute young
Young farmers simultaneous needs for people (World Bank n.d.).
finance and information can be addressed by
linking agricultural credit to extension services, Contracting Arrangements
an approach followed by BASIX Social Enter- Some outgrower arrangements offer prefinanc-
prise Group, a livelihood promotion institution ing of inputs and assured marketing chan-
based in India. Initially established to provide nels. In Mozambique, Rwanda, Tanzania, and
microcredit to the rural poor, BASIX now pro- Zambia, Rabo Development (a subsidiary of
vides rural households with financial services Rabobank) provides management services and
and advice in managing crop and livestock technical assistance to financial institutions,
enterprises. Almost 1,000 service providers work which, in turn, finance supply chains with
with more than 25,000 villages in India under a range of agricultural clients. Participants
the program. BASIXs research has shown that include commercial farmers, farmers with
farmers prefer cost-saving and risk-reducing little commercial presence, and an intermedi-
interventions to yield-enhancing ones that ate group of farmers with ambitions to grow
require more investment. The combination of commercially. Rabo takes particular interest in
financial services and information or mentor- linking this last group to finance through con-
ing allows the financial institution to identify tract farming under financial arrangements
the products in greatest demand, such as sav- that limit the risk of default or side selling.10
ings, money transfer, and insurance rather than Kenyas DrumNet Project is piloting a similar
credit (IFPRI and World Bank 2010, brief 13). supply-chain approach to promote agricultural
lending among 3,000 farmers in the horticul-
Grants tural and oilseed subsectors. Risks of default
Matching grants can promote employment are reduced through cashless direct payment to
and employability among young people.9 the input supplier via a bank transfer once the
126 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

product is delivered to the buyer (IFPRI and traditional insurance by being available through
World Bank 2010, brief 14). well-trusted yet innovative channels and by
offering low premiums, products with simple
E-Transfers and Payments designs, flexible payments for premiums, and
Electronic and mobile technology are rapidly prompt settlement of claims. For example,
bringing banking services to rural areas (where more than 11,000 Kenyan maize farmers, some
the regulatory environment permits). For with as little as 1 acre, have obtained insur-
example, Kenyas M-PESA service has trans- ance policies that cover significant losses when
formed rural banking there. This service allows drought or excess rain destroys their harvest.
users to transfer money safely via their mobile Similarly, BASIX and a commercial insurer in
phone without requiring a bank account. Ini- India provide weather insurance based on a
tially intended to enable wage earners to send rainfall index to smallholders to improve their
money home to families in rural areas, M-PESA access to credit. Payments are triggered when
now allows customers to pay bills (utilities, rainfall at local weather stations exceeds a mini-
school fees, and others), repay loans, and pay mum threshold; insurance contracts secure the
insurance and microinsurance premiums. A repayment of loans (IFPRI and World Bank
new business feature allows companies to pay 2010, brief 9).
employees via M-PESA. Equity Bank in Kenya
recently offered all M-PESA users the option Loan Guarantees
to open a savings account, using M-PESA to Banks reluctant to enter the business of agri-
deposit and withdraw funds (IFPRI and World culture can sometimes be induced to do so
Bank 2010, brief 8). Young people are especially through partial guarantee schemes that protect
quick to adopt innovations based on mobile their losses in cases of default. The Alliance for
phones when they have access. a Green Revolution in Africa has established
The use of biometrics is being explored in an innovative financing initiative operating in
the context of credit markets in countries where Kenya, Mozambique, and Tanzania. The initia-
unique identification systems do not exist (mak- tive provides partial guarantees that result in
ing it difficult for banks to spot repeat default- lower interest rates on loans to smallholders.
ers). Biometric identification allows lenders to Since 2009, it has provided US$160 million in
withhold new loans from known defaulters and financing to smallholder agriculture. Rabo-
to grant loans to known responsible borrowers. banks Rabo Sustainable Agriculture Guaran-
An experiment in Malawi linked higher repay- tee Fund issues partial credit guarantees and
ment rates with the use of fingerprint scanning provides other financial products to mitigate
among paprika farmers (IFPRI and World Bank the risks of financial intermediaries, allowing
2010, brief 9). Biometric tools that reduce the them to offer better prices and terms for com-
costs of identifying borrowers and diminish mercial finance to grow and export agricultural
default rates can enhance outreach to hard-to- produce.11
serve clients. Such measures are unlikely to be
introduced solely to foster the employment of Rural Finance Targeted to Young People
young people, but they are yet another example None of these innovations in rural finance
of how measures that generally facilitate agri- is relevant exclusively to young people. Nor
cultural growth have specific, significant ben- should young people be segregated as a group
efits for the young. and offered financial services designed specifi-
cally for them. The risks of working with this
Insurance client base are high, and separating young peo-
Innovations in microinsurance are also under ple from a larger pool for sharing risks would
way. The International Labour Organization make them even less attractive to financial
(ILO) estimates that microinsurance in Africa institutions. Rather, any and all innovations in
almost doubled between 2006 and 2009 from finance that facilitate sustainable outreach to
a very small base. Microinsurance differs from small farmers and rural entrepreneurs should
Agriculture as a Sector of Opportunity for Young Africans 127

be supported. When necessary, additional fea- of land. Accelerated land registration facili-
tures should be added to enable these programs tates land rental markets, which make it easier
to serve young people. for the poor to access land on rental terms . . .
Land access for the poor can also be improved
by redistributing underused and unused agri-
cultural land to them.
Land Policies That Benefit
the Young Policies and programs to improve access
to land can include special provisions to assist
Of the many aspects of land administration young people. Several are described next.16
that require attention in Africa, the two that
matter most to young entrants to the labor Systematic Inventory and Registration
force are the need to improve security of ten- of Land
ure and the need to relax controls on rental. Systematic land registration is a prerequisite for
Land redistribution will also influence young creating employment in agriculture through
peoples access to land. In general, policies and any of the four pathways. Notable efforts are
measures that help the poor to gain access to yielding results for various categories of ten-
land will also help young people. ure, but the pace of activity does not reflect the
High food prices and the resulting spike in urgency of the problem.
demand for land add urgency to the challenges Only 10 percent of occupied land in Africa is
of improving land governance for all citizens formally registered (World Bank 2012b). State
and applying appropriate safeguards to protect ownership of land is widespread, but even
the land rights of the poor. When arrangements state-owned land is not fully documented, and
for governance are weak, the rights of tradi- long-term use and occupancy by individuals or
tional users may be overlooked or abused, con- groups blur ownership claims and limit invest-
sultation with communities about impending ment. For example, in Ghana in 2000, the state
transactions may be limited, and transparency owned about 40 percent of urban and periur-
may be constrained (IDS 2012). ban land, most of it undeveloped (Kasanga and
Decentralized land administration can Kotey 2001). Periurban land is often in transi-
empower local communities, expedite deci- tion from agricultural to nonagricultural use.
sions on land management and uses (highly It is well placed to offer high returns in inten-
desirable for individuals pursuing pathways sive horticulture, tank aquaculture, and pig or
1 and 2), and help to clarify the legal rights poultry production, but it requires significant
of landowners and tenants amid the surge in investment. Holders of periurban land often
demand for land.12 Various models for decen- have other income streams and are linked to
tralization exist (see Bruce and Knox 2009, the financial system, so they can, in principle,
for example). Their success depends on their make the required investments. They will not
design, implementation, and prevailing local do so, however, if their ownership or the dura-
conditions. tion of their tenure is ambiguous.
The Land Governance Assessment Frame-
work13 and the Voluntary Guidelines on the Inventory and registration of individual land
Responsible Governance of Tenure of Land, Fish- rights. Several countries are making progress
eries, and Forests in the Context of National Food in formally documenting individual land-
Security14 have been developed to assist deci- ownership. By the end of 2012, Rwanda had
sion makers at the country level and guide the demarcated all 10.5 million land parcels in the
formulation of land tenure projects and poli- country and registered and prepared leases
cies.15 According to the World Bank (2012b), for at least 83 percent of them. Of the almost
Sound land policies can safeguard the liveli- 1 million leases collected as of March 2012,
hoods of the very vulnerable by giving them 7 percent were claimed by women, 5 percent
access to land and income-earning opportuni- by men, 83 percent by married couples, and
ties through rental markets or redistribution 1 percent by other legal entities (World Bank
128 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box 4.8
securing an agreement with an outside inves-
tor (that will generate jobs within the com-
munity) or allocating a portion of communal
Documenting land rights: Encouraging land to young people for new farm starts. As
investment and reducing the cost of noted in a recent World Bank review (World
land transfers Bank 2012b), registration can be very slow if
there are no clearly defined community own-
The economic literature has long held that more secure tenure will ers of land and if new formal entities have to
increase investments in land. Evidence from Ethiopia and Rwanda be developed. Demarcation of communal
appears to confirm this finding and to highlight improvements in land boundaries requires time and financial
environmental management as well. Other estimates suggest that resources. Registration needs to be followed
certification-induced investment increased output in Ethiopia by
up with resources to plan for land use and to
about 9 percentage points (Deininger, Ali, and Alemu 2011). Invest-
delineate common property resources (such as
ment and productivity improvements were also found in Benin, where
households participating in rural land use plans planted more peren-
grazing land).
nial crops than nonparticipants (Selod 2012).
The same documentation of rights that strengthens tenure can Inventory of state land. The extent of state
reduce the cost of transactions. By 2010, both Ghana and Rwanda landownership in Africa is largely unknown, as
had reduced the cost of transferring property to less than 1 percent of most lands have not yet been surveyed and reg-
property value (World Bank 2010b). istered. Some governments have started inven-
torying state-owned land, including recent
efforts in Ghana and Uganda. Underused or
poorly used state land can be auctioned to
2012b). Ethiopia used a participatory public the private sector in ways that combine large-
process to award certificates for more than scale operators and small and medium farm-
25 million parcels in rural areas throughout ers in innovative relationshipswith care to
the country, with noted benefits, including avoid disenfranchising indigenous users such
reduced conflicts, empowerment of women, as herders and subsistence communities. Long-
increased individual and community invest- term occupants can be formally (legally) rec-
ment, and improved security (World Bank ognized as owners (as in Kenya), and land can
2012b). Madagascar has issued 75,000 certifi- be made available to land-poor farmers (as in
cates akin to traditional land titles; Tanzania Malawi), including the young (for Kenya, see
issued about 27,000 certificates of customary United Republic of Kenya 2010; World Bank
rights of occupancy in two districts. A pilot 2011; for Malawi, see World Bank 2004; Tchale
program in Ghana registered nearly 10,000 2012). Individuals in pathway 2 are most likely
land parcels in periurban areas, and a similar to benefit from these programs, and underused
program in Uganda registered 10,000 parcels state-owned land is a clear source of supply for
in three districts. Benin, Burkina Faso, and young people showing promise in farming.
Cte dIvoire have been piloting various rural
land use plansplans
fonciers rurauxxas Reforms in Land Rental Markets
another way to establish individual land use For the very poor, the landless, the young, and
rights. While methods have differed and suc- migrants, land rental is the gateway to agricul-
cess has varied, these efforts have done much tural employment and eventual landownership.
to establish smallholders land rights (box 4.8). For those pursuing pathway 1 (perhaps hoping
to acquire additional land to expand family
Inventory and registration of communal holdings) and pathway 2, rental is a workable
land. Where legal provisions recognize cus- approach to gain access to land. Worldwide,
tomary tenure and communal land, it may be evidence demonstrates that introducing
more appropriate to register communal land long-term leases or certifying land rights can
than individual holdings. Registration of com- increase land rental activity,17 because people
munal land can be an important first step in with secure rights are more likely to offer tem-
Agriculture as a Sector of Opportunity for Young Africans 129

porary use of their land to others. In turn, well- Box 4.9


functioning land rental markets can facilitate
labor mobility, increase efficiency by transfer-
ring land to more productive users, increase Mexicos program to speed intergenerational
equality, and enhance structural transforma- land transfers
tion. Rental can be particularly helpful in eas-
ing the intergenerational transfer of land while Most land in Mexico was held in common under unclear tenure
still providing income to elderly owners (box arrangements until reforms initiated in the 1990s. Heavy restrictions
on the transfer of rights to common land from one generation to
4.9). The most common restrictions on rental
another limited young farmers access to land. In the early 2000s, with
markets, such as ceilings on rental rates or pro-
support from the World Bank and as part of a wider set of reforms
hibitions against absentee landownership, are in land administration, the Government of Mexico initiated its Young
often introduced to safeguard smallholders Rural Entrepreneurs and Land Fund Program (Programa para Jvenes
interests, but instead they may lock land into Emprendedores Rurales y Fondo de Tierra) to accelerate the intergen-
inefficient patterns of use, greatly disadvantag- erational transfer of land. This successful program provided credit for
ing prospective young users (Deininger 2003). rural youths without land to acquire underused common land. The
Land rental markets have promoted com- young people were trained and received technical assistance in set-
mercial farming in Ghana and created new ting up their farming activities. The program also helped older land-
opportunities elsewhere in West Africa (for owners who transferred land to young farmers to gain access to social
Ghana, see Amanor and Diderutuah 2001; welfare schemes for their retirement.
for elsewhere in West Africa, see Estudillo, Source: FAO, IFAD, and MIJARC 2012.
Quisumbing, and Otsuka 2001). In Sudan land
rental markets facilitated the transfer of land
to smaller producers (Kevane 1996). In con-
trast, Ugandas rental markets largely ceased to
function in the 2000s due to severe ceilings on be seen in Malawi, South Africa, and Zambia,
rent and controls on the eviction of tenants. In and each of which has drawn on lessons from
Ethiopia, restrictions on land rental markets programs in Brazil.
in all regions except Amhara not only reduced
opportunities to use land more productively Malawis pilot land reform program. Malawi
but also may have inhibited development of recently piloted a land reform program in four
the nonfarm sector, as individuals who took districts in which underused land from former
nonfarm jobs perceived that the risk of los- tea estates was made available to smallholders
ing their land through redistribution was high wishing to relocate from densely settled areas.19
(Deininger et al. 2003). Patterned after Brazils market-based approach
to land reform, the pilot had three key ele-
Redistribution of Agricultural Land ments: (1) communities voluntarily acquired
Land redistribution programs can profoundly land from estate owners, the government, or
and positively affect the poor, but their suc- private donors; (2) resettlement and on-farm But even for a
cess depends critically on their objectives and development included transportation of set-
farmer, without
design. If operated at sufficient scale, they can tlers, establishment of shelter, and purchase
change the income distribution and increase the of basic inputs and advisory services; and (3) education, forget
incentives and opportunities for investment by redistributed land was surveyed and registered, about good
poor households. If poorly designed, they can initially under group title, with the expecta- production.
transfer land to persons poorly suited to farm tion that individual titles would be provided to Tanzania
it and can discourage investment by heighten- beneficiaries on demand in the future. A cap
ing uncertainty about future redistribution. As on the maximum amount of a grant that could
individuals in pathway 2 have the greatest need be spent to acquire land improved the bargain-
for new land, they will have the most to gain or ing power of beneficiaries in relation to land
lose from approaches to redistribution. Exam- sellers,20 and access to advisory services signifi-
ples of approaches to land redistribution can cantly lowered the failure rate.
130 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Although the program did not focus explic- similar to collective farms and experienced the
itly on attracting young people, most partici- deficiencies in internal management that are
pants were young. They preferred to relocate common under such arrangements.
within or close to their original home, which
preserved sociocultural ties and supported Zambias irrigation development and support
young people when they were forming families project. In this project (approved in 2011 and
and needed links to the older generation. The receiving just over US$200 million from all
program distributed an average of more than funding sources), smallholders can exchange
1.5 hectares to each of 15,142 rural house- small parcels for holdings of 35 hectares as
holds, increased agricultural incomes 40 per- part of a larger scheme that will join small pro-
cent a year on average for beneficiaries between ducers, large commercial operators, and mid-
200506 and 200809, and had positive effects size farmers in a shared area. Management of
on surrounding communities. irrigation services for the entire scheme will
be contracted to a concession. To ensure that
South Africas land reform program. Despite small and mid-size farmers earn enough to
having had programs in place for a decade and pay irrigation fees, professional farm manage-
a half, South Africa has made little progress ment services will be available to assist with
in providing growing numbers of underem- production and marketing. The selection of
ployed rural young people with land that they smallholders taking on the mid-size parcels is
can farm.18 At the end of apartheid in 1994, not complete, so the age distribution of par-
South Africas new government introduced ticipants is unknown, but this opportunity is
tenure reform, restitution, and redistribu- expected to appeal to young people with prior
tion of land. The redistribution program was experience in farming.
designed to transfer land through market-
mediated transactions to historically disad-
vantaged South Africans who wanted to enter Enhancing Skills and Building a
farming. After disappointing results, a new Better Educational Foundation
program launched in 2001 provided graduated
areas of land and start-up grants depending on Rural children need to go to school and learn.
the amount of the beneficiarys contribution. Better-educated farmers are more likely to
Those who could contribute little (and most of adopt modern farm inputs and technolo-
that in kind) received a base allotment of land gies, make better use of purchased inputs and
and a grant of R 20,000 (almost $3,000). Those labor, choose technologies more effectively,
who could contribute more or leverage a bank and respond rapidly to changes in markets or
loan could receive larger holdings and a grant to natural calamities (Schultz 1988). Basic edu-
of up to R 100,000 (about $14,000). Although cation can significantly improve the efficacy of
the goal was to redistribute 30 percent of the agricultural training. The relationship between
land by 2014, as of March 2011, only 6.27 mil- education and agricultural development cuts
lion hectares (7.2 percent of land owned by both ways, and the two are mutually reinforc-
white African farmers) had been redistributed ing, with demand for schooling rising as rural
to black African farmers, and many recipients incomes increase.
struggled to manage that land well. The pro- To equip young Africans with the skills
gram had limited success because allocations to thrive in all four pathways to agricultural
of land and start-up capital were not accom- employment, schools must do a better job of
panied by advisory services or technical assis- providing the basic skills for any endeavor.
tance. Those who received land through the Foremost among these are reading, writing,
program were prohibited from subdividing numeracy, and the ability to use digital tech-
it, even though repeal of the prohibition was nology to access and interpret information
announced several times. Beneficiaries of small (box 4.10). Beyond these basics, the skills
allotments were forced into group structures required for individuals in pathways 1 and 2
Agriculture as a Sector of Opportunity for Young Africans 131

Box 4.10

Information and communication technologies: Altering the flow of agricultural


information
For African farmers operating in an environment of rapid cli- price and weather information in Colombia and India failed
matic and economic change, the age-old questions of what to have a substantial impact on crop choices, revenues, or
to plant, when to plant, and how to plant have assumed profits (Camacho and Conover 2011 on Colombia; Cole and
immense importance. Answers are proliferating, as rural Hunt 2010 on India). These findings suggest the need to
radio, television, the Internet, and mobile services offer an experiment with different content and methods of delivery.
expanding array of information about specific technologies More attention should be given to the underinvestigated,
and practices, climate change, disaster management, early distinct, and potentially complex issue of using ICT to sup-
warning (for drought, floods, and diseases), prices, natural port agricultural production and production technologies, as
resource management, production efficiency, and market distinct from marketing information.
access (World Bank 2012a). For newer ICTs such as mobile phones and the Internet to
Researchers are rigorously testing the effectiveness of dif- convey agricultural information effectively, the content and
ferent information and communication technologies (ICTs) at mode of delivery may need to change, but what about the
reaching and benefiting farmers, focusing primarily on the users themselves? Much has been made of young peoples
transmission of price information.a Radio, a long-standing ready adoption of newer ICTs, as well as the capacity of ICTs
method of communicating with farmers, has helped them (newer and older) to break through barriers to the acquisi-
to obtain better farm-gate prices by providing information tion of information and skills, such as distance, the inability
on commodity prices. Internet stations with agricultural mar- to read and write, or the expense of producing and dissemi-
ket information (e-Choupals) have done the same in Mad- nating audiovisual information. Much has also been made
hya Pradesh, India. Mobile phones have allowed fishermen of the potential for interactive ICTs to provide agricultural
and onshore buyers in Kerala, India, to communicate supply recommendations tailored to an individual farmers circum-
and price information, resulting in higher profits, lower con- stances. Yet much depends on whether the individual user
sumer prices, and less waste. Among grain traders in Niger, of ICTs is able to frame relevant questions based on learning
the introduction of mobile phone coverage in two markets acquired in good primary schools, coupled with practice in
reduced the price variation between the two, ultimately imagining states of the world other than those already expe-
increasing traders profits, decreasing prices paid by consum- rienced. As discussed in chapter 3, most African educational
ers, and increasing total welfare. Cell phone coverage also systems are not delivering high-quality basic education, even
reduced within-year price variation for producers. though enrollment is increasing. Among rural youths who
Actors in the public and private sector are interested in lack a basic cognitive foundation on which they can build,
using mobile phones to deliver information to farmers in the benefits of ICTs may be slower to emerge.
developing countries. A rigorous evaluation of one program
found that text messages provided by Reuters Market Light
a. See Svensson and Yanagizawa (2009) on radio and farm-gate prices;
did not have a robust effect on producer prices or input Goyal (2010) on Internet stations in India; Jensen (2007) on fishers in
use among farmers of five crops in Maharashtra, India (Faf- Kerala; Aker (2008) on traders in Niger; and Aker and Fafchamps (2010)
champs and Minten 2012).Similar interventions to supply on phone coverage and variation in producer prices.

may differ from the skills required in pathways from processing and marketing to agricultural
3 and 4. The majority of farmers, who will have research.
little more than a primary school education, This section describes recent initiatives and
will need access to effective agricultural exten- changes in schools of thought regarding the
sion services to sharpen their skills and clearly role and delivery of both basic and agricultural
convey their requirements for information education, agricultural extension, and other
and technology to service providers. Finally, innovative models of training and research
a growing and diversifying agricultural sec- and development. As with some of the finance
tor will create jobs that demand increasingly mechanisms discussed earlier, many of these
advanced technical and professional skills, programs are experimental. They have not
132 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

been rigorously evaluated or tested for their without schooling, assuming that both have
effectiveness or sustainability on a larger scale. access to the same assets, and this effect is
magnified in environments undergoing rapid
Schooling and Learning technical change (Rosenzweig 2010). Schooling
To the extent that schooling raises literacy and thus enhances learning, and a dynamic agricul-
numeracy skills and enhances the ability to tural sector provides opportunities to apply it.
process agricultural information, an educa- Education offers spillover effects when
tion effect can exist independent of the design uneducated farmers are able to observe the
of school curriculum. Returns to such skills choices and outcomes of their better-educated
I decided to get are particularly magnified in a modernizing neighbors. This type of social learning is usu-
married after agricultural sector, where access to advanced ally inferred from observed behavior or out-
technology complements an understanding of comes over time. For example, in Ghana, social
my stepmother learning played an important role in diffusing
how to use it. The decision to adopt new tech-
refused to pay nologies is an investment decision if significant knowledge on pineapple cultivation among
school fees for costs are incurred in obtaining information and farmers. In this case, the experiences of the
me, and the learning about the performance of one or more farmers and their neighbors influenced profit-
job I could new technologies, while the returns are distrib- ability and adoption rates (Conley and Udry
find there was uted over time. Furthermore, only a small share 2010).
of new technologies will be profitable for any The importance of female labor in agri-
only farming. culture brings into sharp focus the urgency
given farmer to adopt. Given the degree and
Tanzania multiple sources of uncertainty facing farmers, of improving access to schooling for girls and
effective schooling may help them to make bet- women. There is widespread recognition of the
ter decisions to increase farm profitability. need to improve both basic education and agri-
Returns to schooling in rural areas depend, cultural vocational education for women and
in part, on the pace of technological innovation to enhance rural womens access to extension
in farming. A large body of literature has shown services.
that more educated farmers are the first to
adopt new seed, tillage practices, fertilizer, and Postsecondary Education in Agriculture
animal breeds (for example, see Welch 1970; Alongside jobs in primary production, a grow-
Huffman 1977; Besley and Case 1993; Foster ing and diversifying agricultural sector creates
and Rosenzweig 1996; Abdulai and Huffman demand for skilled labor in rural areas inside
2005). Moreover, farmers with primary educa- and outside of the sector. Africas existing agri-
tion tend to earn higher profits than farmers cultural vocational schools can play a construc-
tive role in training skilled personnel for jobs
in processing, marketing, machinery opera-
Box 4.11 tion and repair, transport, logistics, and quality
controlprovided that students have suffi-
Vocational agricultural education: cient preparation to benefit from that training
(box 4.11).
A poor substitute for general education
The number and quality of trained techni-
To remedy gaps in skills, many African governments and their devel- cal and professional personnel in agriculture
opment partners in past years focused on vocational agricultural train- are critical factors in agricultural development,
ing, often at the expense of primary, secondary, or postsecondary because a sector undergoing structural trans-
education. More often than not, attempts to substitute vocational formation has an expanding need for skills.
education in agriculture for general education have failed. The returns In addition to gaining technical skills, workers
to such training have been mixed at best, largely because the indi- need to master teamwork, communication, dili-
viduals undertaking the training and the neighbors who could learn
gence, creativity, and entrepreneurship. In many
from their example lacked sufficient basic education to make use of
cases, these behavioral soft skills are learned
more advanced, specific skills.
through mentoring and through the standards
of performance set in the formal workplace.
Agriculture as a Sector of Opportunity for Young Africans 133

As formal nonfarm employment increases, a settings around the world. Their needs then Many who
larger cohort of young people can be expected were quite similar to those of young Africans received training
to acquire behavioral skills in this way. now entering the labor force in rural and urban
commented
Institutional infrastructure for agricul- areas. Much of what has been learned about
tural higher education and training has been effective extension methods may be used to that their
in place in Africa since the 1960s but has not design advisory services and mentoring pro- farming efforts
strengthened sufficiently over time to meet the grams for young people generally, in farming are now more
enormous demands evident now. Sub-Saharan and in other spheres of activity. efficient and
Africa now has more than 200 public universi- Early models of agricultural extension were sustainable.
ties (compared with 20 in 1960), about 100 of centralized, public, and linear. The basic model
Ethiopia
which teach agriculture and natural resource was one in which a trained extension worker
management. Private universities complement traveled over a large area to convey messages to
this public capacity (World Bank 2007a). Much farmers, who then applied the advice to improve
stronger national and regional institutions are their operations. The deficiencies of this model
needed to train future professionals and lead- became clear over the years, especially in Africa.
ers with appropriate technical and functional The foremost deficiencies involved cost, qual-
skills. ity, and relevance. Traditionally designed agri-
Women face particular obstacles in obtain- cultural extension programs are now a rarity,
ing the education and training to become more although the term is still used and applied to
successful in agriculture, whether as farmers, nontraditional approaches. Newer programs
entrepreneurs, providers of extension infor- empower farmers to specify the informa-
mation, or leaders in agricultural research and tion they require and to select the provider
education. Few women graduate from agricul- (box 4.12; see Davis 2008). The provision of
tural education programs, few women become information is still recognized as a public good,
agricultural extension workers, and women are and the government assumes a share of the cost,
often marginalized during agricultural events, particularly for small farmers and the poor. The
activities, and programs. These problems are advice may be delivered by public officials, pri-
widely evident, although detailed gender- vate advisers, NGOs, or the media, depending
disaggregated data are only available sporadi- on farmers needs. The new systems are decen-
cally or are not reported at all (World Bank tralized, integrated with the private sector, coor-
2009). Efforts are under way to give stronger dinated with agricultural research, and tailored
recognition to the role of women in agricul- to local contexts. Extension is understood to be
ture, to increase the number of female students part of a broader innovation system.
in agricultural schools and colleges, and to pro- Agricultural extension services can con-
vide resources for extension services directed to tribute significantly to young farmers success,
women farmers. An innovative program was but the design of successful programs is still an
launched in 2008 by the Gender and Diversity open empirical question. Several approaches
Program of the Consultative Group on Inter- have been tried and reviewed in different con-
national Agricultural Research. The African texts, but rigorous assessment is elusive (Davis
Women in Agricultural Research and Develop- 2008). For example, participatory and group-
ment Program seeks to strengthen the research based approaches are gaining traction. These
and leadership skills of African women in agri- methods have the potential to overcome bar-
cultural science, empowering them to contrib- riers to participation, foster inclusiveness, and
ute more effectively by establishing mentoring lead to more demand-driven services. Many
partnerships, building science skills, and devel- African countries have pluralistic extension
oping leadership capacity. services (which have a variety of service pro-
viders), including Kenya, Mozambique, and
Agricultural Extension Uganda.
Agricultural extension arose to address farm- Many factors in addition to the mode of
ers needs for information in a wide array of providing extension services affect agricultural
134 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box 4.12

Innovations in agricultural extension: Relying on farmers to improve service delivery


The question of whether agricultural extension services are nicator. Small performance-based material and social incen-
best provided by the public sector (the traditional model), the tives were distributed to a subset of the treatment villages.
private sector, or a range of providers continues to generate The results from these large pilots suggest that female
debate in light of the mixed results obtained with the tra- farmers can be as productive as male farmers in teaching
ditional model.a This uncertainty has complicated efforts to their peers about a new technology and getting them to
widen the adoption of improved agricultural technologies adopt it. Adding a woman communicator to a male-cen-
and increase agricultural productivity. Newer models of exten- tered model for delivering extension advice can add value
sion, which are driven by farmers and reinforce the quality of and change the numbers of male and female beneficiaries.
service delivery through incentives and other innovations, are Evidence on the use of performance-based incentives sug-
proving more effective than traditional methods, but they, gests that providing service to the community is more costly
too, encounter difficulties and constraints to effectiveness. for women leaders, as they are more responsive to incen-
The impact of innovative approaches that mobilize farm- tives. Finally, despite performing as well as, and in some
ers to improve returns to agricultural extension was recently cases better than, male communicators, female communica-
evaluated on a large scale. In Malawi and Mozambique, tors still suffer from discrimination and are rated as worse
randomized controlled trials tested multiple modalities for teachers than men.
implementing peer and lead farming. In both experiments, Overall, these results suggest that development projects
communities nominated lead or peer farmers, who were that place the adoption of new agricultural techniques at the
trained to use sustainable land management techniques and center of their theory of change may consider using peer and
mandated to communicate those techniques to other farm- lead farming interventions to boost their returns. Given that
ers in their village through demonstrations. female leaders appear to be as productive as male leaders in
In Malawi, the social status (peer versus lead) and gender getting farmers to learn about and adopt new techniques,
of the communicator were subject to random assignment, empowering women to take on leadership roles may not
and a small performance-based material incentive was given only increase equity but also add value. Performance-based
to a subset of the communicators. The project designated incentives can play an important role in getting women lead-
shadow communicators in control villages to provide ers to devote additional time and effort to working with their
a counterfactual. In Mozambique, lead farmersmostly community.
menwere already designated by the project team in all
project villages at baseline. The intervention trained a ran- a. For example, Birkhaeuser, Evenson, and Feder (1991) found no signif-
dom subset of these lead farmers in sustainable land man- icant relationship between the provision of traditional extension services
and farm productivity in Africa, whereas Evenson (2001) and Dercon et
agement. To add a gender variation, a woman lead farmer al. (2009) identified some successes. Anderson and Feder (2003) pro-
was added to a random subset of treatment villages, since it pose an organizational inquiry into which model of extension (public or
was not possible to demote the previously chosen commu- private) can deliver superior results.

performance. Spillover effects are hard to cap- Each pathway to agricultural employment
ture or isolate. Selection bias may enter even has particular needs for advice and training
in controlled environments, and programs per- that may determine which approach will work
forming well at scale can be subverted by cli- best. For example, programs of competence-
entelism and patronage (Anderson and Feder based training in Ethiopia and Uganda in high-
2004). While most experts would agree that value export crops (horticulture and floricul-
advisory services or extension of some kind ture, respectively) are providing a workforce
are vital, particularly in light of the challenges for these demanding subsectors. Individuals in
faced by young people entering agriculture in pathways 3 and 4 (engaged in wage work either
Africa, the profession does not have a clear view part or full time) might benefit most from such
on the best approach to program design. training. For those in pathways 1 and 2, farmer
Agriculture as a Sector of Opportunity for Young Africans 135

field schools may be useful. They exist in many help they need, coupled with careful evalua- When asked
countries and are a participatory method of tion and transparent display of user satisfaction how their days
learning, technology development, and dis- with the various channels of information. The
differ from
semination based on adult-learning principles alternative approach of seeking a new, highly
such as experiential learning (World Bank structured, unitary style of extension system, their parents
2012a). A recent study in East Africa found widely applicable to all, is not likely to deliver generation,
that farmer field schools are especially benefi- good results. In designing a skills agenda for one young man
cial for women, people with low literacy levels, Africas rural young people, distinctions should offers, Those
and farmers with medium-size landholdings. be made between the needs of the stock of days were days
Field school participants had significant dif- young adults in the labor force todaywhose
for farming and
ferences in outcomes with respect to the value elementary education is incompleteand the
of crops produced per acre, the livestock value children who will flow into the labor force in that is it. Now
gained per head, and agricultural income per the future. The very young need better schools we do farming,
capita (Davis et al. 2010). For those in path- with more learning as a matter of highest we do business,
way 1 who adopt a more corporate approach urgency. Those who are already beyond school we even go to
to family farming, the shift to entrepreneurial age will need a mix of short-term remedial pro- school in great
family farms can be aided by local agribusiness grams for applied literacy and numeracy and
numbers.
development services, which are advisory ser- access to mentoring, apprenticeships, and flows
vices with a business orientation. Although the of just-in-time information, perhaps deliv- Tanzania
provision and use of these services are still rela- ered through electronic media.
tively new, anticipated impacts for smaller-scale
farmers and entrepreneurs include enhanced
rural income (both directly and through Current Agricultural Programs
employment) and enhanced small-scale entre- Deliver Too Little, Too Slowly,
preneurial activity (World Bank 2012a). Such to Meet the Needs of Africas
services could also assist young people seeking Young People
to combine self-employment with part-time
farming (pathway 3). As early as 2003, African heads of state met
Producer organizations can be a highly in Maputo, Mozambique, and pledged to give
effective means of building members skills renewed attention and resources to agriculture.
and entrepreneurial expertise by improving The pledge was made under the rubric of the
access to advice and training. Once again, how- Comprehensive African Agriculture Develop-
ever, the ability to self-organize and participate ment Programme (CAADP) of the African
effectively in such organizations requires the Union and the New Partnership for Africas
fundamentals of a solid education. Development.21 The CAADP framework rec-
ognizes the breadth of the agricultural agenda
Priorities for a Diverse Skills Agenda and the corresponding need for multiple entry
The skills agenda to meet the needs of Africas points and complementary public investments
young people is diverse, and the resources to in several areas (box 4.13).
address that agenda are highly constrained. Until food prices spiked in 2008, the com-
Priority should be accorded to improving the mitment to increase public spending on agri-
quality of basic education and keeping young culture was not implemented widely, but
people in school long enough for them to between 2003 and 2008, the technical work to
acquire basic skills. Agricultural programs in design a framework for reinvestment in agri-
tertiary education must be strengthened to culture under CAADP proceeded. When rising
produce a new generation of scientists and food prices caught the attention of global and
teachers in all fields. In the intermediate arena African leaders, the conceptual framework was
of extension and outreach, emphasis should be available to address the long-standing neglect
placed on providing resources to the final users of key public goods and services. The frame-
of information, so that they can seek out the work does not specifically recognize the unique
136 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box 4.13

Overview of the Comprehensive African Agriculture Development Programme (CAADP)


CAADPs four pillars are complementary. The first pillar, land ity and profitability provide a cushion of savings for hard
and water, addresses the design of programs and invest- times.
ment required to improve land administration, sustainability Finally, the agricultural technology pillar underpins the
of land use, and management of water through irrigation other three. Modern agriculture is science based, and pro-
and water harvesting and storage. ducers at all levels of sophistication benefit from improved
The second pillar identifies investment and reforms in systems to generate and spread improved technologies.
policy and regulations needed to improve smallholders Some of these entail breeding improved crops and animals
access to markets. Many of these interventions focus on rural to address changing demand or agro-ecological conditions
infrastructure, including roads, rail transport, and power or to allow producers to select a desired level of risk. Oth-
(both on- and off-grid), but important regulatory measures ers emphasize new systems of management and rotation,
also require attention, such as regulation of the trucking to reduce costs of inputs, enhance soil health, and capture
industry and food safety standards. These measures aim to carbon for additional revenue streams.
reduce marketing costs to make farming more profitable, The CAADP framework is applied to help countries and
while reducing food prices for net buyers to accelerate job regions to improve the quality of their agricultural planning
creation. and policy making and to use them as the basis for scaled-
The third pillar addresses measures that will make up investment in the sector. CAADP offers political, tech-
agriculture less risky for those with a commercial orienta- nical, and financial support for countries and regions that
tion and strengthen the resilience of the very poor when engage in this process, through a partnership of continental
shocks hit. Diversification, affordable insurance products, and regional African institutions in collaboration with other
and rural safety nets can help people to manage risks, and stakeholders, including civil society, the private sector, and
higher income levels associated with growth in productiv- Africas development partners.

demography of Africa, nor does it make spe- and private sectors, domestically and interna-
cific provisions for young farmers, but its key tionally, under strategic initiatives already in
features can be enriched to address a youth place. No new or separate strategy is required,
agenda. but the current slow pace of implementa-
Complementing the largely public ele- tion, if continued, will fail young people and
ments of CAADP, local and international pri- compromise Africas future. Existing com-
vate investors are expressing growing interest mitments must be accorded focused atten-
in the opportunities in agriculture. The Afri- tion, with improved quality of public spend-
can Union has declared a Decade on Youth ing, more efficient approaches to increasing
Development in Africa 20092019. The United production of food staples, more attention to
Nations General Assembly has called for mem- meeting demand for high-quality products by
ber states to prepare a National Review and the growing urban middle classes, continued
Action Plan on Youth Employment, and the progress on policy and regulatory reforms, and
African Union, Economic Commission for improved data and tracking of progress. With
Africa, African Development Bank, and the better-implemented public programs, private
ILO have recently proposed a Joint Initiative investment will accelerate, and opportunities
on Job Creation for Youth in Africa. The initia- for young people will increase. Some proac-
tives demonstrate the level of attention being tive additional attention to meet the specific
given to the youth employment issue (Proctor needs of the large group of young people may
and Lucchesi 2012). Each of these organiza- be required, but doing so without more effec-
tions also emphasizes agriculture. tive programs in general will be counterpro-
Thus efforts to reach out to Africas young ductive. Successfully mobilizing the talents of
farmers can draw on resources from the public young people will increase the likelihood that
Agriculture as a Sector of Opportunity for Young Africans 137

CAADP and other ongoing initiatives will meet years oldthe mature young. Energy, cre-
their ambitious goals. ativity, and strength are attributes that Africas
young people have in abundance. The agricul-
ture that attracts them will have to be profit-
Harnessing Agricultures Youth able, competitive, and dynamic. These same
Dividend characteristics are needed for agriculture to
deliver growth, to improve food security, and
Agriculturealready Africas largest to preserve a fragile natural environment. With
employeris changing, and the large num- much higher priority accorded to the imple-
bers of young people entering the sector will mentation of well-designed programs of public
accelerate the pace of change. Africas leaders investment in agriculture, continued progress
recognize that agriculture is a source of growth, on regulatory and policy reform, and a mod-
an instrument for improved food security, and est overlay of attention to assure the inclusion
a means to steward valuable natural resources. of young people in Africas agricultural renais-
As the potential for the sector to absorb the sance, the sectors youth dividend can be col-
large numbers of new job seekers and to offer lected and widely shared.
meaningful work with public and private ben-
efits becomes clearer, agriculture will gain even Notes
more attention from policy makers. 1. Whether an economys agricultural labor force
This attention will be necessary, because the rose or fell in absolute numbers as the relative
sectors ability to create jobs will not be real- share of the sector declined depended on birth
and death rates in rural areas, migration, and
ized without modifications to public programs.
the size and labor intensity of sectors that were
Present levels of public investment are not suf- growing more rapidly than agriculture. See Tim-
ficient. The quality of investment is inadequate mer and Akkus (2008).
to yield high returns. Too much has gone into 2. For example, farmers grow modern improved
short-term palliatives, such as fertilizer sub- varieties of food crops on an estimated 35 per-
sidies, without complementary attention to cent of all planted area, compared to just 23 per-
improved technologies and management prac- cent in 1998 (Renkow and Byerlee 2010).
tices and long-term investments in research 3. A band of settlements of 10,000 or more inhab-
and infrastructure. The investment climate still itants now stretches from Djibouti to Dakar,
cannot attract the private firms needed in mar- with few gaps in between. Another rings Lake
keting, processing, input supply, and finance. Victoria, and another marks the Kinshasa-
Brazzaville corridor.
Public policies governing trade, the introduc-
4. Agricultural total factor productivity is grow-
tion of new varieties, licensing and intellectual ing at just over and under 3 percent annually in
property rights, and taxation offer weak incen- Southeast Asia and South America, respectively.
tives to producers and innovators. Since 2000, total factor productivity in Sub-
Detailed agendas in each of these areas are Saharan Africa has been higher than the aver-
beyond the scope of this chapter, but the future age in the four prior decades but is still short
of Africas young people is at present hostage to of being transformative. Estimates range from
the wide gap between rhetorical commitment just under 1 percent annually to just over 2 per-
to the importance of agriculture and actual, cent annually, owing to severe deficiencies in the
effective attention accorded to it by Africas underlying data; see Fuglie (2011); Nin-Pratt,
leaders. Efforts to address constraints to land, Johnson, and Yu (2012).
5. After food prices spiked in 200708, govern-
capital, and skills will have to be redoubled and
ments began to set ambitious growth targets for
accelerated, and features to make programs agriculture. At 810 percent, those rates exceed
friendly to the needs of the young introduced. the 6 percent target set by the African Union
Although farming is often done by the through the Comprehensive Africa Agriculture
elderly, the professions requirements for Development Programme and the rates recently
energy, innovation, and physical strength make observed for the entire region (3.84.0 percent;
it ideally suited for persons who are 2545 World Bank 2012c).
138 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

6. This section draws heavily on AgriFin (2012) for transportation, water, shelter, and farm
and IFPRI and World Bank (2010). development.
7. Organisation pour lHarmonisation en Afrique 21. See http://www.nepad-caadp.net/.
du Droit des Affaires (Organization for the Har-
monization of Business Law in Africa).
8. Caisses dEpargne et de Crdit Agricole
References
Abdulai, Awudu, and Wallace E. Huffman. 2005.
Mutuelles, a cooperative agricultural financial The Diffusion of New Agricultural Technolo-
institution. gies: The Case of Crossbreeding Technology in
9. This section draws from World Bank (2010a). Tanzania. American Journal of Agricultural Eco-
10. IFPRI and World Bank (2010, brief 4); see also nomicss 87 (3): 64559.
http://www.rabobank.com/content/products_ AgriFin. 2012. Making Finance Work for Africa:
services/business_clients/professionalproducts/ Policy Brief on Agricultural Finance in Africa.
raboagrifund/index.jsp. Report sponsored by the African Union, GIZ,
11. See http://www.rabobank.com/content/products_ and BMZ. Washington, DC.
services/business_clients/professionalproducts/ Aker, Jenny C. 2008. Does Digital Divide or Pro-
raboagrifund/index.jsp. vide? The Impact of Cell Phones on Grain Mar-
12. For a perspective on equity issues arising from kets in Niger. CGD Working Paper 154, Center
heightened global interest in Africas farmland, for Global Development, Washington, DC.
see Deininger and Byerlee (2011). Aker, Jenny C., and Marcel Fafchamps. 2010. How
13. See Deininger, Selod, and Burns (2011) for more Does Mobile Phone Coverage Affect Farm-Gate
on this relatively quick and innovative tool. Prices? Evidence from West Africa. Working
14. Endorsed by the Committee on World Food Paper, Tufts University, Department of Econom-
Security in May 2012, the Voluntary Guidelines ics and the Fletcher School; Center for Global
promote secure tenure rights and equitable Development; University of Oxford, Center for
access to land, fisheries, and forests as a means the Study of African Economies. http://www.
of eradicating hunger and poverty, supporting aeaweb.org/aea/2011conference/program/
sustainable development, and enhancing the retrieve.php?pdfid=629.
environment. They set out principles and inter- Amanor, Kojo S., and Maxwell K. Diderutuah.
nationally recommended standards for respon- 2001. Share Contracts in the Oil Palm and Cit-
sible practices. They are a framework that actors rus Belt of Ghana. International Institute for
can use when developing their own strategies, Environment and Development, London.
policies, legislation, and programs, allowing Anderson, Mary, Dayna Brown, and Isabella Jean.
government authorities, the private sector, civil 2012. Time to Listen: Hearing People on the
society, and citizens to judge whether their pro- Receiving End of International Aid. CDA Col-
posed actions and the actions of others consti- laborative Learning Project, Cambridge, MA.
tute acceptable practices. Anderson, Jock, and Gershon Feder. 2003. Rural
15. Encouraging collaboration with the Sustain- Extension Services. Policy Research Working
able Commodity Roundtables can also help to Paper 2976, World Bank, Washington, DC.
increase the extent to which crop production . 2004. Agricultural Extension: Good Inten-
systems meet voluntary environmental and tions and Hard Realities. World Bank Research
social criteria, including those of the Roundtable Observerr 19 (1): 4160.
for Responsible Soy, the Roundtable on Sustain- Besley, Timothy, and Anne Case. 1993. Modeling
able Palm Oil, the Better Sugarcane Initiative, Technology Adoption in Developing Countries.
and a variety of forest certification processes. American Economic Revieww 83 (2): 396402.
16. The following sections draw heavily from World Birkhaeuser, Dean, Robert Evenson, and Gershon
Bank (2012b). Feder. 1991. The Economic Impact of Agricul-
17. For example, in China, the Dominican Republic, tural Extension: A Review. Economic Develop-
Ethiopia, Nicaragua, and Vietnam. ment and Cultural Changee 39 (3): 60750.
18. This section is adapted from Lahiff and Li Bruce, John W., and Anna Knox. 2009. Structures
(2012); World Bank (2012b). and Stratagems: Decentralization of Authority
19. Adapted from Tchale (2012); World Bank over Land in Africa. World Development, special
(2012b). issue on the limits of state-led land reform 37
20. Each family received a grant of US$1,050, man- (8): 136069.
aged directly by the beneficiary; up to 30 per- Camacho, Adriana, and Emily Conover. 2011. The
cent was for land acquisition, and the rest was Impact of Receiving Price and Climate Informa-
Agriculture as a Sector of Opportunity for Young Africans 139

tion in the Agricultural Sector. Working Paper De Wolf, Stefan, Yves Rolland Rakotoarisoa, Lau-
IDB-WP-220, Inter-American Development rence Vanpaeschen, and Honor Rabekoto. 2008.
Bank, Washington, DC. Madagascar: Le Grand Livre des Petits Mtiers:
Chirwaa, Ephraim W. 2008. Land Tenure, Farm Portraits of Daily Life Professions. Heule, Belgium:
Investments, and Food Production in Malawi. Snoek Publishers.
Discussion Paper 18, prepared for Institutions Djurfeldt, Agnes Andersson, and Magnus Jirstrm.
and Pro-Poor Growth (IPPG). 2013. Urbanization and Changes in Farm Size in
Cole, Shawn, and Stefan. Hunt. 2010. Information, Sub-Saharan Africa and Asia from a Geographi-
Expectations, and Agricultural Investment: Evi- cal Perspective: A Review of the Literature. A
dence from a Field Experiment in India. Work- Foresight Study of the Independent Science and
ing Paper, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA. Partnership Council, Consultative Group on
International Agricultural Research, Washing-
Conley, Timothy, and Christopher Udry. 2010. ton, DC. http://www.sciencecouncil.cgiar.org/file
Learning about a New Technology: Pineapple admin/templates/ispc/documents/Strategy_and_
in Ghana. American Economic Review
w 100 (1): Trends/2013/Foresight.Andersson.pdf.
3569.
Estudillo, Jonna P., Agnes R. Quisumbing, and
Davis, Kristin. 2008. Extension in Sub-Saharan Keijiro Otsuka. 2001. Gender Differences in
Africa: Overview and Assessment of Past and Land Inheritance and Schooling Investments in
Current Models and Future Prospects. Journal of the Rural Philippines. Land Economicss 77 (1):
International Agricultural and Extension Educa- 13043.
tion 15 (3): 1528.
Evenson, Robert. 2001. Economic Impacts of Agri-
Davis, Kristin, Ephraim Nkonya, Edward Kato, cultural Research and Extension. In Handbook of
Daniel A. Mekonnen, Martins Odendo, Richard Agricultural Economics. Vol. 1a: Agricultural Pro-
Miiro, and Jackson Nkuba. 2010. Impact of duction, edited by Bruce L. Gardner and Gordon
Farmer Field Schools on Agricultural Productiv- C. Rausser, 573628. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
ity, Poverty, and Farmer Empowerment in East
Africa. IFPRI Discussion Paper, International Executive Office of the President. 2011. Economic
Food Policy Research Institute, Washington, DC. Report of the President 2011. U.S. Council of
Economic Advisers, Washington, DC.
Deininger, Klaus. 2003. Land Policies for Growth
and Poverty Reduction. Washington, DC: World Fafchamps, Marcel, and Bart Minten. 2012. Impact
Bank. of SMS-Based Agricultural Information on
Indian Farmers. World Bank Economic Review
Deininger, Klaus, Daniel A. Ali, and Tekie Alemu. 26 (3): 383414.
2011. Impacts of Land Certification on Tenure
Security, Investment, and Land Market Participa- FAO (Food and Agriculture Organization). 2011.
tion: Evidence from Ethiopia. Land Economics Women in Agriculture: Closing the Gender Gap
87 (2): 31234. in Agriculture. State of Food and Agriculture
Report. Rome: FAO.
Deininger, Klaus, and Derek Byerlee. 2011. Rising
Global Interest in Farm Land: Can It Yield Sus- FAO (Food and Agriculture Organization), IFAD
tainable and Equitable Benefits? World Bank, (International Fund for Agricultural Develop-
Washington, DC. ment), and MIJARC (Mouvement International
de la Jeunesse Agricole et Rurale Catholique).
Deininger, Klaus, Songqing Jin, Berhanu Adenew,
2012. Facilitating Access of Rural Youth to Agri-
Samuel Gebre-Selassie, and Mulat Demke. 2003.
cultural Activities. Farmers Forum Youth Ses-
Market and Non-Market Transfers of Land in
sion, Rome, February 18.
Ethiopia: Implications for Efficiency, Equity, and
Nonfarm Development. Policy Research Paper Foster, Andrew D., and Mark R. Rosenzweig. 1996.
2992, World Bank, Washington, DC. Technical Change and Human-Capital Returns
Deininger, Klaus, Harris Selod, and Anthony Burns. and Investments: Evidence from the Green
2011. The Land Governance Assessment Frame- Revolution. American Economic Review
w 86 (4):
work: Identifying and Monitoring Good Practice 93153.
in the Land Sector. ARD Series, World Bank, Fox, Louise, and Thomas Pave Sohnesen. 2012.
Washington, DC. Household Enterprises in Sub-Saharan Africa:
Dercon, Stefan, Daniel O. Gilligan, John Hoddinott, Why They Matter for Growth, Jobs, and Liveli-
and Tassew Woldehanna. 2009. The Impact of hoods. Policy Research Working Paper 6184,
Agricultural Extension and Roads on Poverty World Bank, Washington, DC.
and Consumption Growth in Fifteen Ethiopian Fuglie, Keith. 2011. Agricultural Productivity in
Villages. American Journal of Agricultural Eco- Sub-Saharan Africa. In The Food and Financial
nomicss 91 (4): 100721. Crises in Sub-Saharan Africa: Origins, Impacts,
140 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

and Policy Implications, edited by David R. Lee Africa. IFPRI Discussion Paper 01059, Interna-
and Muna Ndulo. Cambridge, MA: CABI. tional Food Policy Research Institute, Washing-
Goyal, Aparajita. 2010. Information, Direct Access ton, DC.
to Farmers, and Rural Market Performance Morris, Michael, Hans Binswanger-Mkhize, and
in Central India. American Economic Journal: Derek Byerlee. 2009. Awakening Africas Sleeping
Applied Economicss 2 (3): 2245. Giant. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Huffman, Wallace E. 1977. Allocative Efficiency: Nagayets, Oksana. 2005. Small Farms: Current Sta-
The Role of Human Capital. Quarterly Journal tus and Key Trends. Information brief prepared
of Economicss 91 (February): 5979. for the Future of Small Farms Research Work-
IDS (Institute of Development Studies). 2012. shop, Wye College, June 2629.
Young People and Agriculture in Africa. IDS Nin-Pratt, Alejandro, Michael Johnson, and
Bulletin, special issue 43 (6). Bingxin Yu. 2012. Improved Performance of
IFPRI (International Food Policy Research Insti- Agriculture in Africa South of the Sahara: Taking
tute) and World Bank. 2010. Innovations in Off or Bouncing Back? IFPRI Discussion Paper
Rural and Agriculture Finance: Focus 18. Wash- 01224, International Food Policy Research Insti-
ington, DC. tute, Washington, DC.

