You are on page 1of 6

American Economic Association

Intrinsic Motivation and Incentives


Author(s): Canice Prendergast
Source: The American Economic Review, Vol. 98, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the One
Hundred Twentieth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association (May, 2008),
pp. 201-205
Published by: American Economic Association
Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/29730020
Accessed: 24-06-2017 10:00 UTC

REFERENCES
Linked references are available on JSTOR for this article:
http://www.jstor.org/stable/29730020?seq=1&cid=pdf-reference#references_tab_contents
You may need to log in to JSTOR to access the linked references.

JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted
digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about
JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org.

Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at
http://about.jstor.org/terms

American Economic Association is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to The
American Economic Review

This content downloaded from 193.226.62.221 on Sat, 24 Jun 2017 10:00:15 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
American Economic Review: Papers & Proceedings 2008, 98:2, 201-205
http://www. aeaweb.org/articles.php?doi=10.1257/aer. 98.2.201

WORK INCENTIVES, MOTIVATION, AND IDENTITY*

Intrinsic Motivation and Incentives

By Canice Prendergast*

Workers act in the interests of their employ? The reason for this is rather simple?that jobs
ers for a host of reasons. Sometimes money is within firms are specialized. So, for example,
the motivation, but often it is because they care some people make things, others design them,
about what they do. Despite the importance of yet other sell them, and so on. Similarly, aca?
such intrinsic motivation, the economic litera? demics do research, deans raise money, admin?
ture has offered little in terms of understanding istrators do the books, social workers provide
relevant trade-offs when alignment of inherent services to clients while their superiors are
preferences (rather than monetary interests) is charged with cost control, etc. The principal
what motivates people.1 Instead, the literature novelty of this paper is to show how hiring
has focused largely on the efficiency gains that practices?and specifically the intrinsic moti?
arise from agents sharing the preferences of their vation of those hired?changes as the ability
employers.2 This paper offers such a theory of to contract worsens in a world where tasks are
intrinsic motivation, where firms partially solve specialized. In doing so, it paints a picture of
agency problems by hiring agents with particu? firms responding to noncontractibility by hiring
lar preferences. Unlike the previous literature, agents with very extreme interests, at the cost of
I show that firms, in general, hire agents who their ignoring other aspects of their jobs. So, for
do not share their interests?instead, agents are example, if the output of a social worker cannot
disproportionately motivated to carry out a sub? be measured, a natural response will be to hire
set of what the firm cares about. Specifically, agents who are highly motivated to get benefits
I show that the institution hires the agent with to clients, at the cost of their ignoring things like
similar preferences to himself only in the limit? cost control. Simple though this observation is,
ing case where the agent's preferences are irrel? it illustrates a cost to using intrinsic motiva?
evant?namely, when output can be perfectly tion?namely, the endogenous hiring of those
contracted on. Instead, the optimal response of who increasingly care only about one aspect of
the institution is to hire biased agents, with the their job. In this way, the simple model outlined
degree of bias increasing as contracting mea? here lays the foundation for a view of "poor
sures get worse. contracting" firms as fiefdoms, where those
with extreme competing interests reside, a point
* Discussant: Robert Gibbons, Massachusetts Institute
of Technology.
I elaborate on elsewhere (Prendergast 2008).
For a theory of intrinsic motivation to be use?
* Graduate School of Business, University of Chicago, ful, firms must have some control over it. The
1101 East 58th Street, Chicago, IL 60637 (e-mail: canice.
prendergast@gsb.uchicago.edu). Any errors are my own. central assumption here is that firms have some
Thanks to Bob Gibbons for very helpful comments. ability to hire employees based on these intrin?
1 The idea that something other than money must moti? sic preferences. I build a model of an institution
vate people seems clear, a point often made in studies of the
that carries out two activities?say, service pro?
public sector. For example, even the US Post Office?an
institution with little link between employee performance
vision and cost control. It employs two agents
and pay?has on-time delivery rates of mail in the region to do so. The tasks are somewhat specialized,
of 98 percent. See Charles Goodsell (1998) for a review of in that one agent primarily (but not exclusively)
this literature.
does service provision and the other primarily
2 For the relevant literature, see Mathias Dewatripont,
does cost control. The institution has an objec?
Ian Jewitt, and Jean Tir?le (1999), Bruno Frey and Reto
Jegen (2001), Roland Benabou and Jean Tir?le (2003), tive that trades off these two components and has
George Akerlof and Rachel Kranton (2005), Tim Besley a performance measure that can reward agents.
and Maitreesh Ghatak (2005) and Prendergast (2007). The firm also chooses whom to hire. Potential
201

