You are on page 1of 51

Journal of Economic Literature

Vol. XXXII
Journal of (December 1994), pp. 16671717
Economic Literature, Vol. XXXII
Borjas:
(December
The Economics
1994) of Immigration

The Economics of Immigration


By G EORGE J. BORJAS
University of California at San Diego
and National Bureau of Economic Research

I am grateful to Julian Betts, Daniel Hamermesh, James Rauch,


and Stephen Trejo for useful comments, and to the National Sci-
ence Foundation for research support.

1. Introduction ployment opportunities of natives? Fi-


nally, which immigration policy most

T HERE HAS BEEN a resurgence of im-


migration in the United States and in
many other countries. The United Na-
benefits the host country?
The policy significance of these ques-
tions is evident. For example, immi-
tions estimates that over 60 million peo- grants who have high levels of productiv-
ple, or 1.2 percent of the worlds ity and who adapt rapidly to conditions
population, now reside in a country in the host countrys labor market can
where they were not born (United Na- make a significant contribution to eco-
tions 1989, p. 61). Although most immi- nomic growth. Natives need not be con-
grants choose a traditional destination cerned about the possibility that these
(over half typically go to the United immigrants will increase expenditures on
States, Canada, or Australia), many other social assistance programs. Conversely, if
countries are receiving relatively large immigrants lack the skills that employers
immigrant flows. Nearly 11 percent of demand and find it difficult to adapt, im-
the population in France, 17 percent in migration may significantly increase the
Switzerland, and 9 percent in the United costs associated with income mainte-
Kingdom is foreign-born. Even Japan, nance programs as well as exacerbate the
which is thought of as being very homo- ethnic wage differentials already in exist-
geneous and geographically immune to ence in the host country.
immigrants, now reports major problems Similarly, the debate over immigration
with illegal immigration. policy has long been fueled by the wide-
As a result of these changes in the im- spread perception that immigrant
migration market, the impact of immi- hordes have an adverse effect on the
gration on the host economy is now be- employment opportunities of natives.
ing debated heatedly in many countries. Which native workers are most adversely
The political discussion is centered affected by immigration, and how large
around three substantive questions. is the decline in the native wage?
First, how do immigrants perform in the Finally, there is great diversity in im-
host countrys economy? Second, what migration policies across countries. Some
impact do immigrants have on the em- countries, such as the United States,
1667
1668 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXII (December 1994)

TABLE 1
LEGAL IMMIGRANT FLOW TO THE UNITED STATES 18811990

Immigrant Flow as Percentage of Population


Immigrant Flow Percentage of Change that is Foreign-Born at
Decade (in 1000s) in Population End of Decade
18811890 5,246.6 41.0 14.7
18911900 3,687.6 28.3 13.6
19011910 8,795.4 53.9 14.6
19111920 5,735.8 40.8 13.2
19211930 4,107.2 24.6 11.6
19311940 528.4 5.9 8.8
19411950 1,035.0 5.3 6.9
19511960 2,515.5 8.7 5.4
19611970 3,321.7 13.7 4.7
19711980 4,493.3 20.7 6.2
19811990 7,338.1 33.1 7.9

Sources: U.S. Department of Justice. Immigration and Naturalization Service (1993, p. 25); U.S. Department of
Commerce. Bureau of the Census (1975, pp. 8, 14; 1993b, p. 50).

award entry visas mainly to applicants quires an understanding of the factors


who have relatives already residing in that motivate persons in the source
the country. Other countries, such as countries to emigrate and of the eco-
Australia and Canada, award visas to per- nomic consequences of pursuing particu-
sons who have a desirable set of socio- lar immigration policies. As a result, the
economic characteristics, and still other most important lesson is that the eco-
countries, such as Germany, encouraged nomic impact of immigration will vary by
the migration of temporary guest work- time and by place, and can be either
ers in the 1960s, only to find that the beneficial or harmful. Although the dis-
temporary migrants became a permanent cussion focuses on the experience of the
part of the German population. The United States (simply because most stud-
choice of the right immigration policy ies in the literature use data drawn from
can obviously have a significant impact the U.S. decennial Censuses), we will
on economic activity both in the short see that much can be learned by compar-
run and in the long run. ing the U.S. experience to that of other
The past decade witnessed an explo- host countries.
sion in research on many aspects of the
economics of immigration. This litera- 2. Immigration to the United States: A
ture is motivated mainly by the various Brief History
policy concerns and provides valuable in-
sights into all these issues. This paper As Table 1 shows, the size of the immi-
does not attempt to provide an encyclo- grant flow has fluctuated dramatically
pedic summary of the empirical results during the past century. The First Great
in the literature; instead, it surveys the Migration occurred between 1881 and
themes and lessons suggested by the on- 1924, when 25.8 million persons entered
going research. Perhaps the most impor- the country. Reacting to the increase in
tant theme is that an assessment of the immigration and to the widespread per-
economic impact of immigration re- ception that the new immigrants dif-
Borjas: The Economics of Immigration 1669