Jensen, Robert. 2007. The Digital Provide: Infor- OECD and FAO (Organisation for Economic Co-
mation (Technology), Market Performance, and operation and Development and Food and Agri-
Welfare in the South Indian Fisheries Sector. culture Organization). 2012. Agricultural Outlook
Quarterly Journal of Economicss 122 (3): 879924. 20122012. Annex B, Table B.1. Paris: OECD;
Rome: FAO.
Kasanga, Kasim, and Nii Kotey. 2001. Land Man-
agement in Ghana: Building on Tradition and Petesch, Patti, and Ines Rodrguez Caillava. 2012.
Modernity. International Institute for Environ- Voices of Young Villagers in Sub-Saharan
ment and Development, London. Africa. Background paper, World Bank, Wash-
ington, DC.
Kevane, Michael. 1996. Agrarian Structure and
Agricultural Practice: Typology and Application Proctor, Felicity J., and Valerio Lucchesi. 2012.
to Western Sudan. American Journal of Agricul- Small-Scale Farming and Youth in an Era of
tural Economicss 78 (1): 23645. Rapid Rural Change. International Institute for
Environment and Development, London.
Kloeppinger-Todd, Renate, Ajai Nair, and Annabel
Mulder. 2004. Leasing: An Underutilized Tool in Renkow, Mitch, and Derek Byerlee. 2010. The
Rural Finance. ARD Discussion Paper 7, World Impact of CGIAR Research: A Review of Recent
Bank, Washington, DC. Evidence. Food Policyy 35 (5): 391402.

Lahiff, Edward, and Guo Li. 2012. Land Redistri- Rosenzweig, Mark. 2010. Microeconomic
bution in South Africa: A Critical Review. Work- Approaches to Development: Schooling, Learn-
ing Paper for the Land Administration and ing, and Growth. Journal of Economic Perspec-
Reform in SSA study, World Bank, Washington, tives, American Economic Association 24 (3):
DC. 8196.

Larson, Donald, Keijiro Otsuka, Tomoya Matsu- Schultz, T. Paul. 1988. Education Investments and
moto, and Talip Kilic. 2012. Should African Returns. 1988. In Handbook of Development Eco-
Rural Development Strategies Depend on Small- nomics, Vol. 1, edited by Hollis Chenery and T. N.
holder Farms? An Exploration of the Inverse Srinivasan, ch. 1, 543630. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
Productivity Hypothesis. Policy Research Work- Selod, Harris. 2012. Formalizing Rural Land
ing Paper 6190, World Bank, Washington, DC. Rights in West Africa: Results from an Impact
Losch, Bruno, Sandrine Frguin-Gresh, and Eric Evaluation in Benin. Paper prepared for the
Thomas White. 2012. Structural Transformation conference Land and Poverty 2012, World
and Rural Change Revisited: Challenges for Late Bank, Washington, DC, April 2326.
Developing Countries in a Globalizing World. Sutton, John, and Nebil Kellow. 2010. An Enterprise
African Development Forum series. Washington, Map of Ethiopia. London: International Growth
DC: World Bank. Centre.
Maertens, Miet, Bart Minten, and Jo Swinnen. Svensson, Jakob, and David Yanagizawa. 2009.
2009. Growth in High-Value Export Markets in Getting Prices Right: The Impact of the Market
Sub-Saharan Africa and Its Development Impli- Information Service in Uganda. Journal of the
cations. LICOS Discussion Paper 245, Katho- European Economic Association 7 (23): 43545.
lieke Universiteit, Leuven. Tchale, Hardwick. 2012. Pilot Redistributive Land
Minot, Nicholas. 2011. Transmission of World Reform in Malawi: Innovations and Emerging
Food Price Changes to Markets in Sub-Saharan Good Practices. Working Paper for the Land
Agriculture as a Sector of Opportunity for Young Africans 141

Administration and Reform in SSA study, World Region Human Development Department, World
Bank, Washington, DC. Bank, Washington, DC.
Timmer, Peter, and Selvin Akkus. 2008. The . 2007b. South Asia: Livelihoods Learning:
Structural Transformation as a Pathway out of Community-Managed Microfinance: A New
Poverty: Analytics, Empirics, and Politics. Work- Model from Sri Lanka. Series 1, Note 5, World
ing Paper 150, Center for Global Development, Bank, Washington, DC.
Washington, DC. . 2009. Gender in Agriculture Sourcebook.
Torkelsson, Asa. 2012. Sex Disaggregated Data on Washington, DC: World Bank.
Agriculture, Water, and Food Security: Lessons . 2010a. Designing and Implementing
from Kenya. World Water Week Seminar on Agricultural Innovation Funds: Lessons from
Global Practice in Promoting Gender Equality in Competitive Research and Matching Grant Proj-
the Water Sector, Stockholm, August 30. ects. Report 54857-GLB, World Bank, Washing-
United Republic of Kenya. 2010. The Constitu- ton, DC.
tion of Kenya 2010. National Council for Law . 2010b. Doing Business 2011: Making a
Reporting, Nairobi. Difference for Entrepreneurs. Washington, DC:
Welch, Finis. 1970. Education in Production. World Bank.
Journal of Political Economyy 78 (1): 3559. . 2011. Kenya Informal Settlements
Improvement Project. Project Appraisal Docu-
World Bank. n.d. Sri Lanka Community Develop-
ment, World Bank, Washington, DC.
ment and Livelihood Improvement Gemidiriya
Project: Analysis of Youth Inclusion and Partici- . 2012a. Agricultural Innovation Systems: An
pation in Gemidiriya. World Bank, Washington, Investment Sourcebook. Washington, DC: World
DC. Bank.
. 2004. Malawi Community-Based Rural . 2012b. Land Administration and Reform
Land Development Project. Project Appraisal in Sub-Saharan Africa: From Piloting to Scaling
Document, World Bank, Washington, DC. Up. World Bank, Washington, DC.
. 2007. Cultivating Knowledge and Skills . 2012c. World Development Indicators
to Grow African Agriculture: A Synthesis of an 2012. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Institutional, Regional, and International Review, . 2013. Growing Africa: Unlocking the
2007. Report No. 40997-AFR. Agriculture and Potential of Agribusiness. AFTFP/AFTAI
Rural Development Department and Africa Report, World Bank, Washington, DC.
FOCUS Safety Nets and Pathways to
NOTE 2 Productive Employment

S
ocial safety nets are programs that aim to ment at a critical period when youth may be
increase households consumption of basic completing their education, transitioning to
commodities and facilitate access to basic work, or already working on their own account
services (Grosh et al. 2008; Monchuk 2014). in low-productivity occupations. As such,
They can also help households to cope with safety nets with these complementary compo-
shocks such as an economic crisis, drought, nents have the potential to improve produc-
or illness. The coverage of safety net programs tive employment for the current generation of
targeted to poor and vulnerable households is youth.
growing rapidly in Africa (Monchuk 2014; Sub-
barao et al. 2013; McCord and Slater 2009). The
most common safety nets include public works Short-Term Benefits of Safety Net
and cash transfer programs. Participants in Programs
public works programs receive cash or food in
exchange for engaging in labor-intensive work African governments rely extensively on pub-
to build or maintain public goods such as local lic works programs to provide short-term
infrastructure. Some longer-term public works employment. Public works programs are com-
programs ensure temporary employment to the mon throughout the region and typically offer
poor at critical junctures, such as lean periods temporary employment for periods ranging
in the agricultural cycle. Cash transfers provide from 10 days to 6 months.2 For example, the
temporary relief to households to reduce pov- Malawi Social Action Fund has offered tem-
erty. These traditional safety nets can improve porary employment to more than 800,000
productivity in the long term through a range individuals for 12 days on average since 1995
of channels (Alderman and Yemtsov 2013). (World Bank 2011). The Tanzania Social Action
For instance, safety nets have been shown to Fund offers cash transfers through short-term
increase human capital by improving nutrition employment in a labor-intensive public works
and access to education and health services.1 program, which has offered an average of 75
Such improvements for todays children can days of employment to more than 200,000 ben-
contribute to higher labor productivity for eficiaries since 2000 (World Bank 2010). One
tomorrows youth. public works program of longer duration is
Because safety net programs explicitly tar- Ethiopias Productive Safety Net Program. Par-
get the poor or vulnerable, they often reach the ticipants, who can remain in the program for
core of the population engaged in low-produc- up to five years, work during the lean season
tivity employment, particularly in agriculture on labor-intensive projects building commu-
and household enterprises. Many governments nity assets, such as soil and water conservation
also deliver complementary productive inter- structures. The program reaches more than 7
ventions through safety net programs, with million people and operates with an annual
the explicit objective of fostering productive budget of nearly US$500 million (Gilligan,
employment in the short to medium term. The Hoddinott, and Taffesse 2009).
intention is to allow poor households to build Public works programs have well-docu-
pathways to raise productivity in the farming mented short-term benefits, including on par-
sector, diversify livelihoods, or enter into non- ticipants income. To work the hours required
farm household enterprises. If complementary by these labor-intensive programs, beneficiaries
productive interventions are targeted to youth, usually forgo other income-earning opportuni-
they can pave a pathway to productive employ- ties (Subbarao et al. 2013). For this reason, ben-
142
Focus Note 2 143

eficiaries earnings generally increase less than a range of outcomes such as food security or
the actual wages they receive (which are usu- nutrition, and increasing the use of health or
ally based on estimated market rates for wage education services (see Fiszbein and Schady
employment or a minimum wage). Argentina 2009 for a review). There is also growing evi-
initiated a public works program in 2002 after a dence showing that cash transfer beneficiaries
severe economic crisis pushed unemployment are able to save and enter into more produc-
and poverty to record heights. Net earnings tive activities, even if these programs were not
(after subtracting income forgone from other designed with that objective in mind.3 For
activities) were estimated to be two-thirds of instance, in Malawi, cash transfers facilitated
the benefits offered by the public works pro- investments in agricultural assets and livestock
gram during the crisis and only one-third of and reduced adults participation in low-skilled
those offered after the crisis had dissipated labor (Covarrubias, Davis, and Winters 2012).
(Galasso and Ravallion 2004). In Mexico, cash transfers led poor rural house-
In low-income African countries, nearly holds to invest in productive assets such as farm
all individuals are working, and very few are animals and land for agricultural production,
unemployed (see discussion in chapter 1). In increasing agricultural income by 10 percent
this context, public works do not necessarily (Gertler, Martinez, and Rubio-Codina 2011).
substantially increase overall employment. At Beneficiaries were also more likely to start non-
the same time, public works programs tend agricultural household enterprises, particularly
to be oversubscribed despite paying low wages the production of handcrafts for sale.
and can strongly increase the earnings of ben- A new generation of safety net programs
eficiaries. Few evaluations measure net earn- is trying to be more explicit about maximiz-
ings gains from participating in public works ing their productive potential in the short to
programs in Africa. medium term.
Overall, public works programs are first
and foremost social protection programs that
provide temporary employment. They are Safety Nets Plus Explicit
generally not designed to foster sustainable Productive Components
productive employment beyond beneficiaries
participation in the program. Some evidence A growing number of safety net programs
suggests that traditional public works pro- attempt to create the conditions for benefi-
grams can open pathways to employment in ciaries to access pathways to more productive
new activities, even if that is not their primary employment or sustainable livelihoods in the
goal. In Liberia, participants reported using short to medium term. Policy makers start with
14.2 percent of the income from public works the proven ability of safety net programs to
for farm and nonfarm investments (Andrews stabilize household consumption and add pro-
et al. 2011). In Ethiopia, beneficiaries from the ductive interventions that may lead to sustain-
public works program were more likely to enter able, productive employment for the current
in nonfarm business activities and less likely generation. For example, public works plus
to work as day laborers (Gilligan, Hoddinott, delivers complementary services such as links
and Taffesse 2009). Evidence from an impact to financial services or training in a range of
evaluation in Sierra Leone shows that partici- skills. Some cash transfer plus programs take
pation in a cash-for-works program increased a similar approach.
participation in informal saving groups, led to
accumulation of assets such as livestock, and Financial Services
fostered the creation of new household enter- A growing number of public works programs
prises (Rosas and Sabarwal 2013). aim to strengthen financial inclusion or build
Cash transfer programs also primarily linkages to other intermediate services. Par-
focus on immediate poverty relief, and there ticipants in Rwandas Vision Umurenge Pro-
is solid evidence documenting their short- gramme are given access to bank accounts and
term impacts on reducing poverty, improving encouraged to save some of their earnings.
144 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Beneficiaries of Tanzanias Productive Safety and My Community, Making a Living, Manag-


Net Program can participate in small groups ing Money, My Workplace, My Health, and My
that promote community savings to increase Future.
their ability to save for future needs and invest- Some programs deliver a package of benefits
ments; a similar approach is being considered including cash transfers together with a range
for a public works program in Mozambique. A of complementary productive interventions.
public works program in Cte dIvoire includes For instance, the targeting the ultra-poor or
a component that fosters saving by deliver- graduation model is currently being tested
ing payments to a bank account (during its in 10 countries around the world including
pilot phase, the program awarded a matching Ethiopia and Ghana (Hashemi and Montes-
grant to participants who had saved a certain quiou 2011). The intervention targets the poor
amount). For more discussion on financial ser- and offers basic consumption support similar
vices, see focus note 3. to a safety net program. It also facilitates sav-
ings, transfers assets to allow the poor to enter
Capital into higher-productivity farming activities (for
Participants in Ethiopias public works program example, livestock) or start a household enter-
are linked to the Household Asset Building Pro- prise, and provides skills training and regular
gram to help them to make their farms more technical assistance to beneficiaries. The stated
productive and to increase their long-term food objective of this approach is to help households
security. They obtain at least one of several to graduate from extreme poverty through pro-
productivity-enhancing transfers or services, ductive employment.
including access to credit, agricultural extension
services, technology transfer (such as advice on
food crop production, cash cropping, livestock Do Complementary Interventions
production, and soil and water conservation),
Open Pathways toward
and irrigation and water harvesting schemes
(Gilligan, Hoddinott, and Taffesse 2009). Productive Employment for
Youth?
Skills Training
Many public works programs also provide Despite their potential to increase productiv-
short-term training in basic literacy, skills for ity and facilitate entry into new employment
microenterprise development, technical skills, opportunities, few rigorous evaluations have
or life skills. In South Africas Expanded Public shown that expanded safety net programs
Works Program, beneficiaries receive two days lead to employment or productivity gains.4 In
of training each month in literacy and numer- Ethiopia, households with access to the public
acy, vocational skills, and business skills. In works program and complementary interven-
Cte dIvoire, the public works program imple- tions are more likely to be food secure and
mented by the national roads agency includes are more likely to borrow for productive pur-
sensitization in basic life skills, training in basic poses, use improved agricultural technologies,
business skills to help participants to set up a and operate nonfarm own business activi-
household enterprise, and sensitization to wage ties (Gilligan, Hoddinott, and Taffesse 2009).
employment opportunities to help youth to Their incomes grow, and distress sales of assets
prepare themselves and search for a wage job. decline. Elsewhere in Africa, evidence on the
In Liberia, the community works component productive impacts of public works plus
of the Youth Employment and Skills Project programs is limited, especially evidence on the
provides eight sessions of life skills training effectiveness of short training modules and
during the 40-day works program. Each of links to financial services. An evaluation testing
these sessions lasts two to three hours and is alternative complementary training targeted to
led by 1 trainer for every 25 trainees. The life young beneficiaries of a public works program
skills training has six main sections: Myself is under way in Cte dIvoire.
Focus Note 2 145

Figure F2.1 Impacts of conditional cash transfers plus business grants or conditional cash transfers plus skills
training in Nicaragua

a. Consumption and employment b. Profits and wages


14 1,400

12 1,200

Change in local currency (C$)


10 1,000

8 800
% increase

6 600

4 400

2 200

0 0

2 200

4 400
Consumption (log) Nonagricultural Nonagricultural Profits in nonagricultural Wage in private jobs
self-employment wage job self-employment

Conditional cash transfers plus training Conditional cash transfers plus grants

Source: Macours, Premand, and Vakis 2012.


Note: Impacts are measured as differences between beneficiaries and a control group. The impact on consumption and entry in a nonagri-
cultural wage job is not significant for beneficiaries of the conditional cash transfers plus training package, while the impact on entry in
a nonagricultural wage job and on wages in a private sector wage job is not significant for beneficiaries of the conditional cash transfers
plus grant package.

Evidence is also thin on the effectiveness training delivered to cash transfer recipients was
of productive components embedded in cash to increase wages in private wage jobs. But over-
transfer programs. In Niger, monitoring data all the average impact on income and consump-
suggested that beneficiaries save a substantial tion across all beneficiaries was not significant.
share of their earnings through savings groups Early results from impact evaluations of the
created by the program. A new cash transfer graduation model also suggest substantial
program in Cameroon encourages beneficia- productive impacts. For instance, a program
ries to participate in awareness and training that targets the ultra-poor with a package
activities to learn about generating income, including large asset transfers and intensive
understand how to access microfinance, and training was effective in inducing entry into
acquire business skills. Impact evaluations are self-employment in Bangladesh. The com-
under way in both countries. bined intervention was successful in inducing
Although the effectiveness of complemen- a change from agricultural wage labor to small
tary productive interventions has not been businesses, raising annual income 36 percent
ascertained in Africa, promising evidence is on average (Bandiera et al. 2012). These results
emerging elsewhere. In rural areas of Nicaragua, are consistent with evidence emerging from
an evaluation tests the relative effectiveness of similar programs in Honduras, Pakistan, and
complementing a cash transfer program with West Bengal.
business grants or vocational training (see fig-
ure F2.1; Macours, Premand, and Vakis 2012).
Two years after the end of the program, results Safety Nets as Vehicles to Deliver
show that the business grant enabled cash Interventions Aimed at Improving
transfer recipients to enter nonagricultural self- Youth Employment Outcomes
employment and increased profits in household
enterprises as well as overall income and con- Traditional safety nets do not seek primarily to
sumption. The main effect of the vocational foster productive employment for the current
146 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

generation of youth, but they have the potential to those of a program delivering cash to benefi-
to do so. These programs target the very house- ciaries amounting to the labor and capital costs
holds that are engaged in low-productivity of a public works program.
activities. As such, safety net programs have the
potential to deliver complementary interven- References
tions opening pathways toward more produc- Alderman, Harold, and Rusla Yemstov. 2013.
How Can Safety Nets Contribute to Economic
tive employment for the poor. There are not Growth? World Bank Economic Review.
necessarily any equity-efficiency trade-offs in
Andrews, Collin, Prospre Backiny-Yetna, Emily
targeting productive interventions to the poor: Garin, Emily Weedon, Quentin Wodon, and
in fact, poor households often would benefit the Giuseppe Zampaglione. 2011. Liberias Cash
most from productive interventions (Macours, for Work Temporary Employment Project:
Premand, and Vakis 2013). The effectiveness of Responding to Crisis in Low-Income, Fragile
these complementary interventions for opening Countries. Social Protection and Labor, World
Bank, Washington, DC.
such pathways is yet to be evaluated rigorously
in Africa, but their potential to help individu- Andrews, Colin, Mirey Ovadiya, Christophe Ribes
Ros, and Quentin Wodon. 2012. Cash for Works
als to graduate to more productive and secure
in Sierra Leone: A Case Study on the Design and
livelihoods deserves to be considered as part Implementation of a Safety Net in Response to a
of inclusive employment strategies. Greater Crisis. Social Protection Discussion Paper 1216,
attention could be paid to targeting productive World Bank, Washington, DC.
interventions to youth within poor households Asfaw, Solomon, Silvio Daidone, Benjamin Davis,
benefiting from such programs. Josh Dewbre, Alessandro Romeo, Paul Winters,
Katia Covarrubias, and Habiba Djebbari. 2012.
Analytical Framework for Evaluating the Pro-
Notes
ductive Impact of Cash Transfer Programmes on
1. Safety nets can also create positive externalities Household Behaviour? Methodological Guide-
on the local economy. lines for the From Protection to Production
2. See Subbarao et al. (2013) for a review. For Project. Working Paper 101, International Policy
instance, Liberia and Sierra Leone rolled out Centre for Inclusive Growth, Brasilia.
cash-for-work programs in 2008 to cushion Bandiera, Oriana, Robin Burgess, Selim Gulesci,
the impacts of soaring food prices (Wodon and Imran Rasul, and Munshi Sulaiman. 2012. Can
Zaman 2010). In its first phase, the program in Entry-Level Entrepreneurship Transform the
Sierra Leone reached 16,000 beneficiaries, who Economic Lives of the Poor? Mimeo, London
worked for approximately 50 days, for six to School of Economics.
eight hours a day, on road rehabilitation, refor- Blattman, Christopher, Nathan Fiala, and Sebastian
estation, soil conservation, and cultivation of Martinez. 2011. Employment Generation in
rice and alternative crops (Andrews et al. 2012). Rural Africa: Mid-Term Results from an Experi-
The program in Liberia offered, on average, mental Evaluation of the Youth Opportunities
40 days of temporary employment to 17,000 Program in Northern Uganda. Social Protection
households, which mostly rehabilitated public Discussion Paper 66523, World Bank, Washing-
agricultural land and cleaned and cleared roads, ton, DC.
drains, and public spaces (Andrews et al. 2011). Covarrubias, Katia, Benjamin Davis, and Paul
The program was later scaled up to cover 45,000 Winters. 2012. From Protection to Production:
beneficiaries. Productive Impacts of the Malawi Social Cash
3. Cash transfers can contribute to raising growth Transfer Scheme. Journal of Development Effec-
through channels other than their direct impact tiveness 4 (1): 5077.
on beneficiaries (Alderman and Yemstov 2013). Fiszbein, Ariel, and Norbert Schady. 2009. Con-
For instance, simulations also suggest that they ditional Cash Transfers: Reducing Present and
have productive impacts on the local economy Future Poverty. Washington, DC: World Bank.
(Asfaw et al. 2012). Galasso, Emanuela, and Martin Ravallion. 2004.
4. Pilots delivering cash grants to beneficiaries have Social Protection in a Crisis: Argentinas Plan
had large impacts on employment and earn- Jefes y Jefas. World Bank Economic Review 18
ings (for example, Blattman, Fiala, and Marti- (3): 36799.
nez 2011). It remains unclear how the impacts Gertler, Paul J., Sebastian W. Martinez, and Marta
from a public works program would compare Rubio-Codina. 2011. Investing Cash Transfers
Focus Note 2 147

to Raise Long-Term Living Standards. Ameri- Monchuk, Victoria. 2014. Reducing Poverty and
can Economic Journal: Applied Economics 4 (1): Investing in People: The New Role of Safety Nets in
16492. Africa. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Gilligan, Daniel O., John Hoddinott, and Ale- Rosas, Nina, and Shwetlena Sabarwal, 2013. Pub-
mayehu Seyoum Taffesse. 2009. The Impact of lic Works as a Productive Safety Net in a Post-
Ethiopias Productive Safety Net Programme and Conflict Setting? Evidence from a Randomized
Its Linkages. Journal of Development Studies 45 Evaluation of Sierra Leones Cash for Work
(10): 1684706. Program. World Bank, Washington, DC.
Grosh, Margaret, Carlo del Ninno, Emil Tesliuc, Subbarao, Kalanidhi, Carlo del Ninno, Colin
and Azedine Ouerghi. 2008. For Protection and Andrews, and Claudia Rodrguez-Alas. 2013.
Promotion: The Design and Implementation of Public Works as a Safety Net: Design, Evidence,
Effective Safety Nets. Washington, DC: World and Implementation. World Bank, Washington,
Bank. DC.
Hashemi, Syed M., and Aude Montesquiou. 2011. Wodon, Quentin, and Hassan Zaman. 2010.
Reaching the Poorest: Lessons from the Gradu- Higher Food Prices in Sub-Saharan Africa:
ation Model. CGAP Focus Note 69, Consultative Poverty Impact and Policy Responses. World
Group to Assist the Poor, Washington, DC. Bank Research Observer 25 (1): 15776.
Macours, Karen, Patrick Premand, and Renos Vakis. World Bank. 2010. Project Paper on Second Addi-
2012. Transfers, Diversification, and Household tional Financing Credit in the Amount of SDR
Risk Strategies: Experimental Evidence with 23.1 Million (US$35 Million Equivalent) in Pilot
Implications for Climate Change Adaptation. Crisis Response Window Resources to the United
Policy Research Working Paper 6053, World Republic of Tanzania for the Second Social
Bank, Washington, DC. Action Fund Project. World Bank, Africa Region
. 2013. Demand Versus Returns? Pro-Poor Social Protection Unit, Human Development,
Targeting of Business Grants and Vocational Washington, DC.
Skills Training. Policy Research Working Paper . 2011. Implementation Status and Results
6389, World Bank, Washington, DC. of Malawi Third Social Action Fund (MASAF3)
McCord, Anna, and Rachel Slater. 2009. Overview APL II (P110446). Report ISR7009, World Bank,
of Public Works Programmes in Sub-Saharan Washington, DC.
Africa. Overseas Development Institute,
London.
Chapter

Creating Productive Employment


for Youth in the Household
Enterprise Sector

Despite the large share of employment in house- has not left the household economy. Employ-
hold enterprises (HEs) and the potential for sub- ment in HEs is growing especially rapidly for
stantial growth, few governments recognize that those who have not completed a secondary
the informal will be normal or develop effec- educationthe majority of new entrants into
tive policies and programs to help youth to create Africas overwhelmingly young, burgeoning
productive enterprises. Young people who lack the workforce. These young people generally lack
education for a wage job recognize the potential the education for a wage job but can pursue the
in HEs, but they often struggle to amass the sav- economic opportunities that HEs offeras a
ings, skills, and market know-how to enter and full-time activity or together with agriculture
consistently succeed in the HE sector. At a time in a mixed-livelihood strategy.
when the formal wage sector is just beginning to Development processes in other regions
gain ground, supportive national strategies are have included HEs in parallel with large-scale
needed to facilitate entry into the HE sector, pro- manufacturing, so the growth of HEs in Africa
vide an environment to make it more productive, is not surprising (figure 5.1). Such enterprises
Because I am and realize the corresponding benefits for youth are still an important source of employment
not educated, employment and economic growth. in low-income countries where nonfarm wage
I could not jobs have grown rapidly, such as in Bangladesh
be employed. In Africa today, most employment in low- and Cambodia. In Asia and Latin America,
Therefore, I had income households comes from household- HEs provided an important pathway for sur-
based activities. These activities include family plus labor to move out of agriculture as farm
no other option
farming and very small nonfarm enterprises, productivity improved. In Africas low- and
than employing which we call household enterprises (HEs; see middle-income countries, where the mod-
myself. box 5.1). As countries have become richer, the ern wage sector has not grown fast enough to
Tanzania labor force has shifted out of agriculture, but it absorb everyone who is prepared to leave agri-

149
150 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box 5.1

What is a household enterprise?


Household enterprises (HEs) are unincorporated, nonfarm on hours worked or output, although they may share in
businesses owned by households. From an employment per- the profits. Some call these enterprises microenterprises,
spective, they include self-employed people running unin- but the term is not used uniformly (for example, in Grimm,
corporated businesses and family memberss working in those Knorringa, and Lay 2012). Some authors categorize both
businesses. When employment in the HE sector is tabulated, self-employment and larger, more substantial businesses as
employees from outside the family are not included in this microenterprises (and may include partnerships and firms
category; they constitute wage workers. The owners them- that employ workers regularly). In this report, only HEs that
selves account for most of the employment in the sector. hire workers (less than 4 percent of all owners) are classified
Family helpers make up only 11 percent of employment in as microenterprises.
the sector (not counting wage workers). From an enterprise Some refer to HEs as informal enterprises. The Interna-
perspective, they follow the same pattern. Most HEs in Africa tional Labour Organization (ILO) considers everyone working
today are pure self-employment, and only 10 percent have in an unincorporated business with less than five employees
hired someone outside of the family (see figures B5.1.1 and as having informal sector employment (ILO 1993; see Fox and
B5.1.2). Therefore, employment in the sector grows primarily Pimhidzai 2013 for a discussion). The label informal sector
through the creation of new enterprises. ignores the household nature of these businesses, however,
HEs may also be referred to as own-account work- and the ILO definition does not distinguish between the fam-
ers (another term for self-employed) or as contributing or ily (which gets the profits from the enterprise and absorbs
unpaid family workers, indicating that the family members the losses) and outside wage workers (who are paid for a
work in the enterprise but receive no cash payment based task but not expected to share in profits or losses).

Figure B5.1.1 Most people working in the HE sector are owners Figure B.5.1.2 Most HEs are family operations

100
90
80
Family helper
70
11%
60
Percent

50
40
30
20
Owner
89% 10
0
Self-employed Self-employed With 14 5+ employees
with family employees
helpers

Source: Fox and Sohnesen 2012. Source: Fox and Sohnesen 2012.

culture, the HE sector is larger than in compar- between higher rural HE income and lower
ator countries. The HE sector has generated the poverty have been observed in several Asian
majority of new nonfarm jobs in most low- and countries (Haggblade, Hazell, and Reardon
lower-middle-income countries of Africa, even 2010; Lanjouw, Quizon, and Sparrow 2001).
during times of high economic growth (figure The shift in primary economic activity out of
5.2). This trend is expected to continue. agricultureincluding day laborand into
HEs are an important way for households running a nonfarm business contributed sub-
to move out of poverty. Strong correlations stantially to poverty reduction in Bangladesh
Creating Productive Employment for Youth in the Household Enterprise Sector 151

Figure 5.1 Household enterprises are an important share of nonfarm employment in low- and middle-income
countries

100
90
Household enterprise share of nonfarm

80
70
employment (%)

60
50
40
30
20
10
0
Sub- Lao PDR Bangladesh Cambodia Sub- Bolivia Vietnam Nicaragua Philippines Mongolia
Saharan Saharan
Africa Africa
Low-income countries Lower-middle-income countries
Source: Based on standardized and harmonized household and labor force surveys for Sub-Saharan Africa (most recent data available) and
on household and labor force surveys for countries in other regions (see appendix).

Figure 5.2 In Africa, as labor moved out of agriculture, more people moved into the HE sector than into private
wage employment

25
Percentage point change in employment share

20

15

10

10

15

20

25
Nigeria Rwanda Ghana Uganda Tanzania Senegal Cte dIvoire

Agriculture Wage Household enterprise


Source: Based on standardized and harmonized household and labor force surveys (see appendix).

and Uganda over the last decade (see Inchauste for youth to take advantage of the opportuni-
and Olivieri 2012 on Bangladesh; Fox and Pim- ties these businesses present. Youth often lack
hidzai 2012 on Uganda). even the small amount of savings needed to
In Africa, most government strategies over- start a trading business, and banks and micro-
look the HE sector, partly because policy mak- finance entities rarely lend to start-ups. A
ers may know little about the sector or its role small-scale processing or service venture could
in creating youth employment and support- require more capital than a trading venture, as
ing economic growth. Urban policies often well as some technical skills that school leavers
actively discourage HEs, making it challenging may not have. Young people may also need to
152 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

develop business and behavioral skills, if they agriculture and into the services sector, as the
have not acquired them in school or through majority of HEs engage in trading (figure 5.3).
experience. In short, it is difficult for youth to At the same time, HEs have contributed to
find pathways into the HE sector. employment in the industrial sector, where they
Facilitating entry into the HE sector and engage in manufacturing (primarily transform-
providing an enabling environment to make it ing agricultural goods or natural resources into
more productive are fundamental policy chal- products such as charcoal, flour, roof thatching,
lenges. Research across Africa and other regions or bricks) and artisanal activities (producing
shows that these challenges can be met; the key custom furniture and ironwork, dressmaking
is to recognize the potential. By changing the and tailoring, or construction). In the services
fragmented approach to the HE sector into a sector, HEs engage in food services (making
One who does
coherent, coordinated approachwith a strong and selling snacks or meals), transport, and
not have a focus on sustainable employment for youth personal services (barbering and hairdressing).
nonagricultural government, donors, nongovernmental organi- Partly because of local opportunities to pro-
enterprise zations (NGOs), and other stakeholders could cess agricultural products, manufacturing is a
stays idle for lift the constraints on productivity and open common activity for rural HEs. Although street
most of the dry opportunities for sustainable employment for vendors and local markets are the most visible
everyone in this sector. signs of HE activity, many businesses operate
season when
This chapter outlines the opportunities and out of the owners home.
agricultural challenges facing HE owners in Africa today. It HEs survive and grow because they pro-
activities are explores why young people often struggle to vide low-cost goods and services demanded
few. Therefore, enter the sector and describes policies and pro- in a growing but less developed economy that
I started my grams that could change this reality and make lacks a modern services sector. In urban areas,
enterprise of the sector more productive. mobile retail traders and HEs in market stalls
provide the services found in convenience stores
selling soft and
and malls in richer countries. The lower-quality
alcoholic drinks. The Household Enterprise Sector goods manufactured by HEs typically will not
Tanzania Today be demanded as incomes rise and mass-pro-
duced or higher-quality goods enter the market.
HEs have been an important part of the recent For this reason, services tend to dominate the
shift of value added and employment out of sector and to persist longer than manufacturing.

Figure 5.3 Most HEs are in the trading sector

a. Female b. Male
Mining/natural resources/construction/energy Mining/natural resources/construction/energy
4% 5%
Other services
15%
Other services
24% Manufacturing
Manufacturing 27%
26%

Wholesale/retail Wholesale/retail
46% 54%
Source: Fox and Sohnesen 2012.
Creating Productive Employment for Youth in the Household Enterprise Sector 153

Although HEs account for a larger share Table 5.1 Rural versus urban household enterprises
of employment in urban areas, 60 percent of Indicator Urban Rural
HEs in Sub-Saharan Africa are located where Share of households owning an HE 53 36
the population isin rural areas. HEs are dif- Share of HEs as primary activity for owner 82 42
ferent in rural and urban areas (table 5.1).1 It
Share of HE owners working more than 30 hours a week 79 45
is quite common for rural households with an
Share of HE owners operating their own business at least 10 months a year 69 61
HE to operate a farm, either for subsistence and
food security or as a commercial venture. The Share of HE owners operating their business at home 30 43
majority of these households consider the HE Share of HE owners who are female 55 47
to be a secondary activity. Most HEs in rural Share of HE owners with hired labor 8 11
areas operate during at least 10 months of the Source: Fox and Sohnesen 2012, based on data from Cameroon (2001), the Republic of Congo
(2009), Ghana (2005), Mozambique (2008), Rwanda (2005), and Tanzania (2005).
year, but for less than 30 hours a week. Often
rural HE owners can do business only on week-
ends, when markets are open and foot traffic is in the labor force, so has the level of education All of us have
heavier. Owners in rural areas are more likely among HE owners. Figure 5.4 shows that the the maximum
to operate their business at home; in rural areas youngest owners are much less likely than their
of primary
without electrification, HEs usually cannot parents generation to have no education. Still,
operate after sunset. only 29 percent of young adults (ages 2534) education,
Urban HEs are almost always the primary employed in the HE sector have completed and this cadre
activity of the owner, but some owners have more than primary school, much less than the represents the
multiple businesses or lines of work. When HEs 59 percent in the modern wage sector. majority who
are a secondary activity, the primary activity is are roaming in
usually a wage job. As a result, urban owners
The Business: Constraints and the streets. It is
work long hours; 47 percent work more than
50 hours a week. Almost all of those who hire Opportunities impossible for
paid labor are based in urban areas. Women are such people to
as active in the urban HE sector as men, but As businesses, Africas HEs are quite hetero- get employment
they are slightly underrepresented in rural HEs. geneous. Even in the trading sector, some are because there are
Women and men clearly gravitate toward dif- very small-scale operations, using little human better educated
ferent types of enterprises. For example, females or physical capital, whereas others sell higher-
individuals.
are more likely to do tailoring, and men are value products, have a substantial inventory,
more likely to work in construction (Fox and and provide a much higher income. For exam- Tanzania
Sohnesen 2012). The result of this gender seg- ple, a study of female HE owners in Accra,
regation is that women are less likely to work in Ghana, found high-profit females, who had
the sectors where earnings are higher (box 5.2). much higher average profits and capital stock,
Basic education is a key pathway for youth to working in roughly the same sectors as low-
transition into the HE sector. Individuals who profit females (Fafchamps et al. 2011).
enter the labor force with a completed primary Profits vary by sector as well. An analysis
education are the most likely to become an HE of data from seven capital cities in West Africa
owner, and primary education is the main for- found monthly profits ranging from US$70
mal opportunity for developing skills that most for petty traders to US$107 for construction
young people now entering the HE sector will workers (Grimm, Krger, and Lay 2011). That
ever have. Whereas 35 percent of young adults same analysis found very high returns to capital
(ages 2534) who work in agriculture have for many self-employed and family businesses,
never been to school, 79 percent of those in the especially at low levels of investment (Faf-
nonfarm HE sector have at least some school- champs et al. 2011 found similarly high rates
ing. Although the majority of HE owners in in Accra). Monthly marginal returns on capital
Africa do not have primary education (reflect- are estimated to be about 70 percent for those
ing the low levels of education among the older with capital stock valued at less than US$150.
generations), as the level of education has risen Although most businesses report capital con-
154 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box 5.2

Why do females earn less? Occupational segregation in the household enterprise sector
Gender segregation is common among HE owners. Both Evidence also suggests that men and women have dif-
women and men are likely to engage in trading, but women ferent information or expectations about particular enter-
are much more likely to do tailoring or catering (lower-paying prises. In Kenya, a recent experiment with vocational
activities) and men to engage in carpentry, metalworking, and training vouchers found that prior to enrollment males
repair (higher-paying activities). For example, owners of HEs overwhelmingly preferred traditionally male-dominated
surveyed in the Kassida workshop area of Kampala, Uganda, courses such as motor vehicle mechanics, whereas women
indicated that even in metalworking, males almost completely almost exclusively chose traditionally female-dominated
dominate the higher-earning fabrication activities, while more courses such as hairdressing (Hicks et al. 2011). The pro-
females engage in scrap metal processing, where earnings are gram administrators randomly provided half of the partici-
lower. One of the sectors with the lowest earningsselling pants with information on the actual returns to training,
drinksis almost completely dominated by females. highlighting the higher returns in male-dominated trades
The reasons for this gender segregation are complex. They and using soft persuasive methods, such as a video of
include social norms, the lack of female role models who have female auto mechanics, to encourage females to pursue
entered occupations traditionally performed by men, and more traditionally male-dominated trades. Females exposed
constraints on time and money, which can be more binding to the information were almost 9 percentage points more
for women than for men. For example, studies in South Asia likely to express a preference for a male-dominated course,
and Kenya found that when women choose to work outside and they were 5 percentage points more likely to enroll in
the home, they spend more time traveling on slower modes one. Younger and more educated females were especially
of transport, which limits them to employment options that likely to prefer male-dominated fields. This experiment sug-
are closer to home (Uteng 2011; Gulyani, Talukdar, and Jack gests that efforts to provide information and encourage-
2010). Regardless of the cause, women tend to earn less than ment have potential to reduce occupational segregation and
men from HEs (Fox and Sohnesen 2012). increase womens earnings.

Figure B5.2.1 Earnings are higher in male-dominated subsectors than in female-dominated subsectors

400 $371
350
Average monthly earnings (US$)

$296
300

250

200
$148
150 $128

100 $86

50

0
Saloons Scrap metal works Catering Metal fabrication Electrical
90% 24% 98% 4% 8%

Share of women
Source: Campos et al. 2013.

straints, returns do not appear to increase with Banks and microfinance institutions in Africa
the level of capital stock. rarely lend to start-ups. Almost all owners
People need savings to start an HE, because report that they started their business with their
it is virtually impossible for them to get credit. own savings and a loan or grant from their fam-
Creating Productive Employment for Youth in the Household Enterprise Sector 155

Figure 5.4 Younger HE owners tend to have more acy can add as much as 40 percent to their earn-
education than older ones ings, controlling for sector, location, and other
characteristics (see the discussion in chapter
35
3; Fox and Sohnesen 2012). While some of
30 this earnings premium probably reflects other
Percentage of age cohort

25
characteristics of primary school completers,
it suggests that the basic skills acquired in
20 primary schoolsuch as literacy and numer-
15 acymatter for productivity in HEs. Develop-
ment policies and programs often confuse HEs
10
with small and medium enterprises (SMEs) or
5 micro, small, and medium enterprises. This is
0
a mistake (box 5.3 explains why). Even though
No education Primary Primary Secondary +
there is substantial heterogeneity among HEs,
incomplete complete a fundamental difference between HEs and
Ages 1524 Ages 25+ SMEs is that while HEs often persist for a long
Source: Fox and Sohnesen 2012.
time (more than five years), they are not ori-
ented toward employment growth (Fox and
Sohnesen 2012). Even if productivity improves,
ily or friends (table 5.2). Very few applied for a these businesses rarely grow beyond HE status.
loan after starting their enterprise. To the extent Data from West Africa show that capital grows
that these enterprises have access to financial quickly to a steady state, and even after 10 years
services, those services tend to be informal. of operation, the capital stock of the business
Suppliers credit (informal loans at high interest
rates) is common for trading enterprises. Other Table 5.2 Sources of capital for household enterprises: Start-up and credit for
sources include informal local systems such as operations
rotating savings and credit associations and vil- Source Male Female All
lage savings and loan associations, which pool
Start-up capital a
savings within a village and lend small amounts
Personal savings 79.9 71.6 75.1
for a short term, usually no more than one
year (see focus note 3). Microfinance has not Official or formal 1.3 0.8 1.0
yet reached this sector, even for working capi- Relative or friends 6.6 13.9 10.8
tal. Despite the high returns to capital, current Microfinance, NGO, cooperative 1.3 1.3 1.3
owners, those who did not start a business, and Informal 3.0 3.2 3.1
those who closed a business all reported that Other 7.9 9.2 8.7
limited access to capital is the most important
Total 100.0 100.0 100.0
business constraint they face.
Completing primary education is a key Credit for business operation b
driver of profits for HE owners. Compared to Official or formal 17.0 15.8 16.3
having no schooling at all, having only a few Relative or friends 39.9 43.0 41.7
years of education does not add to earnings in Microfinance, NGO, cooperative 28.7 21.4 24.7
the HE sector. This outcome reflects the fact
Informal 10.3 13.1 11.9
that in many African countries a few years of
Other 4.0 6.6 5.5
basic education fail to provide basic skills such
as literacy and numeracy. Because 45 percent Total 100.0 100.0 100.0
Source: Fox and Sohnesen 2012, based on World Bank harmonized household surveys.
of young adults in the HE sector have not com- Note: Official or formal includes commercial banks and public programs. Other includes loans
pleted basic education, the lack of basic skills from employers and other unspecified loans. Informal includes credit from customers or suppliers,
informal moneylenders, rotating savings and credit associations, village savings and loan associations,
contributes to their low earnings. By contrast, and savings and credit cooperatives.
youth who have completed primary school and a. Includes Cameroon (2001), the Republic of Congo (2009), Ghana (2005), Rwanda (2005), and
Uganda (2005).
reached functional levels of literacy and numer- b. Includes Ghana (2005), Rwanda (2005), Tanzania (2005), and Uganda (2005).
156 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box 5.3

Small and medium enterprises are not the same as household enterprises
Policies and programs to encourage business start-ups often Relationships between the enterprise and the state with
place HEs and SMEs under one umbrella, often called micro, respect to registration and payment of taxes depend in part
small, and medium enterprises. But HEs and SMEs have on the rules and practices in each country.
important differences.
Differences in registration and taxation requirements:
Differences in where they locate:
In many countries, it is legal to run HEs without any busi-
HE are usually not located in a building (establishment) in ness registration or license. However, local governments
a business or commercial area. They may locate in a regu- may require HEs to get a trading permit or license or to
lar market stall, on a usual corner, or in the owners house. register for a place in a public market stall.
Many have no fixed location. Most countries require SMEs to have a business license,
SMEs operate from a fixed location. They may be a sole and their hiring is subject to national labor laws. At the
proprietorship or have multiple owners, but they usually same time, SMEs are known for hiring workers infor-
do not operate from the household, and they separate the mallythat is, without paying payroll taxes or enrolling
business from the household accounts. them in a mandatory social insurance system. In part this
practice reflects the lower labor productivity in the SME
Differences in number of employees:
sector, which calls for lower real wages.
Most HEs do not hire labor.
Differences in access to financial services:
SMEs by definition hire labor. Definitions of size vary, but
in Sub-Saharan Africa a business with 520 employees is HEs usually combine household and business finances.
considered small, and a business with 2150 is considered The HE is part of the households livelihood portfolio, in
medium. However, some global studies classify businesses which funds move back and forth between the HE and
with less than 250 employees as small (see, for example, other activities (such as purchasing farm inputs).
Ayyagari, Demirg-Kunt, and Maksimovic 2011). Differ- SMEs are likely to have a relationship with a bank or micro-
ences in classification often lead to confusion in policy finance institution (as a saver or borrower), but they depend
discussions. on their own and their familys savings for capital as well.

remains the same (Grimm, Knorringa, and use informal retail networks, including HEs, as
Lay 2012). Most enterprises never hire another vendors to reach consumers (for example, sell-
worker (Fox and Sohnesen 2012). ing bottled beverages or mobile phone cards).
This steady state is not simply the result of Depending on location and sector, the mar-
capital constraints. It arises for multiple reasons. ket for their product may be limited, which
First, consistent with their growth-oriented restricts growth.
approach, SMEs tend to start not as HEs but Third, HEs tend to operate in sectors that
as SMEs, with more assets and employees at are relatively easier to enter, so they face a lot
the beginning. From the start, they are a differ- of competition. Expansion would require more
ent type of business. The owners have demon- capital and constitute a big risk. HE owners
strated that they have an important skillthe report having to work hard to keep customers
ability to hire and manage labor outside the and stay ahead of the competition. In a West
family. Managerial skill is often considered a Africa study, 60 percent of HEs reported that
key indicator of entrepreneurial potential (De competition and lack of customers are major
Mel, McKenzie, and Woodruff 2012b; Gelb et threats to their existence (Grimm, Knorringa,
al. 2009). and Lay 2012).
Second, almost all HEs rely on households, Fourth, even if the market for their prod-
not other businesses, as their customers. HEs uct has growth potential, expansion for a self-
are rarely connected to larger value chains. employed HE owner means taking on employ-
The exception occurs when large wholesalers ees, with associated management costs that
Creating Productive Employment for Youth in the Household Enterprise Sector 157

owners usually do not want to handle. HEs are Sub-Saharan Africa is still mostly rain-fed, Despite the
likely to take on apprentices, but not full-time resulting in substantial seasonal underemploy- difficulties in
employees. ment. Another reason is that farmers still use a days work, I
Fifth, HEs operate in a risky environment, very basic production techniques, which make make as much
with limited opportunities to hedge their it hard for them to get ahead.
as a civil servant
risk. Given the retail nature of their sales, HEs In urban areas, some HE owners earn more
depend on growth in income both from agri- than they could expect to make in a wage job,
does in a month.
culture and from wages and salaries to survive. either because their lower education and skills Madagascar
This dependence means that their incomes are limit their access to a wage job or because wage
pro-cyclical; a negative shock to the local agri- rates are still low in Africa. It is usually the
cultural sector can hurt them as well. Expan- roughly 10 percent of HE owners who have
sion may only increase risk. the managerial skills to hire workers whose
Seventh, in addition to business risk, HEs earnings exceed those from wage employment
face household risk. In surveys, business risk (Fox and Sohnesen 2012). Other benefits cited
tends to be listed as more important, although by HE owners include the opportunity to be
females tend to cite household events such as their own boss and flexible hours (Falco et al.
an illness in the family as a reason for exiting 2012).
the HE sector. In addition, HEs rarely sepa-
rate the business accounts from the household
accounts. Constraints for Young People to
Finally, HE owners have other responsibili- Enter the HE Sector
ties (in farming or the household, for example),
so they do not have additional time to devote Owners of HEs tend to range between the ages
to their business. In their risky environment, of 25 and 40 (figure 5.5). Despite having more
giving up subsistence farming to devote more education than older workers, young people
time to the business may not make sense for struggle to enter the HE sector. They are held
the household. back by multiple constraints, including insuf-
For creating employment, the implication of ficient capital or savings, inadequate informa-
these differences is that employment grows in tion on markets and input supply, and the lack
the HE sector because an individual or house- of a range of skills, such as literacy, numeracy,
hold seizes a business opportunity and creates and business, behavioral, and technical skills.
a new enterprise, not because HEs hire a young Often the most important constraint is lack of
person looking for work. capital. Young people may leave school with
Even though HEs will not transform them- the aspiration to start a business, but with-
selves into SMEs, they are often a good business out savings, they find it very difficult to start
opportunity in Africa. In African countries they a business.
tend to be found in richer areas, and house- Many young people, including those still in
holds with these enterprises are less likely to be school, work in the HE sector, but not as busi-
poorthey tend to be clustered in the middle ness owners. They contribute work to a fam-
quintiles (Fox and Sohnesen 2012). Stron- ily business without receiving a regular wage.
ger evidence from recent panel data in a few This experience can be a pathway to sustain-
Eastern and Southern African countries indi- able employment in the sector (see chapter 2).
cates that adding an HE does make household Working in a family business can provide essen-
income and consumption grow faster regard- tial on-the-job trainingin business or tech-
less of wealth level, suggesting that HEs help to nical skillsand build the informal networks
reduce poverty. necessary for success. These young people may
For many rural households, the hourly also be earning the trust of their family, who
income from an HE is higher than the hourly might eventually supply start-up capital for an
income from the agricultural sector. One rea- enterprise. Studies in West African capital cit-
son for this discrepancy is that agriculture in ies show a strong correlation between having a
158 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Figure 5.5 Household enterprise owners tend to be over 25 years of age HE. Some occupations, including trading (the
most common business), do not require spe-
35
cific technical skills, but some do (for example,
30 construction, manufacturing, repair, and per-
25 sonal services such as hairdressing). Young
people acquire these skills through training
20
Percent

or apprenticeships, mostly supplied by private


15 providers rather than public institutions. Gov-
ernments need to recognize that, just as infor-
10
mal employmentt is normal, informal trainingg is
5 normal for youth in the HE sector. Most such
0 training consists of private courses and appren-
1519 2024 2529 3034 3539 4044 4549 5054 5559 6065 66+ ticeships, as discussed extensively in chapter 3
Age (years) and summarized in box 5.4.
Distribution of household Share of age group that are
Two issues related to apprenticeship have a
enterprise owners household enterprise owners bearing on young peoples ability to enter and
Source: Fox and Sohnesen 2012. remain in the HE sector. First, the skills offered
through apprenticeships are often quite narrow,
limited to a specific production technology,
self-employed parent and being self-employed and difficult to transfer to another occupation.
(Pasquier-Doumer 2013). Second, the time spent in an apprenticeship
Another common way for youth to enter the can make it challenging for young people to
sector is to gain skills and experience. Techni- accumulate the savings they will need to apply
cal skills are not a prerequisite for starting an their new skills in an enterprise of their own.