This content downloaded from 193.226.62.221 on Sat, 24 Jun 2017 10:00:15 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
202 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MAY 2008

hires have preferences over outcomes, and the between the two efforts. Specifically, while all
firm can recruit based on these preferences. It is effort by agent a on task 1 increases the returns
in the context of this setup that bias arises. solely of activity A, effort on task 2 has shared
benefit. Specifically, a fraction x of e2 benefits
I. Model the activity in which the agent is engaged, while
the remaining (1 - jc) benefits the other activ?
Consider an institution that carries out two ity. The most natural interpretation of this is that
tasks, A and B. The institution employs two agents activity 2 involves cost containment, which has
to carry out these tasks. The agents are partially benefits across the entire organization as cost
specialized, in that one agent (agent a) primar? savings are shared, such as where a benefit offi?
ily does activity A, while the other (agent b) cer disqualifies a candidate for those benefits.
primarily does activity B. Initially, consider the For agent b, his output is the mirror image with
actions of agent a who is primarily carrying all his ex increasing activity B, and (1 - jc) of his
out activity A. Agent a provides efforts on two e2 increasing output A.
tasks?1 and 2?that generate benefits for the So far, there is little conceptually novel about
firm. The agent exerts effort ex and e2 on these constraints on efficiency?it offers a specific
activities, each of which yields marginal ben? parameterization of multitasking problems
efits of 1. For the sake of concreteness, consider which would offer the obvious implication of
effort 1 as yielding services to clients, and effort lower-powered incentives when 8 gets larger.
2 as doing so at lower cost. To keep matter sim? The novelty concerns the role of intrinsic moti?
ple, the costs of effort on task / is e]/!. (There vation, where agents care about outcomes.
is no linkage between efforts in the cost func? Specifically, I assume that agents have observ?
tion to avoid usual multitasking issues.) Assume able preferences over activities A and B, given
that the preferences of the principal are to maxi? by (/xA,/i5), so that the welfare that they receive
mize the standard notion of surplus: E \ex + e2 from outcomes {yA,yB) is l?AyA + AW^.3 As a
- e\/2 - e\/2\. (See Prendergast (2008) for a result of this, the principal chooses not only
discussion of this.) As a result of these simplify? what contracts to offer to agents, but also what
ing assumptions, the first-best level of effort is type of agent to hire. Ignore the participation
given by e* = 1. decision of the agent, as it is subsumed in the
There are two difficulties in inducing efficient preferences of the principal.
effort. The first is familiar?that effort cannot To avoid the facile observation of "hire those
be directly contracted upon where available who care more," I assume that (a) no agent exists
performance measures are imperfect in a way who internalizes all benefits without at least
that the agent can take advantage of. Following some monetary incentives, and (b) on the rel?
George Baker (1992), I assume that the principal evant frontier there is a trade-off between how
can observe an unbiased but imperfect signal of much they care about the two activities. If that
surplus: distribution includes the point (1,1), then the
first best is attainable by simply choosing that
(1) y = (1 + D)ex + (1 - D)e2, individual and offering no payment based on
output. I ignore this trivial solution by assuming
where D takes on values 8 and ?8 with equal that ?xA + ?jlb = M, where M < 2 and /x? > 0.4 It
probability. The parameter 8 thus measures the is worth discussing this frontier briefly. First, it
extent to which effort can be effectively con? is negatively sloped with the point Mil < 1. As
tracted upon, and is privately observed by the a result, it introduces a role for monetary con?
agent after contracts are signed. At one extreme, tracts, as the unbiased point (M/2,A//2) does not
0 = 0 and performance measures are perfect, yield efficient outcomes. (This point is unbiased
while at the other extreme 8 = o?, they are use?
less. This abstract contracting technology is
used simply to illustrate contracting distortions, 3 yA is the sum of ex + xe2 of agent a and (1 ? x) of e2 by
agent b, with yB defined accordingly.
while retaining the inherent symmetry of the
4 The assumption of /jla and pB being perfect substitutes
problem. implies that there are no supply-side reasons for bias, as the
The second issue that becomes relevant to trade-off between the supply of agents is identical to how
incentive provision is that there is an asymmetry the principal trades off the two activities.