fered from the old, Congress closed the and Nationality Act (and subsequent re-
floodgates in the 1920s by enacting the visions) repealed the national origin re-
national-origins quota system. This sys- strictions, increased the number of avail-
tem restricted the annual flow from able visas, and made family ties to U.S.
Eastern Hemisphere countries to residents the key factor that determines
150,000 immigrants, and allocated the vi- whether an applicant is admitted into the
sas according to the ethnic composition country. As a consequence of both the
of the U.S. population in 1920. As a 1965 Amendments and of major changes
result, 60 percent of all available visas in economic and political conditions in
were awarded to applicants from two the source countries relative to the
countries, Germany and the United United States, the national origin mix of
Kingdom. the immigrant flow changed substantially
During the 1930s, only .5 million im- in the past few decades. As Table 2
migrants entered the United States. shows, over two-thirds of the legal immi-
Since then, the number of legal immi- grants admitted during the 1950s origi-
grants has increased at the rate of about nated in Europe or Canada, 25 percent
one million per decade, and is now near- originated in Western Hemisphere coun-
ing the historic levels reached in the tries other than Canada, and only 6 per-
early 1900s. By 1993, nearly 800,000 per- cent originated in Asia. By the 1980s,
sons were being admitted annually. only 13 percent of the immigrants origi-
There has also been a steady increase in nated in Europe or Canada, 47 percent
the number of illegal aliens. Demo- in Western Hemisphere countries other
graphic studies conclude that around two than Canada, and an additional 37 per-
to three million persons were illegally cent originated in Asia.
present in the United States in the late In recent years, the debate over immi-
1980s, and that the net flow of illegal gration policy led to the enactment of
aliens is on the order of 200,000 to two major pieces of legislation. Fueled
300,000 persons per year (U.S. General by charges that illegal aliens were over-
Accounting Office 1993). running the country, Congress enacted
Table 1 also illustrates that the size of the 1986 Immigration Reform and Con-
the immigrant flow has increased not trol Act (IRCA). This legislation gave
only in absolute terms, but also as a per- amnesty to three million illegal aliens
centage of population growth. In fact, and introduced a system of employer
the contribution of the Second Great Mi- sanctions designed to stem the flow of
gration to population growth is fast ap- additional illegal workers.1 The 1990 Im-
proaching the level reached during the migration Act permits the entry of an ad-
First Great Migration, when immigration ditional 150,000 legal immigrants annu-
accounted for 40 to 50 percent of the ally. The legislated increase in the size of
change in population. As a result of these the immigrant flow makes it likely that
trends, the fraction of the population the United States will admit a record
that is foreign-born rose from 4.7 to 7.9 number of immigrants during the 1990s.
percent between 1970 and 1990.
The huge increase in immigration in 1 In 1986, the Border Patrol apprehended 1.8
recent decades can be attributable partly million illegal aliens. Although the number of an-
to changes in U.S. immigration policy. nual apprehensions declined to about one million
Prior to 1965, immigration was guided by following the enactment of IRCA, they are now
back up to about 1.3 million, or 2.5 apprehensions
the national-origins quota system. The per minute (U.S. Department of Justice. Immigra-
1965 Amendments to the Immigration tion and Naturalization Service 1993, p. 156).
TABLE 2
NATIONAL ORIGIN COMPOSITION OF LEGAL IMMIGRANT FLOW TO UNITED STATES, 19311990