Box 5.4

Informal training is normal for youths seeking to operate a household enterprise


Young people working in HEs are substantially more likely to narrow set of technical skillssuch as tailoring, carpentry,
have gone through informal skills training or an apprentice- vehicle repair, or hairdressingthat are used primarily in the
ship than formal vocational training. Among 25- to 34-year- HE sector. In addition to being specific to the sector of activity,
olds employed in the HE sector, 32 percent have been an such skills may be specific to the technology used by the mas-
apprentice at some point, but only 6 percent have gone ter (Frazer 2006). Ghanas highly developed apprenticeship
through formal vocational training. system is a good example (Monk, Sandefur, and Teal 2008).
Private, informal training is the primary source of tech- Apprenticeships take many forms and vary in duration.
nical skills for HEs. The spectrum of providers includes for- If a family lacks cash to compensate the master, the master
profit private institutes and firms, NGOs, religious and com- may take on the apprentice for a lower fee but require more
munity organizations, and individuals. The vast majority of time (labor) from the apprentice in return. Many apprentice-
these providers develop their own teaching programs, are ships are informal, although some are based on a contract.
self-financing, and operate on a very small scale with little To enforce this contract, the first year of the apprentice-
government oversight or support. Training is generally short ship often involves little training, just unskilled labor. The
and intensive, and it may offer a certificate. In some coun- time spent in an apprenticeship without earning money
tries, informal private training providers enroll more trainees may account for the lower payoff to apprenticeship that is
than public institutes providing formal vocational training. observed in countries such as Ghana, where this practice is
Apprenticeship, in which an experienced enterprise owner common. Unless young people can save money during their
(master) teaches skills on the job, is by far the most common apprenticeship, they still face barriers to entering the sector.
and important institution providing training. Apprentices gen- After completing an apprenticeship, youth often report that
erally have at most a junior high school education. The scope a lack of capital prevents them from applying their newly
and content of apprenticeships are heavily focused on a basic, acquired skills.
Creating Productive Employment for Youth in the Household Enterprise Sector 159

In addition to capital and skills, a third barrier little guidance on which interventions could
to entry is young peoples general lack of infor- work on a large scalethat is, beyond small-
mation about opportunities in the HE sec- scale pilots. What is clear is that, although
tor, especially relative to wage and salary jobs. young people encounter specific constraints in
Young people participating in a small survey in the HE sector, reducing the multiple obstacles
urban Tanzania in 2005 reported that they had that all HE owners encounter in entering and
spent an average of five years idle or doing odd earning a living in the sector can generate pro-
jobs while seeking a wage or salary job in an ductive employment for many. The next sec-
enterprise. Three-fourths of the respondents tion focuses on how governments and policy
ended up self-employed (Bridges et al. 2013). makers can support productive employment
Could this search time be reduced by provid- for the large numbers of people who will spend
ing better information about opportunities for their working lives outside of the wage econ-
self-employment or programs to help young omy in the HE sector.
people to enter the HE sector?
The short answer is that the large number of
public and nongovernmental projects under- Creating and Sustaining
taken in Africa to help young people to enter Productive Employment in
and remain in the HE sector have provided lit- Household Enterprises
tle evidence on the best ways to facilitate entry
and raise the earnings of HEs (box 5.5 presents The HE sector has developed with little public
examples from Rwanda). In particular, there is support. Public policy has neglected this sec-

Box 5.5

Rwanda: Many programs to support household enterprises, but little information


on results
In 2010 the World Bank and Government of Rwanda inven- HEs. While this fragmentation is common in low-income
toried the major public and nongovernmental programs to countries, it means that the whole is less than the sum of
support HEs and then conducted focus group discussions its parts.
around the country to elicit HE owners perceptions of the Several organizations contacted for the inventory com-
programs. Of 19 NGO and 7 government programs identi- plained that their products were not being taken up. Pro-
fied, most government programs targeted SMEs, not HEs; grams directed at women noted that social attitudes limiting
most NGO programs targeted HEs and emphasized training. the scope of womens activities hindered participation. Some
Some NGO programs combined training with small grants to NGOs may not be providing a product appropriate for the
start a business. NGO programs tended to support specific majority of the clients or government policies may not be
groups, such as women, youths, people with human immu- supportive of their efforts. Training cannot be effective if it
nodeficiency virus/acquired immune deficiency syndrome cannot be used productively.
(HIV/AIDS), and so on, which meant that many participants Since systematic evaluation of many of these projects is
felt excluded. Few participants had received any support, but rare, it is difficult to measure their effectiveness. Some pro-
those who had were generally appreciative. Most programs grams could not even provide assessments of beneficiaries
focused on providing support to set up a business; partici- or basic monitoring data. A few had evidence on outcomes,
pants felt that assistance is also needed after a business is however. The literacy programs had data on the number of
started. women who passed the test. Better monitoring and evalu-
Given the huge number of HEs operating in Rwanda, the ation would help the government to identify which pro-
demand for assistance is high, but support is relatively mod- grams might be scaled up effectively and to help the NGO or
est because funding is limited, as reported by many nongov- agency involved obtain financing to do so.
ernmental and civil society organizations. These limitations
partly reflect the tremendously fragmented effort to support Source: World Bank and IPAR 2012.
160 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

torboth by failing to support youth to enter In many cases, public support is needed only
it and by failing to provide the business climate to facilitate entry and to encourage the private
to sustain incomes and productivity. Govern- initiatives that already serve the sector. In other
ment strategies tend to identify the SMEs as a cases, information gaps or market failures indi-
source of employment, but not the HE sector. cate a need for public intervention in the form
Often the main obstacle to supporting the of regulation or targeted financial support.
HE sector is an implicit bias against HEs, which
are not necessarily attractive in the eyes of National Strategies
Employment policy, including youth employ-
public authorities, who sometimes even chase
ment, is embedded in national growth strat-
them out of business areas in capital cities. The
egies. In Africa, most national strategies
perception of HEs as unworthy of public sup-
explicitly recognize that private enterprise
port renders systematic efforts to support them
is the key agent in economic growth and job
politically challenging. In some development
creation, but they focus on farms, SMEs, and
circles, HEs have been criticized for not offer- larger firms, despite the large share of employ-
ing the income and benefits of wage and salary ment in HEs and the potential for substantial
employment, so national governments hesitate growth. Limited national support for the HE
to include them in their strategies, despite the sector as an agent of economic development
evidence that they contribute to growth, reduce trickles down to subnational governments,
poverty, and provide better opportunities than which often exclude HEs from local develop-
other occupations such as agriculture. Recog- ment (box 5.6). Mechanisms to organize the
nizing that the informal will be normal is the sector and give its constituents a voice are
first step in developing effective policies and not developed, and national institutions lack
programs to help youth to create sustainable channels to provide support to HEs. Because
enterprises. national and local policies, programs, and
Analysis of the sector and its multiple con- projects that could support productive HEs
straints yields five key areas where public policy are not designed with the sector in mind, gov-
can be effective in supporting the creation and ernments miss opportunities to improve the
growth of HEs:2 incomes and prospects of HEs and encour-
age entry into the sector for many who could
National strategies that recognize HEs, benefit from it. The result is that HEs and the
encourage the sector, and give HEs a voice employment they provide are invisible to pol-
in developing national and local strategies icy makers.
Urban policies that provide adequate loca- To the extent that HEs are even on the stra-
tions where HEs can work and sell their tegic radar screen, they are seen as entities to
products, along with essential support ser- be transformed into SMEs and formalized.
vices such as lighting, water, sanitation, and In Tanzania, a law from 1972 outlawing busi-
security nesses that operate without a fixed premise is
still on the books. This law effectively makes
Financial sector policies and programs that
more than 80 percent of HEs illegal (a fact con-
encourage private providers and NGOs to
improve household access to financial ser- veniently ignored when the government col-
vices, including savings and credit lects taxes or fees from HE owners). The objec-
tive of national economic policy (2008)to
Support for programs that tackle multiple empower the informal sector to become formal
constraints, either by building a range of in order for them to access finance, training, or
skills (technical, business, and behavioral any other business development serviceruns
skills) or by combining skills with capital directly counter to HEs own aspiration nott to
Support for programs that improve access be transformed into an employer, but rather to
to markets by integrating HEs into value survive and bring sufficient cash income into
chains the household. It is not clear how a sector that
Creating Productive Employment for Youth in the Household Enterprise Sector 161

is virtually regulated out of business by law Box 5.6


could become formal in the sense of comply-
ing with the law.
Rwandas development strategies (Vision Need for a comprehensive approach
2020 and the Economic Development and
In 2007 Victor Tokman, one of the first researchers on informal enter-
Poverty Reduction Strategy), while support-
prises, published a seminal article called Modernizing the Informal
ive of the informal sector in general, do not
Sector (Tokman 2007). He observed,
recognize HEs as key economic actors. HEs
either are not differentiated from SMEs or There is general agreement over the need to pay attention to
are excluded entirely from government sup- the informal sector because of its importance to employment
port (for example, the SME policy is limited to and poverty issues. There are also an increasing number of pro-
grammes aimed at supporting similar informal activities in highly
enterprises with hired labor). The disconnect
diverse national contexts . . . Nevertheless, to the extent that it
between Rwandas national strategies and the fails to embrace a shared strategic vision, this is a limited con-
characteristics of the HE sector creates a poor sensus that hinders the effectiveness of policies implemented in
business environment in which HEs are largely this area. While often adequate on an individual basis, they are
overlooked and their specific needs are not insufficient and produce limited effects by failing to respond to a
addressed. Even so, the fact that HEs are legal more comprehensive approach.
in Rwanda gives the government large scope to
broaden national policies specifically to include
them.
Ghana, where HEs have been included in tative mechanisms between the government
the national strategy and institutions for many and the private sector. Aside from providing
years, provides a positive example of what can mechanisms for dialogue at the strategic level,
be achieved (box 5.7). Its rich history as a trad- the development of HE associations helps to
ing economy, dating back before colonization, improve information flows and access to tech-
is one of the reasons why it has some of the nologies and markets, allowing national and
most developed public and private institu- international distributors to integrate informal
tions to support informal enterprises. For agents into their value chains.
example, one objective detailed in the national
Poverty Reduction Strategy Paper of 2006 is
Urban Policies and the Household
to enhance productivity and income/wage,
Enterprise Sector
with equal opportunities for men and women
HEs are much more common in urban areas,
in all sectors of the economy, including the
and urban residents are more likely to identify
informal economy (Republic of Ghana 2006).
their business as their primary and only activity
The National Board for Small Scale Industries
(although rural HEs are an important pathway
(NBSSI) explicitly includes the self-employed
out of agriculture, as detailed in chapters 2 and
within its mandate and has used technical assis-
4). Youth unemployment and idleness are also
tance and donor funding to pilot, refine, and
more frequent in urban areas. Yet the business
scale up locally developed programs to sup-
climate for HEs in urban areas is rarely sup-
port this sector. Rather than shunning HEs,
portive and often hostile. The most frequent
the trade union movement in Ghana opened
complaint relates to the lack of functional space
its doors to them, taking in nascent organiza-
in which to do business. Other complaints refer
tions such as the Ghana Traders Association
to authorities petty corruption in the context
(which at the time primarily covered Accra
of enforcing regulations or collecting taxes and
City) to give a collective voice to this impor-
the lack of services such as security.
tant economic group. In 1996, the Ghana Trade
Urban authorities have five responsibilities
Union Congress adopted a policy to encourage
that affect the entry and productivity of HEs:
the organization of informal enterprises and
informal economy workers and to support Controlling the use of public space (side-
their integration into the organized consul- walks, streets, parks, and the like)
162 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box 5.7

Ghanas integrated approach to HE development


Ghanas development strategy explicitly acknowledges the One lesson learned as Ghana has sought to target youth
contribution of HEs to employment absorption, income self-employment more forcefully is that too many initia-
growth, and local economic development. The strategy tives, with too little coordination, are under way in various
places a growing emphasis on enabling youths and women ministries and nongovernmental programs. In response, the
to obtain the skills and capital they need to succeed in busi- Ministry of Employment and Social Welfare, with support
ness. The approach is sustainable because it is decentralized. from the World Bank, has developed a National Strategy
Local officials support HEs growth because they recognize and Action Plan for Informal Enterprises. The plan estab-
that their political survival and the generation of internal lishes a national policy framework, identifies strategic areas
revenue depend on a vibrant local economy that includes for action by every ministry and agency from within their
HEs. At the national level, the government collaborates with own resources and programs, and provides for coordination
donors to provide supportive programs and policies that cre- through a National Committee on the Informal Economy.
ate a consistent framework, disseminate lessons learned, Although the process of submitting the action plan to the
and provide targeted funding. The approach has been cabinet was interrupted by the recent election, consulta-
developed in phases since the late 1990s, largely through tive validation with key stakeholders has disseminated some
the Rural Enterprise Programme of the Ministry of Trade and of its key messages and principles. The following areas are
Industry, with funding from the International Fund for Agri- identified for concerted, coordinated action:
cultural Development and the African Development Bank.
Continue to work with local governments to improve
The local business advisory centers are the cornerstone of
the policy and business environment, especially the legal,
the system. Overseen on a technical basis by the NBSSI, they
regulatory, and fiscal environment and mechanisms for
receive financial support from local governments (the munic-
dialogue
ipal or district assemblies). The NBSSI funds up to two staff
Reduce vulnerability, particularly through infrastructure
members, whose responsibilities include monitoring and
and secure sites for business
liaising with the NBSSI. The business advisory centers match
Improve access to finance and business development
donor and government projects and programs to the needs
services
of local clients and help to strengthen local associations of
Raise productivity and widen access to markets, especially
household, small, and medium enterprises. The associations
by upgrading the apprenticeship system and standardiz-
have several important roles: expressing members needs,
ing the skills and qualifications system
organizing training, liaising with authorities, disseminating
Use social protection to reduce household vulnerability
information, and in some cases assisting authorities in man-
aging markets and collecting market fees.

The authorities Developing and enforcing rules on the use owners complain that their interests are not
are harassing us of private space (zoning regulations) being adequately addressed.
Providing urban services to support local eco- For HEs, the lack of secure premises (a
and confiscating
nomic development, including local roads, problem frequently exacerbated by outright
our assets. I have legal or extralegal harassment from local
street lighting, public transport, and security
decided to open authorities) delays start-ups, which especially
my business Vetting businesses in order to protect con-
handicaps youth. In a survey of tailors and
sumers (for example, ensuring that taxi driv-
at night. I do ers know how to drive, professionals have dressmakers in capital cities in West Africa,
business when required training, and restaurant kitchens are 43 percent of enterprises in operation for less
than one year reported the lack of an adequate
the government hygienic)
locality for their business as a major problem
is asleep. I earn Setting and collecting fees and revenue to
(Grimm, Knorringa, and Lay 2012). This prob-
a living for my support local activities
lem also prevents businesses from expanding.
family by doing Authorities have to balance many interests The most common and violent conflicts occur
this. Tanzania in executing these responsibilities, and HE when police exert control over the space where
Creating Productive Employment for Youth in the Household Enterprise Sector 163

hawkers and other traders attempt to reach sense of insecurity and vulnerability among I did well
potential customers. These conflicts usually HEs (as borne out by Lyons and Msoka 2007; before the local
erupt because local authorities fail to recognize Liviga and Mekacha 1998; Sisya 2005). authority moved
the importance of these trading businesses to Overlapping and insecure land rights com- the market.
the local economy and do not provide adequate plicate the problem of finding space. In Dar es
Now I have
space for them to operate. Local authorities do Salaam, the local government is not allowed to
not always consider how rapidly HEs can be develop its own rules on the use of land next
difficulty feeding
expected to grow as urbanization increases. to national roads because it does not own the my family and
In some cases, authorities have attempted to landthe Ministry of Transportation owns it. cannot afford to
develop markets or other work space for HEs, The local government is therefore required to send my children
but without consulting them, so the space enforce rules set by the Ministry of Transpor- to school.
developed has been unsuitable. Different busi- tation and not allowed to develop and enforce Rwanda
nesses have different needs. Traders and per- rules that might support local enterprises in
sonal service providers need premises with foot using the land. Land tenure systems based on
traffic, not outside of town but in central busi- a combination of customary and common
ness districts (on sidewalks, especially through law restrict the development of efficient land
the creation of pedestrian-only streets), at bus markets and can prevent HEs from obtaining
stops and terminals, near major road intersec- land. In Nairobi, efforts to establish secure land
tions, and other places that are convenient for tenancy for slum dwellers who run HEs are
people to shop and transact business. Repair complicated by multiple land rights and land
shops and manufacturers such as metalworking disputes (World Bank 2013).
operations need to cluster to realize agglom- Another problem limiting HEs productiv-
eration efficiencies and share technology, and ity is the poor quality of urban services they
urban areas need to provide suitable sites for receive. The construction and maintenance
them to do so. Industrial estates designed for of markets, where traders and service provid-
large firms can include HEs in planning and ers can congregate to sell and customers can
space allocation, for the convenience of work- gather to purchase, is one of the most impor-
ers and the firms. tant urban services needed by HEs, which pay
Cities that fail to anticipate the growth of a fee to locate in the market. In most urban
HEs and proactively identify locations for their areas, governments are simply not creating
activity enter destructive cycles of deconges- markets fast enough to keep up with popula-
tion. The precipitating event is usually a forth- tion growth. In addition, although fees are paid,
coming political or sporting event that will security and sanitation may not be provided as
swell crowds and heighten security concerns. expected. As demand for valuable urban land
Authorities decongest the city by mobilizing goes up, developers pressure local governments
police or other security forces to evict traders to close markets rather than to develop higher-
from the city center and other lucrative areas, density, multiple-use solutions. In the end, HEs
sometimes confiscating their inventory and lose customers. Other key services that can
other assets, or demolishing their temporary affect their productivity are transport (taken by
business structures. Eviction is rarely perma- HE owners to reach markets and by customers
nent. HEs retreat, but many gradually amass to reach HEs) and water supply.
the capital to return to their trading location A common perception is that HEs do not
until the next eviction. pay their fees and taxes, so they do not deserve
Forceful eviction from the more lucrative these services. Nothing could be further from
areas where traders make spot sales presents the truth. Analysis suggests that although HEs
a compelling case for the failure of local gov- may be exempt from national corporation taxes
ernments to support HEs (box 5.8 presents an or value added tax registration, the majority of
example from Tanzania). Even though local HEs pay local business taxes at a higher rate
authorities are simply enforcing the law, their than large businesses (Fox and Sohnesen 2012).
operations are counterproductive: they increase Taxes, fees, and local rules regarding land use
rather than reduce poverty and heighten the are reported to be sources of petty corruption,
164 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box 5.8

Weakening the local economy by perpetuating the machinga cycle in Dar es Salaam
Dar es Salaam has limited business premises in its high-rent, even though most such regulations apply only to formal
lucrative commercial areas. Owners of HEs take to the streets enterprises. HEs have little knowledge of the tax code or
at the borders of these areas as mobile operators (machin- registration requirements and no place to complain. Many
gas), crowding sidewalks and roads, even if zoning laws pro- report paying large sums to unscrupulous officials to avoid
hibit them from doing so. The proliferation of cars, foot traf- having their merchandise confiscated.
fic, and traders, especially during rush hours, is more than city In response to the lack of market space, the city of Dar
authorities can manage. To curb the congestion that mobile es Salaam recently took out a loan and built a seven-story
vendors and service people bring to towns and cities, the building for use by itinerant traders. Dubbed the mach-
authorities, especially in Dar es Salaam, Arusha, and Mwanza, inga complex, the project was estimated to cost T Sh 13
regularly engage in clean-up operations, in which mobile billion (approximately US$13 million), but it does not meet
traders are especially vulnerable targets. Faced with eviction, the needs of the machingas, who were not consulted in its
some HE operators abandon their business. Local authorities design. Among other issues, the building has no elevators
deploy disproportionate force to drive out those who remain. to move customers or merchandise. No parking is avail-
HE owners cite harassment by local government and law able. The building was designed to provide 10,000 work
enforcement officers as their biggest problem. More than 60 spaces (compartments or stalls), but in the end, only 6,500
percent of 622 operators interviewed for one study said that rooms were built. Fewer rooms increased the average cost,
forceful eviction is their most vivid experience of government requiring city authorities to raise rents to repay their loan.
intervention. The same study catalogues machingas losses When the complex opened, only the bottom floor was filled
from local eviction and relocation policies: physical capital by vendors, who then complained to authorities that the
(kiosks), operating capital (fines, confiscation of inventory), machingas selling on the sidewalk were undercutting them.
customers and supply lines (through increased distance), and Eventually, the upper floors were rented out to other ten-
trading time (through jail sentences or time spent rebuilding ants who prize the downtown location but do not need
capital to return to business). Repeated cycles of loss and to locate goods on-site for sale. Meanwhile, the machinga
hardship resulting from these policies increase the poverty problem has not been solved.
and deprivation of household members.
Local officials also subject HEs to inspections to check
compliance with licensing, taxation, and other regulations, Source: Kweka and Fox 2011.

especially by police. Failure to pay the requested government is not elected by the citizens, but
bribe can result in disproportionately negative it is stronger outside the capital, where local
consequences (such as confiscation of inven- authorities are elected and responsibility for
tory). Often owners of HEs do not even know local economic development has been decen-
the current fee schedule or how much they tralized. Outside Accra, local authorities focus
should pay. Corrupt local officials can then take more on creating space for HEs to operate
advantage of them. and less on controlling space to exclude them
Two overarching factors contribute to the (box 5.9). Improvements in the organization of
poor business environment in urban areas for HEs at the local level, facilitated by the locally
HEs: national policies and strategies exclude recruited and managed business advisory offi-
HEs, and local governments are not accountable cers, have reportedly enhanced communication
to their citizens. In Rwanda, national policies between HEs and elected local officials.
that exclude HEs and strictly limit their loca-
tions in urban areas create indifference to HEs
needs among local authorities. The authorities Easing Access to Credit to Start and
see their job as enforcing national regulations Sustain a Household Enterprise
to control HEs, not to support their develop- HEs need capital to start a business and work-
ment. In Ghana, the cooperation between HEs ing capital to maintain it. Most HEs struggle
and local authorities is poor in Accra, where the to obtain capital. Over and over in surveys
Creating Productive Employment for Youth in the Household Enterprise Sector 165

Box 5.9

Clustering household enterprises for the benefit of all


In the city of Bechem, Ghana, national commitment and For the businesses:
public-private-donor collaboration supported the establish-
They gain a secure location.
ment of a mini industrial site for metalworking, car repair,
Through clustering, trades find it easier to obtain com-
and carpentry workshops. Prior to the project, these work-
mon services and participate in value chains (particularly if
shops were scattered around the city, some occupying valu-
project-funded support services such as training or finance
able downtown locations. The city endeavored to obtain a
are located on-site).
suitable parcel of land outside the most congested areas and
Access to business development services improves, because
to develop it for the HEs, allowing the workshops to form
training providers easily reach clustered clients.
productivity-enhancing clusters and the city to assign use of
Access to electricity, water, sewerage, and garbage removal
the valuable city-center land to higher-density, higher-value
improves.
projects.
Business associations become stronger.
The project, which required multiple consultations with
HE associations, took nearly four years to develop, but it For local authorities:
finally opened in 2012 with 37 masters and 68 appren-
tices. The rest of the space is being filled as new HEs move Activities that local governments prefer to locate outside
in. The site provides work space, electricity, and water. the town center, such as metalworking, carpentry, and
Once the site was open, seven spare parts dealers and auto repair, are moved and clustered.
some food vendors (also HEs) moved in behind the main Businesses are easier to tax and less prone to avoid taxes,
tenants to supply support services. Organizations offering because they see value for money in the public services
training in areas such as basic engineering skills and elec- they receive.
tronic engine servicing have also reached out to the HE For clients:
owners, as they can easily reach a critical mass for their
services. Suppliers concentrate in one location, giving easier access
When done with adequate prior consultation and prepa- to regional as well as local markets.
ration of facilities, such sites achieve mutually satisfactory
objectives. Source: William Steel, personal communication.

asking about the major constraints to starting needs and supply is widest for young people
or expanding a business, HE owners list capi- looking to start an HE.
tal constraints at the top (see Fox and Sohne- At the root of this problem is the lack of
sen 2012; Grimm, Krger, and Lay 2011). In financial inclusion for households in Africa (see
Mozambique, in a survey of HE owners who focus note 3). Most households in Africa do not
had to close their business, 56 percent reported have access to a bank or microfinance institu-
lack of capital or liquidity as the primary rea- tion (MFI), either for saving or for credit. Many
son (Fox and Sohnesen 2013). households rely on informal savings groups to
Unable to obtain credit through formal help them to save for business or household
sources, they use their own savings and infor- emergencies and to obtain short-term credit
mal sources of credit to meet their needs when savings are not enough. Young people
(box 5.10). A complicating factor for HEs is have started to join these groups, and it is one
that business and household finances are often of the reasons why more than 25 percent of
linked, so efforts to smooth household con- youth in the low-income and lower-middle-
sumption (to pay for lumpy expenditures such income countries report having saved some
as school fees or home repairs) may compete funds in the last 12 months (FINDEX data).
with efforts to maintain business liquidity and Young people with access to a bank still have
potentially undermine the sustainability of the trouble getting a loan for start-up capital. Even
business. Access to credit would help to balance MFIs in Africa, which target a lower-income
these competing needs. The gap between credit population than banks, prefer to lend to indi-
166 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box 5.10

Sources of credit used by households to start a business in Tanzania


I got my capital, amounting to T Sh 250, from my mother My initial capital of T Sh 5,000 was given by my husband,
in 1986 and started by selling local brew known as and I started selling vegetables.
wanzuki.a I started selling cooked food and local brew with locally
I started with a capital of T Sh 50,000, which I obtained borrowed money (T Sh 10,000). From this business I
from my father in April 2007. obtained a capital of T Sh 30,000. Then I decided to
I started with a capital of T Sh 20,000 in 1994. I got the change business by opening a genge (fresh food stand).
capital from selling maize which I had produced. I am operating a grocery where I am selling beer and
I had accumulated a capital of T Sh 50,000 from my soft drinks and had started with an initial capital of
wages as I was formerly employed. T Sh 200,000, half of which was given by my mother and
I started with suppliers credit (mali kauli) to sell goods: 1 the other half was obtained from agricultural production.
kilogram of sugar, 2 kilograms of rice, 1 liter of cooking I borrowed materials for starting cooked food vending: 3
oil, tea leaves, salt, and firewood that I collected from the kilograms of rice, 2 kilograms of meat, cooking oil (a half
bush. liter), and salt. I obtained my initial capital amounting to
I started by hiring a sewing machine for T Sh 5,000 per T Sh 8,000 from my uncle, and I decided to do a business
month in 2007. I worked with that machine until I got of keeping and selling guinea fowls.
enough money (T Sh 120,000), which I used to buy my
own sewing machine.
I obtained the initial capital amounting to T Sh 5 million Source: Kweka and Fox 2011.
from selling cashew nuts, and the profit from our shop. a. Wanzuki is a local brew made of honey and yeast. Sometimes sugar,
We then bought a milling machine. tea leaves, and yeast are used to make it when honey is not available.

viduals with a salary so that they have a better to existing businesses in Sri Lanka helped to
chance of repayment. Some MFIs will lend to improve sustainability, providing evidence of
households based on collateral (such as house- capital constraints both at start-up and during
hold assets) or the guarantee of a relative or operation (De Mel, McKenzie, and Woodruff
friend who has a salary. In this case, an initial 2012b).
savings deposit is often required. The main problem with the pilot grant pro-
If young people are not creditworthy grams for youths to start a business relates to
because they do not have enough savings or the availability of funds: funds are not available
a track record with a formal savings institu- to provide the 5 million or so youths who are
tion, are grants an option to help them to expected to start a business every year in Africa
start a business? Most of the NGO-led pilots over the next 10 years with a grant of US$100
in Africa that help people to start a business (about the average size of grant used in the
use grants instead of loans, and grants have pilot programs). And even if youth grants on
been tried in South Asia and Latin America that scale were affordable, what about adults
as well. In almost all cases, they facilitated who want to start a business? Excluding them
entry into the sector. But in no cases did the could be politically difficult. In Tanzania, gov-
experiment use only grants for start-up capi- ernment involvement in grant programs to
taleither business training and support support business creation led to poor target-
services or vocational training was supplied ing, suggesting that governments should tread
as well. Other experiments used matching carefully in this area (Kweka and Fox 2011).
grants plus financial education to encour- A more broad-based strategy would be to
age savingg so that youths would have start-up expand financial inclusion (especially savings)
capital. These approaches also produced posi- by reducing the costs of financial services and
tive results, but the target groups were quite improving the range of products available to
well off by African standards. Grants provided HE start-ups.
Creating Productive Employment for Youth in the Household Enterprise Sector 167

What Should Governments Do to incomes (car repair, metalworking). But


Help Equip Youth with Skills for the effect of the training and the effect of
other, unmeasured personal characteristics
the HE Sector?
associated with choosing the sector are so
comingled that the returns to the training
Training programs are the most common
are hard to identify.
government and donor intervention to sup-
port HEsboth for facilitating entry and Many people who take training do not prac-
for improving incomeswhether targeted tice their skill for various reasons, including
at youth or not.3 Programs provide technical the inability to finance an enterprise.
training in a specific sector (such as tailoring,
As a result, more systematic and care-
metalworking, operating a bakery), business or
ful evaluations are needed, including impact
financial literacy skills (such as basic account-
evaluations that measure outcomes among
ing or money management), behavioral and
program participants and a relevant com-
life skills, or a mixture of skills. Programs tar-
parison group (chapter 3, box 3.9). Only a few
geted specifically to youth focus primarily on
programs designed to foster self-employment
the skills needed to enter the sector and may
were subjected to an impact evaluation in the
include all four types of skills listed above. Pro-
past decade. More high-quality impact evalu-
grams targeted at existing HEs tend to focus
ations are needed, including studies that spe-
on the business skills needed to strengthen
cifically evaluate the best ways to design youth
With some
or expand an enterprise, moving toward the training the
employment programs (especially the best
goal of improving earnings and productivity. future will be
components to package together and the most
The good news for youth employment is that
programs designed to facilitate entry appear to
effective agencies for delivering programs), the better. Instead of
have had some success (more than those tar- cost-effectiveness of those programs at scale, simply resoling
geted at existing entrepreneurs), so there are and their general equilibrium effects. shoes, I would
Despite the limited evidence, information
some positive models. like to start
Despite the large number of training pro- from recent impact evaluations and other stud-
ies offers a starting point to guide policy and manufacturing
grams, evidence of their effectiveness among them. Uganda
HEs in Africa remains thin. Most training pro- identify promising approaches to help youth
grams operate on a small scale, do not collect to enter and stay in the HE sector. This section
monitoring data on dropout or graduation reviews evidence on the effectiveness of three
rates, and are unable to track outcomes, let major types of trainingtechnical skills, busi-
alone outcomes for a comparison group. Even ness skills, and behavioral skills. It concludes
the larger programs have not systematically that programs combining multiple interven-
documented success (or failure). Analysis of tionsdifferent types of training or training
household survey data on HE earnings is not plus capitalare more successful than pro-
able to isolate specific returns to training, for grams offering one intervention. None of the
several reasons: combined interventions has been scaled up,
however, and cost is an issue. Finally, we con-
Participation in training programs is poorly sider what the limited evidence suggests about
captured in household survey data, par- the potential role for government and public
ticularly for the more prevalent types of policy in building skills for more productive
apprenticeships or private training. and sustainable HEs.
The product itself is very heterogeneous,
even in the same sector or skill. Building Technical Skills
The majority of existing HE owners did not As discussed here and in chapter 3, technical
participate in any training, and training is training, through apprenticeships and other
not needed to start a business in, for exam- types of private training outside of the formal
ple, trading. Training is needed to enter spe- education system, is the most popular form of
cific sectors, which often do provide higher training for HEs. Informal training is very het-
168 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

erogeneous. Training can be just a few months vehicle repair, tailoring, and hairdressing. The
of on-the-job learning with a skilled HE owner, apprenticeships lasted 3.3 months on aver-
or it can last for years; it can combine classroom age, including a week of life skills and business
instruction with on-the-job learning. Many training; 63 percent completed their appren-
informal training programs or apprentice- ticeships, and a small number received start-up
Our landlord ships build narrow sets of technical skills (for capital. The estimated cost per participant was
had a wood example, in tailoring, carpentry, mechanics, US$800. Participants were encouraged to start
workshop, and I or hairdressing). Little is known about which their own business upon completion of the
passed in front modalities are the most effective and about the apprenticeship. Results showed no improve-
best way of promoting them to ensure that they ments in labor market outcomes or returns
of it every day improve skills and productivity. in the short term, although the training did
when going Household survey data show an association develop skills and improve business practices
to school. I between private apprenticeships and increased (Cho et al. 2012).4
started stopping employment and earningsfor example, in
there to play, Nigeria, Rwanda, and Tanzania (Van Adams, Building Financial Literacy and
and the owner Johansson de Silva, and Razmara 2013). Business Skills
Apprenticeships in Ghana offer a return in Evidence suggests that financial literacy and
introduced me, specific activities, such as construction, espe- general business skills are weak in the HE
little by little, to cially in rural areas, but not in other activities, sector. According to a 2008 survey of micro,
the profession. such as tailoring (Fox and Sohnesen 2012). small, and medium businesses in Zambia, just
Madagascar Apprenticeships also offer returns to work- 27 percent kept up-to-date financial accounts
ers who apprentice in a firm and then leave to (FinMark Trust 2011). In a sample of tailors
found their own business. The former appren- and dressmakers in Ghana, only 17 percent
tice basically replicates both the technology reported keeping any written financial records,
and business practice of the firm, but as a self- only 7 percent said that they had spent money
employed individual (Frazer 2006). These for- on marketing their services during the previ-
mer apprentices earn about 49 percent more ous year, and only 30 percent rated their shop
a year than those who stay on as employees. as very organized (Karlan, Knight, and Udry
Even though primary school completers are 2012). In a sample of microfinance clients in
the group most likely to get an apprenticeship, Tanzania (most of whom were SMEs, not HEs),
returns to apprenticeships appear to be higher two-thirds kept records, but only half engaged
for individuals with lower levels of academic in marketing to attract customers (Berge, Bjor-
achievement, suggesting that apprenticeships vatn, and Tungodden 2011).
can provide technical skills even to those The fact that many operate in the HE sector
without a basic education. Among currently without strong financial literacy and business
employed people who have no formal edu- skills might suggest that young people do not
cation but who have had an apprenticeship, need those skills to enter. Yet the lack of those
earnings are 50 percent higher (Monk, Sand- skills could limit the sustainability and produc-
efur, and Teal 2008). tivity of the enterprise, including those run by
The only impact evaluation of an appren- young people. Can business or financial literacy
ticeship program in Africa comes from a small- training boost the creation and productivity of
scale pilot that was part of a national appren- HEs? The evidence on programs providing only
ticeship program in Malawi. The pilot program financial literacy orr general business skills is mixed.
targeted 1,900 low-income school dropouts. Very few studies have been done in Africa (see
The great majority (84 percent) had completed McKenzie and Woodruff 2012 for a review).5
primary school or less. Masters (with their Basic financial literacyy is the most funda-
own HE) selected through the Technical Edu- mental business skill for HEs (see the review
cation and Vocational Education and Training in Xu and Zia 2012). Financial literacy can
Authority (TEVETA) provided training to par- encompass many concepts, but among HEs
ticipants in occupations such as bricklaying, in low-income countries it entails the most
Creating Productive Employment for Youth in the Household Enterprise Sector 169

basic levels of financial awareness, the ability literacy had no significant effects on business
to understand the financial aspects of the busi- start-up in Bosnia and Herzegovina, in a sam-
ness, and the ability to access financial services. ple where 85 percent of the participants had
Substantial inequalities in financial literacy completed secondary school (Bruhn and Zia
prevail. Women and less educated people con- 2011). In a lower-income context, a Start and
sistently measure lower (on average) on tests of Improve Your Business Program in Sri Lanka
financial literacy. Poor financial literacy could for urban women ages 2545 with a second-
contribute to low access to the formal financial ary education increased their likelihood of
systembanking in particular. launching a business (De Mel, McKenzie,
There is very little evidence that interven- and Woodruff 2012a). An eight-day business
tions to build financial literacy in low-income training course in Pakistan, targeted to new
countries affect the earnings of HEs or the microfinance clients with much less educa-
capacity of youth to enter this sector. Evalu- tion, yielded no impacts on business creation
ations are under way for generic programs among households that did not operate an
(including some in Ghana, South Africa, and enterprise at baseline (Gin and Mansuri
Uganda), but results are not available. One 2011). Efforts to evaluate the integration
study from Indonesia found that financial liter- of entrepreneurship training in secondary
acy had no effect on promoting saving of train- school are under way in Uganda.
ees overall, although impacts were detected on The record on general business training for
trainees with the very lowest levels of initial existing HEs is even weaker. While evaluations
financial literacy (Cole, Sampson, and Zia 2011; show that business training has changed busi-
Xu and Zia 2012, 27). ness practices, it has rarely improved produc-
General business skills trainingg ranges from tivity or survivorship of the typical small busi-
very basic rule-of-thumb programs to more nesses in the HE sector. Studies show that some
advanced classroom programs designed to help programs have changed business practices and
small businesses to grow, which are often called knowledge, such as recording sales and record-
business development services programs. One ing money taken for household needs (HEs
problem with such programs is that they are in Pakistan); keeping records of withdrawals
usually aimed at SMEs, not at the types of busi- from the business, reinvesting profits into the
nesses found in the HE sector in Africa. Often business, and innovating in business (HEs and
the programs target microfinance clients, mean- SMEs in Peru); improving business practices
ing that other constraints, such as start-up capi- among the Start and Improve Your Business
tal and access to work space, have already been Program participants (HEs in Sri Lanka); and
surmounted. For these reasons, it is important separating personal and business expenses,
to sift through the growing evidence on this keeping accounting records, and formally cal-
training to determine if it is applicable to youth culating revenues (both HEs and SMEs in the
employment in African HEs. Dominican Republic).7
Several programs piloted in other regions More intensive programs have somewhat
have facilitated entry into the HE sector for larger impacts. In Peru, intensive personalized
youth, but these programs were designed for business training for microfinance clients (most
more educated individuals, not for young of whom had businesses larger than an HE)
people with only a primary education, which improved business practices and outcomes,
is the target group in Africa. Hands-on busi- whereas simple classroom-based instruction
ness training and coaching provided to uni- yielded no impacts (Valdivia 2011). The evi-
versity students in Tunisia increased their dence that more is better does not always
entry into self-employment, although the hold, however. In the Dominican Republic, a
impact was small in absolute terms (Premand rule-of-thumb approach that taught simple
et al. 2012).6 The training also improved busi- rules for financial decision making was com-
ness and behavioral skills. In contrast, com- pared to a more formal approach that focused
prehensive business training and financial on the fundamentals of financial accounting.
170 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

All of the programs impacts came from the the binding constraint. Given the expense of
rule-of-thumb training. In both the Domini- these programs for both the providers and the
can Republic and Pakistan, follow-up visits beneficiaries, it may not be justified or feasible
yielded no additional impacts (Drexler, Fischer, to expand this kind of program to HEs. At least,
and Schoar 2010 for the Dominican Republic; more careful cost-effectiveness is required.
Gin and Mansuri 2011 for Pakistan).
But changes in business practices do not Building Life Skills for Work
always translate into improvements in produc- Limited socioemotional, or limited behavioral
tivity or business survivorship. In none of the skills, or even low aspirations can prevent
studies just mentioned (the Dominican Repub- potential entrants from finding and seizing
lic, Pakistan, Peru, Sri Lanka) did changes in opportunities in the HE sector. Among other
business practices measurably increase sales, hurdles, the lack of these skills or aspirations
revenues, profits, or employment. In Pakistan, may make it hard for youth to attempt to enter
some impacts were measured among men, and the sector or take up interventions designed
in Peru some impacts were measured in par- to overcome barriers to entry, such as skills
ticularly bad months, but overall the evidence training or capital. Because behavioral skills
is weak that training improved business perfor- are still malleable among young people, vari-
mance. In Ghana, a program delivering busi- ous programs have been shown to affect them.
ness skills training and support to existing tai- Changing the mind-set and attitudes of young
loring businesses did not lead to higher profits, people (especially young women) seems to
despite short-term improvements in business help them to transition into the HE sector.
practices (Karlan, Knight, and Udry 2012). Changes in behavioral skills may be part of the
One exception to this pattern comes from benefits of apprenticeship or other on-the-job
Sub-Saharan Africa, but not from HEs. An training.
evaluation of a high-quality intensive busi- Young females face specific challenges in
ness training program in Tanzania targeted to entering the HE sector (see chapter 2), and there
SME microfinance clients (who already had is some evidence that behavioral skills training,
employees) yielded profits that were 29 per- combined with social support, can help them
cent higher among males but had no effect to overcome those challenges by teaching skills,
on profits for females. The effect came mainly influencing attitudes toward the future, or
through business expansion but also through unlocking aspirations. These particular com-
better management of employees. In this case, ponents, included in a broader program, may
simply graduating clients to a larger loan did reduce risky behavior or early pregnancy in
not improve outcomes (Berge, Bjorvatn, and females and allow them to develop a plan to
Tungodden 2011).8 Still, it is not clear that this enter the HE sector while they are young.
type of intensive training would pay off even Partly because behavioral skills training is
for male HE owners (or that they would have often one part of a comprehensive program,
the time to attend such a program). there is little evidence that programs focused
Clearly the heterogeneity in results across only on building behavioral skills can improve
settings suggests that much remains to be labor market outcomes. However, programs
learned about building business capacity that aim to shape behavioral skills together with
both how to do so and for whom. Positive other skillss have shown promise.
impacts suggest that the lack of business skills
may be a constraint in some settings and that Building a Range of Complementary
interventions may improve practicesand Skills
sometimes business outcomes. At the same Youth often face multiple skill constraints in
time, the results confirm that growth-oriented entering the HE sector. Programs attempting
businesses are rare in the HE sector, so perhaps to build one skill at a time may have limited
sustainability, not growth, is the better out- impact, but evidence from pilots that build a
come to target. The studies also suggest that range of complementary skills together is more
skills may not be the only constraint or even promising. These programs include bundled
Creating Productive Employment for Youth in the Household Enterprise Sector 171

interventions that deliver behavioral, business, cash grants to youth groups for investment
and technical skills training as part of a com- capital and vocational training. The program
prehensive package of support. had large, sustainable impacts on employment
For example, in Uganda, BRAC delivered and earnings, especially for male partici-
training in behavioral skills and technical skills pants.11 Monthly real earnings increased by
targeted to adolescent girls ages 1420.9 The U Sh 17,785 (about US$9.88) after two years
program increased employment 32 percent, and U Sh 19,878 (US$11) after four years, cor-
mainly through entry into self-employment, responding to increases in income of 49 and
and it shaped life skills and reduced risky 41 percent, respectively, relative to the control
behavior (Bandiera et al. 2012). The direct cost group. The average grant was US$374
per participant was US$18 per eligible girl, or (U Sh 673,026) per group member, so the esti-
approximately US$85 per participating adoles- mated return to the average grant was 3539
cent girl. percent.
In Liberia, a program for adolescent girls and Another pilot program in northern Uganda
young women combined either technical and targeted to very poor women provided four
behavioral skillss or business and behavioral skills. days of business skills training,
g an individual
The program was highly effective in increasing start-up grantt of US$150, and regular follow-up
employment and income among adolescent by trained community workers. The program
girls, most of whom had some secondary edu- led to a large increase in income of 98 per-
cation (World Bank 2012). The training pack- cent, or US$6.50 a month. The program was
age combining business and behavioral skills particularly effective for the poorest women.
was more effective at facilitating entry into self- Additional technical assistance through
employment than the training package com- follow-up had little additional impact (Blatt-
bining technical and behavioral skills.10 Direct man et al. 2013). The program cost US$688
cost per participant was US$1,221 for the busi- per beneficiary.
ness and behavioral skills training, leading to These results have two main implications
an increase in monthly income of US$75 on for designing programs to facilitate produc-
average (a 115 percent increase). tive employment for youth in the HE sector.
The rural enterprise projects of the Inter- First, to facilitate entry, integrated strategies
national Fund for Agricultural Development tackling multiple constraintssuch as build-
(IFAD), operating in several African countries, ing a range of skills or combining skills with
finance demand-driven, privately provided increased access to capital and urban space
technical training to improve the productiv- are more promising.12 Both behavioral skills
ity and sustainability of existing enterprises and business skills are best included in these
and to help new entrants to start an enterprise integrated packages. Second, it is not clear
(box 5.11). While no impact evaluation is avail- that current HE owners need more training to
able, tracer studies on beneficiaries in Ghana raise their productivity or sustainability. Most
suggest that both objectives can be achieved at operators do not list skillsbusiness or tech-
very low cost. Although the project specifically nicalas their main problem. They are much
targeted employment growth through business more likely to mention the need for finance or
expansion, most of the employment created customers (access to markets, market infor-
was through start-up self-employment. mation, or work space). But when technical
or business training is offered at little or no
Combining Skills and Capital cost, participation is substantial. For privately
Consistent with the evidence that multiple provided, demand-driven technical training,
constraints hinder entry into the HE sector, the tracer studies on the Jua Kali Program in
bundled interventions combining skills train- Kenya (chapter 3, box 3.7) and the IFAD pro-
ing with capital are also promising. gram in Ghana (box 5.11) suggest that benefits
To stimulate economic development and can accrue to trainees. For business training,
employment in northern Uganda following the outcomes on productivity are elusive, espe-
the cessation of hostilities, a program delivered cially for owners of HEs.
172 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box 5.11