This content downloaded from 193.226.62.221 on Sat, 24 Jun 2017 10:00:15 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 98 NO. 2 INTRINSIC MOTIVATION AND INCENTIVES 203

as it trades off the two activities in the same way


up" those incentives that derive from intrinsic
motivation.
as the principal.) Second, the frontier is nega?
tively sloped, so there is a potential trade-offA second natural result is that, as a2 rises,
that firms must makes?should they hire those ? falls for the familiar reason that it mitigates
who care more about A or about Bl distortionary effort decisions. Third, as intrin?
The firm can condition a wage paid to an agentsic incentives become more aligned with thos
on observed output J. (Ignore agent subscripts of the principal, monetary incentives fall. This
can be seen in two ways. First, as M rises, th
for simplicity.) For ease of exposition, consider
agents have intrinsic preferences closer to th
these as linear contacts where the agent is given
a fraction of output, ? J, and a fixed payment.5first-best level, and so j?* falls with M. Second
the parameter x measures the extent to which
First, consider the behavior of agent a who has
type (/?4,/>tfi) with marginal linear incentives activity
of A captures all the benefits of the agent
?. She chooses effort of ex = ?jla + (1 + D)?,efforts. It is the fact that x deviates from 1 tha
and e2 = x/jla + (1 - x)?jlb + (1 + D)?. Thus, leads the firms not to choose the most biase
effort is increasing in intrinsic motivation and agent.
in Hence, it follows that, as x rises, thes
monetary incentives. The objective of the prin?external effects decrease, and so ?* falls (sinc
?x*A
cipal is then to choose ?jla, jjlb and ? to maximize > Mil?see below) as intrinsic incen
E[ex + e2 - e]/2 - e\ll\ subject to e{ definedtives are more aligned with the wishes of th
above, /jla + ?jlb = M, /?z > 0, and D = 8(-8) principal.
with probability 1/2. Straightforward calcula?Now consider who is hired?the optimal bia
of agents. Consider agent a. First, ?jla > Mil,
tions yield the efficient level of incentives and
bureaucratic preferences as with the equality strict if 8 > 0 and x > 0, s
that bias is optimal?this follows from the spe?
(2) cialization of tasks. Second, as jc tends to 0, the

. f?2x-(2x-l)(l-x)M-?\
ULA = mm \M,-;-rz-\,
agent's tasks are not specialized and hence it is

^A X l-(2;t-l)2 J efficient to choose an agent with representativ


preferences, \xA ? Mil, while as x tends to 1, th
and agent's efforts affect only activity A and so ?j
tends toward M. Of most importance, note tha

(3) ^,-
i-*/*;-(i-*)f
. 1,+ CT bias (?t* - Mil) decreases in ? as monetary an
intrinsic incentives are substitutes. Hence, firm
respond to poor contractibility of output {a2) b
7 =M(1+ +? 5)2 + (1 - 8)2 - 1
where a2_
hiring agents with more extreme preferences.
Remember, however, that there is another
agent, b, whose tasks are the mirror image o
those of agent a. The optimal choice of agent b
First, consider the optimal contract offered
is simply the mirror image of ?nA : jjlb ? M
liA.
to the agent, ?*. The efficient level of effort is As a result, the view that this paper offer
e* = 1. In the case where there are no distor?
of agencies where output is hard to contract on
tions in the output measure, 5 = 0, the contract
is not the usual one where agents simply sto
ensures that this level of effort arises. When
exerting effort, but instead the firm responds
8 = 0, the firm chooses pi\ = Mil and partially
?* = by hiring biased agents whose equi
1 - Mil. In words, in firms where output mea? librium biases move in opposite directions t
sures are good, there is no need to bias the selec?
each other. So, for instance, social work depart
tion of the agent, and effort is at the first-best
ments would be populated with social worker
level, where incentives are used solely to who "topare highly motivated to provide benefits t
clients, yet who show little interest in control?
ling costs (see Martha Derthick (1979) and John
Brehm and Scott Gates (1977), for evidence o
5 As there is no aggregate uncertainty about observed
this) and superiors who show excess interest in
output in this model, this is without loss of generality. The
cost
interpretation of a linear contract is merely to illustrate control. For instance, in a survey on th
preferences of social workers, Robert Peabod
the extent to which marginal pay depends on observed
performance. (1964, 66) notes that "by far the most dominan