193140 194150 195160 196170 197180 198190


Number of Immigrants (in 1000s)
All Countries 528.4 1035.0 2515.5 3321.7 4493.3 7338.1
Europe 347.6 621.1 1325.7 1123.5 800.4 761.6
Germany 114.1 226.6 477.8 190.8 74.4 92.0
Greece 9.1 9.0 47.6 86.0 92.4 38.4
Ireland 11.0 19.8 48.4 33.0 11.5 32.0
Italy 68.0 57.7 185.5 214.1 129.4 67.3
Poland 17.0 7.6 10.0 53.5 37.2 83.3
United Kingdom 31.6 139.3 202.8 213.8 137.4 159.2
Asia 16.6 37.0 153.2 427.6 1588.2 2738.2
China 4.9 16.7 9.7 34.8 124.3 346.7
India 0.5 1.4 3.4 10.3 164.1 250.8
Iran 0 0.5 25.5 29.6 45.1 116.2
Japan 1.9 1.6 46.3 40.0 49.8 47.1
Korea 0 0.1 6.2 34.5 267.6 333.7
Philippines 0.5 4.7 19.3 98.4 355.0 548.8
Vietnam 0 0 0.3 4.3 172.8 280.8
America 160.0 354.8 996.9 1716.4 1982.7 3615.2
Canada 108.5 171.7 378.0 413.3 169.9 156.9
Mexico 22.3 60.6 299.8 453.9 640.3 1655.8
Cuba 9.6 26.3 78.9 208.5 264.9 144.6
Dominican Republic 1.2 5.6 9.9 93.3 148.1 252.0
Haiti 0.2 0.9 4.4 34.5 56.3 138.4
Africa 1.8 7.4 14.1 29.0 80.8 176.9
Oceania 2.5 14.6 13.0 25.1 41.2 45.2
Percentage Distribution
Europe 65.8 60.0 52.7 33.8 17.8 10.4
Germany 21.6 21.9 19.0 5.7 1.7 1.3
Greece 1.7 .9 1.9 2.6 2.1 .5
Ireland 2.1 1.9 1.9 1.0 .3 .4
Italy 12.9 5.6 7.4 6.4 2.9 .9
Poland 3.2 .7 .4 1.6 .8 1.1
United Kingdom 6.0 13.5 8.1 6.4 3.1 2.2
Asia 3.1 3.6 6.1 12.9 35.3 37.3
China .9 1.6 .4 1.0 2.8 4.7
India .1 .1 .1 .3 3.7 3.4
Iran .0 .0 1.0 .9 1.0 1.6
Japan .4 .2 1.8 1.2 1.1 .6
Korea .0 .0 .2 1.0 6.0 4.5
Philippines .1 .5 .8 3.0 7.9 7.5
Vietnam .0 .0 .0 .1 3.8 3.8
America 30.3 34.3 39.6 51.7 44.1 49.3
Canada 20.5 16.6 15.0 12.4 3.8 2.1
Mexico 4.2 5.9 11.9 13.7 14.3 22.6
Cuba 1.8 2.5 3.1 6.3 5.9 2.0
Dominican Republic .2 .5 .4 2.8 3.3 3.4
Haiti .0 .1 .2 1.0 1.3 1.9
Africa .3 .7 .6 .9 1.8 2.4
Oceania .5 1.4 .5 .8 .9 .6

Source: U.S. Department of Justice. Immigration and Naturalization Service (1993, pp. 2728).
Borjas: The Economics of Immigration 1671