Rural enterprise projects bolster skills and business development in Ghana and Senegal
The International Fund for Agricultural Development (IFAD) repaid. But the participation of banks and MFIs in the credit
supports rural enterprise projects to provide the skills and component was low owing to creditworthiness issues with
other resources that help rural people, especially women and the start-ups. (Typical reasons for such low participation are
young people, to create and develop local businesses that discussed in focus note 3.) Microenterprise subcommittees
provide income and employment off the farm. Projects may established within local governments help to sustain project
include the following components: gains (see box 5.7). Although the second phase specifically
targeted employment growth through business expansion,
Business advisory centerss provide a range of business devel-
most of the employment created was through self-employ-
opment services, including business orientation seminars,
ment in a start-up (sometimes following a paid apprentice-
community-based skills training, small business manage-
ship). This result reinforces the point that targeting start-ups
ment training, literacy and numeracy training, and infor-
is the most promising avenue for creating employment.
mation and referral services.
The Promotion of Rural Entrepreneurship (PROMER) Proj-
Rural technology facilities support master craftspersons,
ect in Senegal, implemented by IFAD in 2006, sought to
traditional apprenticeships, and the promotion, dissemi-
reduce rural poverty by fostering and consolidating profit-
nation, production, and repair of technology for rural HEs
able rural HEs and microenterprises capable of offering
and microenterprises.
stable jobs. PROMER focused on strengthening and profes-
Rural financial services, offered in conjunction with finan-
sionalizing rural entrepreneurship and improving the overall
cial institutions, include credit for on-lending to small rural
political, legal, and institutional environment for such enter-
businesses and training for financial institutions to provide
prises. For its target populationrural youths and women
financial services to vulnerable groups.
ages 1835 who were poor, unemployed, and out of school
Support for rural household and microenterprise orga-
and who either operated or wanted to start an enter-
nizationss includes support for local trade associations to
prisePROMER provided a combination of technical and
build partnerships with stakeholders and support for for-
management training and funding. Technical skills training
mulating and strengthening polices through a working
primarily involved agribusiness, including food processing,
group on enterprise development.
and provided skills to 700 entrepreneurs in metalworking,
In Africa, IFAD has implemented rural enterprise projects equipment manufacturing, textile and clothing production,
in Ghana, Madagascar, Rwanda, and Senegal. Impacts and and hygiene and quality monitoring. Management training
challenges of projects in Ghana (the longest-running project) was provided to about 500 entrepreneurs. The project cost
and Senegal are highlighted here. CFAF 10 billion from 2006 to 2013.
The Rural Enterprise Projectt in Ghana was implemented PROMER helped to create 240 enterprises, consolidate
in two phases between 1993 and 2012. During the second 665 enterprises, create 3,750 jobs, and teach 458 people to
phase (200312), the project collaborated with Ghanas read. It usually takes enterprises three to five years to reach
NBSSI and the Ghana Regional Appropriate Technology their full potential, and finding a niche in the economy can
Industrial Service to develop 53 business advisory centers and be critical for success. Through the project, for example, a
13 rural technology facilities in 24 districts at a cost of US$30 baker started to make traditional bread, which was in high
million, financed by IFAD, the African Development Bank, the demand in periurban areas but not supplied by modern bak-
Government of Ghana, and contributions from project bene- eries. Apprentices trained informally by the baker opened 20
ficiaries (62 percent of whom were women). Almost half (47 enterprises of their own and created about 84 jobs.
percent) of participants reported that they had increased their Other rural enterprises were not as successful. Some
profits as a result of better record and bookkeeping prac- developed products that succeeded in rural markets but not
tices, and 37 percent reported that they had improved their in urban markets because of high transport costs, poor mar-
management and marketing skills. Following technical train- keting, or poor quality. Most entrepreneurs reported chal-
ing in skilled occupations such as processing palm oil, pro- lenges in maintaining quality and continuous production.
ducing tie-dyed and batik cloth, and making leather goods Rural enterprises had trouble finding an urban location in
and soap, 22,000 new enterprises were established, 63 per- which to present their products, a result that highlights the
cent headed by women. About 15 percent of the start-ups problem of multiple constraints. Exhibitions have played a
later became inactive because they lacked a market, working major role in bringing some rural products to a wider mar-
capital, or raw materials; their processing equipment failed; ket, especially furniture, and have attracted better contracts
or they had personal reasons for closing the business, such as that have led to modest job creation.
moving to another area. About 4,300 loans were disbursed
through participating rural banks and MFIs; 87 percent were Sources: IFAD 2011; Senegal Ministry of Agriculture 2011.
Creating Productive Employment for Youth in the Household Enterprise Sector 173

Governments Role in Building Skills mentioned in box 5.2, young people in Kenya
The role of public policy in building young had misperceptions about the returns to voca-
peoples skills for productive employment in tional training.
the HE sector needs to be considered carefully. There is limited justification for govern-
The accumulating evidence that building skills ments to provide directly the type of training in
can help to facilitate entry and raise earnings in basic technical skills that is delivered routinely
HEs, along with the fact that a range of skills by private providers active in countries today.
matters for productivity, does not constitute a Governments should not create additional dis-
case for public financing or provision of skills tortions in training markets. Attempts to limit
training. Not every type of training is cost- or overly regulate the many small training
effective, and the private sector routinely pro- providers have proven ineffective and should
vides many types of training. For all of these be avoided. However, private providers rarely
reasons, governments must carefully assess and provide other relevant skills such as behavioral
justify whether there is scope for directly financ- or business skills. There may be scope for pub-
ing or providing specific training opportunities. lic policy to encourage the provision of these
The rationale for public intervention needs to complementary skills, which are particularly
be informed by well-identified market failures relevant for the HE sector (curriculum devel-
and assessed against risks of government fail- opment is one option for doing so).
ures in providing or financing training. Overall, the appropriate role for govern-
If young people cannot afford to finance ment is likely to be greater for financing than
their training, governments may need to help. for providing training. Governments can
Youths from the poorest households have the leverage the private sector, including NGOs, to
least access to training. For example, young deliver the most promising models. The range
people from the richest quintile of the wel- of training delivered by private providers is
fare distribution are three times more likely to very diverse, and so are the content, duration,
apprentice than those from the poorest quintile and quality of that training. Given the lack of
(chapter 3). Gender patterns in participation data on the full range of privately provided
in training and the types of training selected training, the degree to which training prices
are also strong. Females are less likely to pur- accurately signal the quality of training oppor-
sue training; when they do, they often choose tunities remains unclear. When governments
training that builds a narrow set of skills, such finance training, they should strongly consider
as tailoring or weaving. In this context, public performance-based contracting of private pro-
policies to facilitate inclusion can be put in viders based on outcomes or at least key indica-
place. Government interventions have shown tors of quality. For instance, Liberias Economic
that financial barriers to training opportunities Empowerment of Adolescent Girls and Young
can be overcome through interventions such as Women Project (EPAG) Program for adoles-
vouchers (see box 3.7 on the Jua Kali Program cent girls achieved a dropout rate of less than
in Kenya) or cash grants targeted to youth 5 percent through innovative design elements
groups (the Youth Opportunities Program in that ensured high participation and training
northern Uganda; Blattman et al. 2013). quality (see World Bank 2012; and box 3.7 in
Information failures lead not only to under- chapter 3). Training providers were incentiv-
investment in training but also to investment ized through performance bonuses, and the
in suboptimal types of training. Poor informa- program included frequent and unannounced
tion can also contribute to a misalignment of monitoring visits to check on the quality of
aspirations, expectations, and attitudes toward provision.
self-employment among young people. In this
context, government involvement in providing National Skills Strategies
better information on existing training options Many governments develop national skills
and employment opportunities is warranted. strategies, but too often they focus exclusively
For instance, information on training oppor- on the formal labor and training markets. Often
tunities or on earnings in different occupations these strategies fail to recognize the importance
can influence womens choice of training. As of the nonfarm HE sector and fail to acknowl-
174 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

edge the prevalence of private providers and bine skills training with increased access to
the existence of training markets. capital.
The strategies could identify areas where Experiment with demand-driven financ-
failures exist in the HE training market, such as ing for training. Such experiments would
failures in information provision, and consider include using techniques that have shown
the role that government programs and poli- some results in other programs, such as
cies could play in addressing them, mindful of vouchers.
the cautions noted earlier. Governments could
also use these strategies to provide information
Prioritize financial assistance and programs
targeting the poor and women. Targeting
about market needs and successful approaches the poor and women should be a priority
to the multitude of donors and NGOs active in for reasons of efficiency and equity. Recent
this area. In developing these strategies, govern- impact evaluations found that programs
ments could consider the following options: for the poor and for women may have high
Focus programs for youth on the transi- returns (Macours, Premand, and Vakis
tion into the nonfarm HE sector. Programs 2013). Programs that are simply offered
appear most effective at facilitating entry on demand, however, may not reach
into the nonfarm HE sector, including pro- the poor or women. Indeed, those groups
grams that enable young people to transi- might not aspire to participate in such
tion out of agriculture. Evidence is weaker programs, and they are more likely to lack
on how to raise the earnings of those who the social networks that facilitate access to
already operate HEs. Policies aimed at facil- them. To design inclusive programs that
itating entry are more likely to yield the reach the poor and women, explicit efforts
highest earnings and productivity gains. are required, as well as close attention to the
barriers that females face in entering the
Adopt an evidence-based and learning-based
HE sector and earning an adequate return.
approach. At the very minimum, encourage
all programs to track and report outcomes. Pilot programs such as BRACs program
This monitoring should be done through in Uganda (targeting females) should be
provider organizations, not through expen- encouraged as a means of identifying the
sive and bureaucratic registration and certi- most effective and scalable approaches.
fication processes. Overall, the governments Finance the development of a curriculum and
role in building skills in the HE sector needs learning materials to teach very basic business
to be selective, performance driven, and skills in local languages and incorporate train-
evidence based. As discussed, packages or ing in those skills into education and training
integrated interventions show the most programs. As part of this effort, the use of
promise, although many design questions existing modulestested and evaluated in
remain, especially with respect to scal- the local contextshould be encouraged.13
ability, cost, and cost-effectiveness. There- Consider providing information to primary
fore, governments should use a learning- school students and their parents on economic
based approach to design, pilot, and evalu- opportunities in the HE sector and on the types
ate models to find cost-effective and scal- of training that have had the best outcomes.
able interventions. The evidence discussed
in this chapter can guide the initial choice
of models. Market Access and Voice
Encourage the delivery of bundled inter-
ventions that tackle multiple constraints. Current and prospective HE owners report
Specifically, these interventions include that poor access to input and product markets
programs that deliver behavioral, business, is a serious constraint. Although traditional
or technical skills training as part of a com- private sector development approaches assume
prehensive package or programs that com- that HEs exclusion from defined markets and
Creating Productive Employment for Youth in the Household Enterprise Sector 175

large value chains cannot be remedied, new gained a dominant market share of Kenyas My main
research is challenging that assumption. HEs money transfer and e-money market. challenge is stiff
can participate in international value chains The second and third are buyer-led models,
competition,
if producer associations can be created and because the buyer helps to organize the value
markets structured to include them. Recent chain so that producers can access a bigger made worse
analysis by the Monitor Group highlights how or more secure market. These models require by customers
imaginative new bottom of the pyramid HE producers to organize in associations or who take long
business models in low-income Sub-Saharan cooperatives, with which the buyer works to to pay or dont
Africa can include HEs (Kubzansky, Cooper, obtain a product for a market defined by the pay, including
and Barbary 2011). Three distinct business buyer. For example, the buyer provides output
the subcounty
models are identified: specifications and the necessary training to the
association or cooperative and manages and government,
Distribution and sales through informal shops.
monitors the quality of the output. The con- whose failure to
In this model, enterprises develop a route
tract production model has been successful in pay compelled
to market that leverages (and sometimes
the handicraft sector (box 5.12). It relies on a me to lay off
upgrades) informal distribution and sales
dedicated entrepreneur at the top of the value workers.
channels to sell products through multiple
chain to organize both production and export
fragmented or unorganized shops. Uganda
into existing distribution channels. The deep
Contract production. This system sources procurement model relies on existing large
produce directly from a large number of contractors to reach out to HEs as subcontrac-
small-scale producers in (often rural) sup- tors to supply their value chains.
ply chains. The contractor organizes the Young people are well placed to participate
supply chain from the top and provides in these initiatives. They more easily adopt new
critical inputs, specifications, training, and technology and methods brought to the HE sec-
credit to suppliers. The suppliers provide tor by the large companies; this was especially
assured quantities of specialty produce at true for the mobile phone and mobile money
fair and guaranteed prices. value chains, where many youths got their first
Direct procurement. Direct procurement job as sellers of air time or pay-per-use phones.
setups bypass traditional intermediar- Governments have usually not played a direct
ies and purchase directly from large net- role in facilitating these efforts, as private sector
works of low-income producers, often pro- expertise is required. However, by encouraging
viding training to meet quality and other partnerships and donor financing of technical
specifications. assistance and initial risk capital as well as pro-
viding the enabling environment, governments
The first model, the producer-ledd model, is can support these efforts. For example, the
probably the best known. It has been used by Rwanda government was a key partner in scal-
Coca-Cola, Bayer, mobile phone companies, ing up the Rwanda basket initiative. Challenge
and the M-PESA mobile money system, for grant funds from the Department for Interna-
example. These companies have been able to tional Development in the United Kingdom
forge links with HE traders, using simple meth- helped to develop M-PESA in Kenya, with the
ods of distribution to benefit from access to support of Kenyas central bank.
the wide marketing channels that petty trading
provides for their products or services. Kottoh Associations
(2008) found that the proliferation of trading HE associations are critical to successful devel-
in mobile phone credits by hawkers for MTN, opment of the sector. As millions of individu-
Vodafone, and other telecommunication giants als operating millions of very small, scattered
in Ghana is providing above-average income businesses, HE owners lack a unified voice
to the HEs while benefiting the companies. By and struggle to be heard alongside the mul-
training small-scale traders to be its agents in tiple players in the development process. Indi-
rural and periurban areas, M-PESA quickly vidually, HEs are an easy target for predatory
176 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box 5.12

Taking a household business to the international market: Gahaya Links and Rwandas
peace baskets
A basket-weaving tradition made its way from the villages ness model. The sisters worked with the weavers to develop
of Rwanda to American households, changing the lives of uniform designs and use stronger materials. To expand
thousands of Rwandan women basket weavers. For decades, rapidly, the company recruited women through churches,
women in Rwanda have produced distinctive, cone-shaped villages, and word of mouth to serve as contract weavers.
baskets that are traditionally used to carry wedding gifts. The They established a rigorous training program starting with
baskets are handcrafted from enzyme-washed papyrus and master weavers, who could then train others in the area to
banana leaf. The traditional zigzag design tells an ancient meet high standards of quality. The Government of Rwanda
story of friends walking together, visiting neighboring vil- helped by organizing the self-employed women weavers into
lages along the way. The women who weave the baskets cooperatives and building local training centers. Rwanda also
at home used to hawk them on the streets in tourist loca- joined the African Growth Opportunity Act, which allowed
tions. In 1995, Janet Nkubana, who was managing a hotel Rwandan crafts to enter the United States market duty free.
in Kigali, decided to set up a shop on the hotel premises to Participation in a New York trade show in 2005, sponsored
market the baskets to hotel guests. She also took some bas- by the U.S. Agency for International Development, facilitated
kets to sell in the United States when she visited her sister. connections with international retail stores.
Their popularity there encouraged the two sisters to set up Gahaya Links reported annual sales of US$300,000
a factory with the women weavers and market the baskets in 2007; that same year, it contracted with approximately
worldwide. The baskets were renamed peace baskets, 3,200 women in household basket-weaving enterprises
because the weaving groups include Hutu and Tutsi women, across Rwanda to make their product. Gahaya Links issues
who find that working together is a healing process. purchase orders based on standard designs, and the weav-
Gahaya Links initially started with 27 weavers as employ- ers receive one-third of the proceeds from basket sales.
ees. It gained international exposure after a Marie Claire fea- The company thrives because it focuses on quality, training
ture on reconciliation through peace baskets brought orders weavers to supply a product consistently valued by interna-
for 1,000 baskets. This order was a huge challenge for tional consumers.
Gahaya Links, but it provided an opportunity to identify and
remedy flaws in their products and to develop a new busi- Source: World Bank 2008.

officials or economic agents (box 5.13). Their Ghana to distribute information about new
contribution to the local economy may not products being brought to the market.
be recognized. Because policies and regula- Effective participatory organizations are
tions are developed without their input, these rarely created by governments, but govern-
businesses are often over- and underregulated ments can easily undermine them. National
(Roever 2006). HE associations make it pos- strategies should recognize the need for effec-
sible to manage the consultation required to tive associations. Local government policies and
develop and implement successful projects to regulations covering the use and disposition of
supply public goods that benefit HEs and the public space should recognize the need to con-
local economy (such as development of the sult with HEs and encourage the formation
workshop cluster in Ghana, described in box of local associations to facilitate this process.
5.9). Economic agents seeking to work with Donors and other international actors can be
HEs to strengthen value chains also need effec- helpful in encouraging and supporting associa-
tive producer organizations as partners. HE tions. Donor financing for associations of HEs
associations can provide the necessary chan- through the Trade Union Congress in Ghana
nels to transmit information about support was helpful in building the capacity of these
programs and can be used by private sector groups, and support for creating local HE asso-
operators seeking to integrate HEs into their ciations was included in the terms of reference
value chains. For example, Procter and Gamble for the business advisory centers supported by
works through the hairdressers association in IFADs Rural Enterprise Project in Ghana.
Creating Productive Employment for Youth in the Household Enterprise Sector 177

Box 5.13

Reducing isolation and exploitation through self-help associations


Gaining a voice in the national policy dialogue is especially collectors. SEWA representatives participated in crafting
challenging for Africas youth, whose livelihoods depend national legislation on sexual harassment in the workplace
overwhelmingly on activities outside traditional wage in 2010, a law that explicitly covers domestic workers, and
employment (and will do so for the foreseeable future). in developing a national policy on vendors and hawkers in
These activities are inherently vulnerable to high volatility in 2004.
earnings, lack of legal recourse in case of expropriation or Given that nonwage work is likely to persist in Africa and
theft, and limited access to safety net programs. These vul- given its strong gender and youth dimensions, finding ways
nerabilities are compounded by an inability to influence the to support active engagement offers a better way forward
policies that affect their working conditions. For women and than ignoring them, formalizing them, or suppressing
youths, who are overrepresented in most forms of vulner- their activities. With rare exceptions (Ghanas Trade Union
able employmenta in Africa, the need for formalized chan- Congress is one), including trade unions in the policy dia-
nels that allow access to policy makers and afford a measure logue is unlikely to suffice, because traditional trade unions
of visibility in the public sphere is especially pressing. usually exclude nonwage-earning participants in the labor
These conditions are not inevitable. Over the past few force. Policies on issues as diverse as natural resource man-
decades, new models for collective action have emerged, agement, urban zoning, sexual harassment and discrimi-
enabling workers to advocate for their interests directly with nation, the minimum wage, and social safety nets affect
buyers, sellers, and the state (often at multiple levelslocal, all workers, not just the minority with a formal contract or
national, and international). These worker associations registered business. Without associations that legitimately
occupy a unique space somewhere between an NGO, which represent their interests, the voices of informal workers are
provides services to its members, and a labor union, which unlikely to be heard or taken seriously.
represents workers in negotiations with employers. Associa- Although an organization of SEWAs breadth and experi-
tions in Africa and other regions are growing in number and ence has yet to develop in Africa, several organizations are
establishing this form of organizing as a viable means of applying similar models. The results of these efforts can be
improving conditions in nonwage work. as straightforward as improving the visibility of HE owners
The worlds largest and probably best-known worker and casual workers in national statistics and as far-reaching
association is in India. The Self-Employed Womens Associa- as including HE owners and casual workers under public
tion (SEWA), established in 1972, broke traditional barriers health insurance programs. Associations of street vendors
to form organizations representing cigarette rollers, head have been among the most successful to date. For example,
porters, and others who did not have employers to bar- they have enabled street vendors in Ghana, Kenya, Liberia,
gain with and hence were excluded from the trade union and South Africa to receive literacy and skills training, orga-
movement. After decades of developing innovative organiz- nize child care and informal schooling, rehabilitate markets,
ing modalities to negotiate with municipalities, buyers (such finance their operations, and arrange to source, transport,
as cigarette and garment factories), and other actors (such and store merchandise.
as forest management councils), SEWA has established itself
as a leading force in Indias trade union movement. SEWAs a. The ILO defines vulnerable employment as self-employed and con-
activities include obtaining official identification cards for tributing family workers. Those pursuing such activities are less likely
workers to allow them to access state social protection pro- to have formal work arrangements and are therefore more likely to lack
grams, programs to develop and upgrade members skills, elements associated with decent employment such as adequate social
security and recourse to effective mechanisms of social dialogue. Vul-
bargaining over piece rates paid to contract workers, provi- nerable employment is often characterized by inadequate earnings, low
sion of space and licenses for vendors in marketplaces, and productivity, and difficult conditions of work that undermine workers
lobbying for better access to forests and markets for gum fundamental rights (ILO 2010).

Conclusion generate enough new nonfarm wage employ-


ment to absorb both the new entrants and those
Governments need to give serious consider- who seek to leave agriculture. HEs are growing
ation to the HE sectors potential to create jobs as a share of the labor force not because of fail-
for youth. Even exceptionally high economic ures in regulation and economic growth, but
growth in nonfarm sectors has not and will not because households that manage to stay in the
178 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

sector make moneymore than those working should be encouraged at the local level so
only in agriculture or as casual laborers. that HEs can have a voice.
Young people see these opportunities and Better financial access for households. Regu-
are trying to enter the sector, but they are latory reform is needed to reduce the costs
frustrated by the lack of capital, information of retail banking, encourage savings, and
on markets and opportunities, productivity- develop youth-focused products. NGOs
enhancing skills, and locations to work. Because should be encouraged to expand low-cost
the HE sector grows when new businesses arise, strategies to help youth to save start-up
the strategy for increasing employment in this capital, such as village savings groups.
sector is to encourage business creation, sup- More effective skills strategies. Governments
port higher earnings, and increase sustainabil- should focus their efforts on market-
ity. Initiatives that address the most important enhancing programs, such as programs to
constraints on creating a businesslack of disseminate information about opportuni-
finance and space to workwill be the most ties and facilitate access to existing training
effective. for disadvantaged youth and not attempt to
Most countries have no such strategy for deliver training directly. They should also
the HE sector. Instead, they have a fragmented invest selectively in good-quality training
youth employment strategy focused primar- programs that tackle multiple constraints,
ily on the wage sector and a strategy for SMEs. either by building a range of skills such as
This set of strategies is not working. Initiatives technical, business, and behavioral skills or
for SMEs rarely reach HEs. Boutique NGO by combining skills with capital.
projects cannot reach enough prospective HE Development of value chains. This activ-
owners to make a difference. ity resides primarily with the private sec-
A comprehensive national HE strategy tor. Governments should encourage social
should focus on approaches that are demand entrepreneurs to include HEs in value chain
driven and address the main constraints to development.
start-up and sustainability. Elements of a Associations. Associations are especially
comprehensive national strategy for the HE important at the local level. Regulations
sector, based on a shared vision of the sectors on consultation prior to land use planning
potential to generate productive employment, or implementation should encourage local
include the following: governments to work through independent
HE associations. Donors and NGOs should
National strategies. Growth and employ-
extend support to these associations, help-
ment strategies need to recognize the sec-
tors potential and propose a supportive ing to develop their capacity.
policy framework. The strategy should
endorse the creation of independent HE
Notes
associations to reduce the costs of reaching
1. In many countries, rural households include
individual enterprises and to give this sec- households in market towns or periurban areas.
tor a voice in government decision making. They are often designated rural because agricul-
The specific outcomes to be attained in the ture is still the predominant economic activity.
sector should be to expand the number of 2. This section draws from World Bank studies of
businesses and increase their productivity. HEs in the Republic of Congo, Ghana, Kenya,
Rwanda, Tanzania, and Uganda as well as
Urban policies. HEs also need to be recog-
broader reviews of the literature and evidence.
nized as an important element in local eco-
3. At the time of writing, the youth employment
nomic development. Local governments inventory included 86 youth employment proj-
must be accountable to HEs and include ects in Africa, of which 79 provide skills train-
them in decisions related to planning, zon- ing. In a review of interventions to support
ing, and land use, land markets and land young workers in Sub-Saharan Africa, Rother
tenure, and infrastructure. HE associations (2006) found, In most cases, these programs
Creating Productive Employment for Youth in the Household Enterprise Sector 179

include elements targeted at helping young participated in the training; of those who par-
people to start their own businesses, com- ticipated, 85 percent took part in the life skills
bined with elements of skills development and training and 53 percent took part in the voca-
training. tional skills training (primarily in dressmaking
4. Outside Africa, few studies offer evidence that or tailoring).
technical training by itself can facilitate entry 10. The latter package was designed primarily to
into self-employment. For instance, skills train- help females to attain a wage job. The main
ing had no significant impact among a sample reason for the low impact is that there was little
of workfare participants in a welfare-dependent demand in the wage employment sector for the
region of Argentina (Galasso, Ravallion, and Sal- graduates.
via 2004). 11. Cash grants targeted to youth groups can affect
5. While the number of programs providing busi- occupational choice and improve income.
ness skills or financial literacy training has been Blattman, Fiala, and Martinez (2013) evaluate
increasing in Africa (see Messy and Monticone the impact of a Youth Opportunities Program
2012; Xu and Zia 2012), only a handful of recent implemented by the Ugandan government in the
impact evaluations analyze the effect of such context of the northern Uganda Social Action
programs on entry into self-employment. For Fund. The program targeted youth groups of
instance, most evaluations quoted by Messy 1030 persons, who received grants averaging
and Monticone (2012) analyze the effect on US$374 per group member. (Participants were
intermediary outcomes (such as knowledge of poor by most measures, but the average appli-
financial literacy or savings behavior), but not cant was slightly above the average wealth and
on employment outcomes (such as entry into education level in the region. For instance, 93
self-employment) or earnings. percent had completed some primary school,
6. In developed countries, Oosterbeek, van Praag, 45 percent had completed some secondary, and
and Ijsselstein (2008) studied the impact of only 7 percent had no education.) Of those who
entrepreneurship education on students com- received the cash transfer, 80 percent enrolled in
petencies and intentions. They found that the vocational training, and most invested heavily
program did not have the intended effects: the in business assets. The program was effective in
effect on students self-assessed entrepreneur- changing the type of work that youth perform
ial skills was insignificant, and the effect on the in an environment where most employment is
intention to become an entrepreneur was sig- outside the modern wage sector: 68 percent of
nificantly negative. grant recipients were working in a skilled trade,
7. For Pakistan, see Gin and Mansuri (2011). For compared with 34 percent of the control group.
Peru, see Karlan and Validivia (2011). For Sri Income was also higher for grant beneficiaries.
Lanka, see De Mel, McKenzie, and Woodruff On average, grant recipients had net income 50
(2012a). For the Dominican Republic, see Drex- percent higher than the control group, a return
ler, Fischer, and Schoar (2010). on the initial transfer amounting to 35 percent
8. The business training course consisted of 21 a year.
sessions, each lasting 45 minutes, and covered 12. Another example of integrated intervention
topics such as Entrepreneurship and Entrepre- can be found in rural Nicaragua, where ben-
neurial Character, Improving Customer Service, eficiaries from a cash transfer program also
Managing People in Your Business, and Market- received either technical training or a business
ing Strategies. Overall, these results suggest that grant. The business grant packages led to entry
insufficient human capital among poor micro into self-employment as well as higher aver-
and small business owners may be the more age income and consumption. The vocational
important constraint to increasing productiv- training package led to entry into self-employ-
ity. The results also highlight the need for more ment for the poor and higher wage income for
comprehensive measures to promote develop- the nonpoor, but had no impacts on income or
ment among female entrepreneurs. consumption on average (Macours, Premand,
9. The program was implemented in urban and and Vakis 2013). Both the training package and
rural areas through local adolescent develop- the business grant package also helped house-
ment clubs in which a female mentor led the holds to protect themselves against shocks by
activities. The program targeted girls ages 1420 allowing them to smooth income through
who were still in school or had dropped out. Of diversification (Macours, Premand, and Vakis
the girls in the target communities, 21 percent 2012).
180 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

13. Examples of modules in wide use include ILOs Campos, Francisco, Markus Goldstein, Laura
Start and Improve Your Business Program (see McGorman, Ana Maria Munoz Boudet, and
http://www.ilo.org/empent/areas/start-and- Obert Pimhidzai. 2013. Breaking the Metal
improve-your-business/lang--en/index.htm) Ceiling: Female Entrepreneurs Who Succeed in
Male-Dominated Sectors in Uganda. United
and various materials produced by the Peace
Nations Foundation; ExxonMobile Foundation.
Corps (http://www.peacecorps.gov/library/
pubindex/); for example, see the Microenter- Cho, Yoonyoung, Davie Kalomba, Mushfiq
Mobarak, and Victor Orozco. 2012. The Effects
prise Training Guide (http://files.peacecorps. of Apprenticeship Training for Vulnerable Youth
gov/multimedia/pdf/library/M0068_microent. in Malawi. Working Paper, World Bank, Wash-
pdf). ington, DC.
Cole, Shawn, Thomas Sampson, and Bilal Zia. 2011.
References Prices or Knowledge: What Drives Demand for
Ayyagari, Meghana, Asli Demirg-Kunt, and Financial Services in Emerging Markets? Journal
Vojislav Maksimovic. 2011. Small vs. Young of Financee 66 (6): 193367.
Firms across the World: Contribution to De Mel, Suresh, David McKenzie, and Christopher
Employment, Job Creation, and Growth. Policy Woodruff. 2012a. Business Training and Female
Research Working Paper 5631, World Bank, Enterprise Start-up, Growth, and Dynamics:
Washington, DC. Experimental Evidence from Sri Lanka. Policy
Bandiera, Oriana, Robin Burgess, Selim Gulesci, Research Working Paper 6145, World Bank,
Washington, DC.
Imran Rasul, and Munshi Sulaiman. 2012. Can
Entry-Level Entrepreneurship Transform the . 2012b. One-Time Transfers of Cash or
Economic Lives of the Poor? London School of Capital Have Long-Lasting Effects on Micro-
Economics. enterprises in Sri Lanka. Sciencee 335 (6071):
96266. doi: 10.1126/science.1212973.
Berge, Lars, Kjetil Bjorvatn, and Bertil Tungodden.
2011. Human and Financial Capital for Micro- De Wolf, Stefan, Yves Rolland Rakotoarisoa, Lau-
enterprise Development: Evidence from a Field rence Vanpaeschen, and Honor Rabekoto. 2008.
and Lab Experiment. NHH Department of Eco- Madagascar: Le Grand Livre des Petits Mtiers:
nomics Discussion Paper 1/2011, Chr. Michelsen Portraits of Daily Life Professions. Heule, Belgium:
Institute, Bergen. Snoek Publishers.
Drexler, Alejandro, Greg Fischer, and Antoinette
Blattman, Christopher, Nathan Fiala, and Sebastian
S. Schoar. 2010. Keeping It Simple: Financial
Martinez. 2013. Credit Constraints, Occupa-
Literacy and Rules of Thumb. CEPR Discus-
tional Choice, and the Process of Development:
sion Paper, Centre for Economic Policy Research,
Long-Run Evidence from Cash Transfers in London. http://dev3.cepr.org/meets/wkcn/7/784/
Uganda. Columbia University, New York. papers/FischerFinal.pdf.
Blattman, Chris, Eric Green, Jeannie Annan, and Fafchamps, Marcel, David McKenzie, Simon
Julian Jamison, with F. Aryemo, N. Carlson, Quinn, and Christopher Woodruff. 2011. When
M. Emeriau, and A. Segura. 2013. Building Is Capital Enough to Get Female Microenter-
Womens Economic and Social Empowerment prises Growing? Evidence from a Randomized
through Enterprise: An Experimental Assess- Experiment in Ghana. CSAE Working Paper
ment of the Womens Income Generating Sup- 2011-11, Centre for the Study of African Econo-
port (WINGS) Program in Uganda. Innovations mies, Oxford.
for Poverty Action, New Haven, CT. http://www.
Falco, Paolo, William F. Maloney, Bob Rijkers,
poverty-action.org/sites/default/files/wings_full_
and Mauricio Sarrias. 2012. Heterogeneity in
policy_report_0.pdf. Subjective Well-Being: An Application to Occu-
Bridges, Sarah, Louise Fox, Alessio Gaggero, and pational Allocation in Africa. Policy Research
Trudy Owens. 2013. Labour Market Entry and Working Paper 6244, World Bank, Washington,
Earnings: Evidence from Tanzanian Retrospec- DC.
tive Data. Paper prepared for the CSAE confer- FinMark Trust. 2011. Financial Education in Zam-
ence Economic Development in Africa, Oxford bia: What Does FinScope Tell Us? Financial
University, Oxford, March. Access Matters 6, Marshalltown, South Africa.
Bruhn, Miriam, and Bilal Zia. 2011. Stimulating http://www.finmark.org.za/publication/
Managerial Capital in Emerging Markets: The financial-education-in-zambia-what-does-
Impact of Business and Financial Literacy for finscope-tell-us/.
Young Entrepreneurs. Policy Research Paper Fox, Louise, and Obert Pimhidzai. 2012. Is Infor-
5642, World Bank, Washington, DC. mality Welfare-Enhancing Structural Transfor-
Creating Productive Employment for Youth in the Household Enterprise Sector 181

mation? Evidence from Uganda. Policy Research Haggblade, Steven, Peter Hazell, and Thomas Rear-
Working Paper 5866, World Bank, Washington, don. 2010. The Rural Non-Farm Economy:
DC. Prospects and Poverty Reduction. World Devel-
. 2013. Different Dreams, Same Bed: Col- opmentt 38 (10) 142941.
lecting, Using, and Interpreting Employment Hicks, Joan Hamory, Michael Kremer, Isaac Mbit,
Statistics in Sub-Saharan Africa: The Case of and Edward Miguel. 2011. Vocational Education
Uganda. Policy Research Working Paper 6436, Voucher Delivery and Labor Market Returns: A
World Bank, Washington, DC. Randomized Evaluation among Kenyan Youth.
Fox, Louise, and Thomas Pave Sohnesen. 2012. Report for the Spanish Impact Evaluation Fund
Household Enterprises in Sub-Saharan Africa: (SIEF) Phase II, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Why They Matter for Growth, Jobs, and Liveli- IFAD (International Fund for Agricultural Devel-
hoods. Policy Research Working Paper 6184, opment). 2011. Promoting Rural Enterprise
World Bank, Washington, DC. Growth and Development: Lessons from Four
. 2013. Household Enterprises in Mozam- Projects in Sub-Saharan Africa. Field Experi-
bique: Key to Poverty Reduction but Not on the ences 2, IFAD, Rome.
Development Agenda? Policy Research Working ILO (International Labour Organization). 1993.
Paper 6570, World Bank, Washington, DC. Resolution Concerning the International Clas-
Frazer, Garth. 2006. Learning the Masters Trade: sification of Status in Employment (ICSE),
Apprenticeship and Human Capital in Ghana. Adopted by the Fifteenth International Con-
Journal of Development Economicss 81 (2): ference of Labour Statisticians. ILO, Geneva.
25998. http://www.ilo.org/public/english/bureau/stat/
Galasso, Emanuela, Martin Ravallion, and Augus- download/res/icse.pdf.
tin Salvia. 2004. Assisting the Transition from . 2010. Global Trends in Employment:
Workfare to Work: Argentinas Proempleo Pro- January 2010. ILO, Geneva.
gram. Industrial and Labor Relations Review w 57 Inchauste, Gabriela, and Sergio Olivieri. 2012.
(5): 12842. Understanding Poverty Reduction in Bangla-
Gelb, Alan, Taye Mengistae, Vijaya Ramachandran, desh: A Microdecomposition Approach. Back-
and Manju Kedia Shah. 2009. To Formalize or ground Paper prepared for the 2012 Poverty
Not to Formalize? Comparisons of Microen- Assessment, World Bank, Washington, DC.
terprises from Southern and East Africa. CGD
Karlan, Dean, Ryan Knight, and Christopher Udry.
Working Paper 175, Center for Global Develop-
2012. Hoping to Win, Expected to Lose: Theory
ment, London.
and Lessons on Micro Enterprise Development.
Ghana, Republic of. 2006. Poverty Reduction NBER Working Paper 18325, National Bureau of
Strategy Paper. National Development Planning Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.
Commission. IMF Country Report 06/225, IMF,
Washington, DC, June. Karlan, Dean, and Martin Valdivia. 2011. Teach-
ing Entrepreneurship: Impact of Business Train-
Gin, Xavier, and Ghazala Mansuri. 2011. Money ing on Microfinance Clients and Institutions.
or Ideas? A Field Experiment on Constraints Review of Economics and Statistics 93 (2): 51027.
to Entrepreneurship in Rural Pakistan. World
Bank, Washington DC. http://siteresources. Kottoh, M. 2008. Linking Corporations to House-
worldbank.org/DEC/Resources/Money_or_ hold Enterprises: Ghana Telecom (Vodafone
Ideas.pdf. Ghana) Value Chain. New Legon Observer,
Institute of Statistical, Social, and Economic
Grimm, Michael, Peter Knorringa, and Jann Lay. Research, University of Ghana.
2012. Constrained Gazelles: High Potentials in
West Africas Informal Economy. World Devel- Kubzansky, Michael, Ansulie Cooper, and Victoria
opmentt 40 (7): 135268. Barbary. 2011. Promise and Progress: Market-
Based Solutions to Poverty in Africa. Monitor
Grimm, Michael, Jens Krger, and Jann Lay. 2011. Group. http://web.mit.edu/idi/idi/Africa-%20
Barriers to Entry and Returns to Capital in
PromiseAndProgress-MIM.pdf.
Informal Activities: Evidence from Sub-Saharan
Africa. Review of Income and Wealth 57 (5): s27 Kweka, Josaphat, and Louise Fox. 2011. The
53. doi: 10.1111/j.1475-4991.2011.00453.x. Household Enterprise Sector in Tanzania: Why It
Matters and Who Cares. Policy Working Paper
Gulyani, Sumila, Debabrata Talukdar, and Darby
5882, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Jack. 2010. Poverty, Living Conditions, and
Infrastructure Access: A Comparison of Slums Lanjouw, Peter, Jaime Quizon, and Robert Sparrow.
in Dakar, Johannesburg, and Nairobi. Policy 2001. Non-Agricultural Earnings in Periurban
Research Working Paper 5388, World Bank, Areas of Tanzania: Evidence from Household
Washington, DC. Survey Data. Food Policyy 26 (4): 385403.
182 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Liviga, Athumani, and Rugatiri Mekacha. 1998. Policy Research Working Paper 6285, World
Youth Migration and Poverty Alleviation: A Bank, Washington, DC.
Case Study of Petty Traders (Wamachinga) in Roever, Sally. 2006. Enforcement and Compli-
Dar es Salaam. Research Report 98.5, Research ance in Limas Street Markets: The Origins and
on Poverty Alleviation, Dar es Salaam. Consequences of Policy Incoherence toward
Lyons, Michal, with Colman Msoka. 2007. Micro- Informal Traders. In Linking the Formal and
trading in Urban Mainland Tanzania: The Way Informal Economy: Concepts and Policies, edited
Forward. Report for HTSPE Development Con- by Basudep Guha-Khasnobis, Ravi Kanbure, and
sulting Services for the Development Partner Elinor Ostrom, 24662. Oxford: Oxford Univer-
Group, Tanzania. sity Press.
Macours, Karen, Patrick Premand, and Renos Vakis. Rother, Friederike. 2006. Interventions to Support
2012. Transfers, Diversification, and Household Young Workers in Sub Saharan Africa: Regional
Risk Strategies: Experimental Evidence with Report for the Youth Employment Inventory.
Implications for Climate Change Adaptation. World Bank, Washington, DC.
Policy Research Working Paper 5137, World Sisya, Marietta R. 2005. The Impact of Reloca-
Bank, Washington, DC. tion of Petty Traders on Income Generation for
. 2013. Demand versus Returns? Pro-Poor Local Authorities to Finance Social Services: The
Targeting of Business Grants and Vocational Case of Ilala Municipal Council. MPA thesis,
Skills Training. Policy Research Working Paper Mzumbe University, Morogoro.
6389, World Bank, Washington, DC. Tokman, Victor E. 2007. Modernizing the Informal
McKenzie, David, and Christopher Woodruff. 2012. Sector. DESA Working Paper 42, United Nations
What Are We Learning from Business Training Department of Economic and Social Affairs,
and Entrepreneurship Evaluations around the New York.
Developing World? Policy Research Working Uteng, Tanu Priya. 2011. Gender and Mobility
Paper 6202, World Bank, Washington, DC. in the Developing World. Background paper
Messy, Flore-Anne, and Chiara Monticone. 2012. for the World Development Report 2012: Gender
The Status of Financial Education in Africa. Equality and Development,t World Bank, Wash-
OECD Working Paper on Finance, Insurance, ington, DC.
and Private Pensions 25, OECD Publishing, Valdivia, Martin. 2011. Training or Technical
Paris. doi: 10.1787/5k94cqqx90wl-en. Assistance? A Field Experiment to Learn What
Ministry of Agriculture, Senegal. 2011. La promo- Works to Increase Managerial Capital for Female
tion des micro et petites entreprises rurales: Un Microentrepreneurs. Grupo de Anlisis para el
moyen efficace pour lutter contre la pauvret en Desarrollo (GRADE), Lima.
milieu rural; livret de capitalisation (PROME- Van Adams, Arvil, Sara Johansson de Silva, and
RII). Dakar. Setareh Razmara. 2013. Improving Skills Develop-
Monk, Courtney, Justin Sandefur, and Francis Teal. ment in the Informal Sector: Strategies for Sub-
2008. Does Doing an Apprenticeship Pay Off? Saharan Africa. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Evidence from Ghana. CSAE Working Paper World Bank. 2008. Weaving Peace in Rwanda. In
2008-08, Centre for the Study of African Econo- Doing Business: Women in Africa, 1721. Wash-
mies, Oxford. ington, DC: World Bank.
Oosterbeek, Hessel, Mirjam van Praag, and Auke . 2012. Preliminary EPAG Midline Report:
Ijsselstein. 2008. The Impact of Entrepreneur- Economic Empowerment of Adolescent Girls
ship Education on Entrepreneurship Competen- and Young Women (EPAG) Project in Liberia.
cies and Intentions: An Evaluation of the Junior World Bank, Washington, DC.
Achievement Student Mini-Company Program.
IZA Discussion Paper 3641, Institute for the . 2013. Time to Shift Gears: Accelerat-
Study of Labor, Bonn. ing Growth and Poverty Reduction in the New
Kenya. Kenya Economic Update, World Bank,
Pasquier-Doumer, Laure. 2013. Intergenerational Washington, DC.
Transmission of Self-Employed Status in the
Informal Sector: A Constrained Choice or Better World Bank and IPAR (Institute of Policy Anal-
Income Prospects? Evidence from Seven West- ysis and Research Rwanda). 2012. Raising Pro-
African Countries. Journal of African Economies ductivity and Reducing Risks of Household Enter-
22 (1): 73111. doi: 10.1093/jae/ejs017. prises in Rwanda. World Bank, Washington, DC.
Premand, Patrick, Stefanie Brodmann, Rita Xu, Lisa, and Bilal Zia. 2012. Financial Literacy
Almeida, Rebekka Grun, and Mahdi Barouni. around the World: An Overview of the Evidence
2012. Entrepreneurship Training and Self- with Practical Suggestions for the Way Forward.
Employment among University Graduates: Policy Research Working Paper 6107, World
Evidence from a Randomized Trial in Tunisia. Bank, Washington, DC.
Financial Inclusion and the Transition to FOCUS
Sustainable Livelihoods for Young People NOTE 3

F
inancial inclusion means that individuals households take out a loan to make potentially
can obtain a range of financial products high-yielding but risky investments.
savings, credit, insurance, and payment sys- Agricultural households need to save and
tems, including systems to send remittances borrow for a range of reasonsto obtain and
at a reasonable cost and on a sustained basis sustain land to farm, to buy or rent equipment,
(Gardeva and Rhyne 2011). Financial inclusion and to acquire other inputs that make their
remains elusive for many African households, efforts more productive. Households that oper-
which generally develop their own strate- ate a nonfarm enterprise also need to save and
gies for saving and rely on loans from family, borrow to start and maintain their business.
friends, and informal lenders to meet their A complicating factor for farm households
need for credit. The gap in access to savings and households operating nonfarm enter-
vehicles is at least as important as the gap in prises is that the finances of the farm, house-
access to credit. Closing these gaps is challeng- hold enterprise (HE), and household itself are
ing for most households, especially for young often linked, so household income smoothing
people, whose access to formal financial ser- and credit needs (for example, funds to pay
vices is often limited by banking regulations, for lumpy expenditures such as school fees or
the lack of products designed to meet their home repairs) may compete with farm or busi-
particular needs, and the difficulty of estab- ness liquidity needs, potentially reducing the
lishing their creditworthiness. Across Africa, sustainability of the business. For this reason,
technology is reducing the cost and increasing the gap in access to credit occurs at both the
the accessibility of formal financial services; household and the enterprise level.
at the same time, informal savings and credit Young or aspiring farmers and HE owners It is not easy
groups are expanding. These informal groups can have the most difficulty mobilizing capital, for us to access
may offer a promising venue for integrating the because their capacity to save and borrow is credit like the
delivery of youth programs in communities, often so constrained. In many countries, young adults. Uganda
including programs to foster savings behavior, people cannot access the formal banking system
build business and soft skills, empower females, even if they want to, because laws prohibit open-
and expand financial inclusion, with the goal ing a bank account before age 18.1 Even where
of enabling young people to pursue sustainable no legal obstacles stand in their way, young
livelihoods. people can be frustrated by the lack of products
designed to meet their particular needs as savers
and borrowers of small amounts.
Gaps in Access to Savings Despite these limitations, low-income
and Credit youths in various situations (at home with par-
ents, living away from home, or living on the
The ability to save is intricately linked with the street) persist in saving for school, emergen-
ability to obtain credit. Without the habit of cies, and less often, to start a business (USAID
regularly setting money aside, individuals have 2009). Saving not only is important for meet-
difficulty repaying loans. In addition, lenders ing those needs, but having financial assets by
will always require borrowers to use a portion itself has positive behavioral effects for young
of their savings to pay for part of a proposed people, increasing future orientation, long-
investment (the down payment). Savings can term thinking, planning, and self-efficacy
also serve as a form of self-insurance when (Kilara and Latortue 2012). Research shows
183
184 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

that behaviors such as saving and exercising inson 2009). Women sometimes go to extraor-
financial discipline are best developed at a dinary lengths to set money aside. For example,
young age. If young people do not develop the in the absence of other mechanisms to save,
habit of saving, they will have trouble starting market women in India with more established
and sustaining farm and nonfarm enterprises businesses report taking loans from informal
later on. moneylenders at very high interest rates just so
they will be required to put funds aside every
day. They resort to this strategy even though
Formal Savings Services: they could accumulate much more capital and
Issues and Options profits if they were to save a part of their profits
every day to self-finance the next replacement
A secure place for savings allows people to of inventory (Karlan and Appel 2011).
improve their planning, financial decisions,
and risk management by keeping their money African Households Save, but Rarely
out of temptations way (Mullainathan and at the Bank
Shafir 2011; Collins et al. 2009). Although low- African households are no different from
income households and individuals may have households elsewherethey know the value
very little cash on a given day, a savings habit of savings. Controlling for national income,
can transform that cash over time into a larger African adults are actually more likely to save
sum, which can then be used for lumpy expen- than non-African adults, especially in low-
ditures such as school fees or investment in income countries (figure F3.1). African youths
inventory or tools for an HE. But when people in lower-income countries also report sav-
lack a secure place to put their money, they are ing more than their counterparts in countries
much less likely to save, as the difficulties of with similar income levels. In some countries,
daily life for the household and the extended more than 20 percent of individuals ages 1525
family demand a short-term financial focus, reported that they had been able to save some
and multiple requests for cash reduce self- funds in the last year.
control. Access to a secure place for savings is Although youths and older adults say that
particularly important for womens ability to they save, they do not use a bank account
build up capital for a business, because women for that purpose. Some use informal savings
are especially subject to pressure for funds from groups in the village or neighborhood, but
other members of the family (Dupas and Rob- many simply keep their cash at home, the least

Figure F3.1
by savings mechanism

a. Ages 1524 b. Ages 25 and older


50 50

40 40
Percent

Percent

30 30

20 20

10 10

0 0
Low- Lower- Upper- Low- Lower- Upper- Low- Lower- Upper- Low- Lower- Upper-
income middle- middle- income middle- middle- income middle- middle- income middle- middle-
countries income income countries income income countries income income countries income income
countries countries countries countries countries countries countries countries
Sub-Saharan Africa Rest of the world Sub-Saharan Africa Rest of the world

Formal Informal/club Other

Source: Based on FINDEX data.


Focus Note 3 185

safe place. In surveys, young people and adults Box F3.1


express a desire for an affordable, convenient,
safe place to keep their moneya service usu-
ally provided by a bank. Rural banks in Ghana: Reaching clients who
Access to banking services rises with income are underserved by other banks
and urbanization. Banking is an industry with
economies of scale, so banks go where the Ghanas rural and community banks (RCBs) were established by the
money and the customers are (unless spe- government in the late 1970s to facilitate Cocoa Board payments to
farmers. The banks were privatized and became microfinance institu-
cial provisions are made; see box F3.1 for an
tions in the 1990s, and today they provide various affordable sav-
example of rural banking from Ghana). Given
ings products (savings accounts, current accounts, daily deposits col-
the low incomes and low population density lected by agents who go door to door, and fixed or time deposits),
prevalent in Africa, it is not surprising that few credit products (microfinance loans, personal loans, salary loans, and
households use formal banking services: only overdraft facilities, for example), and money transfer and payment
24 percent of households in Africa have access services. Ghanas RCBs reach 2.8 million depositors and 680,000 bor-
to a bank account.2 rowers, consisting mainly of farmers, government employees, and
But the lack of a bank account is far from the small and microentrepreneursclients often underserved by formal
whole story in Africa. As in the rest of the world, financial institutions. They are now the largest providers of formal
in Africas banking industry, technological financial services in rural Ghana. With some additional outreach, they
innovation and regulation interact in complex could benefit young peopleanother underserved population.
ways to influence how much it costs to provide Source: IFPRI and World Bank 2010, brief 5.
financial services and who can obtain them.