This content downloaded from 193.226.62.221 on Sat, 24 Jun 2017 10:00:15 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
204 AEA PAPERS AND PROCEEDINGS MA Y 2008

organizational goal perceived as important... is extreme case of the use of "interviews" to deter?
service to clientele," where 83 percent of survey mine preferences arises from congressional
respondants view such service as important, hearings on political appointees, such as to the
compared to only 9 percent who see "obliga? Supreme Court.
tion to taxpayers" or "assistance to the public in While this endogenous alignment of pref?
general" as important concerns affecting their erences is new to the agency literature, the
decisions. By contrast, those institutions that notion that matching preferences to the needs of
can contract on output have interests aligned, employers is already well established in studies
not just because of monetary concerns, but also on efficiency in the public sector. Specifically,
because their preferences are more similar. there is a field of research in public adminis?
tration called "representative diversity," which
II. Conclusion deals with the idea that?since compensation
cannot be used to align incentives effectively?
There are many instances where the use the US bureaucracy should resemble the popula?
of significant monetary incentives is likely to tion of the country in terms of education, voting
backfire. Yet firms still seek some way to moti? behavior, and attitudes toward social issues.6
vate their employees, and spend considerable The basis of this literature is little more than
resources thinking about how to do so. This the following: if you cannot use money to align
paper argues that a useful line of research may incentives, then aligning preferences might be a
be to consider sorting based on the preferences useful alternative.
of potential employees. It shows that a likely
price to be paid from not being able to contract REFERENCES
on output is that there will be a divergence of
preferences across different parts of the organi? Akerlof, George, and Rachel Kranton. 2005.
zation, not only because it is hard to use money "Identity and the Economics of Organiza?
to align interests, but also because the firm may tions." Journal of Economic Perspectives,
end up hiring workers with radically different 19(1): 9-32.
interests. As a result, a likely cost of operating Baker, George. 1992. "Incentive Contracts and
a, say, nonprofit organization is the possibility of Performance Measurement." Journal of Politi?
strife across different parts of the firm, as shown cal Economy, 100(3): 598-614.
in Prendergast (2008). B?nabou, Roland, and Jean Tir?le. 2003. "Intrin?
The central premise of the paper is that firms sic and Extrinsic Motivation." Review of Eco?
can at least partially observe the preferences nomic Studies, 70(3): 489-520.
of their employees. The most obvious example Besley, Timothy, and Maitreesh Ghatak. 2005.
of this is in the political process, where voters "Competition and Incentives with Motivated
make a determination of the candidate's prefer? Agents." American Economic Review, 95(3):
ences based on campaigns. Firms also devote 616-36.
considerable resources to identifying such fit Brehm, John, and Scott Gates. 1997. Work?
issues. For example, social welfare departments ing, Shirking, and Sabotage: Bureaucratic
attempt to identify the extent to which social Response to a Democratic Public. Ann Arbor:
workers identify with their clients, and there is University of Michigan Press.
evidence that such altruism affects performance Derthick, Martha. 1979. Policymaking for Social
(see Prendergast 2007 for details). In another Security. Washington, DC: Brookings Institu?
realm, the Reagan Administration routinely tion Press.
used questionnaires with potential appointees,
asking them about their political views before 6 Two results typically arise from this literature (see
hiring them, and used associations with groups Goodsell, 2004, for details). First, overall bureaucrats look
such as the Federalist Society (positive) or Sierra quite like the population. Second, there is variation across
Club (negative) as indicators of such preferences departments in preferences, where those in "traditional"
agencies such as Commerce, Agriculture, Treasury etc.,
(Marissa Goldin 2000). In other instances, such tend to be more conservative than those in more "activist"
information may be gleaned from interviews-a agencies such as Health and Human Services and Housing
considerable part of the purpose of interviews is and Urban Development (Stanley Rothman and Robert
to identify how well candidates match firms. An Lichter, 1983).

This content downloaded from 193.226.62.221 on Sat, 24 Jun 2017 10:00:15 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms
VOL. 98 NO. 2 INTRINSIC MOTIVATION AND INCENTIVES 205

Dewatripont, Mathias, Ian Jewitt, and Jean Goodsell, Charles. 2004. The Case For Bureau?
Tir?le. 1999. "The Economics of Career cracy. Washington, DC: CQ Press.
Concerns, Part II: Application to Missions Peabody, Robert. 1964. Organizational Author?
and Accountability of Government Agen? ity. New York: Atherton Press.
cies." Review of Economic Studies, 66(1): Prendergast, Canice. 2007. "The Motivation and
199-217. Bias of Bureaucrats." American Economic
Frey, Bruno, and Reto Jegen. 2001. "Motivation Review, 97(1): 180-96.
Crowding Theory." Journal of Economic Sur? Prendergast, Canice. 2008. "The Price Of Intrin?
veys, 15(5): 589-611. sic Motivation." Unpublished.
Golden, Marissa. 2000. What Motivates Bureau? Rothman, Stanley, and Robert Lichter. 1983.
crats? New York: Columbia University "How Liberal Are Bureaucrats?" Regulation,
Press. 7(1), 16-22.

This content downloaded from 193.226.62.221 on Sat, 24 Jun 2017 10:00:15 UTC
All use subject to http://about.jstor.org/terms

You might also like