Options for Lowering Costs and


Expanding Outreach
At the firm level, the high fixed costs of operat- population density makes brick-and-mortar Even if you have
ing a bank office (building, machinery, banking branch banking unprofitable, but the con- 100 shillings, you
staff, security), the need for reliable infrastruc- struction of cell phone towers and networks
can save your
ture and services (electricity and communica- has opened opportunities to bank through a
tions), and customers unwillingness to use a mobile phone, ATM, or point-of-sale device. little money.
bank that is far from their work or home mean In branchless banking, the costs of savings Uganda
that high population density is a prerequisite account and bill payment services are as much
for traditional banking services to spread.3 as 50 percent lower, and the costs of money
Given the fixed costs associated with maintain- transfers are about 20 percent lower, than they
ing customer accounts (recording transactions, are in traditional banking by microfinance
processing fees and interest), small account bal- institutions (MFIs) and other banks oriented
ances can be a losing proposition for the bank toward the poor (McKay and Pickens 2010).4
and for the customer, to whom those costs are The rapid spread of M-PESA in Kenya, which
passed in the form of account and transaction increased household access to formal finance
service charges. Regulations can compound by 10 percentage points in three years, shows
the cost problem when they require proof of the potential (King 2012). The use of mobile
identification (birth certificates and similar phones and other new technology to expand
documents), which many low- and moderate- access to formal banking is particularly attrac-
income individuals lack and which are difficult tive for young people, who are always early
to acquire. In Kenya and India, to cite just two adopters.5
examples, technology is helping consumers to At the same time, banks need to use these
bypass these problems (box F3.2). new channels for connecting with young peo-
Recent technological applications such pleto offer products attractive to youths and
as mobile banking have sharply reduced the bring them in as customers earlyeven if the
costs of retail banking, offering a major new benefits are more likely to materialize over the
opportunity to increase household access to long term. This effort may require support as
secure savings and payment mechanisms. Low part of financial sector development.
186 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box F3.2

Use of technology: Bringing secure financial services to new markets in Kenya and India
Just as the cellular telephone revolution has lowered the issuers and e-money transactions. Rather than simply block-
cost of communication and allowed poor countries in Africa ing Safaricom from operating the system, the central bank
and elsewhere to leapfrog over the problem of building a negotiated an agreement under which Safaricom would
landline phone network, branchless banking using mobile operate the system. The agreement stipulated that the
phones and micro automated teller machines (ATMs) that e-money on deposit with Safaricom through M-PESA would
read unique bioidentifiers could be used to extend financial be separated from the companys accounts and cash flow
access to the vast unbanked population. Already, Africa (in the same way that other nonbank financial institutions,
is the second-largest mobile money market, in part because such as stock brokerages, are required to isolate custom-
remittances are so important in this region. But as with the ers assets from the assets and accounts of the company).
rollout of mobile phones, regulatory policy will be as impor- The central bank kept a close watch on the systems opera-
tant as innovation in determining the outcome. tions, including sporadic checks to see that at the close of
the day the amount of funds that e-money customers had
stored with Safaricom in their phone accounts was equal to
Kenyas Venture into Mobile Money the amount of funds that Safaricom had placed in its trust
account at its partner bank. After three years of this test-
Since its launch in Kenya in 2007, M-PESA, a mobile phone
and-learn supervision, the central bank began work on a
based banking system run by Safaricom, has dramatically
set of e-money and e-payment regulations.
changed the financial services landscape. M-PESA allows
registered users to store money in their account by buying
phone credits, to transfer money to or receive money from Indias Solution to the High Cost of Verifying
other registered users through their mobile phone, as well as Bank Clients
to transform their credit balance into cash at any authorized
dealer. By building on its existing cell phone record-keeping For low-income populations, a major obstacle to interacting
infrastructure and agent network, Safaricom has been able with the formal banking system is the lack of verifiable iden-
to offer basic banking services at much cheaper prices than tification. Banking systems need to be able to identify their
a branch bank (about 50 percent cheaper, depending on the customers to ensure that financial transactions are secure;
service and size of transaction). It has doubled the share of in addition, they have to comply with supervisory reporting
the population with access to a secure place to store cash, requirements on transactions, some of which are set inter-
and, by operating as a debit card (or electronic wallet), it has nationally as part of global anticorruption and antiterrorism
reduced users vulnerability to robbery. regulations. Low-income countries are less likely to have reli-
M-PESA differs from a bank in two important ways. It able national identification systems, and these databases are
does not offer loans (although M-PESA customers can use unlikely to cover lower-income populations and people in
the system to link with banks, receive loaned funds, and rural areas. Faced with the high cost of verifying the identity
make the required loan payments), and it does not pay inter- of such clients, banks often choose not to serve them at all.
est on its accounts. Given that the interest earned on small The Government of India is finding a way around this
savings accounts in commercial banks is usually eaten up by problem through the Unique National Identification project,
account fees, small savers are better off using M-PESA, even in which identification is based on biometrics rather than
without the interest. In 2012, an analysis concluded that standard approaches such as birth certificates and postal
M-PESAs branchless banking system had brought banking addresses. At a very small cost per participant, more than
to previously unserved low-income populations and had 300 million people registered in the first two years. Banks
flattened the geographical constraints to access across have responded enthusiastically to this system, investing in
Kenya (King 2012, 28). Despite being a low-income coun- basic biometric readers, which are linked to the database
try, Kenya has one of the highest levels of financial access and can instantly identify and verify account holders. Agents
in Africa, with mobile money transactions equivalent to 60 in rural areas have been equipped with micro ATMs
percent of Kenyas gross domestic product (GDP) in 2012 point-of-sale devicesthat read the clients biometrics (usu-
(Blycroft Ltd. 2012). ally fingerprints) and record the transactions in the bank
At least as important as Safaricoms product innovation database, reducing the need for customers to travel to
and successful implementation was the stance of the bank bank branches. Government agencies are using this system
regulator, the central bank of Kenya. When M-PESA was to disburse cash transfers to households through low-cost
launched, Kenya had no law regulating nonbank e-money bank accounts, and citizens can also pay school fees and
(continued)
Focus Note 3 187

Box F3.2

(continued)

utility bills through this system. Initially envisaged as a way ing the way for dramatically increased access by providing
to simplify administrative procedures and reduce the costs financial services at a much lower cost.
of service delivery (including leakages), the system is set
to transform the financial services landscape in India, pav- Sources: King 2012; Lauer and Tarazi 2012.

Regulation to Increase Financial finance expansion and mobile banking as well


Inclusion and Encourage the Use of as programs to support the growth of afford-
New Technology able credit to nonfarm businesses in rural areas.
As figure F3.2 shows, even at the same income Mongolia has used a dynamic mobile network
level, national policies for the financial sec- system and a G2P payment system to broaden
tor can produce very different results. Coun- access. Given the rapid evolution of bank-
tries such as Kenya, Mauritius, and Rwanda in ing technology and its potential to change the
Africa and China, India, Mongolia, and Thai- financial landscape, countries need to develop a
land in Asia have achieved much higher finan- regulatory structure that encourages the spread
cial access than other countries at similar levels of the technology, while protecting consumers
of income. And given income levels, Africa is through interoperability and other regulations
not doing badly. Among poor countries (with (see Dias and McKee 2010; Lauer and Tarazi
GDP per capita under US$1,000), the major- 2012; World Bank 2013).
ity of African countries for which we have data In the CFA system in Western and Central
are actually above the trend line of the rest of Africa, regulation has restrained innovation in
the world. The exception is countries in the the financial sector. Regional central banks are
CFA (Communaut Financire dAfrique) involved in financial regulation, and changes to
zone, which tend to lag the rest of the world in the system require the agreement of all partici-
extending bank accounts to households. pants. This arrangement has kept competition
Countries with high household access to in the formal banking sector low, and house-
finance tend to have one or more of the follow- hold financial inclusion well below the trend
ing features: (1) a competitive banking sector, for the rest of Africa and the world. It has ben-
which encourages banks to look for customers; efited insiders at the expense of new entrants
(2) a vibrant microfinance sector, which tends (World Bank 2013). The penetration of MFIs
to specialize in products tailored to the needs is low, and regulations to facilitate their growth
of lower-income households; (3) proportion- were not adopted by all countries of the West
ate supervision, including a test-and-learn African Economic and Monetary Union until
approach, which encourages innovation; and 2012 (Riquet and Mbenge 2013). Mobile car-
(4) a national strategy. The national strategy riers such as Safaricom (Kenya) cannot start
encompasses the first three characteristics. It mobile banking initiativesonly banks have
can also include policies to encourage banks to the right to do so, and they have no incentives to
offer products that are appropriately designed serve low-income customers. Ideally, a regional
and priced for low-income people, along with regulator could spur the development of a large
policies that require all government payments market for mobile banking by developing har-
to individuals (G2P payments) to be elec- monized cross-border payment systems, but
tronic, which encourages financial inclusion. that has yet to happen. There are signs that the
For example, Kenya has both a vibrant micro- regulatory environment is adapting, however.
finance sector and a policy environment that It is hoped that the new MFI regulations will
encourages innovation (box F3.2). Rwandas help to create a trustworthy system interested
national strategy to encourage financial inclu- in serving the currently unbanked population.
sion is reflected in policies to encourage micro- A new financial inclusion strategy, which will
188 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Figure F3.2 Percentage of individuals with an account at a formal financial institution

100 a. Ages 1524

90

80
MNG MUS
70
CHN
60 THA
Percent

50
KEN
40 RSA

30 IND GHA AGO


ZWE SWZ
20 UGA NGA BWA
RWA
10 BFA COM GAB
SEN EGY COG
0 NER MLI TKM
350 3,500

100 b. Ages 25 and over

90

80 MUS
MNG
70 THA
CHN
60
RSA
Percent

ZWE
50
AGO
40 RWA KEN IND EGY
NGA BWA
30 UGA SWZ
GHA
COM
BFA GAB
20

10 COG
SEN
NER MLI TKM
0
350 3,500

GDP per capita 2011 (current US$)

CFA countries Non-CFA Sub-Saharan African countries Rest of the world


Trend of CFA countries Trend of non-CFA Sub-Saharan African countries Trend of rest of the world
Source: Based on FINDEX data.
Note: The x axis of this figure is on a log scale.

require all financial service providers to offer a will remain high. There are fixed staff costs in
basic bank account with a package of free ser- loan appraisal. Because most loans are for such
vices, is scheduled to be adopted in 2013. Thus small amounts, even the best MFIs report that
the prospects for improved household financial they must earn an average of 19 percent a year
access are high in this region. on their loan portfolios just to cover operating
costs of US$114 per loan (see MIX 2008). Large
nonprofit MFIs such as BRAC and Grameen
Bank in South Asia cover part of these costs
Formal Credit Services:
through donations, but the commercially ori-
Challenges in Expanding Options ented MFIs that are more common in Africa,
for Smallholders, Household such as Ecobank and Equity Bank, have to
Enterprises, and Young People charge high interest rates to cover these costs.
For banks, lending to smallholders is risky.
Even if retail banking costs fall and savings Agricultural cycles are unpredictable. The cli-
accounts become cheaper, the costs of lending ents are in remote locations, are often unfa-
to smallholders, HE owners, and young people miliar with financial services, and have few
Focus Note 3 189

assets to use as collateral. Young smallholders Lending to HEs has similar problems. HEs We form groups
can offer few assurances to formal lenders, but face high risks of doing business (ranging from to borrow money
they are likely to need capital to acquire the fluctuating demand to seizure of goods by
to engage in
agricultural technologies, land, and equipment authorities), and they are vulnerable to shocks
that will allow them to pursue more produc- and demands for cash within the household petty trade,
tive and often more commercial agricultural (sickness, for example) and community (funer- pay school fees,
livelihoods. Chapter 4 discusses constraints als). HEs may be unable to generate the rates and to build or
on financial services in agriculture and details of return required to pay back a loan. Lend- improve on our
several ways in which banks and nongovern- ers have to assess these risks and price loans houses.
mental organizations (NGOs) are innovating accordingly. HEs that can generate the returns
Uganda
to provide them. Financial services alone may to pay the loan back may not maintain a busi-
not be a strong springboard for smallholders ness account, however, and thus may not be
to improve agricultural productivity and com- able to present themselves as creditworthy, even
mercial activity. Some approaches combine the to financial institutions oriented toward serv-
provision of financial services with the provi- ing low-income households.
sion of agricultural information (planting and Microfinance programs use group liabil-
marketing advice, for example; see the discus- ity lending to ameliorate some of the risk and
sion of BASIX in chapter 4). Other approaches high cost of lending to people with very limited
recognize that integrating smallholders with assets. Because the group guarantees the credit
agribusinessdomestic supermarkets, agro- of the individual members, it acts as a support
processors, or (further along the supply chain) mechanism for the farmer or enterprise owner
exportersmay reduce some of the risk in and as a risk reduction mechanism for the
providing financial services to smallholders. lender. The lending methodologies applied by
Kenyas DrumNet Project is one example of a leading MFIs have succeeded in holding their
supply-chain approach to agricultural lending portfolio at risk (more than 30 days) below an
(box F3.3). average of 3 percent (MIX 2008).

Box F3.3

Linking smallholders to supply chains to improve their access to financial services


DrumNet (a project of PRIDE AFRICA, a microfinance non- the input credit and served as security for the loans. After
profit) sought to improve Kenyan smallholders access to signing a fixed-price contract to supply sunflower seed to
financial services through a pilot program that integrated Bidco, farmers received credit for inputs from Equity Bank.
them into the supply chain for oilseeds. The pilot, which Farmers obtained no cash from Equity Bank; instead, the
lasted from 2007 to 2009, involved Equity Bank and Bidco, bank paid input suppliers directly for inputs that farmers pur-
a large manufacturer of vegetable oils, fats, margarines, chased with the credit. When farmers delivered their produce
and protein concentrates in East Africa. Bidco required an to Bidco, Bidco paid them through DrumNet, which deducted
assured supply of sunflower seed. Farmers were recruited the cost of the loan and transferred it to Equity Bank. The
to grow sunflowers instead of their typical crop. The other remainder was deposited in the farmers account with Equity
partners were input suppliers and AgriTrade (which recruited Bank. DrumNet facilitated the financial transactions and com-
farmers and managed sunflower production, harvest, and munication via mobile phones, text messages, and e-mail.
collection). DrumNet brought the parties together, negoti- More than 2,000 smallholders participated in the sun-
ated the contracts on which their collaboration was based, flower pilot. The arrangement between farmers, buyers,
and managed the flow of information and financial transac- banks, and retailers, although complex, brought smallhold-
tions among them, earning revenue for those services. ers into the formal financial system, integrated them into a
Farmer groups (usually about 20100 farmers in the same supply chain for a commercial crop, and improved efficiency
area) opened an account with Equity Bank, through which all throughout the oilseed supply chain.
payments were made. Each farmer contributed to a Transac-
tion Insurance Fund, which was 25 percent of the value of Source: World Bank 2011.
190 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box F3.4

Shifting from group to individual liability lending as a positive microfinance innovation:


Evidence from the Philippines
A central decision in designing credit programs for poor bers. The finding that monitoring decreased but repayment
people is whether to rely on group or individual liability. was stable suggests that the screening process changed
Individual liability places more responsibility on the lending without worsening repayment. One possibility is that the
institution, so borrowers prefer it (Karlan and Appel 2011). removal of group liability may have induced credit officers to
Although individual liability lending is becoming more com- increase screening and monitoring, although their workload
mon in microfinance, little empirical research has compared did not increase.
the two approaches. Between 2004 and 2007, two random- The second trial offered new borrowers group liability in
ized controlled trials with Rural Green Bank of Caraga, an some areas and individual liability in others. No statistically or
MFI in the Philippines, examined how loan monitoring and economically significant difference was found in repayment
repayment differed under group liability and individual liabil- rates. The move toward individual liability lending appears to
ity lending. All of the loans (roughly US$18US$90) went to have distributed the burden for screening, monitoring, and
female owners of HEs to expand their businesses. enforcement more equitably between clients and credit offi-
The first trial converted group liability lending programs cers. The level of institutional enforcement seen in the two
to individual liability, while retaining the group structure. No trials was sufficient for the lender to recover loans without
increase in defaults or loss of profits was found for centers group liability and, in some cases, to attract and retain more
that switched. Individual liability centers gained more clients clients. Although the experiment was limited to one MFI in
(new clients were more likely to remain in the program), one setting, the results imply that other microfinance innova-
but because clients loans were smaller, the individual liabil- tors that are pursuing strategies for individual (and more flex-
ity centers disbursed about the same amount as the group ible) lending to the poor may be moving in the right direction.
liability centers. Groups that switched to individual liability
spent less time monitoring repayment by other group mem- Source: Gin and Karlan 2013.

Yet microfinance groups can require sub- (especially for farmers) or business equipment
stantial time and financial guarantees from as collateral, also have downsides. Smallhold-
participants. The time required to participate ers and HE owners could lose critical assets just
in the group may deter smallholders or owner- when they need them most. MFIs using these
managers of an informal enterprise from using strategies in Africa are more selective; they pre-
MFI services. If the group is not formed prop- fer to lend to households where a wage earner
erly and someone defaults, the downside shock can act as a cosigner for the loan. These require-
to smallholders and HE owners, whose margins ments help to explain why HE owners and
are already low and who have their own loans farmers, who constantly face liquidity prob-
to pay off, is high (box F3.4). The combination lems because of low and uncertain cash flow,
of group liability with low flexibility on the part rarely borrow from banks or MFIs and remain
of the lender excludes borrowers who want within their informal financial networks.
to finance risky projects or investments that
will take some time to pay off, creating a bias Informal Services to Fill the Savings
toward small, safe projects. In short, microfi- and Credit Gaps
nance group lending methodologies that help Although their scope is almost always small,
to solve the problems of high cost and risk to informal financial services have sprung up in
the financial institutions effectively impose part Africa to fill the gap in savings and credit ser-
of these costs on the clients; therefore, they are vices for households. These various savings and
suited only for particular types of customers. credit services have a long history and have
Alternative strategies, such as lending to developed rules for participation that ensure
individuals on more flexible terms but requir- success (box F3.5). They meet a need that can-
ing them to pledge key assets such as land not be met through more formal financing
Focus Note 3 191

arrangements, owing to the small amounts and among adults over 25; almost half of adults in
numerous small transactions involved, as well lower-middle-income countries who save use
as the lack of information on the participants these groups. These groups also help young
creditworthiness. Informal services are a valu- people to save, and they may explain why the
able bridge to financial literacy, a widespread youth savings rate in Africa is the highest in the
savings culture, and, eventually, formal finan- world.
cial inclusion and more productive enterprises, A key tenet of savings groups that also pro-
as African countries continue to develop their vide credit is that members must save before
formal financial sectors. they can obtain other services. This practice
As seen in figure F3.1, savers in Africa use screens out borrowers who are less likely to
formal financial services more than savers any- repay loans. Members in effect pledge their
where else in the world, especially in Africas savings deposit as partial collateral against
lower-middle-income countries, where the the loan. To ensure that members save, some
overwhelming majority of households no lon- groups employ a member or other person to
ger suffer from extreme poverty. The use of collect funds daily or weekly from members
informal savings mechanisms is more common at their homes (a susu collector). Informal

Box F3.5

ROSCAs, VSLAs, SHGs, and SACCOs: Examples of informal savings and credit systems
Rotating savings and credit associations (ROSCAs) form a cash box with multiple locks. The key holders are not part
when individuals agree to save together. They have evolved of the management committee. The group determines the
throughout the worldwitness West Africas tontines, services offered (savings, lending) and corresponding terms
Nepals dhikuti, and Indonesias arisan. Members meet regu- and conditions. At regular meetings, members purchase one
larly, and all deposit the same amount of money into a com- to five savings shares; the share price is determined by the
mon pot at every meeting. At each meeting, on a rotating group and remains unchanged throughout the year. These
basis, one member gets the whole pot. ROSCAs have advan- savings capitalize a loan fund for members, who can borrow
tages. They require no bookkeeping (an asset where liter- amounts not exceeding three times their savings. Loans are
acy is limited), everyone witnesses the transactions at every given to individuals or groups, for a term not exceeding the
meeting, and the sums involved are small. Their accessibility groups end point, at a monthly interest rate of 510 percent
and simplicity make ROSCAs an important source of finan- (though rates as low as 1 percent or as high as 20 percent
cial services even where specialized MFIs operate. ROSCAs are reported). Record keeping takes three forms: memoriza-
empower their members (the majority of whom are women) tion, passbooks that record only the ending fund balance,
and help to build social capital in communities. The struc- or central ledgers that track financial activity. When a cycle
ture can be useful in operating informal social protection ends, group members share the savings and corresponding
schemes as well, such as burial societies. Yet these associa- interest. Returns can range from 35 to 50 percent; after only
tions also have drawbacks. Members cannot always access a few years, a group might manage US$2,000US$10,000.
savings when they want them, and the timing of required Through small periodic contributions, groups may also main-
contributions and payouts may not match their cash flow tain a social fund available to the entire community. Mem-
needs. The approach favors people with steady incomes who bers may leave the group at any time, under terms decided
can contribute consistently. by the group. As a result, unlike ROSCAs, VSLAs intermedi-
Village savings and loan associations (VSLAs), also called ate funds between savers and investors within a group over
accumulating savings and credit associations (ASCAs), were a short period of time.
pioneered in the early 1990s by CARE International, which Aside from CARE, numerous organizations have pro-
developed a standard model for VSLAs based on Nigers ton- moted VSLAs, including Aga Khan Foundation, Catholic
tines. Generally 1525 individuals agree to join forces for sav- Relief Services, Oxfam/Freedom from Hunger, Pact-WORTH,
ing and borrowing during a fixed period (usually one year). PLAN, the United States Peace Corps, World Relief, and
The group elects a management committee and money World Vision. VSLAs have reached at least 61 countries
counters. No one else handles the money, which is stored in in Africa, Asia, and Latin America and have more than
(continued)
192 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

savings and credit groups limit banking costs limiting losses (little time passes before it is
through their own outreach, governance, and clear whether a member can honor an obliga-
accounting, and they can recruit staff locally tion). The loans are useful for covering lumpy
at relatively low salaries. For this reason, they household expenditures such as school fees or
can charge lower interest rates than MFIs. the expenses related to a festival, but they are
Larger groups with access to a local bank may not suited to an investment in a farm or in HE
opt to protect funds there at an affordable cost equipment, which may require a longer repay-
(account charges are shared across members, ment period. Everyone in the group pays the
along with any interest earned on the deposit). same interest on loanseven risky loans
These informal services have some disad- which appropriately biases risk downward.
vantages. Their local nature and structure limit Even the larger and more sophisticated savings
intermediation. They depend on members for and credit cooperatives (SACCOs) may strug-
funds and can lend only the money that is avail- gle with profitability, as their membership base
able in the group. The lending terms are short, may never be large enough for them to spread
rarely exceeding one year and usually lasting out the basic overhead costs of facilities, man-
only a few months. This brief time horizon has agement, and security and achieve lower unit
the benefit of allowing close supervision and costs than other financial institutions, espe-

Box F3.5

(continued)

6 million active participants. The organizations promoting they may belong to the same workplace, community, or
the savings groups train the members in group operation religious group). A volunteer board of directors is elected
and governance, but because these groups are essentially from among the membership; each member has one vote.
self-managed, the risk that funds may be lost through fraud, SACCOs finance their loan portfolios by pooling members
theft, or borrower default remains. Larger groups in or near voluntary savings rather than seeking outside capital. Ide-
urban areas may safeguard their funds in a bank, and CARE ally, members earn higher returns on savings, pay lower
is testing the use of mobile banking technology to store and interest on loans, and generally pay fewer fees. SACCOs
withdraw group funds in VSLAs in East Africa. local nature can prevent them from expanding and reducing
Self-help groups (SHGs) are small village groups of 1020 their unit costs, especially in rural areas. Their democratic
women who pool their savings over a few months until they nature requires members to balance borrowers preference
have sufficient capital to lend to group members or to oth- for low interest rates against the high returns sought by
ers in their village. SHGs link with banks and form federa- shareholders, who mainly save. Finally, because SACCOs
tions with other villages, allowing them to accumulate more operate far more like banks than cooperatives, their gover-
capital for lending. The interest is not distributed back to nance and regulation urgently demand attention. Although
members; it is left to grow. Used widely in India, SHGs have their assets form a very small share of the banking systems
potential in Africa, but efforts to establish them have had assets, SACCOs serve a very large (and relatively poor) pop-
mixed success. In India they rely on strong social dynam- ulation. A system to guarantee SACCOs probity, stability,
ics among women within villages and social connections and accountability may not necessarily be costly. It may suf-
between villages to catalyze federations. The social struc- fice to institute sound governance and internal controls to
tures in African villages are not as conducive to developing protect members deposits and limit SACCOs exposure to
strong womens groups, and women in Africa are less able risk, but much more research is needed to determine what
than women in India to devote the time required to attend works best.
meetings, in part because the lower density of settlement
requires them to travel longer distances. Sources: Allen and Panetta 2010; Bakiene et al. 2012; Collins et al.
2009; IFPRI and World Bank 2010, brief 3; VSL Associates, About Us:
Savings and credit cooperatives (SACCOs), or credit
VSL Model, http://www.vsla.net/aboutus/vslmodel; Rotating Savings
unions, are member owned, not-for-profit financial coop- and Credit Association, http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Rotating_Savings_
eratives providing savings, credit, remittances, and other and_Credit_Association; What Is a Credit Union? http://www.woccu.
services to members connected in some way (for example, org/about/creditunion.
Focus Note 3 193

cially in sparsely populated rural areas (5,000 district capitals, presumably in the hands of Group
clients is often considered a minimum efficient the officials there. Only the NGO-organized management of
size for MFIs). The agreed rates on loans are VSLAs effectively provided capital to HE own-
loans is very bad.
typically 3.03.5 percent a month for SAC- ers (Kweka and Fox 2011).
COs in Uganda, which may still exceed what An especially damaging practice is for gov- One lady in our
many smallholders and HE owners can afford ernments or NGOs to use an informal savings group borrowed
while still being able to profit from a loan for group to inject capital into the community. T Sh 500,000
an enterprise (Bakiene et al. 2012; Collins et al. Studies show that this practice reduces the and then ran
2009). groups incentives to build up their own savings away. I had
pool and places the sustainability of the initia-
borrowed only
The Role of Government: Increasing tive at risk. For this reason, NGOs seem better
suited than governments to the task of devel- T Sh 100,000.
Access and Protecting Consumers
Normally, informal finance exists outside the oping and supporting informal savings groups. How come the
scope of government regulation and support, one who had
but government, NGO, and donor programs The Role of Informal Financial borrowed
have supported the spread of SACCOs and Institutions: Expanding Financial T Sh 100,000
VSLAs through outreach, training, and the Inclusion had to pay for
formation of national SACCO member asso- VSLAs and SHGs both hold potential for
someone who
ciations. Program staff train group members including young people and addressing their
on procedures to keep the funds safe and limit capital constraints, particularly if the group had borrowed
the loss of funds through theft, fraud, or bad offers mentoring and access to information as T Sh 500,000?
loans, but according to all accounts, reliability well as finance. In Uganda, an innovative strat- Tanzania
remains a problem.6 egy is being developed to work through NGOs (US$1 =
To protect consumers, governments are to establish VSLAs and promote the inclusion T Sh 2,500)
looking for ways to supervise the larger groups, of young people. A donor (the International
such as SACCOs, but supervising a large num- Fund for Agricultural Development) will pro-
ber of small groups is rarely feasible.7 Gov- vide funds for the Ministry of Finance and Eco-
ernment involvement in SACCOs and VSLAs nomic Development to contract with NGOs to
can also backfire. Informal groups operate develop and nurture VSLAs. The proposed tar-
on trust, supported by a set of procedures to get is to establish 15,000 new VSLAs over five
ensure transparency. They keep costs down for years. At least 15 percent of the new members
their members because they operate efficiently are expected to be young people, either through
and do not have to spend time complying with the formation of youth savings groups or the
regulators requests for information. For larger incorporation of young people into VSLAs.
SACCOs, in which members find it more chal- Project funds will support the staff and materi-
lenging to exert proper supervision themselves als to train local groups; no funds will be pro-
and the sums involved are substantial enough vided as paid-in capital to the groups.8
to undermine the SACCO program, some sort In addition to providing informal financial
of public supervision may be justified. services, savings groups support their members
In general, however, governments should in the same way as lending circles in MFIs
keep their involvement in informal savings they provide encouragement and a forum for
groups to a minimum. The public tends to members to share experiences. Numerous
interpret government involvement in such descriptions of savings groups attest to the
programs as a signal that participants can exert importance of this feature (see box F3.6 for an
less financial discipline, which undermines example from Mali), which could be a valuable
the approach. In Tanzania, a qualitative study means for young people to learn from others
documented numerous cases in poor districts and build social capital (Banerjee and Duflo
where public funds intended to provide grants 2011; Nimusiima et al. 2012). As savings groups
or bring cheap credit to owners of HEs never spread to young people, group members are
materialized. Instead, the funds stayed in the approaching their NGO partners for additional
194 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box F3.6

Village women in Mali: Achieving food and financial security through savings and
credit groups
Saving for Change (SfC), a village savings and loan program located within the RCT zone in Sgou; four were outside the
initiated in rural Mali in 2005, places women firmly in charge RCT zone and had participated in SfC since 2005. In each
of their own financial inclusion. The women served by the village in 2009 and 2012, researchers spent two to three
program are largely illiterate, poor (mostly living on less days conducting focus group discussions, community inter-
than US$1 a day), and living in very isolated areas. By regu- views, and key informant interviews. In the villages familiar
larly saving small amounts and lending group funds short with SfC since 2005, these activities provided details on how
term to members with interest, each group of about 1525 community members had adapted the SfC model to meet
women accumulates and mobilizes capital without relying local conditions, needs, and livelihood strategies over time.
on matching or external funds. By July 2008, SfC had 95,000 The RCT found an overall increase in savings (by 31 per-
members; later that year, the program expanded into four cent), a greater flow of credit to women in SfC villages (12
of Malis five nondesert regions. By April 2013, SfC served percent more women reported borrowing from the savings
18,804 groups (423,654 members). A rigorous evaluation groups), the accumulation of assets (livestock holdings grew
of SfCs impact was conducted between 2009 and 2012 to in value by 13 percent in SfC villages), and a reduction in
document the programs contribution to household liveli- hunger during periods of food insecurity. Most women cited
hood strategies and savings and credit provision. a less tangible impactthe social capital generated through
A randomized controlled trial (RCT)the gold standard participation in a savings groupas one of the programs
for impact assessmentused detailed socioeconomic sur- most highly valued benefits. The groups included younger,
veys of 6,000 households in 500 villages in 2009 and 2012 less socially integrated women, although they joined slightly
to gather information from SfC participants and nonpar- later than the initial participants. Finally, the savings groups
ticipants in treatment and control villages. In the interim, had no measurable impact on business development or
researchers repeatedly surveyed a subset of 600 households expansion, perhaps because many groups are located in
from treatment and control villages on their financial trans- such remote areas.
actions, assets, income generating activities, consumption, SfC seems to have improved food and financial security
and health. The resulting information provided insights into in these isolated, food-insecure, and impoverished areas.
how households were evolving over the course of the study. The fact that some women surveyed in the control villages
To interpret and contextualize the RCT data, qualitative formed savings and credit groups on their own, without
research elicited detailed information from a small sample external advice from SfC, indicates that these groups offer
of 19 villages chosen to reflect some of the variationin perceived advantages and are well adapted to local needs.
geographic location, ethnicity, livelihood strategies, and
other variablesacross SfC sites. Fifteen of the villages were Source: BARA and IPA 2013.

services, including business education and life communities. Through such groups, national
skills training. Plan International, an NGO strategies for youth could combine programs
active in supporting youth savings groups in to foster savings behavior, build business and
West Africa, has been meeting these requests by soft skills, support female empowerment, and
contracting with local trainers to provide short expand financial inclusion, with the goal of
courses on demand. Based on this experience, enabling young people to pursue sustainable
they are developing a holistic training syllabus livelihoods.
for their youth savings groups. The content,
which is adapted to the needs and learning
preferences of young people, is designed to Notes
1. In these countries, a bank account is considered
support disadvantaged youths in the transition a contract; the minimum age to sign a contract
to adulthood and a sustainable livelihood.9 is 18, and no provision is made for an adult
Savings groups may be an effective venue cosigner.
to integrate the delivery of youth programs in
Focus Note 3 195

2. See the FINDEX website, http://go.worldbank. Dias, Denis, and Katherine McKee. 2010. Pro-
org/1F2V9ZK8C0. tecting Branchless Banking Consumers: Policy
3. Postal savings account systems were developed Objectives and Regulatory Options. CGAP
to get around this problem by making use of Focus Note 64, Consulting Group to Assist the
Poor, Washington, DC.
underused rural postal service staff, offices, and
security systems to bring savings accounts to Dupas, Pascaline, and Jonathan Robinson. 2009.
populations not served by traditional banking Savings Constraints and Microenterprise Devel-
opment: Evidence from a Field Experiment in
systems. Kenya. American Economic Journal: Applied Eco-
4. Gains are even higher when compared with nomicss 5 (1): 16392.
account charges at up-market commercial
Gardeva, Anita, and Elisabeth Rhyne. 2011.
banks. Opportunities and Obstacles to Financial Inclu-
5. CGAP blog, January 2012 (http://www.cgap.org/ sion: Survey Report. Publication 12, Center for
blog/looking-back-trends-branchless-banking- Financial Inclusion, Accion International, Wash-
2012). ington, DC.
6. See Collins et al. (2009), Karlan and Appel Glisovic, Jasmina, and Mayada El-Zoghbi, with
(2011), and Banerjee and Duflo (2011) for dis- Sarah Forster. 2011. Advancing Savings Services:
cussions on how and why this occurs. Resource Guide for Funders. Technical Guide,
7. This section draws on Glisovic and El-Zoghbi Consultative Group to Assist the Poor, Washing-
(2011). ton, DC.
8. Based on draft project document, November Gin, Xavier, and Dean Karlan. 2013. Group Ver-
2012 (see IFAD 2012). sus Individual Liability: Short- and Long-Term
9. See http://plan-international.org/what-we-do/ Evidence from Philippine Microcredit Lending
economic-security. Groups. World Bank, Washington, DC, June.
IFAD (International Fund for Agricultural Devel-
opment). 2012. Republic of Uganda: Project
References for Financial Inclusion in Rural Areas Detailed
Allen, Hugh, and David Panetta. 2010. Savings Design Report. Report 2772-UG, IFAD, Rome.
Groups: What Are They? SEEP Network, Wash- IFPRI (International Food Policy Research Insti-
ington, DC. tute) and World Bank. 2010. Innovations in
Bakiene, Amor, Louise Fox, Obert Pimhidzai, Rural and Agriculture Finance: Focus 18. IFPRI
and Elizabeth Mehta. 2012. How Non-Farm and World Bank, Washington, DC.
Enterprises Create Jobs for the Middle Class in Karlan, Dean, and Jacob Appel. 2011. More Than
Uganda and How Policies Can Raise Productiv- Good Intentions: How a New Economics Is Help-
ity and Reduce Risk. Policy Research Working ing to Solve Global Poverty. New York: Dutton.
Paper, World Bank, Washington, DC. Kilara, Tanaya, and Alexia Latortue. 2012. Emerg-
Banerjee, Abhijit V., and Esther Duflo. 2011. Poor ing Perspectives on Youth Savings. CGAP Focus
Economics: A Radical Rethinking of the Way to Note 82, Consultative Group to Assist the Poor,
Fight Global Poverty. New York: Public Affairs. Washington, DC.
BARA (Bureau of Applied Research in Anthro- King, Michael. 2012. Is Mobile Banking Breaking
pology) and IPA (Innovations for Poverty the Tyranny of Distance to Bank Infrastructure?
Action). 2013. Final Impact Evaluation of the Evidence from Kenya. IIIS Discussion Paper 412,
Saving for Change Program in Mali, 2009 Institute of International Integration Studies,
2012. Oxfam America. http://www.oxfam Trinity College, Dublin.
america.org/issues/community-finance/files/ Kweka Josephat, and Louise Fox. 2011. The House-
final-impact-evaluation-saving-for-change. hold Enterprise Sector in Tanzania: Why It Mat-
ters and Who Cares. Policy Research Working
Blycroft Ltd. 2012. African Mobile Factbook.
Paper 5882, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Africa and Middle East Telecom-Week. http://
blog.bearing-consulting.com/wp-content/ Lauer, Kate, and Michael Tarazi. 2012. Supervising
uploads/2012/10/Africa.Mobile.Fact_.Book_ Nonbank E-Money Issuers. CGAP Brief (July),
.2012.pdf. Consultative Group to Assist the Poor, Washing-
ton, DC.
Collins, Daryl, Jonathan Morduch, Stuart Ruther-
ford, and Orlanda Ruthven. 2009. Portfolios of McKay, Claudia, and Mark Pickens. 2010. Branch-
the Poor: How the Worlds Poor Live on $2 a Day. less Banking 2010: Whos Served? At What Price?
Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Whats Next? CGAP Focus Note 66, Consulta-
tive Group to Assist the Poor, Washington, DC.
196 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

MIX (Microfinance Information Exchange). 2008. Riquet, Corinne, and Djibril Maguette Mbenge.
MFI Benchmark Data | Microbanking Bulletin 17 2013. Deepening Financial Inclusion in West
(August). http://www.themix.org/publications/ Africa. CGAP blog post, Consultative Group to
microbanking-bulletin/2008/08/mfi-benchmark- Assist the Poor, January 25, http://www.cgap.org/
data-microbanking-bulletin-august-2008-issu. blog/deepening-financial-inclusion-west-africa.
Mullainathan, Sendhil, and Eldar Shafir. 2011. Sav- USAID (United States Agency for International
ings Policy and Decision-Making in Low-Income Development). 2009. Youth Savings Account:
Households. In Insufficient Funds: Savings, A Financial Service Perspective; a Literature and
Assets, Credit, and Banking among Low-Income Program Review. MicroREPORT 163, USAID,
Households, edited by Michael Barr and Rebecca Washington, DC.
Blank, 12146. New York: Russell Sage Founda- World Bank. 2011. Module 7: Broadening Small-
tion Press. holders Access to Financial Services through
Nimusiima, Catherine, Fiona Nshemerirwe, ICTs. In ICT in Agriculture: Connecting Small-
Helen Nyamweu, and Skye Dobson, eds. 2012. holders to Knowledge, Networks, and Institutions.
10 Years of Owegatta: A History of the National Washington, DC: World Bank.
Slum Dwellers Federation of Uganda (NSDFU) . 2013. Global Financial Development Report
Narrated by Members. Kampala: Act Together 2014: Financial Inclusion. Washington, DC:
Uganda. World Bank.
Chapter

Raising Productivity in Africas Modern


Wage Enterprises to Foster Job Growth
for Youth

Although small (around 16 percent of the labor Governments in Africa can do much to rem-
force), the wage employment sector represents edy this situation. The most important step is to
Africas engine for employment and growth in the improve the business climate through key reforms
medium to long term, especially given the sectors to improve access to finance and infrastructure
potential to exploit economies of scale and pro- services, improve trade logistics, and ease regu-
duce for export. Yet wage employment is growing latory constraints to entrepreneurship. Many
unevenly across Africa. Modern manufacturing reforms are not so expensive in monetary terms
firms, in particular, account for only 3 percent of and can deliver huge impacts in the short run by
employment and export very little. This limited reducing distortions and increasing efficiency.
competitiveness in export markets is mainly the Selective and spatially targeted support to emerg-
result of low productivity in the modern wage ing clusters can promote agglomeration econo-
sector. It signals the presence of government and mies. For young people to be truly productive in
market failures, which vary across the subcon- modern firms, governments should foster a strong
tinent but have similar effects. Complementary foundation in basic skills by improving the qual-
inputs to labor (electricity, overland transport, ity of general education. In the training sector,
and so on) are costly, regulations strangle business governments should focus on public goods such
processes and the movement of goods, the high as quality assurance and information to foster a
costs of financial intermediation starve investors sector that is efficient and relevant to the market
of capital, and the small domestic markets and for skills. Programs for disadvantaged youth that
trade barriers suppress competition and reduce integrate training with internships show promise,
pressure to innovate and improve productivity. as do programs offering managerial training.

197
198 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Alongside employment in household farms Africas Modern Enterprise Sector:


and firms, discussed in the previous two An Overview
chapters, employment in modern enterprises
is becoming increasingly important to Afri- Modern nonfarm wage employment is growing
can youth. If history is any guide, this trend across Africa, but inconsistently. With the excep-
will only continue. As European and North tion of some countriesnotably Mauritius and
American countries developed, jobs in modern South Africanonfarm enterprises account for
enterprises gradually replaced other kinds of under 20 percent of the wage employment in
jobs, even in agriculture. In developed coun- Africa (figure 6.1, panel a). Despite reductions
tries today, the modern wage sector domi- in public sector employment, the private mod-
nates employment. In East Asia and China, the ern wage sector still provides less than 10 per-
growth of jobs in modern firms is following a cent of employment in most African countries
similar pattern. (figure 6.1, panel b). Even by the standards of
The modern wage sector, as defined in this Asian and Latin American countries with com-
report, includes small, medium, and large firms parable levels of per capita income, employ-
that continuously employ five or more work- ment in Africas modern nonfarm enterprises
ers. It also includes the public sector. Histori- is low, and it is extremely low in comparison
cally wage employment grew as jobs in public with larger emerging economies such as Brazil,
services and public manufacturing enterprises China, and Indonesia.
expanded, but no more. As governments have The expansion of employment in modern
sought to curb inefficiency and improve com- wage enterprises has been quite inconsistent
petitiveness, they have rolled back employment across Africa. Labor force surveys reveal that
in the public sectorin some cases drastically, while the modern wage sector has absorbed a
as in Ethiopia and Ghana in the 1990swhich growing share of the labor force in Madagas-
has reduced the share of public sector employ- car, Mali, Tanzania, and Uganda, its share in
ees among wage and salary earners. For young total employment has changed little in Ethio-
people seeking wage employment, a public sec- pia, Kenya, and Zambia and has declined in
tor job may be more elusive than ever. Instead, other countries, such as Malawi and Senegal
the primary challenge is to sustain high rates (figure 6.2).
of investment and job creation in the private Africas young people seem to have no spe-
sector, where productivity and competitiveness cial advantage when it comes to modern wage
really matter. employment (box 6.1). Although the current
This chapter closely examines employment generation has more education than its prede-
in modern enterprises in manufacturing, ser- cessors, employers seem to value the experience
vices, and other nonfarm sectors such as con- brought by older workers.
struction because they have the greatest poten- Service jobs, both with and without a for-
tial to drive productivity and employment in mal contract, dominate wage employment in
the medium to long term, as Africas young Africa.1 The single largest share of formal wage
workforce grows. Unlike household farms and employment in services consists of jobs in edu-
firms, modern enterprises in these sectors are cation, health, and other social services (largely
not limited by family size, so they can expand in the public sector). The next largest share
to exploit economies of scale, and they are far consists of jobs in commerce (retail and whole-
more likely to adopt the new technologies that sale) and transportation (figure 6.3, panel a).
permit them to do so. Because modern firms Outside the service sector, manufacturing
can impel higher productivity and create jobs, and construction each account for about 10
policy makers are understandably concerned percent of wage jobs. Almost half of all man-
with their development. But as shown in the ufacturing employment in modern firms is
discussion that follows, the circumstances must found within industries broadly classified as
be right for entrepreneurship and productive food and textiles (including leather and leather
firms to grow. goods) (figure 6.3, panel b). Some countries,
Raising Productivity in Africas Modern Wage Enterprises to Foster Job Growth for Youth 199

such as Cameroon and Rwanda, have sig- Figure 6.1 Africa has less nonfarm wage employment than other regions
nificant employment in the wood-processing a. Private and public sector wage employment
industry. Employment in high-tech industries, 70
such as machinery and electronics, is quite lim-
ited, although employment in the chemicals, 60
LSO CPV
plastic, glass, and paper industries is important EGY

Share wage/employment (%)


MNG
50 PHL LKA GTM
in some countries.
IDN
NIC BOL
40
COM MRT
Modern Manufacturing Delivers 30
VNM
IND
Little Employment, Few Exports MDG KEN
SEND GHA COG
KHM BGD
20 NGA
LBR ZMB
Despite their considerable untapped potential TCD
RWA
10 BEN LAO
for employment growth, modern manufactur-
ETH BFA
ing enterprises currently account for less than
0
3 percent of total employment in Africa, which 0 500 1,000 1,500 2,000 2,500 3,000 3,500 4,000
is a good deal lower than in other regions of the
GDP per capita 2010 (current US$)
world (figure 6.4). The ratio of manufacturing
wage employment to total employment varies
b. Private sector wage employment
significantly from one country in Africa to the 70
next (and it is declining in some countries), but
there is no indication that Africa as a whole is 60
Share private wage/employment (%)

catching up with its comparators. MNG


50
The concern is not just that the manufac- IDN
turing sector is so small, but that manufactur- 40
LSO
PHL GTM
ing firms export so little of what they produce. NIC
BOL
LKA CPV
The percentage of African manufacturing firms 30 EGY
exporting is among the lowest in the world; the BGD
MRT
IND
share of African manufacturing output sold 20 KHM VNM
COM
RWA
domestically is among the highest (figure 6.5). LBR TCD LAO
COG
10 NGA
The poor performance of Africas manufac- BEN ZMB
turing sector is especially worrying because 0
ETH BFA
trade-oriented manufacturing may offer the 0 500 1,000 1,500 2,000 2,500 3,000 3,500 4,000
best chance of quickly creating modern wage GDP per capita 2010 (current US$)
jobs. African economies are small, so develop-
Sub-Saharan countries Non-Sub-Saharan countries
ing an export-oriented sector is more impor-
tant to them than to developing countries in Source: Based on household and labor force surveys.

other regions like South Asia, where domestic


markets are generally much larger (Dinh et al.
2012). Small markets curb productivity and Given the potential significance of trade to
growth in employment by limiting the poten- Africa and the fact that manufactured goods
tial scale economies that industries can achieve. are inherently more tradable than most ser-
Because a small domestic market can support vices, the analysis in this chapter focuses more
only a limited number of firms, the result- on manufacturing than on services. The reason
ing lack of competitive pressure puts a brake for this approach is not that manufacturing is
on investment and growth.2 In the absence of the only alternative for creating productive
trade, small economies are also less likely to modern wage jobs in Africa. It is not. Services
benefit from agglomeration economies, simply represent an increasingly important share of
because manufacturing clusters are much less global trade, and Africa can certainly pursue
likely to emerge (Collier and Venables 2008). this means of expanding wage employment.
200 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Figure 6.2 Wage employment is growing A final consideration is that manufactur-


inconsistently across Africa ing has been the subject of more research than
other sources of wage employment in Africa.
1994
Mali More and better data are available for the
2003 analysis, and the resulting policy lessons can be
1994 applied to firms in other sectors.
Burkina Faso
2003

2000
Tanzania How Competitive Is Modern
2006
Manufacturing in Africa?
1999
Ethiopia
2005 Traditional thinking on international trade
1996 contends that the relative abundance of pro-
Mozambique duction factors like labor, capital, and natural
2008
resources in a given country strongly deter-
1993
Madagascar mines which of its economic activities are
2001
internationally competitive. Given that Africa
2002 has rich natural resources but relatively poor
Uganda
2005 human capital, Africa is thought to have a
1998 comparative advantage in producing pri-
Zambia mary commodities for export rather than
2003
manufactured goods for export (Wood and
1997
Malawi Berge 1997; Wood and Mayer 2001). More
2005
recent thinking suggests that factor endow-
1997 ments alone do not determine trade and that
Kenya
2005 Africa could potentially become competitive
1995 in manufacturing.
Senegal First, aside from labor, capital, and natu-
2005
ral resources, good infrastructure and pub-
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45
lic services also contribute to competitive-
Share wage/total employment,
ages 1564 (%) ness. Utilities like electricity and water affect
how much a firm can produce from a given
Source: Based on household and labor force surveys.
amount of labor, capital, and raw materials.
Transport costs influence the competitiveness
Productivity growth in nontraded sectors of a countrys exports by affecting the cost of
can also create wage jobs, as demonstrated by sending the output to export markets and
recent growth in Africas construction sector. the cost of importing inputs. Manufactur-
But as East Asias rapidly growing economies ing, with its relatively complex supply chains,
suggest, trade-oriented manufacturing may relies more heavily on infrastructure services
offer the greatest potential to create wage jobs. than agriculture and extractive industries.
Equally important is the positive feedback Conceivably, investment in infrastructure
from manufacturing to other domestic sectors. could give rise to an internationally competi-
A growing manufacturing sector that is driven tive manufacturing sector regardless of factor
by tradeand hence not limited by the size of endowments.
the domestic economywill expand domestic Second, newer trade theories suggest that
demand for other industries (including services comparative advantage can be acquired over
and construction) by raising incomes. Manu- time, though not necessarily in a predictable
facturing firms will also demand a range of way. For instance, an industrial cluster can
intermediate goods and services as inputs from sometimes become internationally competi-
domestic suppliers. tive over time because of agglomeration econ-
Raising Productivity in Africas Modern Wage Enterprises to Foster Job Growth for Youth 201

Box 6.1

Where do young people figure in Africas wage employment picture?


At present, in a cross-section of African countries, the ratio Figure B6.1.1 The share of youth in wage employment
of wage employment to total employment among youth is tracks the share in the general population
remarkably similar to the ratio in the general population (see
figure B6.1.1). The implication is that firms have no special 100

proclivity to hire youth. Youth employment in modern enter-

Share of wage employment for population


90
prises simply grows in proportion to the growth of modern
80
enterprisesno more, no less.
At the same time, this figure may not tell the whole story. 70

ages 1534 (%)


It may be possible to enhance the impact of growth in wage 60
enterprises on youth employment. Evidence presented in
50
chapter 1 indicates that many individuals move into wage
employment only when they are 30 years and older, which 40
could reflect a preference for experienced workers. Policies 30
that facilitate young peoples transition to wage employ-
ment, such as programs to support on-the-job training 20
through internships or informational interventions to con- 10
nect youths to firms needing their skills, might enable more
0
young people to fulfill their aspirations for wage employ-
0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100
ment sooner rather than later. The scope for pursuing such
Share of wage employment for population
policies and evidence of their effectiveness are discussed
ages 1564 (%)
toward the end of this chapter.
45 degree line

Source: Based on household and labor force surveys.

Figure 6.3 Services form the largest share of nonfarm wage employment; within manufacturing, the food and textile industries dominate

a. By subsector b. Within manufacturing

Electricity and utilities Construction Machinery, electronics Other


Manufacturing Commerce
Transportation, Metals
storage, and
Other services communications
Food
Financial, Chemicals, plastic,
insurance, and glass, and paper
real estate

Alcohol and tobacco


Defense, law, Education, health, and Clothing, shoes,
and order social services Carpentry and wood and textiles

Source: Based on standardized and harmonized household and labor force surveys (see appendix).

omies. An agglomeration economy can arise suppliers reduces input costs for the exporting
when many input suppliers locate in industrial industry. Knowledge spillovers across firms
clusters, and the resulting competition between located near each other constitute another
202 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Figure 6.4 Africas modern wage manufacturing sector continues to have a small share in employment

a. Africa b. Other regions

1994 1999
Mali India
2003 2009
1994
Burkina Faso 2000
2003 Bolivia
2008
2000
Tanzania 2000
2006 Peru
2010
1999
Ethiopia
2005
2005 Philippines
1996 2010
Mozambique
2008 2000
Guatemala
2002 2006
Uganda
2005 2001
Nicaragua
1998 2005
Zambia
2003 2002
Colombia
1997
Kenya 2010
2005
2001
1993 Brazil
Madagascar 2009
2001
2000
1997 Sri Lanka
Malawi 2008
2005
1995 2005
Senegal Bangladesh
2005 2010

0 3 6 9 12 15 0 3 6 9 12 15
Share of employment (%) Share of employment (%)
Source: Based on household and labor force surveys.

potential agglomeration economy (Fujita, Thus comparative advantage in extractive


Krugman, and Venables 1999). The develop- industries alone is not an inevitable outcome
ment of Indias high-tech information technol- of Africas resource endowments. The question
ogy clusters is a case in point. then becomes whether other sectors, particu-
Third, productivity at the firm level is now larly manufacturing, can become internation-
seen as a key determinant of international ally competitive.
trade patterns. Firms in the same industry but
located in different countries can both export,
provided they are productive by international Unit Labor Costs as a Measure of
standards and can profitably charge competi- Manufacturing Competitiveness
tive prices.3 Firms within the same industry One measure of Africas manufacturing com-
can also vary significantly in their level of pro- petitiveness is how much an industry has to pay
ductivity. The implication is that, aside from workers for producing each unit of output. The
resource endowments and factors that broadly specific measure used here is unit labor costs
influence comparative advantage across sec- wages divided by labor productivity (output
tors, there are other factors, perhaps equally per worker)which are a more comprehen-
important, that determine competitiveness at sive measure of competitiveness than labor
the firm level. productivity or wages alone. Lower unit labor
Raising Productivity in Africas Modern Wage Enterprises to Foster Job Growth for Youth 203

Figure 6.5 African firms export relatively little costs indicate a higher degree of competitive-
ness (although unit labor costs have potential
Middle East and limitations as a single indicator of competitive-
North Africa
ness; see box 6.2).
Sub-Saharan Chinas experience illustrates how growth
Africa
in manufacturing depends on maintaining
South Asia international competitiveness. Between 1980
and 2007, Chinas manufacturing workforce
East Asia
and Pacific
grew threefold, from 24 million to 72 mil-
lion (figure 6.6, panel b). For a long time,
World the exceptional performance of Chinas man-
ufacturing industries benefited from Chinas
Latin America
and the Caribbean low wages relative to the rest of the world
Europe and
including Africa. As employment started
Central Asia to expand, so did wage rates, which qua-
High-income drupled between the early 1980s and 2007.
OECD countries But even as China was losing its labor cost
0 20 40 60 80 100
advantage, its labor productivity grew at a
Percent
rate that compensated for this cost increase,
Firms exporting directly or indirectly
leaving unit labor costs virtually unchanged.
(at least 1% of sales) As shown in figure 6.6 (panel b), Chinas
Proportion of total sales that are unit labor costs remained below those of
domestic sales other emerging economies throughout that
Source: Based on World Bank enterprise surveys. period.

Box 6.2

Measurement issues and other limitations of unit labor costs


Unit labor costslabor costs per worker divided by labor atively weak in Africa, then its competitiveness will be over-
productivity or real (physical) output per workerhave some estimated by revenue-based measures of labor productivity.
limitations as a measure of competitiveness. For instance, the To account for price effects, revenue or value added
unit labor costs in a shirt-making firm are its wages divided per worker is deflated by an aggregate industry-level price
by the number of shirts produced per worker. However, the index. Although this practice adjusts for changes in prices
analysis in this chapter approximates labor productivity by over time, it does not adjust for differences in price mark-ups
value added per worker, where value added is revenue minus across firms in the same industry. Nor does it adjust for dif-
the cost of raw materials. This is standard practice when ferences in mark-ups across countries.
measuring labor productivity, and it is largely unavoidable, Another limitation of unit labor costs is that a firms com-
given that physical output is difficult to measure and to com- petitiveness depends on total costs per unit of output, not
pare or aggregate across firms producing different goods. just on labor costs. If the costs of other indirect inputs
Revenue and value added depend on both physical out- (such as water and electricity) are similar across the coun-
put and prices. Using revenue and value added instead of tries being compared, then labor costs per unit of output are
physical output can artificially inflate the measurement of what really matter. Evidence that African firms pay relatively
productivity when firms charge higher prices than they would more for indirect inputs than firms in other developing coun-
be able to charge in perfectly competitive markets (that is, a tries suggests, however, that unit labor costs overstate the
price mark-up). To the extent that high value added reflects competitiveness of African firms compared to firms in other
a firms ability to charge high prices because of low market developing countries.
competition, it will overstate that firms competitiveness in
international markets. If domestic market competition is rel- Sources: Clarke 2011; Eifert, Gelb, and Ramachandran 2008.
204 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Figure 6.6 Chinas unit labor costs have remained below those of other emerging economies

a. Unit labor costs (3-year averages) b. Employment

198486
China China
200507

199597
Brazil Brazil
200507

199193
India India
200406

198789
Korea, Rep. Korea, Rep.
200608

0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8


Unit labor cost Manufacturing (workers, millions)
1990 2007
Source: UNIDO statistics.

Manufacturing Is Not Competitive in from West and East Africa; and countries with
Most African Countries large and small populations. Data for this sam-
Comparing trends in manufacturing employ- ple are compared to data for emerging econo-
ment and unit labor costs across Africa and mies, particularly China.
emerging economies can help to determine Growth in manufacturing employment
whether African countries are competitive or since 1990 has been inconsistent in these Afri-
on their way to becoming competitive. The can countries (figure 6.7). Ethiopia and Kenya
comparison with China is especially impor- saw significant growth. Although small relative
tant, because China maintains the lowest unit to total employment, manufacturing employ-
labor costs among large emerging econo- ment in Ethiopia increased from 82,000 in
mies and has a large export presence in most 1990 to 135,000 in 2007; over the same period,
industries. Potential large competitors such as manufacturing employment in Kenya grew
India seem to be reaching for similarly low from 188,000 to 256,000. Cameroon, Ghana,
unit labor costs. Because Chinas market pen- and Malawi also experienced growth, though
etration is so widespread, even African firms to a lesser extent. In contrast, Malawi, Senegal,
considering exporting to nearby markets and Tanzania saw relatively little change in the
must maintain competitiveness with China. size of the manufacturing workforce.
Seen through this lens, the manufacturing Figure 6.8 depicts unit labor costs across the
sector in most African countries is not com- sample of African countries and three impor-
petitive, although some countries may have tant emerging economies (Brazil, China, and
reached competitive levels of unit labor costs. India). As with manufacturing employment,
As labor costs rise elsewhere in the world trends in unit labor costs are mixed in Africa,
especially in Chinathey may create an suggesting that some countries could become
opening for African manufacturing. competitive.
The countries selected for review are reason- Based on the limited data available, Ghana
ably representative of Sub-Saharan Africa. They appears to have unit labor costs that are com-
include low-income (Ethiopia, Kenya, Malawi, parable to those in Brazil, China, and India.
and Tanzania) and middle-income (Cameroon, Ghanas level of unit labor costs is consis-
Ghana, and Senegal) countries; resource-rich tent with its growing level of manufacturing
(Cameroon and Ghana) countries; countries employment. Ethiopia too has low unit labor
Raising Productivity in Africas Modern Wage Enterprises to Foster Job Growth for Youth 205

Figure 6.7 Growth in manufacturing wage Figure 6.8 Based on unit labor costs, some African
employment has been inconsistent across African countries could become competitive with other
countries emerging economies

1990 199193
Cameroon Cameroon
2007 200709
1990 199193
Ethiopia Ethiopia
2007 200507
1990 198082
Ghana Ghana
2007 2003
1990 199193
Kenya Kenya
2007 200002
1990 199193
Malawi Malawi
2007 200709
1990 199193
Senegal Senegal
2007 200002
1990 199193
Tanzania Tanzania
2007 200507

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 0 0.1 0.2 0.3 0.4 0.5 0.6


Manufacturing (workers, thousands) Unit labor cost
Source: UNIDO statistics. China India Brazil
Source: UNIDO statistics.
Note: The vertical lines show current unit labor costs in China,
India, and Brazil.
costs, and the years in which manufacturing
rapidly created jobs in Ethiopia coincided with
a sharp decline in unit labor costs. In recent Other approaches to measuring competi-
years, Ethiopia and Ghana have maintained tiveness consistently suggest that Africa is less
unit labor costs almost on par with historical competitive than other developing regions.
levels in China and well below levels in other For example, in the World Economic Forums
major emerging-market economies, including Global Competitiveness Index, which defines
Brazil and India. competitiveness as the set of institutions,
Consistent with their disappointing growth policies, and factors that determine the level
in manufacturing employment, Senegal and of productivity of a country, African coun-
Tanzania have higher unit labor costs compared tries clearly rank the lowest among developing
to the large emerging economies. Tanzanian countries (World Economic Forum 2012). In
unit labor costs have declined in recent years, the World Banks Doing Business index, which
but they are not yet lower than those in Brazil, focuses largely on the regulatory environment,
China, or India. Senegals unit labor costs have Sub-Saharan Africa ranks the lowest as well
remained high for a long time. (World Bank 2012b).
The association between unit labor costs
and employment trends has some exceptions. Is manufacturing creating jobs in some
Unlike Ethiopia and Ghana, Kenya has seen sig- countries?
nificant growth in manufacturing employment Growth in total manufacturing employment
despite having higher unit labor costs than the has been disappointing in Malawi, Senegal,
large emerging economies. Similarly, manufac- and Tanzania, but their wood-processing
turing employment has grown in Cameroon industries (excluding furniture) have created
and Malawi, even though their unit labor costs jobs. In Malawi, the furniture industry and
have been relatively high in recent years. the rubber and plastics industry have also
206 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

created jobs. This information suggests that Figure 6.9 Africa does not have a uniform wage
industry-specific factors, and not just national advantage over other developing regions
determinants, also matter for manufacturing
growth.
Latin America and
Some industries have done well in several the Caribbean
countries, while others have fared poorly. The
number of jobs in the food, beverage, and Europe and
Central Asia
wood-processing industries (and to a lesser
extent the rubber and plastics industry) has
grown substantially in Cameroon, Ethiopia, East Asia
and Pacific
Ghana, and Kenya. The rubber and plastics
industry has generated jobs in Cameroon,
Sub-Saharan
Ethiopia, Ghana, Kenya, and Malawi. In con- Africa
trast, the textile and leather industries have
been shedding modern wage jobs in almost Middle East and
every country analyzed for this report, except North Africa

for Ethiopia (leather and leather goods) and


Kenya (textiles). South Asia
These findings do not imply that certain
industries are destined to do well regardless of 0 2,000 4,000 6,000 8,000 10,000
the country context. For instance, although the Median labor cost (US$)
furniture industry has recently created thou- Small firms Medium firms Large firms
sands of new jobs in Ethiopia, Ghana, Kenya,
and Malawi, it has contracted steadily over the Source: Based on World Bank enterprise surveys.
Note: The figure shows median labor costs (per full-time
past two decades in Cameroon, Senegal, and employee per year in constant U.S. dollars) across firms. Costs
Tanzania. are based on surveys conducted in selected countries during
200810.
Instead, these findings indicate that indus-
tries do well when they are competitive. With
some exceptions, employment trends in a given costs in small and medium-size firms are
industry tend to mirror trends in its unit labor slightly lower than in East Asia and the Pacific,
costs. For instance, the textile industry in Africa they are similar to those in South Asia. Median
has higher unit labor costs than its counterparts labor costs in large firms in Africa are higher
in China and India, and it is losing jobs. Simi- even than those in East Asia and the Pacific,
larly, the leather industry has high unit labor which is significant because large firms tend
costs in most African countries examined here, to be the leading exporters in export-oriented
except for Ethiopia. In contrast, unit labor costs industries.
in the food-processing industry, which has cre- Some African countries have a wage advan-
ated thousands of jobs in several African coun- tage over China and India, but it is more than
tries in recent years, compare favorably with offset by low labor productivity. Even though
those in emerging economies like China and wages have been rising faster in China and
India. India than anywhere in Africa over the past
two decades, Africa is not closing the unit labor
Low Wages Are Not Enough: cost gap with them, because labor productivity
Productivity Is the Linchpin of has not been rising as fast in Africa as in China
Competitiveness for Africa and India.
Can African countries become competitive If Africa cannot compete with large emerg-
on the basis of low labor costs alone? It seems ing economies like China or India, could it
unlikely. African countries do not have a uni- compete with smaller developing countries
form wage advantage over other developing on the strength of low wages? Again, it seems
regions (figure 6.9). Although median labor unlikely. Wages are not lower in African coun-
Raising Productivity in Africas Modern Wage Enterprises to Foster Job Growth for Youth 207

Box 6.3

Does Africa really have a labor cost advantage?


As labor costs in manufacturing continue to rise in China, a age indicators of labor market regulation do not differ sig-
common observation is that other developing countries with nificantly between African countries and the comparators.
lower labor costs will be poised to compete with China (Lin Another explanation is that prices are generally higher in
and Monga 2011). Wages are expected to be lower in coun- African countries. This explanation is supported by a com-
tries with significantly lower per capita incomes than China, parison of price levels, so it is possible that firms in Africa
including African countries. Recent research using firm-level have to pay relatively high wages to compensate workers for
data seems to contradict that view, however, suggesting that the relatively high cost of living.
industrial labor costs in Africa are far higher than might be In turn, the high cost of living could result from the domi-
expected solely on the basis of gross domestic product (GDP) nance of resource-based industries in Africa. High prices are
per capita (Gelb, Meyer, and Ramachandran 2013). Labor a typical feature of resource-abundant countries, because
costs per worker are nearly 80 percent higher in firms in Afri- the high income from resources raises the price of nontraded
can countries than in firms in other countries at the same goods, including labor. These interactions are often cited
level of GDP per capita. to explain why resource-rich countries tend to perform so
These findings are partly explained by an enclave effect: poorly when they rely on export-led growth alone (Sachs and
compared with countries at the same income levels in other Warner 2001).
regions, African countries have an enclave of manufacturing Larger firms, in particular, pay higher wages in African
firms that have high labor productivity and pay high wages. countries. Research based on matched employer-employee
But even after adjusting for this effect, African firms face data from 10 African countries suggests that larger firms pay
nearly 50 percent higher labor costs. higher wages partly because labor management is especially
Higher labor costs could be explained by labor market problematic in Africa, which has a much higher supervisor to
factors such as regulation and unionization, but on aver- worker ratio than elsewhere (Fafchamps and Soderbom 2006).

tries than in other developing countries with World Banks enterprise surveys.4 To avoid
similar levels of per capita income. The exact complications arising from technological dif-
reasons for this difference are unknown, ferences across industries, the analysis focuses
although some plausible hypotheses have been on the textile industry, which is generally ori-
put forward (box 6.3). Given the difficulty of ented toward exports and therefore more com-
lowering wages in dollar terms, the inescap- parable across countries than domestically
able conclusion is that labor productivity is oriented industries.
the linchpin of competitiveness in Africa. This The firm-level data show that labor produc-
conclusion is particularly relevant for resource- tivity is particularly low in Africa, especially in
rich countries, where wages are driven up by the regions low-income countries.5 Figure 6.10
the high cost of living. illustrates this point by showing sales per
worker, a measure of labor productivity, in the
textile industry. For example, the annual turn-
Sources of Productivity Gaps in over per employee in Tanzanias textile indus-
African Manufacturing try is just US$9,000, compared to US$25,000 in
Malaysias garment industry.
To understand how African manufacturing can Labor productivity is low in Africas low-
become internationally competitive, it is neces- income countries partly because workers are
sary to pry labor productivity open and exam- not as well equipped with fixed capital (that
ine its component parts. This section examines is, plant and machinery) as their counter-
components of labor productivity in a group parts elsewhere in the world, such as China,
of developing countries, including many from Malaysia, Mexico, and Thailand (figure 6.11).
Africa, using firm-level data collected by the The typical textile manufacturer in China, for
208 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Figure 6.10 Labor productivity is particularly low in Figure 6.11 African workers are not as well equipped
low-income African countries with fixed capital as their counterparts elsewhere in
the world
Sales per worker in the textile industry Fixed assets per worker in the textile industry

South Africa Namibia


China Mexico
Malaysia
Kenya China
Brazil South Africa
Mexico Malaysia
Thailand
Botswana
Colombia
Morocco Thailand
Swaziland Swaziland
Mauritania Zambia
Zambia
Tanzania
Botswana
Tanzania Morocco
Angola Mauritania
Namibia Colombia
Guinea
Nigeria
Uganda
Nigeria Burundi
Congo, Dem. Rep. Gambia, The
Rwanda Congo, Dem. Rep.
Guinea-Bissau
Gambia, The Rwanda
Burundi Guinea

0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 0 2 4 6 8 10 12 14 16
2000 US$ (thousands) 2000 US$ (thousands)

Source: World Bank enterprise surveys, 200208. Source: World Bank enterprise surveys, 200208.

example, equips every worker with twice as where. The difference in fixed capital between
much plant and equipment as a manufacturer firms from Africa and those from other parts
in Tanzania. of the world is not as great as the difference
Why does African manufacturing use so lit- in output (figure 6.11). For instance, the dif-
tle capital per worker? A major reason for low ference in fixed assets between Tanzanian and
capital intensity in Africa is that African firms Chinese textile firms is significantly lower than
do not have access to the same supply of capi- the difference in output. Namibian textile firms
tal as their counterparts in China.6 Although produce significantly lower output per worker
access to international capital is particularly than their Chinese counterparts but have simi-
important to African manufacturing (given lar levels of fixed assets.
low per capita incomes), studies of interna- Even with the same level of plant and
tional capital flows suggest that Africa and machinery, it is possible that workers in one
other developing regions have limited access to country cannot produce as much as those in
international capital markets (see, for example, another. A range of factors other than plant and
Kalemli-Ozcan, Alfaro, and Volosovych 2008).7 machinery affect labor productivity. Some of
Imperfections in Africas domestic credit mar- these factors are internal to a given firm, such as
kets, discussed later, are also likely to be wors- the quality of management. Others are external,
ening their access to capital. such as the quality of infrastructure. In general,
A low level of fixed capital can only partly these other factors are less concrete than plant
explain why output per worker is so much and machinery and difficult to quantify. To
lower in most African countries than else- distinguish them from machinery and other
Raising Productivity in Africas Modern Wage Enterprises to Foster Job Growth for Youth 209

Figure 6.12 African countries have lower productivity than other regions

a. Textiles b. All manufacturing and service industries

Brazil Brazil
Malaysia Thailand
Colombia Malaysia
China Chile
Mexico South Africa
Thailand Morocco
Morocco China
South Africa Mexico
Tanzania Colombia
Zambia
Angola
Tanzania
Kenya
Guinea
Botswana
Kenya
Zambia
Uganda
Congo, Dem. Rep.
Nigeria
Swaziland Namibia
Nigeria Angola
Guinea Gambia, The
Uganda Burundi
Rwanda Swaziland
Gambia, The Rwanda
Burundi Botswana
Namibia Congo, Dem. Rep.
Guinea-Bissau Guinea-Bissau

0 1 2 3 4 0 1 2 3 4
2000 US$ (thousands)
Source: Based on World Bank enterprise surveys, 200208.

concrete inputs, these factors are often lumped What Determines Productivity at the
together under the term productivity (as Firm Level?
opposed to labor productivity).8 Although productivity is often equated with
Since the individual components of pro- production technology, it should be inter-
ductivity cannot be measured directly, their preted more broadly. The quality of a firms
net effect is simply inferred as that part of total management and its organizational efficiency
output which cannot be explained by the level (which includes elements such as the quality
of measured inputs such as labor, plant, and of factory floor and workplace organization,
machinery. Estimated as this residual, produc- workforce incentive and supervision structures,
tivity is known to account for a large part of the and supply chain management) also contrib-
difference in output per worker across coun- ute to productivity. Productivity is influenced
tries (Hall and Jones 1999). by elements of a firms human and knowledge
When accounting for the difference in labor capital, which cannot be captured in data on
productivity between African and Chinese the formal qualifications of its workforce. For
firms, productivity is found to be responsible example, firm-specific skills generated by on-
for a larger share of the gap than fixed assets. As the-job learning and training for the workforce
figure 6.12 shows, the shortfall in productivity can make employees more productive. Knowl-
in Tanzanias textile industry relative to Chinas edge and tacit technology, such as a more effi-
is slightly larger than its shortfall in fixed assets. cient production process developed through
This productivity gap between African and internal research and development (R&D), are
Chinese firms persists throughout a range of other firm-level components of productivity,
manufacturing industries and services (figure as are computerized processes and databases
6.12, panel b). tailored to a firms needs. Firms often become
210 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

more productive by adapting a technology to parts of the world (Hao and Hulten 2011; Dutz
their contextwhether through trial and error et al. 2012).
or a more formal R&D processand such A firms productivity is also affected by fac-
adaptation also raises productivity. tors external to the firm, such as the quality and
Understanding how much these specific reliability of transport and logistics systems
factors matter to productivity is very relevant and the supply of utilities, including power,
for policy.9 Some studies attempt to unpack telecommunications, and water services.10 Poor
productivity by examining how much firms transportation infrastructure can reduce the
spendd on acquiring specific types of human, efficiency of production by making the supply
knowledge, or organizational capital (Corrado, of raw materials less reliable. Similarly, an inad-
Hulten, and Sichel 2005; OECD 2010). For equate and unreliable utility supply can inter-
instance, a new production process could be rupt production and force workers to remain
the result of R&D expenditures incurred over idle. In effect, it increases the amount of labor
many years. While the quality of the new pro- and capital needed to produce a given level of
duction process itself is difficult to quantify, it output.
is likely to be reflected in the R&D expenditure Poor infrastructure also reduces productiv-
incurred to develop the process. In developed ity by forcing firms to adopt inefficient and
countries, such spending on human, knowl- costly coping mechanisms. Firms may have
edge, or organizational capital is at least as high to compensate for the poor quality of public
as spending on plant and machinery. It is not services on their own; they might purchase
as high in the two emerging economies where generators as back-ups for the public electric-
attempts have been made to measure it (Bra- ity supply, for example. A recent study shows
zil and China), but it is still quite sizable and that costs related to infrastructure services
rising. These differences suggest that variation account for a relatively high share of firms
in firms human, knowledge, and organiza- costs in poor African countries, thus impos-
tional capital could account for a large part of ing an extra burden on the competitiveness of
the productivity gap between Africa and other African firms (Eifert, Gelb, and Ramachandran
2008). Figure 6.13 shows firm-level indicators
Figure 6.13 Africa fares poorly in firm-reported indicators of transport, water, and of the quality of transport, water, and electric-
electricity supply
ity supply in different parts of the world. Along
with South Asia, the Middle East, and North
Proportion of products lost to Africa, Sub-Saharan Africa is generally near the
breakage or spoilage during
shipping to domestic markets bottom of the rankings.

Number of water insufficiencies


How Unproductive Firms Survive and
in a typical month Hurt Industry-Level Competitiveness
One way to raise an industrys competitive-
ness is to make all of its firms more produc-
Losses due to electrical outages
(annual sales) tive. Another way is to let competition between
firms run its course and ensure that only the
most productive firms thrive. The latter is sig-
Number of electrical outages nifgicant because differences in productivity
in a typical month
across firms in the same industry can be sur-
prisingly large, especially in developing coun-
0 5 10 15 20
tries (Syverson 2011; Banerjee and Duflo 2005).
Percent
According to one study on China and India, if
Sub-Saharan Africa South Asia
Middle East and North Africa Latin America and the Caribbean
manufacturing plants are ranked according to
High-income OECD countries Europe and Central Asia their productivity, those near the top of the
East Asia and Pacific rankings produce about five times more with
Source: Based on World Bank enterprise surveys. the same amount of labor and capital as those
Raising Productivity in Africas Modern Wage Enterprises to Foster Job Growth for Youth 211

Figure 6.14 Decomposing textile industry productivity

a. Average firm total factor productivity b. Efficiency of firms


Brazil China
Thailand Malaysia
Colombia Brazil
Malaysia Colombia
Mexico Mexico
Morocco Morocco
South Africa Burundi
China Tanzania
Angola Botswana
Kenya South Africa
Guinea Thailand
Zambia Nigeria
Tanzania Congo, Dem. Rep.
Congo, Dem. Rep. Swaziland
Rwanda Uganda
Swaziland Zambia
Nigeria Kenya
Botswana Angola
Gambia, The Namibia
Uganda Guinea-Bissau
Namibia Guinea
Guinea-Bissau Gambia, The
Burundi Rwanda

0 1 2 3 0.5 0 0.5 1 1.5 2


2000 US$ (thousands) log Index of allocative efficiency

Source: Based on World Bank enterprise surveys, 200208.

near the bottom (see, for example, Hsieh and ference between countries can be decomposed
Klenow 2009). A reallocation of workers from into these two components.12
the least to the most productive firm in an How much of Africas lower productivity
industry would thus raise the productivity of is due to the lower productivity of the typical
the industry fivefold. firm, and how much is due to the fact that less
Indeed, an increase in competition in an productive firms are more likely to survive and
industry is often seen to result in such realloca- maintain outsized market shares? Figure 6.14
tion, or shifting, of labor and other inputs from illustrates these components of productivity
less to more productive firms. Conversely, mar- for the textile industry in a sample of countries,
ket distortions that reduce competition tend including some in Africa. This case is typical of
to protect the market share of less productive most manufacturing and service sectors, and it
firms, which in turn reduces the (aggregate) shows that the greater survival and abnormally
productivity of the industry. large share of unproductive firms (allocative
The productivity of an industry is the sum inefficiency) in Africa explain a large part of
total of the productivity of firms in it. Thus an the productivity gap between African econo-
industry could be more productive in Country mies and emerging economies such as Brazil
A than in Country B for two reasons. The first and China.
is that, relative to Country A, the typical firm in For example, about one-third of the produc-
Country B may be less productive.11 The sec- tivity gap between the textile industries in Tan-
ond is that, compared to Country A, less pro- zania and China is explained by the fact that the
ductive firms may control a larger share of the average Chinese textile firm is more productive
market in Country B. The net productivity dif- than its Tanzanian counterpart. The other two-
212 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

thirds of the gap is explained by the fact that in Figure 6.15 Trading across borders is expensive and
Tanzania, unlike China, unproductive firms have slow in Africa
captured too much market share. A comparison
of South Africa and China illustrates the sig- Ethiopia
nificance of this allocative efficiency even more
strongly. The average productivity of South Afri- Tanzania
can textile firms is actually higher than that of
their Chinese counterparts, but this advantage Zambia
is completely overturned by the dominance of
unproductive firms within South Africa. Sub-Saharan Africa

Potentially, several market distortions could


China
explain why unproductive firms are more likely
to survive and maintain inefficiently large mar- High-income
ket shares in Africa. Credit market inefficiency OECD countries
is a case in point. In the short run, a work- 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50
ing capital constraint can prevent a relatively Time to export Cost to export (per
productive firm from producing as much as it (days) container, in 100 US$)
profitably could.13 Credit constraints can also Source: World Bank Doing Business indicators, 2012.
prevent a productive young firm from invest-
ing in fixed capital and growing to its optimal
size. Larger, older incumbents may have easier It costs 60 percent more to ship to the United
access to credit, even if they are less productive. States from Djibouti than from China and about
Similarly, political favoritismsuch as prefer- the same to ship to Europe, despite the much
ential access to land or other inputs granted to greater distance from China. The costs of inland
politically connected firmscan enable unpro- transportation from the factory to ports are also
ductive firms to capture a large market share. high. A World Bank study estimates that higher
Regulations can also affect allocative effi- shipping and inland transportation costs add a
ciency. For example, labor market regulations 2.5 percent production cost penalty for textiles
can prevent the allocation of labor to its most in Ethiopia and Zambia (Dinh et al. 2012).
productive uses by hampering the movement Export competitiveness is also affected by
of labor across firms.14 port and terminal handling fees, customs clear-
Entry barriers (such as high costs or onerous ance and technical control fees, costs of docu-
procedures for establishing a new enterprise) ment preparation and letters of credit, and the
can also enable unproductive firms to sustain cost of foreign exchange. These additional trade
large market shares by preventing competition costs are exceptionally high in Africa, adding a
from entrants who could be more productive. 5.5 percent production cost penalty for textiles
A reduction in entry barriers can reallocate in Ethiopia and Zambia, for example.
resources away from unproductive incumbents
and toward more productive entrants (Chari
2011). Making African Firms Competitive:
Priorities for Improving the Business
From the Factory to the Market: Climate and Workforce Skills
How Poor Trade Logistics Hurt Africas
Competitiveness Making modern enterprises more competitive
When it is costly to transport goods from the by increasing their productivity is critical for
factory to international markets, an otherwise creating more modern wage jobs that are acces-
productive industry can become uncompeti- sible to Africas youth. Increasing productivity
tive in those markets. Africa does poorly on involves a complex set of reforms and interven-
this dimension of competitiveness (figure 6.15). tions. The most important measures include
Raising Productivity in Africas Modern Wage Enterprises to Foster Job Growth for Youth 213

broad interventions that foster improvement in of survey respondents regarded macroeco-


the business environment by ensuring macro- nomic instability as a major obstacle to business
economic and political stability, strengthening growth, compared to 80 percent of respondents
infrastructure services, reducing trade barri- surveyed in 2003 (World Bank 2009). These
ers, and improving access to finance and more encouraging conditions deteriorated in the
localized interventions that promote competi- wake of the 2008 global recession, demonstrat-
tive industrial clusters. Such measures must be ing that the structure of the Zambian economy
complemented by steps to improve the human (like the economies of other resource-rich
capital of young people, making them more countries in the region) is especially vulnera-
employable and productive. ble to the forces of macroeconomic instability.
Because the range of potential reforms and Maintaining price and exchange stability and
interventions is so large, this section identifies bringing government borrowing under control
the priority areas. Actions within each area are over the long term are critical to the smooth
classified according to whether they are easier functioning of finance and business investment
to implement but have a lower impact (typi- in such countries.
cally those that seek to correct a market failure)
or are much harder to implement but have a Strengthening Infrastructure Services
higher impact (typically those that correct a The poor quality and inadequacy of physi-
government failure). cal infrastructure in Africa is the most visible
aspect of a deep, pervasive infrastructure prob-
Providing a Stable Macroeconomic lem that inhibits the competitiveness of African
Framework firms. The more reassuring aspect of this prob-
Macroeconomic uncertainty and volatility, lem is that governments can begin to address it
such as fluctuations in the cost of borrowing without building new infrastructure. Evidence
abroad and changes in inflation and exchange points to government failure as the main source
rates, disrupt lending and investment. The of Africas infrastructure problem, reflected,
volatility of key macroeconomic indicators is for example, in the underpricing of electricity
quite pronounced in Africa, because primary and water or the monopoly power of trucking
commodities constitute such a large share companies. There is also evidence that infra-
of exports and because government finances structure policies and regulations block firms
depend so greatly on trade in those commodi- access to infrastructure services and undermine
ties. Macroeconomic shocks appear to disrupt the incentives for further investment (Briceo-
credit flows more frequently, with greater force, Garmendia and Foster 2010).
in African countries than in countries where
production is more diversified. Dealing with electricity and other public utility
When the World Bank assessed Zambias shortages. In countries with chronic shortages
business environment in 2003, it found that in infrastructure services, established businesses
firms faced an extremely high cost of borrow- report that frequent outages cause significant
ing, which appeared to be strongly related to losses of revenue. Such shortages particularly
high rates of inflation and currency volatility at affect smaller, younger firms and manufactur-
that time (World Bank 2004). When the Bank ing firms. Start-ups can wait months to be con-
revisited the country with a second assessment nected to the public utility grid, a delay that is
in 2007, the situation was radically different. A likely to reduce firm formation and business
large debt relief program and a copper price entry rates.
boom had dramatically reduced government As electricity shortages have become
borrowing and helped to stabilize the currency. increasingly common, governments have
Real interest rates had dropped sharply, and as sought to promote long-term solutions in
the inflation rate fell to single digits, business the form of large investments in maintenance
lending expanded. In 2007, less than 15 percent and in additional generating and transmission
214 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

capacity. Such solutions ignore opportunities way networks. But immediate measures to pro-
for quicker wins through steps to address the mote more efficient use of the infrastructure
causes of underinvestment and inefficiency that already exists can also help. Nor is govern-
in the power sector. These include the delib- ment investment the only option for build-
erate underpricing of electricity to subsidize ing new networks. Private participation can
household consumption, the failure of poorly be expanded if policy reforms create the right
managed state-owned operators to collect pay- conditions. Mozambique, where high transport
ments, and the absence of a workable legal and costs originate with inefficient railway and port
regulatory framework for private investment. services, is both rehabilitating and expanding
The specific measures needed to resolve the network as a long-term solution. At the
the problem depend on which of these causes same time, it is enacting a series of structural
is most prevalent in a given country. Regula- reforms to improve operations and encourage
tory agencies could revise power tariffs. State- private participation in the management of
owned power companies could be privatized state-owned transport operators. Improving
or reorganized on a more commercial footing rail services is the key to cutting transport costs
to improve payment collection and minimize in Lesotho, where the chronically dysfunc-
transmission and distribution losses. Countries tional rail sector has caused exporters to rely
are often advised to reorganize the industry by exclusively on road transport, which costs three
separating power generation, transmission, times as much as rail.
and distribution into independent opera-
tions conducted by independent enterprises. Reducing Barriers to Trade: Trade
Cross-border and regional initiatives to supply Liberalization, Costs, and Logistics
power are often encouraged because they entail When the domestic market for manufacturing
economies of scale. Initiatives could range from and service industries is fragmented or isolated
cross-border pooling of power based on exist- from regional and global markets, it is hard
ing power grid connectivity among neighbor- for productivity to grow in those industries.15
ing countries to establishing a regional market Such conditions insulate incumbent firms from
in electricity as a component of an integrated competition (domestic or foreign), reduce the
regional energy market, as planned in Southern entry of potentially more productive firms, and
Africa. limit incumbents incentives to innovate.
A central argument for trade liberaliza-
Improving transport infrastructure. Inade- tion is that it increases the competitive pres-
quate and costly transport infrastructure is by sure on domestic firms and encourages them
far the most important factor in Africas excep- to become more productive. The liberalization
tionally high trade costs, the fragmentation of of import tariffs by most African countries in
the domestic market for manufacturing and the 1990s and early 2000s may have consti-
service industries, and the regions isolation tuted one of the most significant policy devel-
from other regional and global markets. Inad- opments in Africas recent economic history.
equate transport infrastructure is a powerful Although there are no systematic assessments
drag on productivity and economic growth, of their impact in the region, anecdotes and
manifested in many ways (the port of Dar es studies of the effects of similar reforms in other
Salaam is one manifestation; see box 6.4). regions suggest that in Africa they could have
Problems with transport infrastructure not led to substantial and widespread productiv-
only limit scale economies but also bestow ity gains by exposing local producers to greater
market power on firms already in the trade by competitive pressure and reshaping the struc-
removing the threat of foreign competition ture of domestic production.
and preventing potentially more productive Recent studies of other developing regions
firms from entering local markets. and developed economies report that trade lib-
Ultimately, the solution to high transport eralization reforms of the kind that took place
costs is large-scale investment in road and rail- in Africa lowered domestic prices and mark-up
Raising Productivity in Africas Modern Wage Enterprises to Foster Job Growth for Youth 215

rates, increasing competitive pressures on the gain market share from unproductive firms, by
large players in the domestic economy. Those encouraging innovation and the adoption of
studies also provide evidence that increased better techniques of production, and by facilitat-
openness to trade generates productivity gains ing economies of scale (see, for instance, Melitz
in three distinct but complementary ways: by and Trefler 2012; Krishna and Mitra 1998).
allowing more productive firms to take fuller Another, newer argument for import lib-
advantage of their superior productivity and eralization originates in the increasing frag-

Box 6.4

The high price of inefficiency at the port of Dar es Salaam


The Dar es Salaam PortEast Africas second-largest port US$0.39 to US$5.00 (the global price is US$0.60US$0.80),
after Mombasais the conduit for about 90 percent of and the ratio between the highest and lowest reported cus-
Tanzanian trade, and it is also a gateway for Tanzanias land- toms values is 152 for rice and 33 for palm oil.
locked neighbors, including Burundi, the Democratic Republic Storage tariffs are structured in ways that discour-
of Congo, Rwanda, Uganda, and Zambia. For Tanzania espe- age rapid clearance of merchandise from inland container
cially, manufacturing, trade, and economic expansion depend depots. After the free storage period of seven days expires,
on the efficient movement of goods through the port. each additional day represents a direct additional profit for
The main agencies involved in the ports operations are TPA, TICTS, and the container depots. TPAs revenues are
the Tanzania Port Authority (TPA), the landlord and service higher when TICTS is less efficient. When berths managed
provider; Tanzania International Container Services (TICTS), by TICTS are full, some of the container traffic is redirected
a private container stevedoring contractor; and the Surface to TPA berths, creating a situation in which the landlord of
and Marine Transport Authority (SUMATRA), the multisec- the port (TPA) competes against its own service provider
toral regulatory agency. (TICTS). TPA obtained an estimated US$36.5 million in this
The port is not efficient by international or East African manner in 2011.
standards. In mid-2012, container vessels waited an aver- Such arrangements reduce incentives among port opera-
age of ten days for a berth in Dar es Salaam, compared to tors to invest in increased capacity. While a small, well-
less than one day in Mombasa. Merchandise took ten days connected coterie benefits from the status quo, Tanzanian
on average to clear and exit the port, compared to three to workers, firms, consumers, and the government bear the
four days in Mombasa (and 48 hours in many East Asian costs. An uncompetitive manufacturing sector creates fewer
ports). Official and unofficial fees are numerous, high, and jobs for workers and produces more expensive goods for
inconsistently applied. The additional costs incurred by ship- consumers. Tanzanian agriculture suffers because port ineffi-
pers and shipping companies in Dar es Salaam compared to ciency adds an estimated 5.2 percent to the cost of imported
Mombasa are equivalent to an additional tariff of 22 percent fertilizer. Policy makers may well ask whether making a single
on container imports and 5 percent on bulk imports. Com- large investment to improve efficiency at the port would be
pared to the port of Mombasa, inefficiencies at the port of better than continuing to subsidize fertilizer year after year.
Dar es Salaam cost Tanzania and its neighbors an estimated The cost of inaction is mounting. The port of Dar es
US$2.5 billion a year. Reforms have been initiated but have Salaam will decline in importance as ports and railways in
progressed very slowly. neighboring countries become operational and prove more
Merchandise fails to clear the port rapidly because pro- efficient. The authorities have been moving to improve port
cesses (especially customs clearance) are slow and storage operations, yet more pointed reform is needed, beyond
periods are quite long. The rules are not transparent and actions to improve infrastructure (such as building new
oversight is poor, creating opportunities for corruption. berths). Efficiency-enhancing reforms would ensure that
In Dar es Salaam, where the port charges fees in propor- end users are aware of the costs related to the ports inef-
tion to the value of the merchandise, official port fees are ficiency and participate in decisions related to port reform,
74 percent higher than those in Mombasa, where the port strengthen competition among port operators, and reduce
charges flat fees. Customs valuations of goods imported via corruption through streamlined and transparent procedures
Dar es Salaam also vary more widely than can be explained and improved oversight.
by normal variations in quality and price. For example, the
stated customs values for 1 kilogram of fertilizer ranges from Source: World Bank 2013b.
216 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

mentation of export value chains. The differ- significantly reduce trade costs. Many coun-
ent stages involved in producing a particular tries could considerably reduce trade costs by
final good are now often performed in many simplifying customs clearance and import pro-
different countries, and a country can special- cedures and increasing the use of inland clear-
ize in specific tasks in this value chain. For an ance facilities to shorten processing times.
African firm to succeed in exporting a manu- Land border crossings remain a major
facturing task, it must be able to import all the obstacle to regional integration in Africa. These
complementary upstream tasks as easily as any obstacles are common along the gateway corri-
international competitor that specialize in the dors serving the landlocked countries, and they
same task (Collier and Venables 2007). Import also hinder regional trade and international
liberalization and other measures to improve transit. Aside from improvements in transport
access to imported inputs can help African infrastructure, improved management of bor-
firms to insert themselves in international value der crossing through institutional reform and
chains. increasing border coordination could also have
Has Africa experienced benefits similar to a major impact on border-crossing times. East
those attributed to tariff reductions in other Africas one-stop border post (OSBP) initiative
regions? Lower tariff barriers should have is a step in this direction. A pilot OSBP between
made African firms more productive by open- Kenya and Uganda seems to have produced
ing them up to competition and enabling their dramatic results even in the absence of infra-
integration within global value chains. Africas structure refurbishment (see box 6.5; Fitzmau-
experience with the Multifiber Agreement sug- rice and Hartmann 2013).
gests that such outcomes did not occur. During
the final years of the Multifiber Agreement, the Improving Access to Finance
United States imposed strict import quotas on The lack of finance is another serious con-
Chinese apparel and awarded duty- and quota- straint on the growth of manufacturing and
free access to African apparel. If African firms tradable services in Africa (World Bank 2008,
were truly competitive, they should have taken 2012c; IFC 2013; see also Dinh, Mavridis, and
advantage of such preferential access to the U.S. Nguyen 2012; Harrison, Lin, and Xu 2013; Li,
market. African apparel exports did rise, but Mengistae, and Xu 2011). Firm surveys suggest
the rise was temporary and has been attributed that the cause is poor access to formal bank
to Chinese firms that shifted their final assem- financing (figure 6.16). A survey comparing
bly steps to Africa to avoid the quota (Rotunno, firms in China to firms in Ethiopia, Tanzania,
Vzina, and Wang 2012). and Zambia found that the most visible advan-
The productivity benefits of tariff liberal- tage enjoyed by Chinese firms was access to
ization may have failed to materialize in Africa bank finance at favorable conditions, such as
because the costs of trade remain extremely low interest rates and low collateral require-
high for reasons unrelated to tariffs, such as ments (Fafchamps and Quinn 2012). Expen-
the regions onerous transport costs. Reducing sive or limited financing suppresses growth
such costs could enable African firms to real- in productivity by forcing firms to operate at
ize the gains of trade liberalization (Djankov, a suboptimal size or to use substandard tech-
Freund, and Pham 2010). nologies. Research suggests that many firms
Freight costs are often the largest compo- cannot take advantage of profitable opportu-
nent of trade costs in most countries, imply- nities for expansion because they cannot obtain
ing that investment in transport infrastructure financing.16
and ports could significantly ease constraints to Access to finance varies by type of economic
regional and global trade. Such investment is activity and is generally more constrained for
expensive and will take time. In the short run, smaller and younger firms. In Namibia, for
tackling nontariff barriers such as inefficient example, banks require small firms (employ-
customs administration and high regulatory ing fewer than 30 workers) to provide twice
costs of cross-border transactions would also the amount of collateral on average as mid-size
Raising Productivity in Africas Modern Wage Enterprises to Foster Job Growth for Youth 217

Box 6.5

Improving land transportation through increased international cooperation and


comprehensive procedural reforms: The Malaba border-crossing pilot
The long-standing response to the chronically slow move- was included in a border-crossing survey commissioned by
ment of goods within Africa has been to build better roads the northern corridor authority.
and border facilities, but better physical infrastructure alone The survey found that the border crossing at Malaba
has not solved the problem. Twenty-five years ago, only 20 improved dramatically after the reforms. The average time
percent of Africas main road network was considered to be to cross the border dropped from 24 to 4 hours. The SSATP
in good condition. Today, almost half of it is considered study estimated that the reforms may have saved up to
good. Border facilities have been remodeled. But a lot of US$70 million a year. Notably, these results occurred in the
time is still lost at the border, largely due to procedural delays absence of infrastructure refurbishment, which is expected
at border crossings. to take place at a later stage. What was so special about the
A more recent approach to resolving border delays is Malaba border-crossing reforms?
the development of one-stop border posts. OSBPs include The primary insight from this case is that simply chang-
more than refurbished facilities; they involve improved coor- ing the procedures is probably not sufficient to improve bor-
dination between border agencies from neighboring coun- der crossings. Before launching the reforms, the authorities
tries and better coordination among the domestic agencies undertook significant preparatory work to build a culture of
managing aspects of transport and border crossings in each cooperation across border agencies (within and between
country. Interagency coordination is challenging to achieve, the two countries), develop a legal framework enabling that
however, and many OSBPs have not met expectations. cooperation to take place, and install the information tech-
The Transit and Transport Coordination Authority of the nology infrastructure making it possible to start the docu-
Northern Corridor has been trying to improve OSBPs in East mentation process even before trucks arrive at the crossing.
Africa by gathering better data on their performance. The Unlike many other OSBPs, at the Malaba OSBP the
authority is supported by the Sub-Saharan Africa Transport reforms targeted all of the key parties involved in border
Policy Program (SSATP), an international partnership for pol- crossings:
icy reform and capacity building in Africas transport sectors.
Border management agencies, through advance prepara-
Their efforts include border-crossing surveys to gain insight
tion with prearrival lodgment of the customs declaration
into the reasons for slow border processing and to docu-
and better coordination between agencies at the crossing
ment the impact of reforms.
Clearing agents, through mandatory prearrival lodgment
During 201112, customs authorities in Kenya and
of declarations (which used to be optional and rarely used)
Uganda modified selected business procedures related to
Truck drivers, through traffic and parking rules to ease
border crossings. They had a unique opportunity to observe
congestion in the customs zone
the impact of those reforms, because the Malaba border
post between Kenya and Uganda (one of the pilot OSBPs) Source: Fitzmaurice and Hartmann 2013.

firms (World Bank 2010; Barker and Men- banks, the high fixed costs per transaction and
gistae 2013). This differential access implies difficulty in attaining scale economies make it
that smaller and younger firms are less likely costlier to lend to smaller firms. As bank man-
to exploit potentially profitable opportunities agers observed in a survey in Rwanda, the poor
than larger and older firms. To the extent that quality of financial statements and business
younger firms are a source of innovation and plans, lack of business skills, inability to man-
productivity growth, such restrictions pose a age risks, and informality of smaller enterprises
particular threat to competitiveness. constitute a big challenge for lenders (World
To some degree, however, the problems Bank 2012c). These observations suggest that
that smaller and less established firms encoun- the problem could be remedied partly by
ter in obtaining credit may reflect the higher improving the management and transparency
costs and risks involved in lending to them. For of firms.
218 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Figure 6.16 African firms use relatively little bank The banking sector should be opened up
financing with care, however, as the system can become
more vulnerable when more banks enter and
World begin to compete. For instance, banks may
take on too much risk in more competitive
East Asia
and Pacific
environments. It is also hard to open up the
financial system to competition if the supervi-
Europe and
Central Asia sory structure is poor. Reforms to improve the
High-income institutions that support the financial sector,
OECD countries described next, are more feasible.
Latin America and
the Caribbean
Strengthening Credit Information
Middle East and Systems
North Africa
Well-developed credit information systems
South Asia have improved access to finance in advanced
economies. One reason why collateral require-
Sub-Saharan Africa ments or interest charges are so high in some
developing economies is that banks have little
0 5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 information on prospective clients, so they
Percentage set high risk premiums. Credit information
Firms using banks to Investments systems that permit banks to share customer
finance investments financed by banks
repayment information can help lenders to
Source: Based on World Bank enterprise surveys.
evaluate prospective customers and bankable
projects (IFC 2013). Most countries in Africa
have no credit information system at all. Where
Even if lending to smaller or younger firms is
credit information systems exist, they tend to
inherently more difficult, basic policy reforms
be rudimentary, with low coverage of potential
to address credit market issues will help them.
borrowers (figure 6.17).
Indeed, reforms will be particularly helpful to
Countries seeking to establish strong credit
smaller and less established firms, because they
information systems require new regulations
are the most disadvantaged by credit market
for the licensing, operation, and supervision of
imperfections. Critical reforms include steps to
credit bureaus. Kenyas credit information sys-
make the banking industry more competitive,
tem, for instance, significantly improved after
the development of credit information systems,
2008, when new regulations were approved
and better creditor rights.
on the licensing, operation, and supervision
of credit bureaus by Kenyas central bank.17 By
Making the Banking Industry More
Competitive
The banking sector in much of Africa is charac- Figure 6.17 Coverage of credit bureaus is generally
terized by a lack of competition (it is dominated low in Africa
by a few large banks) and heavy government
involvement (IFC 2013; Bertrand, Schoar, and Kenya
Thesmar 2007). Measures that would facili- Nigeria
tate new domestic and foreign entry into the
industry could increase competition, make the Rwanda

lending industry more efficient, and increase South Africa


the likelihood that banks will find better ways
Tanzania
of reaching out to firms. Where government
ownership of banking assets is extensive, as in 0 10 20 30 40 50 60
Tanzania, fostering competition may require a % of population
reduction in the governments financial stake. Source: World Bank Doing Business indicators.
Raising Productivity in Africas Modern Wage Enterprises to Foster Job Growth for Youth 219

2010 and 2011, respectively, the first two credit passed in 2009 (World Bank 2012c). Angola,
bureaus had started to operate. The new leg- Botswana, and Swaziland have among the low-
islation allowed banks to share negative credit est global scores on the World Banks Doing
information by obligating banks to report all of Business indicators of contract enforcement,
the nonperforming loans on their books. especially the length of time required to enforce
To be truly effective, credit information a standard contract (World Bank 2011b).
systems must cover not only all potential bor- Banks reliance on real estate and land as
rowers but also all prospective lenders, and prime collateral can further complicate the
they must include both positive and nega- efforts of smaller enterprises to obtain financ-
tive information on borrowers. The scope of ing. Banks typically do not use other assets,
credit information systems is commonly much especially movable assets, as collateral for sev-
more limited in Africa, however. In Zambia, eral reasons. Contract enforcement is weak,
for instance, the credit reference bureau that the registration of assets is poor, and the legal
opened in 2007 has yet to expand its sources to framework for creditor rights does not ade-
retailers, trade creditors, and utility companies quately support secured transactions in assets.
in order to capture a larger share of the popula- Potential reforms include the introduction of
tion of potential borrowers (World Bank 2009). electronic property registration and land titling
Similarly, in a survey following the regulatory systems, along with the adoption of a more
reform in Kenya, the two most prominent con- modern framework of security interests over
cerns highlighted by the banks were the need to movable assets. Such a framework would allow
share positive as well as negative information banks to register security interests over a wide
and the need to incorporate the information range of movable assetsincluding personal
collected by other providers, such as microfi- property, vehicles, machinery, inventory, raw
nance institutions and utility companies. The materials, receivables, and intellectual prop-
sharing of positive data enables the develop- ertyand to enforce claims on those assets as
ment of a credit-scoring system, allowing good collateral.
borrowers to establish a track record and access
loans at more favorable interest rates. Reducing Constraints to the Entry
and Growth of Productive Firms:
Strengthening Contract Enforcement Governance Is Key
and Creditor Rights Institutions A good business environment should facilitate
Legal rights of lenders and borrowers can the entry of new firms and the growth of more
facilitate the use of collateral and the ability to productive firms. Unproductive firms are pres-
enforce claims in the event of default. Strong sured either to improve their productivity or to
creditor rights can expand the supply of loans exit, and overall productivity improves.
by providing legal protection for lenders in Credit constraints, poor start-up financing,
cases of nonpayment. The legal system should and high costs of access to public utilities are
also allow borrowers to use a broader range of major barriers to firm entry and expansion
assets as collateral, which should allow them to in Africa. Another critical influence on firm
obtain loans on better terms. These legal rights entry and growth is the quality of governance.
must also be enforced well in practice. Some Excessive or poorly designed business regula-
of the high risk premiums that banks attach tion, corruption, and weak contract enforce-
to borrowers in Africa reflect their low confi- ment impose high entry and expansion costs,
dence in creditor rights and their enforcement. which reduce productivity through their nega-
Contract enforcement institutions are particu- tive effects on entry and competition (Klapper,
larly weak in most countries in the region, even Laeven, and Rajan 2006; Djankov 2009; see also
upper-middle-income countries. For example, Xu 2011).
banks in Rwanda contend that insolvency and Formal entry requirements are probably the
bankruptcy procedures do not function well most ubiquitous means by which governments
in practice, despite the new legal framework directly regulate entry. Almost everywhere in
220 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Figure 6.18 Africa has the highest formal costs of setting up a business The formal cost of setting up the standard busi-
ness (as a percentage of per capita income) is
Paid-in 105 percent in Angola and 284 percent in the
minimum Democratic Republic of Congo, for example.
capital
These costs are high by international standards,
even compared to South Africa, where the same
Cost of
starting a
cost is a mere 0.3 percent of per capita income.
business Corruption in the granting of entry licenses
and other permits also hinders the setup and
Cost of expansion of firms, and it must be tackled to
getting a strengthen competitive forces in Africa. Sur-
construction
permit vey evidence from Uganda on who has to pay
0 100 200 300 400 500 600 700 800 bribes and how much they have to pay suggests
that more profitable firms have to pay larger
% of income per capita
bribes when seeking access to permits, licenses,
Sub-Saharan Africa South Asia High-income OECD countries
Middle East and North Africa Latin America and the Caribbean East Asia and Pacific and public services. By raising costs dispropor-
Europe and Central Asia tionately for more productive firms, corruption
Source: World Bank Doing Business indicators, 2012. acts as a tax on efficiency. This same research
Note: Paid-in minimum capital is the amount that the entrepreneur needs to deposit in a bank or with suggests that if firms have better informa-
a notary before registration and for up to three months following incorporation.
tion and undertake collective action, they can
improve their bargaining position when deal-
ing with bribe takers and reduce corruption
Africa, anyone setting up a new business needs (box 6.6).
to obtain an operating license from a local and Better governance can also help by strength-
central government authority and to acquire ening contract enforcement. Poor contract
legal status to engage in certain transactions enforcement can constrain the growth of pro-
from the government registrar. Often, various ductive firms by making trust more important
construction permits and site use licenses are than efficiency in determining how production
required to establish or expand a firm. Usually is organized. Owners and top management shy
the time and costs associated with all of these away from delegating responsibility to other
permits and licenses are a substantial share of employees (see, for instance, Cingano and
the overall cost of setting up a business, and
they can be prohibitive (World Bank 2011b).
On average, the formal costs of setting up a Figure 6.19 Business setup costs are higher in
resource-rich African countries
business are higher in African countries than
elsewhere in the world (figure 6.18). Cost of starting a business
Reforms to reduce the start-up and expan-
sion costs linked to regulation should be a prior- Angola
ity for improving the business environment in
Congo, Dem. Rep.
Africa. Many resource-poor countries in Africa
have steadily and significantly reduced business Lesotho
start-up costs over the past five years through a
Madagascar
series of administrative and legislative reforms.
For example, in countries throughout South- Malawi
ern Africa (including Lesotho, Madagascar,
Malawi, and Mozambique), start-up costs have Mozambique
converged with or even fallen below those of
South Africa
South Africa, which have always been low by
emerging-market standards. In contrast, start- 0 50 100 150 200 250 300
up costs remain very high in some resource- % of income per capita
rich countries (figure 6.19; World Bank 2012b). Source: World Bank Doing Business indicators, 2012.
Raising Productivity in Africas Modern Wage Enterprises to Foster Job Growth for Youth 221

Box 6.6

Who must pay bribes? How much? And does it matter?


Who must pay bribes and how much? A unique set of survey Subsequently, researchers used the same data to study
data on corruption, containing quantitative information on the relationship between bribery payments, taxes, and firm
the payment of bribes by Ugandan firms, helps to answer growth. Using industry-location averages to circumvent
these questions. The data have two striking features: not all potential problems of endogeneity and measurement errors,
firms report that they need to pay bribes, and there is consid- they found that the rate of both taxation and bribery is neg-
erable variation in reported graft across firms facing similar atively correlated with firm growth. A 1 percentage point
institutions and policies. These patterns can be explained by increase in the bribery rate is associated with a 3 percentage
differences in control rights and bargaining strength across point reduction in firm growth, an effect that is about three
firms. Firms typically have to pay bribes when dealing with times greater than that of taxation. These results are con-
public officials whose actions directly affect their business sistent with the findings from the original research, which
operations. Such dealings cannot be easily avoided when, suggest that firms investment and technology decisions are
for example, a firm must export or import goods or make driven partly by the desire to minimize bribe payments, even
use of public infrastructure services. though the decisions adversely affect gross profits.
How much must graft-paying firms pay? When the The results have clear policy implications. If the size of
quantitative data on corruption are combined with detailed the bribe that a firm needs to pay is an outcome of a bar-
financial information from the surveyed firms, the size of the gaining process, collective action on the part of the busi-
bribe that a firm needs to pay depends positively on cur- ness community that strengthens the bargaining position of
rent and expected future profits and negatively on expected individual firms may be a successful strategy to reduce the
alternative returns to capital. In other words, firms ability cost of doing business. Potentially effective measures include
to pay and refusal power can explain a large part of the collecting and disseminating information about corrupt
variation in bribes across graft-reporting firms. These results practices; informing the private sector and the public about
suggest that public officials act as price (bribe) discrimina- service standards, guidelines, and norms of major service
tors and the prices of public services are determined partly to providers; increasing the ability of individual firms to commit
extract bribes. Moreover, expecting high demand for bribes, to not paying bribes; and recognizing those who are doing a
a firm might find it profitable to choose a technology with good job by resisting corruption.
higher operating costs per period and thus lower profits, but
one that indirectly reduces the size of the bribe that the firm
needs to pay. Sources: Svensson 2003; Fisman and Svensson 2007.

Pinotti 2012; Bloom, Sadun, and Van Reenen incremental reforms in the investment climate,
2012). Firms also have an incentive to integrate before they are rolled out more broadly.
vertically or to enter into contracts only with Firms engaging in similar or linked activi-
members of their extended family and social ties often cluster, because clustering has many
network. potential advantages. Firms in the cluster can
learn production and business management
techniques from one another.18 Transport and
Localized Interventions to Improve the other types of infrastructure that serve the clus-
Wider Business Environment ter improve as clusters grow. Together, the firms
To increase competitiveness, the ultimate pol- can attract more consumers, more and better
icy objective is to improve the overall business input suppliers, and more skilled workers than
environment, but in some cases localized inter- they could attract if they were dispersed. Clus-
ventions can lay the groundwork for a com- ters can be especially conducive to the growth
petitive, modern enterprise sector to emerge. of specialized input suppliers. They also help
Concentrating public resources in selected clus- to reduce the cost and raise the quality of spe-
ters of activity is one kind of localized interven- cialized inputs. Investments to improve input
tion. Such clusters can also be used to introduce quality or reduce input costs are less risky for
222 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

a supplier when several prospective purchasers be concerned mainly with enabling nascent clus-
are present; when there is only one purchaser, ters to transition toward self-sustaining growth.
the purchaser has the power to bargain those Special economic zones (SEZs) are an
gains away. increasingly popular vehicle for supporting
In this way, clusters can exhibit agglomera- localized growth, especially in the form of
tion economiesthat is, the firms in a cluster export-oriented clusters. The idea is to support
can become increasingly productive as the clus- clustering by concentrating public investment
ter grows and matures. Many of the potential (such as infrastructure) and policy reforms
productivity benefits from growing clusters in specially marked zones. Some SEZs target
occur through spillovers between firmsfor locations that are considered to have an inher-
example, firms learn from one another or ent advantage for insertion into global value
downstream firms benefit from having several chains, such as areas near ports, but the choice
input suppliers located nearby. The gains from of a high-potential location may not be criti-
being in a cluster thus depend on how many cal to success: a particular location may have
other firms locate there, and every firm that no inherent advantage in a sector or task, but it
locates in a cluster could be conferring ben- may acquire comparative advantage as a cluster
efits on the other firms in that cluster. A clus- starts to develop and agglomeration economies
ter that is not out of the ordinary to start with arise (Collier and Venables 2007). As the expe-
may become internationally competitive once rience of successful clusters in Africa suggests,
it is big enough. But when choosing where to SEZs should focus on supporting incipient
locate, firms fail to take this collective benefit clusters to develop beyond a critical threshold,
into account. This is a form of market failure, after which they can sustain themselves. SEZs
so although clusters can emerge spontaneously, in Africa have rarely been located around pre-
they may need some kind of public support to existing clusters, which is thought to be one
reach a truly competitive size. reason that their performance has been less
Public support may be especially necessary satisfactory than that of SEZs in other develop-
to form clusters in manufacturing and tradable ing regions (Farole 2011).
services, given their potential export orienta- Creating a superior business environment
tion. Because they are not limited by the size within SEZs reduces the availability of public
of the domestic market, such clusters can truly resources for improving the business climate
exploit the economies of scale from clustering outside of those areas. If there are significant
production. As discussed, African firms can increasing returns to clustering, then allocating
integrate with global supply chains by special- public resources to SEZs is likely to be supe-
izing in specific tasks or steps in a value chain. rior to spreading public resources everywhere
To do so, they must be able to import inputs as to provide services at a uniformly low level
easily and cheaply as their international com- (Collier and Venables 2007). SEZs do not always
petitors, and they must have access to the same fulfill their potential, however, as indicated by
high-quality physical infrastructure and sup- the varied experience with SEZs worldwide.
portive regulations. Thus one option for public Because it is difficult to measure the extent of
support is to develop clusters specializing in agglomeration economies rigorously, the causal
specific tasks within global value chains.19 impact of promoting clusters through SEZs
Box 6.7 looks at the common attributes of is difficult to evaluate. For that reason, every
11 successful clusters in Africa. These clusters potential SEZ should be considered carefully.
highlight the role of value chains (linking input SEZs designed to cater to the needs of par-
suppliers with downstream firms), knowledge ticular firms or industries to the exclusion of
flows, ability to attract a skilled workforce, and others are especially risky. Such SEZs con-
coordination. All of the clusters had public sup- centrate resources not just spatially, but also
port, although the form of support varied. A in certain lines of activity or firms that are
common pattern, however, was the spontaneous deemed to be winners. This strategy assumes
rather than publicly engineered inception of the that the state has the ability to identify which
clusters, suggesting that public support should firms stand to gain the most from agglomerat-
Raising Productivity in Africas Modern Wage Enterprises to Foster Job Growth for Youth 223

Box 6.7

Knowledge, technology, and the emergence of successful enterprise clusters in Africa


How have successful enterprise clusters evolved in Africa, Africas wine industry benefits from the Elsenburg Agricultural
and what lessons do they offer for encouraging new clusters Training Institute and the Wine Industry Network for Expertise
to develop? A study of 11 clusters that emerged more or less and Technology.
spontaneously in various countries and industries provides All successful clusters have a labor force that is more edu-
insight into those questions.a cated than the norm for Africa, sometimes far beyond the
Except for the Mauritian textile cluster (originating in an norm (in Otigba, 5560 percent of entrepreneurs are uni-
export-processing zone established by the government in the versity graduates). In SuameAfricas largest artisanal engi-
1970s), the clusters arose spontaneously because they had neering cluster75 percent of entrepreneurs have a primary
access to major local markets and infrastructure (all clusters); education or less; only 2 percent have a higher education.
natural resources (the cut flower, fish, and wine industries); Yet such clusters create employment for increasing numbers
and local entrepreneurs with tacit knowledge and basic skills of university graduates, who can be an important force for
in trading, design, or manufacturing (the metalwork, com- continued growth and sustainability.
puter, and Nnewi auto parts clusters, which started with Government support to clusters takes several forms:
trading or repairing and evolved into assembling or manu- defining and implementing sectoral policies, regulations, and
facturing). Strong local demand existed for their products, standards; creating a special agency to promote or develop a
except for cut flowers and fish, which had strong interna- cluster; establishing institutions to provide technical support
tional demand. Governments sometimes promoted clusters and develop capacity; offering incentives in the form of sub-
indirectly. For example, the handicraft cluster in Tanzania and sidized land or infrastructure; and forging strategic alliances
the Suame automotive cluster in Ghana developed because with industries overseas.
the government relocated scattered, unorganized businesses Industrial and professional associations facilitate collec-
to clear the city or facilitate spatial planning. tive action and cooperation. For example, Tanzanian clusters
Efficiencies from a cluster-based value chain were fun- voice concerns and obtain technical advice through associa-
damental. A value chain develops when a cluster achieves tions. Suame associations focus on social welfare. Associa-
a certain scale, gains visibility, and expands further to ben- tions for flower producers engage in lobbying, environmental
efit from efficiencies derived from a larger clientele, syner- conservation, maintaining standards, and facilitating market
gies among firms, the developing knowledge network, and access, among other activities. The Wines of South Africa
shared facilities and services, including some provided by Association markets South African wines internationally.
governments and donors (warehouses, for example). Amid stiff global economic competition, the survival of
To succeed, all clusters had to acquire, adapt, and dis- these clusters depends on overcoming local challenges related
seminate knowledge. Horizontal and vertical links among to the critical mass of skills at their disposal, weak local tech-
firmssubcontracting relationships, connections with cus- nology institutions (disconnected from the business sector),
tomers and suppliers, information and formal collaboration weak government and institutional support, natural resource
through joint ventures and franchises, membership in asso- depletion, and the failure to meet international standards for
ciations, and the movement of skilled personnelcreated product quality and safety. The government has a multifac-
knowledge networks. Foreign knowledge and technology eted role to play in enabling clusters to meet these enormous
sustain several clusters. Foreign direct investment from Hong challenges. Aside from overall coordination, the public sector
Kong SAR, China, and Taiwan, China, brought technology can facilitate the acquisition of knowledge and technology
and know-how to the Mauritian textile industry. Nigerias (through links with foreign enterprises and improved links
Otigba computer village imports computer hardware from between local institutes and businesses), establish a conducive
China, Dubai, and Malaysia, with which it maintains techni- institutional regime (clear regulations, standards, and quality
cal and production channels. Kenyas Kamukunji metalwork- assurance) in collaboration with trade and professional associ-
ers obtain technology from South and East Asia. Formal ations, strengthen training and skills, provide basic infrastruc-
and informal learning and training assume numerous forms. ture, and enact policies that increase consumers purchasing
Technology-intensive manufacturing clusters are trained by power and demand for high-quality goods.
experts (locally and overseas) and offer training on the job or
factory site. South African wine producers participate in vini- Source: Zeng 2006.
a. The clusters were cut flowers and metalwork (Kenya), fish production
culture forums and root stock associations. In most instances, and processing (Uganda), handicrafts and furniture (Tanzania), automo-
universities and technology institutes contribute minimally to tive parts and computer hardware (Nigeria), manufacturing and vehicle
knowledge and technology flows for clusters. Even so, South repair (Ghana), textiles (Mauritius), and wine and textiles (South Africa).
224 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box 6.8

Why have special economic zones failed to thrive in Africa, and what are the lessons for
the future?
Government attempts to launch SEZs in Africa have met entity within the cluster may own more than 20 percent of
with little success. Numerous zones and industrial parks the equity, and each firm occupies land in proportion to the
have been announced but failed to materialize; others have equity it contributes. The PMC receives fees only if the proj-
been built, but never occupied. The few SEZs that have ect is accepted.
emerged are smaller than those in other regions. For exam- The combination of incentives offered under the scheme
ple, SEZs in six African countries supported perhaps 35 firms fosters interdependence among the stakeholders. Institu-
on average, versus 350 in Honduras, nearly 300 in Bangla- tional mechanisms reinforce those relationships, including
desh, and 3,500 in Vietnam (Farole 2011, 71). Evidence is regular monitoring reports from the PMC to the ministry,
emerging that Africas SEZs have started to stagnate at low quarterly central government reviews of the scheme, and the
levels of growth (Farole 2011, 4). What could help the next appointment of directors on the SPV board by the ministry,
generation of SEZs to do better? PMC, and the state.
In India, the Scheme for Integrated Textile Parks, inau- The small size of the parks and the grants seems to
gurated in 2005 by the Ministry of Textiles, is in its early reduce the incentives for interference at the state and central
stages but has successfully built parks and attracted firms level. Because a central ministry rarely has local knowledge
to locate and invest in them. The parks appear to be gener- or human resources to monitor at a micro level, devolving
ating the benefits associated with clustering. The schemes this task to a specialized agency (the PMC) allows the minis-
most prominent innovation is to give the park users a much try to focus on its strategic mission and obtain better micro
greater role, much earlier, in development of the park. In data. The reporting requirements for PMCs are clear and
fact, the first order of business is not to build parks but to standard. Strict rules and methods for grant disbursements
organize entrepreneurs. help to limit the abuse of funds.
Entrepreneurs form a group (called a special-purpose vehi- Responsibility for engagement and coordination with
cle, SPV) to develop a detailed proposal for a park. To assist state agencies lies with local entrepreneurs, who are best
with this task, the SPV selects a specialized project manage- positioned to navigate the political economy of their state.
ment consultant (PMC) that is stringently vetted by the minis- States issue the clearances that are vital for park devel-
try. Guided by the SPV, the PMC designs, costs, and conducts opment, especially for converting land to industrial use.
a feasibility study for the project. The SPV makes the final Although limits on state participation in SPV funding curb
decisions on location, project design, and costing, because the states direct role, the ability to appoint a director to
the entrepreneurs constitute the demand for the park and the SPV board is an incentive to participate. SPVs also have
have the most incentives to select the best alternative. recourse to the center if issues arise with the state.
If the central government approves the proposal, it pro- The scheme appears highly adaptable to Indias diverse
vides a grant for infrastructure to be shared by park users (up conditions and its textile industry. Although this model may
to 40 percent of the cost, up to a maximum of about US$8 not suit circumstances in other industries or countries, it indi-
million). The SPV finances the rest. It may solicit state grants, cates that success is more likely when incentives are carefully
obtain other state and local contributions (such as subsidized calibrated to the political, institutional, and entrepreneurial
land), and even obtain investment from PMCs, but the SPV context.
must contribute at least 51 percent of the equity to ensure
that members retain managerial control. No single private Sources: Saleman and Jordan 2013; Zeng 2006.

ing, which is arguable. The driving principle of Building Skills for the Modern
localizing interventions around incipient clus- Wage Sector
ters should be one not of picking winners but
rather of letting the winners pick each other As discussed in chapter 3, productivity in mod-
by locating near each other. In other words, it ern wage enterprises depends on a range of skills:
is important not to over-engineer who gains cognitive skills, soft skills, and managerial and
entry to an SEZ (see box 6.8 for an example of business skills. Policy discussions often revolve
a more nuanced approach from India).20 around technical skills, but foundational skills
Raising Productivity in Africas Modern Wage Enterprises to Foster Job Growth for Youth 225

acquired through schooling are also important. Several policy recommendations emerge
Recent research from Kenya, for instance, sug- from this evidence on the role of skills. They
gests that by raising literacy and reasoning skills, emphasize the need to focus on foundational
secondary school completion reduces the prob- skills and public goods such as quality assur-
ability of low-skilled self-employment by 50 ance and information, the need for govern-
percent, while raising the probability of formal ment to focus on building portable rather than
employment by 30 percent (Ozier 2013). These job-specific skills, the need for special support
skills seem to matter because they facilitate on- to enable poor and disadvantaged groups to
the-job learning in firms. Literate workers can acquire skills, the need to develop interna-
be trained through written instructions in job tional linkages, and the need for systems that
specifications and procedures, for example, and link employers with trainers. The following
they require less hands-on technical supervision discussion of these recommendations reviews
by others. Such training is rare in Africa, how- interventions that have been tested in Africa
ever, because of low literacy levels (Biggs, Shah, and elsewhere.
and Srivastava 1995).
Employer surveys from some African coun- Focus on Foundational Skills and on
triesBotswana, Lesotho, and Sierra Leone Public Goods Such as Quality Assurance
suggest that employers are also looking for soft and Information
skills in young hires. Employers in Botswana, The discussion on public support to build skills
for instance, rate reliability and punctuality, for youth employment often takes a short-term
commitment and hard work, honesty, and view of the problem and centers on technical
teamwork skills as the top skills required when vocational education and training (TVET), but
hiring skilled workers (World Bank 2011a). it is equally, if not more, important to build a
While there is increasing international evi- solid foundation for individuals to develop
dence on the link between skills and produc- their skills as they progress in life. Basic school-
tivity, firms in Africa generally do not rate ing is a key determinant of wage workers cog-
skills as a top constraint. Self-reported short- nitive and soft skills. It is the foundation for
ages of skills tend to be higher in relatively the acquisition of additional skills, whether
capital-intensive industries. Skills also tend through more formal education, training, or
to become a constraint for high-performing on-the-job learning. Improving access to gen-
firms: businesses that complain of a skills eral schooling and the quality of that school-
shortage consistently outperform those that do ingeven at the basic levelis a priority for
not (Barker and Mengistae 2013). This infor- increasing the productivity of labor in the
mation suggests that while raising skills is not modern wage sector.
going to solve the employment problem by Parental investment and early childhood
itself, it should be part of the policy package interventions in health and education also
for improving competitiveness. Even if skills influence personality traits that become rele-
are currently not a binding constraint, they will vant to productivity later in life, either directly
quickly become binding as the sector takes off. or through the fact that some personality traits
In addition to the limited availability of will make some students more likely to suc-
cognitive, soft, and technical skills among job ceed in school (Almlund et al. 2011). Recently,
seekers, a lack of managerial capital could many governments have included soft skills in
also be constraining the competitiveness of training programs for youth, and while there is
African firms. As discussed in chapter 3, there some evidence of their impact, evidence on the
is increasing evidence that firms in the region significance of early childhood investments is
have visibly poor basic management practices. much better established.
There may be considerable scope for improving Governments should also reevaluate their
productivity (and hence raising employment) role in providing TVET directly. As discussed
by investing in business and management skills in chapter 3, publicly provided TVET has a
training, and perhaps even in individualized poor track record in Africa, where it is expen-
management consulting. sive but often inefficient or irrelevant to the
226 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

labor market. An increasingly large share of better alternative for public support may be
TVET in Africa is provided by the private sec- active labor market programs that have train-
tor (Mingat, Ledoux, and Rakotomalala 2010; ing components and target specific groups
World Bank 2012d; Atchoarena and Esquieu (Almeida, Behrman, and Robalino 2012).
2002; Kitaev 2002). Although private providers It is also critical to make formal TVET more
may offer little training in some specific skills, efficient and market relevant. Several policy
this lack of interest does not necessarily mean recommendations are pertinent here, but they
that nascent private institutes are incapable of are based largely on the experience of devel-
providing such training or that the returns to oped countries. Box 6.9 discusses potential
those skills are too low. Similarly, there may reforms and how they have been undertaken
be an equity-based case for establishing pub- in Africa.
lic TVET institutes in poor or remote areas,
where private entry is limited, but there may
not be high enough returns to TVET training Address Information and Credit
in remote areas. In many cases, low take-up of Constraints to Improve Access to TVET
training is better addressed by improving access among Poor and Disadvantaged Groups
to credit (or grants) and providing information As discussed in chapter 3, the government
about training programs. In other contexts, a could step in to provide targeted financial

Box 6.9

Reforming TVET systems in Africa


One strategy for improving the relevance and quality of job, type and quality of employment, and students satisfac-
skills developed through TVET programs is to grant public tion with the education.
TVET institutions increased autonomy and accountabil- Many African countries have begun to reform their TVET
ity for results. Institutions would have the freedom to set systems along these lines. While this is a positive step, there
fees, adapt training to local needs, hire appropriate staff, is little rigorous evidence yet on whether these reforms
and choose methods of instruction. Accountability can be have improved cost-effectiveness or market relevance. For
increased by basing financing on performance and out- instance, Ethiopia, Ghana, and Tanzania have developed
comes rather than inputs, accompanied by better measure- national qualification frameworks to set standards. Recog-
ment of performance. nizing the need for better coordination in their TVET sys-
Governments also have a role in providing standards, tems, some countries have tried new governance arrange-
accreditation, quality assurance, and information. The TVET ments and have introduced national coordinating bodies
qualifications system should be focused less on providing and national training authorities, with mixed results. Ghana,
inputs and more on assuring that the training has provided for example, established the Council for TVET (or COTVET)
the competencies (skills) required for the market. Lack of in 2006 as a coordinating body. A study of this reform sug-
information about private TVET providers can constrain gests that COTVETs engagement with the private sector and
young people from making informed choices about training, collection of demand-side data could be improved and that
and it can also dull providers incentives to improve their qual- insufficient coordination within the government has led to
ity. Governments can play a role in collecting and disseminat- parallel agendas, plans, programs, and committees. Govern-
ing this information. Instead of measuring inputs (number of ments in Africa may need to build more capacity in the rel-
students, institutions, and teachers) as is currently the norm, evant agencies before they can successfully transplant com-
the emphasis should be on tracking efficiency (dropout, rep- plex TVET systems from developed countries.
etition, and survival rates) and outcomes (share of trainees
entering wage or self-employment after graduating), which
are more relevant to young peoples training decisions. For Sources: Based on Johanson and Van Adams 2004 (mixed results of
governance arrangements); Darvas and Palmer 2012 (TVET in Ghana);
instance, in the Netherlands, almost all graduates of higher World Bank 2012a (TVET with a business component in Uganda); Son-
education institutions are surveyed a year and a half after dergaard and Murthi 2012 (reforms in Eastern Europe and Central Asia);
they graduate to collect information on time taken to find a Krishnan and Shaorshadze 2013 (TVET in Ethiopia).
Raising Productivity in Africas Modern Wage Enterprises to Foster Job Growth for Youth 227

support and information that young people that African firms are particularly constrained
from poor or otherwise disadvantaged back- in providing on-the-job training. World Bank
grounds need to access TVET markets.21 Young enterprise surveys indicate that on average 30
women are less likely to participate in TVET percent of formal firms in Africa provide on-
than young men, and they frequently focus on the-job training, which is comparable to the
narrow types of training such as tailoring or standard level across low- and middle-income
weaving, suggesting that direct financial sup- countries. Nor does the absence of on-the-job
port or information is needed to increase their training in a firm necessarily signal a constraint.
take-up of training with high returns. Targeted A recent study estimates that many firms do
voucher programs that have an information not provide it because the returns to such train-
component, such as the Technical and Voca- ing are close to zero for them (Almeida and
tional Vouchers Program (TVVP) in Kenya, Carneiro 2009). Governments could consider
can improve access to training among poor and supporting on-the-job training in specific cases
disadvantaged youth. The TVVP experience where there is compelling evidence of a market
shows that flexible vouchers (not restricted to failure (box 6.10), but not more generally.
specific types of training providers) are more Some of the constraints to firm-specific
effective than inflexible ones. Another impor- training could be addressed by broader policies
tant lesson from TVVP is that participants are to improve the business climate or productivity
frequently mistaken about the returns to voca- in firms. For example, if liquidity constraints
tional education, with males strongly prefer- prevent firms from investing in training, then
ring traditionally male-dominated courses policies that improve firms access to finance
such as motor vehicle repair and women will also have an impact on on-the-job train-
almost exclusively choosing traditionally ing. To the extent that firms and workers would
female-dominated courses such as hairdress- be more likely to reach an agreement on shar-
ing. TVVP provided information on the higher ing the returns from training if contracts were
economic returns in male-dominated trades, enforceable, strengthening the enforceability
which encouraged women to take up training of contracts and the rule of law could have a
in those areas. positive impact on on-the-job training. Some-
times, firms train workers in very specific or
Focus Government Intervention on outdated skills because they use old technology.
Building Skills That Are Portable, Not Policies that promote innovation and techno-
Job Specific logical upgrading in firms could therefore
Government interventions should be focused also improve the social returns to on-the-job
on building more portable skills, as opposed training.
to skills required only for a particular job or
firm. More portable skills have higher social Facilitate International Linkages in
value, because they are less vulnerable to Training and Technology Upgrading in
changes in the demand for skills specific to cer- Specific Industries
tain firms or industries. Because their current Governments can facilitate technical coop-
market returns could be lower than this social eration with other countries in training and
return, the likelihood of underinvestment is upgrading technology in specific industries,
higher for more portable skills. Firms are also especially with other developing countries that
less likely to invest in portable skills because have technical capacity in the industry. A recent
workers trained in such skills could be poached example is the technical cooperation between
by other firms. Ethiopias Ministry of Trade and Industry, the
Firm-specific skills can be acquired through Ethiopian Leather and Leather Products Tech-
on-the-job training, and public support may nology Institute, and the Footwear Design and
not be necessary to supply them. Credit con- Development Institute of India. The Footwear
straints could prevent firms from investing in Design and Development Institute provided
firm-specific skills, but there is little evidence technical assistance to seven Ethiopian shoe
228 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Box 6.10

Does government have a role in on-the-job training?


To the extent that they are substitutable, on-the-job train- that did not. Ghana offered a similar voucher program to
ing is by design more likely to be more market relevant than informal enterprises in the early 1990s, but it largely failed,
technical or vocational education in the classroom. When apparently because of poor marketing and distribution.
there is evidence that on-the-job training is being underpro- Even when there is evidence that training is underpro-
vided because of credit or other market failures, government vided by some firms, governments should be cautious with
subsidies could be considered. Some developing countries on-the-job training subsidy schemes and their targeting. The
use subsidy schemes (in the form of levy-rebate systems) returns could vary across firms. Training might be subsidized
to promote on-the-job training. For example, Peru allows in firms in which the net returns are insufficient to justify the
firms to use payroll-tax proceeds for in-service training or training, or scarce public resources might be wasted on firms
to purchase training at an accredited training institution. that would have provided on-the-job training even without
Levy-rebate systems have a mixed record of success, how- the subsidy. It is not easy to identify which firms are con-
ever. In South Africa, for example, only 35 percent of small strained in providing training. Many programs try to improve
enterprises claimed the training grant to which they were targeting by using proxies, such as targeting smaller firms
entitledand even fewer large firms appear to be claiming based on the assumption that they are more likely to be
them. credit constrained. These proxies are imperfect, and govern-
Some countries have also used a voucher system that ments should also invest in better monitoring and evaluation
subsidizes the cost of training to firms while giving them systems for such programs. A randomized pilot, for example,
flexibility in choosing the training provider. Kenyas Jua Kali could help to test whether subsidies are a substitute source
Program is a good example. An evaluation of this program, of funding for on-the-job training that would have occurred
which targeted small and microenterprises, found that firms in any case.
using vouchers experienced markedly greater growth in rev-
enue and assets. While this finding is promising, it should be Sources: Based on Johanson and Van Adams 2004; Filmer 2012 (South
interpreted with caution, because the firms that participated Africa); World Bank 2011c (vouchers in Peru); Almeida, Behrman, and
in the program are not necessarily comparable to those Robalino 2012 (Jua Kali).

factories in design, technical upgrading, quality foreign workers may actually create additional
assurance, productivity enhancement, and test- jobs. Building a base of evidence on the net
ing, which improved their productivity and the employment effects of skilled immigration can
overall quality of shoes. For instance, cutting at help to generate support.22 Policies for import-
one of the shoe factories rose from 2,000 pairs ing skills can be designed to maximize domestic
a day to 2,400, and defect rates dropped from 3 spilloversfor instance, by encouraging firms
to 1 percent (Dinh et al. 2012). to train domestic workers in return for permits
If certain technical skills are in demand in to hire technical skills from abroad.
several countries, but the demand is too small to
justify the fixed costs of building a training cen- Foster Systems That Link Employers
ter in every country, governments can cooperate with Trainers
to create regional hubs for technical skills train- Linking TVET systems to employers is neces-
ing. Importing such skills could also make sary to ensure that the training is relevant to the
economic sense, and in response governments market for skills. The returns to specific techni-
could ease constraints on the immigration cal skills can vary substantially across markets
of skilled workers. The current policy regime and over time. For this reason, policies oriented
in most African countries is not conducive to toward improving the skills delivered through
importing technical skills. Policy makers do TVET should build TVET systems with
need to take political economy considerations employers involvement to ensure that employ-
into account, such as concerns about domestic ers transmit information to trainers about
jobs being taken by foreigners, but highly skilled which skills are in demand on a regular basis.
Raising Productivity in Africas Modern Wage Enterprises to Foster Job Growth for Youth 229

Some developing countries already produce Can the transition to work be eased by
regular reports on the supply of and demand inserting training graduates in firms through
for skills, such as the Labor Market Intelligence temporary internships and other programs? A
Reports produced by the Philippines Technical case in point is the German-style dual system,
Education and Skills Development Authority in which theory is taught in educational institu-
(TESDA). TESDAs labor market reports are tions and practical skills are acquired through
based on consultations and focus group discus- an apprenticeship (or internship) in a com-
sions with employer associations as well as on pany. Some evidence suggests that this system
labor market surveys (TESDA 2012a, 2012b). reduces unemployment among graduates (Pio-
Similar approaches are being rolled out in piunik and Ryan 2012), but it is not clear how
Africa. Tanzanias vocational and educational this system can be imported at scale into Africa,
training authority has a monitoring and evalu- where the scope for internships with firms is
ation system based on regular data that are col- much more limited. If adopted, training plus
lected by zonal labor market analysts and mini insertion programs should be selectively tar-
market surveys that track current and prospec- geted to those most in need. Latin Americas
tive industry needs (United Republic of Tanza- Jvenes en Accin model, described later, may
nia and UNESCO 2012). Regular interaction be more suitable to the African context.
between training centers and industry and com- Governments also support insertion
merce is promoted by attaching tutors and stu- through employment or job search agencies.
dents to industry to gain practical exposure and The evidence suggests that such services have
by attaching industrial practitioners to training limited relevance for Africa. Formal public
centers to teach specific topics. The success of placement agencies are underused. A survey
this approach has yet to be determined. of job seekers in 11 African cities found that
Linkages between the training system and only 7 percent were registered with an employ-
industry can also help youth to make the tran- ment agency (De Vreyer and Roubaud 2013).
sition to work. In Africa, matching specialized Similarly, a recent study on the Middle East and
skills to jobs is not a major problem, but in low- North Africa found that many job seekers rely
skilled wage employment, young people from solely on personal and family connections, and
disadvantaged backgrounds have trouble con- most job placements occur outside of public
necting to employers because of basic informa- employment services (Kuddo 2012). A review
tional problems. A signal of these problems is of impact studiesdrawn largely from devel-
the ubiquity of informal networks as a source oped countriesfound that these services
of information about jobs. Young people with- tend to be more effective for the most educated
out networks in modern firmsespecially workers, when demand for labor is high (Bet-
youth from poor families or rural areas, whose cherman, Olivas, and Dar 2004).
family members or friends are less likely to have Comprehensive training-related programs
wage jobswill have greater difficulty finding that link students to employers through intern-
such jobs. Recent research suggests that infor- ships are well-established in Latin American
mal job networks also put women at a disad- countries and have begun to spread to other
vantage. An experiment on hiring in Malawi regions, including Africa. The Jvenes en
found that men referred men unless specifically Accin (Youth in Action) Program in Colom-
asked to refer women, and women referred ill- bia, for example, provided three months of
qualified women unless specifically rewarded classroom-based training and three months
for providing good-quality referrals (Beaman, of on-the-job training through internships in
Keleher, and Magruder 2012). Aside from dis- firms to unemployed young people between
advantaging certain groups, informal job net- the ages of 18 and 25 in the two lowest socio-
works reduce the productivity of job matches economic strata of the population (Attanasio,
by causing them to be based on connections Kugler, and Meghir 2011). Similarly, the Juven-
rather than qualifications and by limiting the tud y Empleo (Youth and Employment) Pro-
pool of potential hires that firms can tap. gram in the Dominican Republic subsidizes
230 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

training for individuals between the ages of 16 Improve Management Practices


and 29 who have not completed high school, Management training can have positive
with the training followed by an internship at impacts, but more evidence is needed on how
a private firm (Ibarraran et al. 2012). The pro- to target it. If poor management practices are
grams involve collaboration with the private as prevalent in Africa as some recent studies
sector to provide internships and select the suggest, there may be considerable scope for
content of training. They usually offer a pack- improving productivity by investing in busi-
age of skills, complementing vocational train- ness skills training and perhaps even in indi-
ing with life skills training intended to improve vidualized management consulting. Better
social interaction and work-related practices management can make firms more productive
and attitudes. and ultimately increase hiring. There is evi-
Rigorous impact evaluations of several dence that firms underinvest in management
Jvenes en Accin programs show mixed but skills because they underestimate its value or
promising results. On average, the programs are credit constrained.
increase formal wage employment at the rate of Programs seeking to promote managerial
about four to six additional jobs per 100 par- skills in established small and medium-size
ticipants. Given the low wage employment rates firms are on the rise in developing countries,
for African youth from poor backgrounds, this including programs that give intensive or
impact could be large in relative terms. The pro- individualized management consulting. Some
grams also lead to significantly higher earnings, have been evaluated in quasi-experimental
but the impacts are larger for female participants, or randomized studies, including studies by
and it is unclear if there is a significant impact the Kaizen Institute of industrial clusters in
on males. Evaluations of Jvenes en Accin pro- Dar es Salaam and Addis Ababa.24 The evalu-
grams and of recent training programs from ations suggest that such programs do lead to
India and Jordan suggest that a more compre- the adoption of new management practices.
hensive packagesuch as a combination of soft The magnitude of these effects is generally
skills training and on-the-job trainingis more small, with some exceptions. Among Ghanaian
effective (see Maitra and Mani 2012 for India; metalwork firms, for instance, the percentage
Groh et al. 2012 for Jordan). of firms keeping records increased 30 percent
These findings suggest that a targeted, com- (Mano et al. 2012).
prehensive (training plus internship) program Evidence on whether the adoption of new
could be an effective instrument for promot- management practices actually improves busi-
ing productive wage employment among dis- ness performance and employment is more
advantaged youth. Such programs are being mixed, with few studies finding statistically
adopted in Africa but have not yet been evalu- significant impacts on sales, profits, or survi-
ated, and there are serious questions about vorship. The most promising finding is from a
their cost-effectiveness in Africa. Jvenes pro- field experiment on large Indian textile firms,
grams were estimated to be cost-effective in in which management practices raised produc-
Latin America, in the narrow sense that their tivity 17 percent in the first year and led within
average impact on earnings exceeded the pro- three years to the opening of more production
gram cost per participant.23 Because the mod- plants (Bloom, Sadun, and Van Reenen 2012).
ern wage sector is relatively small in Africa, These results suggest that improved manage-
the cost of subsidizing internships could be ment practices can create more jobs.
higher there, and impacts on earnings lower. Given the limited but promising evidence,
The small size of the wage sector also makes more pilot studies in Africa would be useful,
scalability a bigger concern. Considering the including studies that examine issues related to
mixed evidence on what type of training works targeting and selectivity. For instance, is limited
best in these programs, they should be imple- managerial capital a constraint only for larger
mented on a pilot basis, and the pilots should firms, as the Indian study suggests? Are the
be evaluated to find the most cost-effective returns to managerial training highest when
model for Africa. training targets firms with the most ability or
Raising Productivity in Africas Modern Wage Enterprises to Foster Job Growth for Youth 231

potential for success, and can that potential in many countries, combined with barriers to
be identified? In industries where healthy com- imports and regional trade, suppress com-
petition among firms does not always occur, it petition and reduce pressure to innovate and
is difficult to identify such potential by look- improve productivity, even among firms that
ing at current performance. Moreover, high- produce for domestic markets.
potential firms may do well even in the absence Governments in Africa can do much to rem-
of government-supported managerial training. edy this situation. The most important step is
Small pilot programs directed at firms with to improve the business climate so that entre-
alternative profiles could be useful for under- preneurship and productive firms can grow.
standing where support is most needed. Key reform objectives are to improve access to
finance and infrastructure services, improve
trade logistics, and ease regulatory constraints
Many Options to Promote to entrepreneurship. Some effortssuch as
Competitive Modern Enterprises providing physical infrastructure for public
utilities and transportrequire costly invest-
Modern manufacturing and services firms ment in the long run. Yet many other policy
have been an engine of job growth in devel- reforms are not so expensive in monetary terms
oped countries and more recently in East Asia. and can deliver huge impacts by reducing dis-
In the long run, the same should be true for tortions and increasing efficiency. Selective and
Africa. The modern enterprise sector presently spatially targeted support to emerging clusters
accounts for a small share of African employ- can make the most of limited resources by pro-
ment, and it is growing unevenly across the moting agglomeration economies. Localized
region. The manufacturing sector, which has interventions of this sort should assist clusters
been a vibrant source of new jobs in other by providing good infrastructure and support-
regions, accounts for less than 3 percent of total ive regulation, but they should never try to
employment in Africa. force clusters into existence by trying to pick
Because African economies are small, winners.
domestic demand alone cannot support a A skills shortage does not seem to be a bind-
thriving modern enterprise sector, where so ing constraint on modern wage employment in
much depends on achieving scale and diversity. Africa, but there is much evidence that a range
Trade in manufacturing (and tradable services) of skillscognitive, behavioral, and techni-
may be essential for modern firms in these sec- calmatters to productivity in firms. African
tors to realize their full potential for productive youths need those skills if they are to be truly
youth employment, but presently they export productive in modern firms, particularly when
very little. Labor costs are generally not lower in this sector starts to take off. Governments
African countries than in their potential com- should, first of all, foster a strong foundation
petitors. If they cannot compete on the strength in basic skills by improving the quality of gen-
of low labor costs, the regions modern enter- eral education. Rather than directly providing
prises must compete on the strength of their TVET, they should focus on providing public
productivitybut African firms are relatively goods such as quality assurance and informa-
unproductive. tion to develop a training sector that is efficient
The lack of productivity signals deeper and relevant to the market for skills. For poor
problems that are not identical across the sub- and disadvantaged youths to gain access to
continent. In some countries, the cost of com- training, governments should provide finan-
plementary inputs to labor (electricity, over- cial support in conjunction with information
land transport, and so on) is too high. In others, that enables them to obtain the right kind of
bureaucratic red tape delays investors access to training. Programs for disadvantaged youths
land or permits or complicates efforts to move that integrate training with internships show
goods (inputs and output) through ports. The promise, as do programs offering managerial
high costs of financial intermediation are starv- trainingbut their scalability and affordability
ing investors of capital. Small domestic markets in Africa remain unproven.
232 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Notes 10. Associations between these business environ-


1. Africas wage employment sector is only partially ment variables and plant-level and aggregate
modern, in the sense that many wage employ- productivity in World Bank enterprise survey
ees work without a formal contract. On average, data are analyzed in several papers, including
about 57 percent of wage employees have a con- Dollar, Hallward-Driemeier, and Mengistae
tract with their employer. Among young people, (2005); Li, Mengistae, and Xu (2011); Harri-
the share with a contract is 47 percent. son, Lin, and Xu (2013). See also Hall and Jones
2. New thinking on international trade reflects the (1999); Bartelsman, Haltiwanger, and Scarpetta
major impact that trade can have on productiv- (2009).
ity. An increasingly large share of the trade in 11. That is, the simple average of firm produc-
goods now comes from trade in different vari- tivities, not weighted by their market shares, is
eties of products within the same industry; for higher in Country A.
example, the United States and European coun- 12. Specifically, it is possible to decompose indus-
tries export cars to each other. Such trade is ben- try productivity into the average of firm-level
eficial, because it allows different varieties to be TFPswhich would be the industrys TFP
produced at an efficient scale, which would not level if all firms had equal market sharesand
be possible if each variety were sold only within an allocative efficiency component. This is
its country of origin. This kind of trade also referred to as the Olley-Pakes decomposition of
allows more efficient producers to take fuller aggregate productivity (Olley and Pakes 1996).
advantage of their efficiency, because a larger See also Melitz and Polanec (2012) and Foster,
marketa direct consequence of lower trade Haltiwanger, and Syverson (2008) for related
barriershas a disproportionately greater posi- decompositions. The Olley-Pakes decomposi-
tive impact on the profitability of more efficient tion can be described as follows: let at be the
firms. As more productive firms gain market weighted average of (log) TFP of a given indus-
share at the expense of less productive ones, the try in year t and let aitt be the log TFP of enter-
industrys potential for generating employment prises constituting the industry with respective
rises (a point addressed later in the analysis of market shares, sit , where i indexes enterprises.
Africas manufacturing competitiveness). Then at can be written as
Nt
3. Less productive firms are limited to selling in the
at = at + (sit st )(ait at),
domestic market, as the price they would have i 1
to charge to recover transport and other costs where letters with upper bars represent un-
of exporting would not be competitive. See, for weighted industry means of variables.
instance, Melitz and Trefler (2012). 13. Banerjee and Duflo (2012), for instance, show
4. The caveat with these data is that the surveys that firms are credit constrained in India. Udry
collect information on firms that are formally and Anagol (2006) discuss evidence on excep-
registered. In most countries, all firms above a tionally high rates of return to capital in Ghana,
certain size are supposed to register, but in prac- which suggests credit constraints.
tice, the registration rates and quality of the reg- 14. In India, for example, labor laws prevent firms
istry information vary across countries. from adjusting employment in response to
5. Some evidence indicates that Sub-Saharan external shocks. See Adhvaryu, Chari, and
Africa, along with South Asia, may have the low- Sharma (2013).
est labor productivity in manufacturing in the 15. Among the indicators of the potential gains
developing world. See Clarke (2011). from reductions in trade costs are the large and
6. An additional reason is that African firms sub- persistent cross-border disparities in the price of
stitute labor for capital by using relatively labor- goods, earnings, and rates of return to capital
intensive production methods, despite the fact among neighboring countries across the region.
that many African countries have higher wages These suggest substantial room for increasing
than China. employment opportunities for young people
7. Moreover, foreign direct investment in Africa is simply by making it easier for countries to trade
dominated by investment in extractive indus- and invest across borders, without necessarily
tries (World Bank 2013a). involving large international migration of peo-
8. The technical term is total factor productivity ple (Habyarimana and Mengistae 2013).
(TFP). 16. Barker and Mengistae (2013). Beck, Dermig-
9. As discussed later, some recent studies, notably Kunt, and Maksimovic (2005) report that firms
Bloom et al. (2013), measure organizational claiming to be more constrained by access to
efficiency. credit are likely to grow more slowly.
Raising Productivity in Africas Modern Wage Enterprises to Foster Job Growth for Youth 233

17. Kenya Gazette Supplement no. 52 (Legislative Almlund, Mathilde, Angela Duckworth, James
Supplement no. 31) and Legal Notice no. 97, of Heckman, and Tim Kautz. 2011. Personality,
11 July 2008. Psychology, and Economics. In Handbook of the
18. Cadot et al. (2013) found that new exporters are Economics of Education, edited by Eric Hanushek,
more likely to survive beyond the first year when Stephen Machin, and Ludger Woessmann, 1181.
Amsterdam: Elsevier.
other firms are exporting the same product to
similar destinations. They argue that informa- Atchoarena, David, and Paul Esquieu, eds. 2002.
tion spillovers account for the finding. Private Technical and Vocational Education in
19. Collier and Venables (2007). See also Monga Sub-Saharan Africa: Provision, Patterns, and
(2012) and Lin and Monga (2011) on the instru- Policy Issues. IIEP/Prg.DA/01.300. Paris: Interna-
tional Institute for Educational Planning.
mentality of localization to that end in the con-
text of industrial policy, which the framework Attanasio, Orazio P., Adriana D. Kugler, and Costas
of Collier and Venables does not necessarily Meghir. 2011. Subsidizing Vocational Training
assume. for Disadvantaged Youth in Developing Coun-
tries: Evidence from a Randomized Trial. Ameri-
20. The issue of localizing interventions in support
can Economic Journal: Applied Economics 3 (3):
of clusters is often intertwined with the issue of 188220.
industrial policy (that is, policy targeted to spe-
cific types of industries or firms). But the two Banerjee, Abhijit, and Esther Duflo. 2005. Growth
are quite distinct. Interventions to localize clus- Theory through the Lens of Development Eco-
nomics. In Handbook of Economic Growth, Vol.
ters do not rely on identifying specific firms or 1A, edited by Philippe Aghion and Steven Dur-
industries that should be clustered. For the cur- lauf, ch. 7, 473552. Amsterdam: Elsevier.
rent debate on industrial policy, as distinct from
the spatial targeting of measures for improving . 2012. Do Firms Want to Borrow More?
Testing Credit Constraints Using a Directed
the investment climate, some key references are
Lending Program. Massachusetts Institute of
Lin (2011); Lin and Monga (2011); Pack and Technology, Department of Economics, Boston,
Saggi (2006); Rodrik (2004). MA.
21. A survey of disadvantaged youth in Malawi
found that only 13 percent had ever received Barker, M., and Taye Mengistae. 2013. Business
Environment, Market Distortions, and Employ-
technical or vocational training (Hicks et al.
ment in Africa: An Analysis of Business Survey
2011). Those who had not received any training Data on Manufacturing Industries and Services.
attributed it to high costs and limited access and Background paper for the Africa Region Report
information. on Youth Employment in Africa, World Bank,
22. That evidence base does not yet exist for Africa. Washington, DC.
23. This assessment is based on particular assump- Bartelsman, Eric, John Haltiwanger, and Stefano
tions about how long the earnings impact lasts. Scarpetta. 2009. Cross-Country Differences in
See Attanasio, Kugler, and Meghir (2011). Productivity: The Role of Allocation and Selec-
24. McKenzie and Woodruff (2013) review these tion. IZA Discussion Paper 4578, Institute for
evaluations of management and business prac- the Study of Labor, Bonn.
tice training programs. Mano et al. (2012), Beaman, Lori, Niall Keleher, and Jeremy Magruder.
Sonobe, Suzuki, and Otsuka (2011), and Kar- 2012. Do Job Networks Disadvantage Women?
lan, Knight, and Udry (2012) are Africa-specific Evidence from a Recruitment Experiment in
evaluations. Malawi. Working Paper, Northwestern Univer-
sity, Department of Economics, Chicago.
References Beck, Thorsten, Asli Dermig-Kunt, and Vojislav
Adhvaryu, Achyuta, A. V. Chari, and Siddharth Maksimovic. 2005. Financial and Legal Con-
Sharma. 2013. Firing Costs and Flexibility: Evi- straints to Growth: Does Firm Size Matter?
dence from Firms Employment Responses to Journal of Financee 60 (1): 3777.
Shocks in India. Review of Economics and Statis- Bertrand, Marianne, Antoinette Schoar, and David
ticss 95 (3): 72540. Thesmar. 2007. Banking Deregulation and
Almeida, Rita, Jere Behrman, and David Robalino, Industry Structure: Evidence from the French
eds. 2012. The Right Skills for the Job? Rethinking Banking Reforms of 1985. Journal of Finance
Effective Training Policies for Workers. Washing- 62 (2): 597628.
ton, DC: World Bank. Betcherman, Gordon, Karina Olivas, and Amit Dar.
Almeida, Rita, and Pedro Carneiro. 2009. The 2004. Active Labor Market Programs: New Evi-
Return to the Firm Investment in Human Capi- dence from Evaluations with Particular Attention
tal. Labor Economicss 16 (1): 97106. to Developing and Transition Countries. Social
234 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Protection Discussion Paper 04012, World Bank, Africa. Paris: Agence Franaise de Dveloppe-
Washington, DC. ment; Washington, DC: World Bank.
Biggs, Tyler, Manju Shah, and Pradeep Srivastava. Dinh, Hinh T., Dimitris A. Mavridis, and Hoa B.
1995. Technological Capabilities and Learn- Nguyen. 2012. The Binding Constraints on the
ing in African Enterprises. Technical Paper 288, Growth of Firms in Developing Countries. In
World Bank, Washington, DC. Performance of Manufacturing Firms in Africa: An
Bloom, Nicholas, Benn Eifert, Aprajit Mahajan, Empirical Analysis, edited by Hinh T. Dinh and
David McKenzie, and John Roberts. 2013. Does George R. G. Clarke, 87138. Washington, DC:
Management Matter? Evidence from India. World Bank.
Quarterly Journal of Economicss 128 (1): 151. Dinh, Hinh T., Vincent Palmade, Vandana Chandra,
Bloom, Nicholas, Raffaella Sadun, and John Van and Frances Cossar. 2012. Light Manufacturing in
Reenen. 2012. The Organization of Firms across Africa: Targeted Policies to Enhance Private Invest-
Countries. Quarterly Journal of Economicss 127 ment and Create Jobs. Washington, DC: World
(4): 1663705. Bank.
Briceo-Garmendia, Cecilia, and Vivien Foster, eds. Djankov, Simeon. 2009. The Regulation of Entry:
2010. Africas Infrastructure: A Time for Transfor- A Survey. World Bank Research Observer 24 (2):
mation. Washington, DC: World Bank. 183203.
Cadot, Olivier, Leonardo Iacovone, Martha Denisse Djankov, Simeon, Caroline Freund, and Cong S.
Pierola, and Ferdinand Rauch. 2013. Success Pham. 2010. Trading on Time. Review of Eco-
and Failure of African Exporters. Journal of nomics and Statistics 92 (1): 16673.
Development Economics 101 (C): 28496. Dollar, David, Mary Hallward-Driemeier, and Taye
Chari, Amalavoyal V. 2011. Identifying the Aggre- Mengistae. 2005. Investment Climate and Firm
gate Productivity Effects of Entry and Size Performance in Developing Economies. Eco-
Restrictions: An Empirical Analysis of License nomic Development and Cultural Change 54 (1):
Reform in India. American Economic Journal: 131.
Economic Policyy 3 (2): 6696. Dutz, Mark, Sergio Kannebley, Maira Scarpelli, and
Cingano, Federico, and Paolo Pinotti. 2012. Trust, Siddharth Sharma. 2012. Measuring Intangible
Firm Organization, and the Structure of Produc- Capital in an Emerging Market Economy: An
tion. Working Paper 2012-133, Bocconi Univer- Application to Brazil. Policy Research Working
sity, Paolo Baffi Centre on Central Banking and Paper 6142, World Bank, Washington, DC.
Financial Regulation. Eifert, Benn, Alan Gelb, and Vijaya Ramachandran.
Clarke, George R. G. 2011. Manufacturing Firms 2008. The Cost of Doing Business in Africa:
in Africa. In Performance of Manufacturing Evidence from Enterprise Survey Data. World
Firms in Africa: An Empirical Analysis, edited by Developmentt 36 (9): 153146.
Hinh T. Dinh and George R. G. Clarke, 4786. Fafchamps, Marcel, and Simon Quinn. 2012.
Washington, DC: World Bank. Results of Sample Surveys of Firms. In Per-
Collier, Paul, and Anthony J. Venables. 2007. formance of Manufacturing Firms in Africa: An
Rethinking Trade Preferences: How Africa Can Empirical Analysis, edited by Hinh T. Dinh and
Diversify Its Exports. World Economy 30 (8): George R. G. Clarke, 139211. Washington, DC:
132645. World Bank.
. 2008. Trade and Economic Performance: Fafchamps, Marcel, and Mans Soderbom. 2006.
Does Africas Fragmentation Matter? Paper pre- Wages and Labor Management in African Man-
sented at the Annual World Bank Conference on ufacturing. Journal of Human Resourcess 41 (2):
Development Economics, Cape Town, June 911. 34679.
Corrado, Carol, Charles Hulten, and Daniel Sichel. Farole, Thomas. 2011. Special Economic Zones in
2005. Measuring Capital and Technology: An Africa: Comparing Performance and Learning
Expanded Framework. In Measuring Capital in from Global Experiences. World Bank, Washing-
the New Economy: Studies in Income and Wealth, ton, DC.
Vol. 65, edited by Carol Corrado, John Haltiwan- Filmer, Deon. 2012. Challenges and Options for
ger, and Daniel Sichel, 1145. Chicago: Univer- Technical and Post-Basic Education in South
sity of Chicago Press. Africa. Policy Note, World Bank, Africa Region,
Darvas, Peter, and Robert Palmer. 2012. Technical Human Development Unit, Washington, DC.
and Vocational Skills Development in Ghana. Fisman, Ray, and Jakob Svensson. 2007. Are Cor-
World Bank, Washington, DC. ruption and Taxation Really Harmful to Growth?
De Vreyer, Philippe, and Franois Roubaud, eds. Firm-Level Evidence. Journal of Development
2013. Urban Labour Markets in Sub-Saharan Economicss 83 (1): 6375.
Raising Productivity in Africas Modern Wage Enterprises to Foster Job Growth for Youth 235

Fitzmaurice, Mike, and Olivier Hartmann. 2013. Skills, Employability, and Training for Disad-
Border-Crossing Monitoring along the North- vantaged Youth: Evidence from a Randomized
ern Corridor. SSATP Working Paper 96, World Evaluation Design. IZA Discussion Paper 6617,
Bank, Washington, DC. Institute for the Study of Labor, Bonn.
Foster, Lucia, John C. Haltiwanger, and Chad Syver- IFC (International Finance Corporation). 2013.
son. 2008. Reallocation, Firm Turnover, and IFC Job Study: Assessing Private Sector Contri-
Efficiency: Selection on Productivity or Prof- butions to Job Creation and Poverty Reduction.
itability? American Economic Revieww 98 (1): Washington, DC: IFC.
394425. Johanson, Richard K., and Arvil Van Adams. 2004.
Fujita, Masahisa, Paul Krugman, and Anthony J. Skills Development in Sub-Saharan Africa. Wash-
Venables. 1999. The Spatial Economy: Cities, ington, DC: World Bank.
Regions, and International Trade. Cambridge, Kalemli-Ozcan, Sebnem, Laura Alfaro, and Vadym
MA: MIT Press. Volosovych. 2008. Why Doesnt Capital Flow
Gelb, Alan, Christian Meyer, and Vijaya Ramach- from Rich to Poor Countries? An Empirical
andran. 2013. Does Poor Mean Cheap? A Com- Investigation. Review of Economics and Statistics
parative Look at Africas Industrial Labor Costs. 90 (2): 34768.
CGD Working Paper 325, Center for Global
Karlan, Dean, Ryan Knight, and Christopher Udry.
Development, Washington, DC.
2012. Hoping to Win, Expected to Lose: Theory
Groh, Matthew, Nandini Krishnan, David McKen- and Lessons on Micro Enterprise Development.
zie, and Tara Vishwanath. 2012. Soft Skills or Working Paper, Yale University, New Haven, CT.
Hard Cash? The Impact of Training and Wage
Kitaev, Igor, with contributions from T. Coleman,
Subsidy Program on Female Youth Employment
J. Glover, and B. Kaluba. 2002. Synthesis of Main
in Jordan. Policy Research Working Paper 6141,
Findings from Two Studies on Private Technical-
World Bank, Washington, DC.
Vocational Education and Training in Ghana and
Habyarimana, James, and Taye Mengistae. 2013. Zambia (Phase II). Draft IIEP/Prg.DA/02.365,
Labor Market Integration in Africa: Evidence International Institute for Educational Planning,
from Trading Blocks. Background paper for the Paris.
Africa Region Report on Youth Employment in
Klapper, Leora, Luc Laeven, and Raghuram Rajan.
Africa, World Bank, Washington, DC.
2006. Entry Regulation as a Barrier to Entrepre-
Hall, Robert E., and Charles I. Jones. 1999. Why neurship. Journal of Financial Economics 82 (3):
Do Some Countries Produce So Much More 591629.
Output per Worker Than Others? Quarterly
Krishna, Pravin, and Devashish Mitra. 1998. Trade
Journal of Economicss 114 (1): 83116.
Liberalization, Market Discipline, and Productiv-
Hao, Janet, and Charles R. Hulten. 2011. Intan- ity Growth: New Evidence from India. Journal of
gible Capital and the Sources of Recent Chinese Development Economicss 56 (2): 44762.
Economic Growth. Paper prepared for the Con-
Krishnan, Pramila, and Irina Shaorshadze. 2013.
ference on Research in Income and Wealth, Pro-
Technical and Vocational Education and Train-
ductivity Program Workshop, Summer Institute
ing in Ethiopia. Working Paper, International
2011, National Bureau of Economic Research,
Growth Centre, London, February.
Cambridge, MA, July 19.
Kuddo, Arvo. 2012. Public Employment, Ser-
Harrison, Ann E., Justin Yifu Lin, and L. Colin Xu.
vices, and Activation Policies. Social Protection
2013. Africas (Dis)advantage: The Curse of
and Labor Discussion Paper 1215, World Bank,
Party Monopoly. NBER Working Paper 18683,
National Bureau of Economic Research, Cam- Washington, DC.
bridge, MA. Li, Wei, Taye Mengistae, and Lixin Colin Xu. 2011.
Hicks, Joan Hamory, Michael Kremer, Isaac Mbiti, Diagnosing Development Bottlenecks: China
and Edward Miguel. 2011. Vocational Education and India. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Sta-
Voucher Delivery and Labor Market Returns: A tistics 73 (6): 72252.
Randomized Evaluation among Kenyan Youth. Lin, Justin Yifu. 2011. New Structural Econom-
Report for Spanish Impact Evaluation Fund ics: A Framework for Rethinking Development.
Phase II. World Bank Research Observerr 26 (2): 193221.
Hsieh, Chang-Tai, and Peter J. Klenow. 2009. Mis- Lin, Justin Yifu, and Clestin Monga. 2011. Growth
allocation and Manufacturing TFP in China and Identification and Facilitation: The Role of the
India. Quarterly Journal of Economicss 124 (6): State in the Dynamics of Structural Change.
140348. Development Policy Review 29 (3): 259310.
Ibarraran, Pablo, Laura Ripani, Bibiana Tapoada, Maitra, Pushkar, and Subha Mani. 2012. Learn-
Juan Miguel Villa, and Brigida Garcia. 2012. Life ing and Earning: Evidence from a Randomized
236 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Evaluation in India. Department of Econom- Rodrik, Dani. 2004. Industrial Policy for the
ics Discussion Paper 44/12, Monash University, Twenty-First Century. CEPR Discussion Paper
Melbourne. 4767, Centre for Economic Policy Research,
Mano, Yukichi, Alhassan Iddrisu, Yutaka Yoshino, London.
and Tetsushi Sonobe. 2012. How Can Micro and Rotunno, Lorenzo, Pierre-Louis Vzina, and Zheng
Small Enterprises in Sub-Saharan Africa Become Wang. 2012. The Rise and Fall of (Chinese)
More Productive? The Impacts of Experimental African Apparel Exports. CSAE Working Paper
Basic Managerial Training. World Development 2012-12, Centre for the Study of Africa Econo-
40 (3): 45868. mies, University of Oxford.
McKenzie, David, and Christoper M. Woodruff. Sachs, Jeffrey D., and Andrew M. Warner. 2001.
2013. What Are We Learning from Business The Curse of Natural Resources. European
Training and Entrepreneurship Evaluations Economic Review w 45 (4-6): 82738.
around the Developing World? World Bank
Saleman, Yannick, and Luke S. Jordan. 2013. The
Research Observer. doi: 10.1093/wbro/lkt007.
Implementation of Industrial Parks: Some
Melitz, Marc J., and Sao Polanec. 2012. Dynamic Lessons Learned in India. World Bank, Wash-
Olley-Pakes Productivity Decomposition with ington, DC.
Entry and Exit. NBER Working Paper 18182,
Sondergaard, Lars, and Mamta Murthi, with Dina
National Bureau of Economic Research, Cam-
Abu-Ghaida, Christian Bodewig, and Jan Rut-
bridge, MA.
kowski. 2012. Skills, Not Just Diplomas: Manag-
Melitz, Marc J., and Daniel Trefler. 2012. Gains ing for Results in Education Systems in Eastern
from Trade When Firms Matter. Journal of Europe and Central Asia. World Bank, Washing-
Economic Perspectivess 26 (2): 91118. ton, DC.
Mingat, Alain, Blandine Ledoux, and Ramahatra Sonobe, Tetsushi, Aya Suzuki, and Keijiro Otsuka.
Rakotomalala. 2010. Developing Post-Primary 2011. Kaizen for Managerial Skills Improvement
Education in Sub-Saharan Africa: Assessing the in Small and Medium Enterprises: An Impact
Financial Sustainability of Alternative Pathways. Evaluation Study. World Bank, Washington,
World Bank, Washington, DC. DC. http://siteresources.worldbank.org/DEC/
Monga, Clestin. 2012. Winning the Jackpot-Jobs Resources/FinalVolumeIV.pdf.
Dividend in a Multi-Polar World. Paper pre- Svensson, Jakob. 2003. Who Must Pay Bribes and
sented at the International Economics Associa- How Much? Evidence from a Cross-Section of
tionWorld Bank Roundtable, Industrial Policy Firms. Quarterly Journal of Economicss 118 (1):
in Africa, Pretoria, South Africa, July 34. 20730.
OECD (Organisation for Economic Co-operation Syverson, Chad. 2011. What Determines Produc-
and Development). 2010. Measuring Innovation: tivity? Journal of Economic Literaturee 49 (2):
A New Perspective. Paris: OECD. 32665.
Olley, Steven, and Ariel Pakes. 1996. The Dynam- Tanzania, United Republic of, and UNESCO
ics of Productivity in the Telecommunications (United Nations Educational, Scientific, and Cul-
Equipment Industry. Econometrica 64 (6): tural Organization). 2012. Management Issues
126397. in Higher, Technical, and Vocational Education
Ozier, Owen. 2013. The Impact of Secondary and Training in Tanzania. In Education Sector
Schooling in Kenya: A Regression Discontinuity Analysis: Beyond Primary Education, the Quest for
Analysis. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting Balanced and Efficient Policy Choices for Human
of the Population Association of America, New Development and Economic Growth, ch. 8, 307
Orleans, April 1113. 32. Dar es Salaam: Government of Tanzania and
UNESCO.
Pack, Howard, and Kamal Saggi. 2006. The Case
for Industrial Policy: A Critical Survey. World TESDA (Technical Education and Skills Develop-
Bank Research Observer 21 (2): 26797. ment Authority). 2012a. Metals and Engineer-
ing Sector: Supply and Demand in Computer
Piopiunik, Marc, and Paul Ryan. 2012. Improv-
Numerical Control (CNC) Machine Operation
ing the Transition between Education/Training
and Other Related TVET Qualification. Labor
and the Labour Market: What Can We Learn
Market Intelligence Report LMIR-ST-PO 03-05-
from Various National Approaches? EENEE
12, TESDA, the Philippines.
Analytical Report 13, European Expert Net-
work on Economics of Education, http://www. . 2012b. Technical Education and Skills
eenee.de/portal/page/portal/EENEEView/_ Development Monitoring and Evaluation Sys-
generische_page_eenee?content=eenee-home. tem: Towards Increasing Efficiency, Effective-
htm&language=us. ness, and Relevance of TVET in the Philippines.
Raising Productivity in Africas Modern Wage Enterprises to Foster Job Growth for Youth 237

Presentation made at the Third International . 2011c. Strengthening Skills and Employ-
Congress on Technical and Vocational Education ability in Peru: Final Report. World Bank,
and Training, Building Skills for Work and Life, Washington, DC.
Shanghai. http://www.unesco.org/education/ . 2012a. Analysis of Ugandas System of
TVET2012/roundtable/3/M-DelaRama.pdf. Business, Technical-Vocational Education and
Udry, Christopher R., and Santosh Anagol. 2006. Training (BTVET). World Bank, Washington,
The Return to Capital in Ghana. Discussion DC.
Paper 932. Yale University, Economic Growth . 2012b. Doing Business 2013: Smarter Regu-
Center, New Haven, CT. SSRN: http://ssrn.com/ lations for Small and Medium-Size Enterprises.
abstract=893023. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Wood, Adrian, and Kersti Berge. 1997. Export- . 2012c. Financing Small- and Medium-
ing Manufactures: Human Resources, Natural Sized Enterprises in Rwanda. World Bank,
Resources, and Trade Policy. Journal of Develop- Washington, DC.
ment Studiess 34 (1): 3559.
. 2012d. World Development Report 2013:
Wood, Adrian, and Jrg Mayer. 2001. Africas Jobs. New York: Oxford University Press.
Export Structure in a Comparative Perspective.
Cambridge Journal of Economicss 25 (3): 36994. . 2013a. Africas Pulsee 7 (April). World Bank,
Washington, DC.
World Bank. 2004. An Assessment of the Invest-
ment Climate in Zambia. World Bank, Washing- . 2013b. Tanzania Economic Update,
ton, DC. Opening the Gates: How the Modernization of
the Port of Dar es Salaam Can Transform
. 2008. Finance for All? Policies and Pitfalls in Tanzania. Report 77729, World Bank, Washing-
Expanding Access. Policy Research Report 41972, ton, DC.
World Bank, Washington, DC.
World Economic Forum. 2012. The Global Com-
. 2009. Zambia: Second Investment Cli- petitiveness Report 20122013: Full Data Edition.
mate Assessment; Business Environment Issues Geneva: World Economic Forum.
in Diversifying Growth. Vols. 1 and 2. World
Bank, Washington, DC. Xu, Lixin Colin. 2011. The Effects of Business
Environments on Development: A Survey of
. 2010. The Business Environment in New Firm-Level Evidence. World Bank Research
Southern Africa: Issues in Trade and Market Observerr 26 (2): 31040.
Integration. Vols. s 1 and 2. World Bank,
Washington, DC. Zeng, Douglas. 2006. Knowledge, Technology,
and Cluster-based Growth in Africa: Findings
. 2011a. Botswana: Skills for Economic from Eleven Case Studies of Enterprise Clusters
Diversification and Economic Growth. World in Africa. Knowledge for Development
Bank, Washington, DC. (K4D) Program, World Bank Institute,
. 2011b. Doing Business 2012: Doing Business Washington, DC.
in a More Transparent World. Washington, DC:
World Bank.
FOCUS Youth Unemployment
Financial Inclusion andinthe
South
Transition
Africa:to
NOTE 4
3 Sustainable
Different Configuration,
Livelihoods for
Different
Young People
Approaches

S
outh Africas labor marketunlike most productionat the expense of low-skilled
others in Sub-Saharan Africahas a high workers and of industries that use low-skilled
share of wage employment off the farm, labor intensively (Mengistae 2011). While
very little employment in household enterprises South Africas industry has become more com-
(HEs), and an even smaller share of employ- petitive over the last decade, it remains less
ment in agriculture (4.5 percent). South Africa competitive than that of many trading part-
also stands apart from other African countries ners. Stringent labor market regulations are
in having a high unemployment rate, estimated typically put forward as the primary cause of
at 25 percent (based on a narrow definition of high unemployment. Yet close scrutiny of the
unemployment) in 2012. evidence suggests that the story is not just
High unemployment is nothing new in about labor market rigidities. Deficiencies in
South Africa, which had an unemployment rate economic growth, coupled with the rapidly
of 39 percent in 2005, compared to 17 percent growing working-age population, are major
in Africas other upper-middle-income coun- contributors to high unemployment in South
tries. At 51 percent, unemployment among Africa.
those ages 1524 was twice the national aver- By many standards, South Africa has
age in 2012. South Africas high rate of youth rigid labor market laws and high barriers to
unemployment reflects the high rate of unem- entry in the HE sector. The minimum wage
ployment throughout the country, which is imposed by the regulations is high, so the
worsened by circumstances specific to youth. ratio of minimum to median wage is 1.52 for
Especially unique is the combination of unskilled workers and can go as high as 2.66
high unemployment and a very small HE sec- in some sectors (Bhorat, Kanbur, and Mayet
tor. The ratio of HE employment to unem- 2011). High unionization and the use of
ployment in South Africa was estimated to be wage bargaining councils raise wages further:
0.300.48 in 2012, which is much smaller than conservative estimates show that union jobs
the ratio in middle-income countries of Asia enjoy a wage premium of at least 17 percent.
and Latin America (11 and 7, respectively) or As a result, the labor market is segmented.
other countries in Sub-Saharan Africa (4.7). Well-paying nonfarm wage jobs occupy the
In South Africa, residual labor is not absorbed upper end of the spectrum, and a pool of the
by the informal sector, as it is in other African unemployed, queuing for wage jobs, occupies
countries or even in middle-income countries the lower end. High barriers to entry in the
elsewhere in the world. In South Africa, larger HE sectorcreated mainly by stringent local
domestic firms occupy the space that HEs government by-laws, limited access to capital,
occupy in many other African countries. and poor entrepreneurial skillsensure that
very few of those who fail to get a wage job
join the nonfarm HE sector. Consequently,
Conventional Perceptions of the a high level of open unemployment coexists
Causes of Unemployment with a small informal sector that cannot be
explained by high reservation wages among
High wage levels and high real unit labor costs the unemployed (Kingdon and Knight 2004;
played a part in dampening the demand for Mitra 2010).
labor and encouraging industry to shift into Yet the contribution of labor market rigidi-
238 more capital-intensive modes and sectors of ties to unemployment appears exaggerated.
Focus Note 4 239

An employment wage elasticity of 0.7 sug- not only from the structure of growth but also
gests that minimum wage laws and the wage from its slow pace in relation to demographic
premiums exacted by unions and bargaining trends. Most of the growth in employment
councils do reduce employment, but the size between 1995 and 2005 was in skilled employ-
of the elasticity also implies that wage rigidi- ment, which grew 22 percent, while unskilled
ties only partially explain why unemployment employment declined 13 percent (figure F4.1,
is so high. It is important to note that viola- panel a). Demand for unskilled labor is weak
tion of minimum wage requirements is high at a time when the unskilled labor force is
in South Africa, reaching 50 percent in 2007 expanding significantly. Owing to this pattern
(Bhorat, Kanbur, and Mayet 2011). Violations of skills-biased growth, a great scarcity of skills
are highest in sectors where minimum wages exists alongside high unemployment among
are higher, suggesting that minimum wages are the unskilled.
only moderately binding. Revised estimates In the decade between 1995 and 2005, prior
of the unionization premium are also much to the global financial crisis, the employment
smaller than previous estimates (Bhorat, Goga, elasticity of growth (ranging from 0.6 to 0.8)
and van der Westhuizen 2012). Indeed, recent and growth of gross domestic product (GDP)
estimates indicate that wage rigidities account were comparable in South Africa and other
for only 1 percentage point of unemployment middle-income countries, except for China and
in South Africa (Magruder 2012). India. Population growth was not comparable,
however. Rapid population growth reduced
growth per capita in South Africa compared
The Real Unemployment Problem: to other middle-income countries (figure F4.1,
Slow Growth panel b). South Africas labor force grew 46 per-
cent between 1995 and 2005, outstripping the
To a larger extent, South Africas unemploy- 29 percent growth in employment. Growth in
ment problem is a growth problem, arising the labor force was propelled by an increase in

Figure F4.1 Patterns in economic and employment growth in South Africa

a. Employment growth by skill category, 19952005 b. GDP growth in South Africa and other countries
25
Argentina

20 Brazil

Botswana
15
Chile
10
China
Percent

5 India

Indonesia
0
Malaysia
5 Poland

10 Turkey

South Africa
15
Skilled Semi-skilled Unskilled Middle-income
countries
Upper-middle-income
countries
0 2 4 6 8 10 12
Percent
Per capita growth GDP growth

Sources: World Bank 2011; Bhorat, Kanbur, and Mayet 2011.


240 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

labor force participation as well as population Improve the Targeting and Design of
growth. Labor force participation rose 11 per- Wage Subsidies
centage points between 1997 and 2005, mostly Subsidies are expected to stimulate labor
because post-apartheid norms enabled greater demand by mitigating the impact of high mini-
involvement in economic activity, especially mum wages, union premiums, or high reser-
among women. At the same time, the share vation wages. Subsidies may not have much of
of the working-age population expanded by 6 an effect on demand for labor in South Africa,
percentage points between 1990 and 2010. The however, because it is difficult to substitute
high unemployment that accompanied growth unskilled for skilled labor (Go et al. 2010).
in the working-age population is one indica- Subsidies may serve only to move those who
tion that South Africas demographic dividend are currently employed into other jobs, and
did not materialize. their effects may well be temporary. High vio-
lation of the minimum wage law in sectors with
the highest minimum wage ratios will further
Inefficient Job Search and reduce the impact of wage subsidies.
Matching Processes Wage subsidies might be more effective
if they target sectors where the response will
For young people in particular, the effects be higher and are designed to reduce the dis-
of South Africas oversubscribed market for placement of workers from one job to another.
unskilled labor are amplified by frictions in job Although preliminary evidence from an impact
search and matching. The quality of unskilled evaluation in South Africa showed that the wage
labor is extremely varied, and unskilled work- subsidy program increased the probability of
ers low level of education offers little indica- getting and keeping employment, a negligible
tion of their real ability to prospective employ- proportion of employers claimed the subsidy.
ers. Firms also face high hiring and firing costs This finding suggests that the real impact of
owing to tight regulations. To minimize hiring the subsidy was that it improved the efficiency
costs, firms tend to hire unskilled labor through of search and matching instead of reducing
word of mouth and other nonpublic advertise- the real wage that the employer would have to
ments; to screen for productivity, they rely on pay. The general finding is that although youth
referrals. For young people, with their limited wage subsidies may have a positive impact,
experience, inability to signal their real apti- their efficacy is conditioned by other labor
tude, poor connections, and poor information market conditions, such as the flexibility of the
on job openings, the job search can become labor market. A youth wage subsidy is just one
very long and demoralizing, and the age at instrumentof manyto tackle youth unem-
which they obtain their first wage job will con- ployment. If wage rigidities prove to be the
tinue to increase. primary cause of unemployment, eliminating
labor rigidities would be a longer-term solution
to the problem. If overall labor demand is low,
Policies to Reduce Unemployment then it will need to increase.

Various policies have been pursued and pro- Provide Incentives for Labor-Intensive
posed to reduce unemployment in South Growth
Africa. Popular proposals on the demand Public works programs have not significantly
side include wage subsidies, labor regulation improved employment in South Africa, based
reform, and public works; on the supply side, on evidence from the Expanded Public Works
they include reforms in education and train- Program (McCord 2007). A better alternative
ing systems, as well as support for entrepre- is to implement national policies that not only
neurship. What might be done to improve the increase the pace of economic growth but also
potential for such strategies to workespe- create incentives for labor-intensive firms to
cially for youth? form and to locate near the pool of labor
Focus Note 4 241

for example, by establishing special economic licensing may work in the opposite direction by
zones (as discussed in chapter 6) or offering increasing the administrative burden for HEs
fiscal incentives favorable to labor-intensive (as well as small and medium enterprises).
industries.
References
Reform Education and Training Systems Bhorat, Haroon, Sumayya Goga, and Carlene
van der Westhuizen. 2012. Institutional Wage
South Africas long-term employment issues Effects: Revisiting Union and Bargaining Coun-
cannot be addressed without reforms in edu- cil Wage Premia in South Africa. South African
cation and training systems. Such reforms can Journal of Economicss 80 (3): 40014.
help to improve the productivity of the labor Bhorat, Haroon, Ravi Kanbur, and Natasha Mayet.
pool, narrow the wide gap between the skills 2011. The Determinants of Minimum Wage
that the labor market demands and workers Violation in South Africa. Working Paper WP
can supply, and increase the signaling ability 2011-05, Cornell University, Charles H. Dyson
School of Applied Economics and Management,
of education, which, in turn, will improve the Ithaca, NY.
search and matching efficiency of the labor
Botha, M., G. H. Nieman, and J. J. van Vuuren.
market. 2006. Evaluating the Women Entrepreneurship
The technical and vocational education Training Programme: A South African Study.
and training (TVET) system is plagued by low International Indigenous Journal of Entrepreneur-
enrollment, low completion, and low prob- ship, Advancement, Strategy, and Education 2 (1):
ability of finding employment, but it could be n.p. http://www.indigenousjournal.com/read.
html.
improved by reforms that strengthen basic edu-
cation (an area where South Africa performs Filmer, Deon. 2012. Challenges and Options for
Technical and Post-Basic Education in South
poorly). South Africa would also benefit from Africa. Policy Note, World Bank, Africa Region,
restructuring the further education and train- Human Development Unit, Washington, DC.
ing (FET) system to permit part-time learning Go, Delfin S., Marna Kearney, Vijdan Korman,
(which would make FET more flexible and Sherman Robinson, and Karen Thierfelder. 2010.
accessible) and to introduce apprenticeships Wage Subsidy and Labour Market Flexibility in
and closer engagement with industry (which South Africa. Journal of Development Studiess 46
would make FET more relevant to the work- (9): 1481502.
place). Sector education and training authori- Kingdon, Geeta Gandhi, and John Knight. 2004.
Unemployment in South Africa: The Nature of
ties should have a simplified bureaucracy, move
the Beast. World Developmentt 32 (3): 391408.
to demand-driven financing, and delegate
Magruder, Jeremy R. 2012. High Unemployment
training to the most competent institutions yet Few Small Firms: The Role of Centralized
using a performance-based financing approach Bargaining in South Africa. American Economic
(see discussion in Filmer 2012). Journal: Applied Economicss 4 (3): 13866.
McCord, Anna. 2007. Training within the South
Revise By-Laws and Offer Focused African National Public Works Programme.
In Human Resources Development Review 2008:
Training to Support Entrepreneurial Education, Employment, and Skills in South
Activities Africa, edited by Andre Kraak and Karen Press.
South Africa should make it easier for young Cape Town: HSRC Press.
people to become self-employed by intro- Mengistae, Taye. 2011. Are South African Wages
ducing by-laws that are compatible with Too High or Growing Too Fast? A Compari-
self-employment and by offering financial son of Manufacturing Pay and Productivity in
Selected Middle-Income Economies. World
support. Although international evidence is
Bank, Washington, DC.
generally mixed, the evidence on the impact
Mitra, Sophie. 2010. Disability Cash Transfers in
of the Women Entrepreneurship Programme the Context of Poverty and Unemployment:
in South Africa suggests that well-structured The Case of South Africa. World Developmentt 38
entrepreneurship training would enhance suc- (12): 1692709.
cess (Botha, Nieman, and van Vuuren 2006). World Bank. 2011. World Development Indicators.
Current proposals to strengthen business Washington, DC: World Bank.
Chapter

Conclusion: Building an Effective


Youth Employment Policy

The challenge of youth employment in Sub- and demographic profile. For that reason, this
Saharan Africa is not amenable to simple solu- report has emphasized short- and medium-term
tions. It reflects the intricate web of challenges strategies that will address current challenges
and opportunities that links all countries in a while laying a foundation for the employment
globalized world. For Africa now, the key employ- agenda to succeed in the long run.
ment issue is that productivityand therefore
earningsin many jobs is low, while aspira-
tions, especially among young people, are high A Programmatic Approach
and rising. Despite progress in many countries,
most of Africas young people will not have an Unemployment, which is typically low in
easy or structured transition to a sustainable low- and lower-middle-income countries, is
livelihood, one of the core aspects of adulthood. just the tip of the iceberg. Most Africans can-
All stakeholders have a role to play in supporting not afford to be unemployed. They work, but
this transition. they earn little for that work. The challenge of
Most African countries endorse the medium- youth employment requires a comprehensive
to long-term agenda to increase employment approach designed to relieve the constraints
in the nonfarm modern wage sectorin other that prevent young people and the private sec-
words, to bring about a structural transforma- tor from seizing opportunities and increasing
tion of their economies. If Africa follows Asias productivity in agriculture, household enter-
model, this effort will rely primarily on expand- prises, and the modern wage sector. Govern-
ing export-oriented manufacturing, with its high ments need to adopt a holistic view of how to
requirements for labor. But even as governments address the situationthey need to own the
embark on policies to foster such a transforma- whole problem.
tion, they increasingly recognize that the process There is a common tendency to believe that
will take time, given Africas small industrial base government-provided training in technical

243
244 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

and vocational skills will suffice to unlock the Rising to the youth employment challenge
potential of youth. However, such action, by requires two kinds of action. Governments
itself, will not address the more fundamental must act now for the short term, by addressing
problems that prevent young people from find- the immediate constraints that hold youth back
ing better opportunities. The gap in technical from finding higher-productivity work. They
skills is only one facet of the youth employment also must act now for the medium term, by tak-
challenge. A comprehensive approach to tack- ing decisions and actions now so that the chal-
ling the challenge will address constraints on lenge of youth employment is easier to address
both the human capital as well as the business in the future (table 7.1).
environment sides of the problem.
As an overall principle, it is important to
recognize that youths will find their opportuni- Do Now for Now: Address the
ties in the private sector, whether in agriculture,
household enterprises, or the modern wage
Constraints Facing Households
sector. Governments should focus on provid- and Firms
ing public goods and services that support pro-
ductivity in both household economic activity Priorities to Get Youth into Productive
and enterprise economic activity. Government Household Economic Activities
should be an enabler for job creation. Both farm and nonfarm household enter-
A key enabling action is to ensure that each prises suffer from financial exclusion. Lifting
cohort of youth entering the workforce has a barriers to credit, financing, and savings vehi-
solid foundation of skills acquired through cles will support greater productivityand
basic education. In addition to getting children growthin the agricultural and nonagricul-
to attend school, a critical priority is to ensure tural sectors. Improving access to credit and
that substantial learning occurs while they are financing is important for financial inclusion,
in school. Given the growing evidence that but the key is to facilitate saving. Saving can
social and behavioral skills are important for be fostered through local savings groups and
productivity, education systems could consider mobile money (especially attractive to youth),
instilling such skills in combination with the as well as the more established banking sector.
other, more traditional, cognitive skills. Mechanisms for saving, which help to build
The defining feature of youth is that it is a the habit of saving, will increase the funds
time of transitions, but youth in Africa are not available for investing and enable mobilizing
finding well-marked pathways to stable and additional financing.
productive livelihoods. While efforts should
help all youth to make the transition, specific
groups will face particular challenges along the Priorities for Agriculture
way. For example, increasing young womens Policies need to enable rural youth to access
empowerment by increasing their agency land. Approaches could include increasing
their control over their own destinieshas been the security of tenure, ownership, and sales
shown to reduce negative outcomes such as to encourage fluid land markets to develop.
early pregnancy and exposure to human immu- Strategies will involve reducing the cost of land
nodeficiency virus/acquired immunodeficiency transfer, promoting rental markets, encourag-
syndrome (HIV/AIDS) and to have positive ing youth-sensitive land redistribution, and
impacts on their earnings. And new approaches promoting youth-focused administration of
should be tried. The new communication tech- communal or government land.
nologies that are spreading throughout Africa New approaches to agricultural extension
(and that hold so much appeal for youth) offer promise to overcome previous shortcomings.
innovative options for government to reach To expand the repertoire of agricultural skills
youth with messages, to help them to shape and increase access to information, these high-
their employment aspirations, and to help quality, demand-driven extension programs
youth learn about employment opportunities. should target youth.
Conclusion: Building an Effective Youth Employment Policy 245

Table 7.1 Priority actions to take now to address the youth employment challenge
Do now for now: Do now for later:
Area for intervention Actions to affect the current cohort of youth Actions to affect future cohorts of youth
Agriculture 1. Enable rental markets for land 1. Establish effective land registration and transaction systems
2. Pilot intergenerational land transfer programs 2. Scale up intergenerational land transfer programs, based on
lessons from pilot programs
3. Support high-quality, demand-driven extension services (covering
information as well as skills) 3. Mainstream youth into smart interventions aimed at increasing
productivity (producer organizations, livestock development,
4. Link agricultural credit to extension services
irrigation, and others)
4. Build skills through rapid improvements in education systems in
rural areas
Agriculture and household 5. Promote rural village savings and loan associations and self-help
enterprises groups
6. Enable financial inclusion for households
7. Use safety net programs as a platform to deliver interventions to
disadvantaged youth
Household enterprises 8. Develop a national strategy for household enterprises that reflects 5. Build foundational skills through rapid improvements in education
the voice of their ownship and youth systems
9. Ensure access to workspace and infrastructure for household 6. Address infrastructure needs of household enterprises in urban
enterprises through improved urban policy development planning
10. Leverage nongovernmental organizations to deliver interventions
that support disadvantaged youth to enter the sector by
addressing multiple constraints (building a range of skills together,
building skills along with providing access to finance)
Modern wage sector 11. Reduce the cost of infrastructure services by addressing quality 7. Increase the quantity of infrastructure services
and efficiency
8. Expand regional markets for products
12. Address logistics bottlenecks
9. Build foundational skills through rapid improvements in education
13. Reduce corruption and the cost of business start-up systems
14. Reform technical and vocational education and training and pursue 10. Improve access to credit through financial sector reform
public-private partnerships for delivering demand-driven training
Cross-cutting areas 15. Increase awareness of opportunities and pathways to self- 11. Promote early child development and nutrition to build a stronger
employment, especially for young women foundation for skills development
16. Consider second-chance education for basic skills 12. Build behavioral skills (consider reforms within the school system)
13. Reduce fertility rates to lower the size of future youth cohorts
(through more girls education, improved maternal and child
health, increased access to family planning)
14. Build better employment data and a stronger evidence base to
identify country constraints, priorities, and opportunities

Smart interventions to raise productiv- voice of those working in the HE sector to be


ity, such as effective producer organizations, heard. When the needs of HE owners cannot
improved livestock production systems, or be expressed and channeled, it is not surpris-
sustainable irrigation and water management, ing that policy makers and politicians neglect
should mainstream youth. Projects should nei- to cater to those needs.
ther treat youth as an enclave nor ignore them. To ensure that HEs can be established and
operate legally and productively, urban policies
Priorities for Household Enterprises should provide adequate locations where HEs
A first step in most countries is to develop a can work and sell their products. In addition,
national strategy for household enterprises smart urban planning should provide access to
(HEs), because at present they are ignored, if essential support services for HEs, such as light-
not suppressed. Such a strategy will involve ing, water, sanitation, and effective security.
working with local governments as a part of Because a very large share of Africas new
urbanization and local economic development nonfarm employment opportunities will need
efforts. In addition to developing plans, the to come from individual self-employment,
strategy should explicitly develop a way for the projects should encourage youth to navigate a
246 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

successful transition to starting up and operat- transportation and other infrastructure, cus-
ing an HE. Depending on the individual and toms, and border control.
sector, this assistance may include support for Another priority is to develop and sustain a
developing a range of skills (behavioral, life, policy environment that enables the most pro-
technical, and business skills) as well as access ductive firms to enter and grow. Here, the vital
to finance for starting a business. Integrated steps include improving access to finance and
approaches that address multiple constraints land, removing barriers to entry, and reducing
simultaneously are promising. the cost of corruption.
Governments should leverage nongovern- The poor quality and scarcity of infrastruc-
mental organizations (NGOs) and steer them ture services clearly inhibit competitiveness,
to support young people who are well placed to but the best immediate solution is not neces-
enter the HE sector. Such support can involve sarily to provide more infrastructure. Strategies
NGOs in delivering integrated approaches to must pay attention to the cost and quality of
removing productivity constraints, with a focus infrastructure services. Better serviceselec-
on poorer youth. Working through NGOs tricity, roads, or ports, for examplemight be
is attractive, because often they can be more provided with existing infrastructure coupled
flexible, community driven, and responsive with better policy and organization. Incentives
to clients than other service providers. Even matter for turning the available infrastructure
so, government financing for NGOs to deliver into effective infrastructure services.
integrated programs for youth should be per- Throughout Africa, the private sector
formance based, with payment linked to the provides a wide range of vocational train-
successful delivery of services that demonstrate ing opportunities. The public sector should
beneficial impact. provide post-school training programs only
Safety net programs (such as those that to carefully targeted groups. When such pro-
transfer cash or livestock assets) are proving grams are undertaken, public-private partner-
to be powerful tools for poor areas and poor ships help to ensure that training is aligned
people to improve their standard of living with business needs. Directly integrating firms
and support productive investments. These into the training is an additional way to facili-
programs can support youth in making the tate the transition to employment. Programs
transition into productive activity (within should not simply displace adult workers and
or outside agriculture) through integrated substitute young workers.
approaches, such as programs combining
public works or transfers with life skills train-
ing, especially if the overall business environ- Do Now for Later: Take Action
ment is conducive. Monitoring and careful for Medium-Term Payoffs
evaluation are essential to identify the most
cost-effective approaches. As governments identify and implement poli-
cies to make their young and growing work-
Priorities to Create More and Better force more productive in the near term, they
Wage and Salary Jobs in Firms must also start to take action on policies that
If the overall number of jobs in the modern will yield payoffs in the medium term. First and
wage sector grows, youth will benefit. Because foremost, many countries will need to reduce
export-oriented manufacturing has the greatest fertility rates more rapidly. Countries that have
potential to generate employment in the wage larger working-age populations in relation to
and salary sector, the first priority is to remove their non-working-age populations will experi-
binding constraints to export competitiveness. ence the most rapid gains in productivity and
Governments will need to address elements investment.
of the business environment that reduce pro- Countries that move urgently to improve
ductivity at the factory level and well beyond their education systems will also gain a sub-
the factory gates, such as constraints related to stantial advantage. Given the size of the cohorts
Conclusion: Building an Effective Youth Employment Policy 247

coming into Africas education systems, no True regional integration that removes the
country can afford to retain an education limitations of Africas relatively small domestic
system that fails to instill the skills to pursue markets for goods and services will require a
a stable livelihood. Underperforming educa- series of efforts that reinforce one another. And
tion systems not only are inefficient but also the payoff from some of these reforms may also
condemn large parts of another generation to take time to materialize, as investors and entre-
poverty. At the same time, children must be preneurs wait to be certain that reforms have
ready to learn when they come to school. Steps taken hold before they step in. But changes
to build the foundation for effective educa- should start today.
tion must be taken in early childhoodsuch At its core, the challenge of youth employ-
as steps to improve the nutrition and cogni- ment is closely aligned with the challenge of
tive development of children under age five. inclusive growth, defined not only as growth
Deficiencies in skills have restricted growth in in which the poorest segments of society share,
productivity in the past, and they will remain a but also as growth in which young peoples
constraint if changes are not made. vitality is harnessed and rewarded. For Afri-
Addressing business environment con- can countries meeting this challenge, the ben-
straints to the creation of more and better efits will build progressively on each other.
jobs in the modern wage sector is a long-term The demographic dividend will start to yield
endeavor that will require sustained effort. results, and Africas prosperity will grow and
Reforming land or financial markets takes time. be shared.
Appendix

A Note on Data

Standardized and Harmonized actual underlying population. The last survey


Household and Labor Force Data from each country was used to create overall
aggregates.
Many of the figures used in this report are In addition to these standardized and har-
based on data from standardized and har- monized data sets for the Sub-Saharan Africa
monized household and labor force surveys. region, the authors selectively analyzed data
The data presented in these figures are derived from the World Bank Research Departments
from the authors analysis of the World Bank International Income Distribution Database
Africa Regions standardized and harmonized (I2D2). This is a compilation by the World
data sets. This standardization was carried Bank Research Department of household and
out under the Survey-Based Harmonized labor force surveys from around the world.
Indicators Program (SHIP), augmented with
similarly standardized and harmonized labor
force surveys (SHIP-LF). These are listed in Demographic and Health Survey
table A.1. Data
The labor force participation variables were
standardized and harmonized across these sur- Certain figures are based on analysis of Demo-
veys so that the data could be aggregated in a graphic and Health Survey data. These data are
meaningful way. When aggregated, population available from www.measuredhs.com. Coun-
weights were used so the data from each survey tries and years used in the analysis are pre-
contribute to the aggregate in proportion to the sented in table A.2.

249
250 YOUTH EMPLOYMENT IN SUB-SAHARAN AFRICA

Table A.1 Standardized and Harmonized Household and Labor Force Surveys
used in report analysis
Country Type of survey Year Last year
Cameroon SHIP 2001
SHIP 2007 x
Comoros SHIP 2004 x
Cte dIvoire SHIP 2002
SHIP 2008 x
Ethiopia SHIP-LF 2005 x
Ghana SHIP 1991
SHIP 1998
SHIP 2005 x
Kenya SHIP 2005 x
Malawi SHIP 2004 x
Mozambique SHIP 2003
SHIP 2008 x
Niger SHIP 2005 x
Nigeria SHIP 2004
SHIP 2010 x
Rwanda SHIP 2005
SHIP 2010 x
So Tom and Prncipe SHIP 2000
SHIP 2010 x
Senegal SHIP 2001
SHIP 2005 x
Sierra Leone SHIP 2003 x
Tanzania SHIP-LF 2006 x
Uganda SHIP 2005
SHIP 2010 x
Zambia SHIP 2010 x
A Note on Data 251

Table A.2 Demographic and Health Survey Data Sets used in report analysis

Transitionsa
Education
Country Year Female Male profileb

Benin 2006 x x x
Burkina Faso 2010 x x x
Burundi 2010 x x x
Central African Republic 1994 x x
Cameroon 2011 x x x
Chad 2004 x x x
Congo, Rep. 2005 x x
Cte dIvoire 2005 x x
Congo, Dem. Rep. 2007 x x
Ethiopia 2011 x x x
Gabon 2000 x x x
Ghana 2008 x x x
Guinea 2005 x x
Kenya 2008 x x x
Lesotho 2009 x x x
Liberia 2007 x x x
Madagascar 2008 x x x
Malawi 2010 x x
Mali 2006 x x x
Mauritania 2000 x x
Mozambique 2003 x x x
Namibia 2006 x x x
Niger 2006 x x x
Nigeria 2008 x x x
Rwanda 2010 x x x
So Tom and Prncipe 2008 x x
Senegal 2010 x x x
Sierra Leone 2008 x x x
South Africa 1998 x
Swaziland 2006 x x x
Tanzania 2010 x x x
Togo 1998 x
Uganda 2011 x x x
Zambia 2007 x x x
Zimbabwe 2010 x x x
a. Chapter 2.
b. Chapter 3.
ECO-AUDIT
Environmental Benefits Statement

The World Bank is committed to preserving Saved:d


endangered forests and natural resources. 10 trees
The Office of the Publisher has chosen to 5 million Btu of
print Youth Employment in Sub-Saharan total energy
Africa on recycled paper with 50 percentt 879 lbs of net
postconsumer fiber in accordance with the greenhouse gases
recommended standards for paper usage sett 4,767 gal. of waste
by the Green Press Initiative, a nonprofit pro- water
gram supporting publishers in using fiberr 320 lb. of solid
that is not sourced from endangered forests. waste
For more information, visit www.greenpress
initiative.org.

You might also like