3. How Do Immigrants Perform in the plicity, we restrict the discussion to the


Host Country? simpler specification.
The coefficient 0 gives the percentage
Many studies in the modern economic wage differential between immigrants
literature on immigration focus on deter- and natives at the time of arrival, while
mining the trends in the skill level and the coefficient 1 gives the rate at which
earnings of the immigrant population in the earnings of immigrants rise relative
the host country. 2 These studies view the to the earnings of natives. The early
labor market performance of immigrants studies of wage determination among im-
in the host country as a measure of the migrant and native men in the United
immigrant contribution to the economys States reached a quick consensus: the co-
skill endowment and productivity. In ad- efficient 0 was negative and the coeffi-
dition, the trends in immigrant skills cient 1 was positive.3 The essence of the
help determine the impact of immigra- results is summarized in Figure 1, which
tion on the employment opportunities of illustrates the predicted immigrant and
native-born workers and on expenditures native age-earnings profiles implied by
in social insurance programs. Chiswicks analysis of the 1970 Census.
At the time of arrival, immigrants earn
A. Aging and Cohort Effects about 17 percent less than natives. Be-
The pioneering work of Barry cause immigrants experience faster wage
Chiswick (1978) and Geoffrey Carliner growth, immigrant earnings overtake
(1980) analyzed how immigrant skills native earnings within 15 years after arri-
adapted to the host countrys labor mar- val. After 30 years in the United States,
ket by estimating the cross-section re- the typical immigrant earns about 11
gression model: percent more than a comparable native
worker.
log wi = Xi + A i + oIi + 1yi + i, (1) Two distinct arguments were used to
explain these results. At the time of arri-
where wi is worker is wage rate; Xi is a
val, immigrants earn less than natives be-
vector of socioeconomic characteristics
cause they lack the U.S.-specific skills
which might include education and re-
that are rewarded in the American labor
gion of residence; Ai gives the workers
market (such as English proficiency). As
age or potential labor market experience;
these skills are acquired, the human
Ii is a dummy variable indicating if the
capital stock of immigrants grows rela-
worker is an immigrant; and yi gives the
tive to that of natives, and immigrants
number of years an immigrant worker
experience faster wage growth. The hu-
has resided in the United States (and is
set to zero for native-born workers). In
3 There is a widespread, though erroneous, per-
practice, the model typically includes
ception that studies based on cross-section data
higher-order polynomials in age and from other countries and other time periods reach
years-since-migration, and the coeffi- similar conclusions. However, Chiswicks (1980)
cient vector (,) is allowed to vary be- study of immigrants in Britain reports that years-
since-migration has no impact on immigrant earn-
tween immigrants and natives. For sim- ings. Similarly, both Francine Blau (1979) and
Barry Eichengreen and Henry Gemery (1986) ana-
2 These questions are not restricted to the mod- lyze the economic mobility of immigrants who en-
ern literature. Paul Douglas (1919), for example, tered the United States at the turn of the 20th
analyzed the occupational distribution of immi- century, but reach conflicting conclusions. Blau
grants who arrived during the First Great Migra- finds wage convergence between immigrants and
tion to determine if the newer immigrants were as natives, while Eichengreen and Gemery find little
skilled as the old. wage convergence between the two groups.
1672 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXII (December 1994)

Log Earnings Wage


in 1970 C
9.1 Immigrants P
1950 Cohort
9.0

8.9 P
Natives Q
1970 Cohort
8.8 and Natives
8.7
Q
R
8.6 1990 Cohort

8.5
R
8.4
20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55 60 65 C
Age Age
20 40 60
Figure 1. The Cross-Section Age-Earnings Profiles
of Immigrants and Natives in the Figure 2. Cohort Effects and the Cross-Section
United States, 1970 Age-Earnings Profile of Immigrants
Source: Chiswick (1978, Table 2, Column 3). All the
variables in the regression are evaluated at the regression in (1) is that it draws infer-
means of the immigrant sample, and immigrants ences about how the earnings of immi-
are assumed to enter the United States at age 20. grant workers evolve over time from a
single snapshot of the immigrant popula-
man capital investment hypothesis, how- tion. It might be the case, however, that
ever, does not by itself generate an over- newly arrived immigrants are inherently
taking point. After all, why would immi- different from those who migrated
grants accumulate more human capital twenty years ago. Hence we cannot use
than natives? The overtaking point was the current labor market experiences of
instead interpreted in terms of a selec- those who arrived twenty years ago to
tion argument: immigrants are more forecast the future earnings of newly ar-
able and more highly motivated than rived immigrants.
natives (Chiswick 1978, p. 900), and im- Figure 2 illustrates the implications of
migrants choose to work longer and this alternative hypothesis. For concrete-
harder than nonmigrants (Carliner ness, consider a situation where there
1980, p. 89). This assumption was typi- are three separate immigrant waves, one
cally justified by arguing that only the wave arrived in 1950, the second in
most driven and most able persons have 1970, and the last in 1990. Assume that
the ambition and wherewithal to pack immigrants enter the United States at
up, move, and start life anew in a foreign age 20. The earliest cohort is assumed to
country. have the highest productivity level of any
The optimistic appraisal of immigrant group in the population, including U.S.-
adjustment implied by the results sum- born workers. If we could observe their
marized in Figure 1 was challenged by earnings in every year after they arrive in
Borjas (1985), who argued that the posi- the United States, their age-earnings
tive cross-section correlation between profile would be given by the line PP in
the relative wage of immigrants and the figure. Lets also assume that the last
years-since-migration need not indicate immigrant wave (i.e., the 1990 arrivals) is
that the wage of immigrants converges to the least productive of any group in the
that of natives. The basic problem with population. Their age-earnings profile is
the assimilationist interpretation of the given by the line RR in the figure. Fi-
Borjas: The Economics of Immigration 1673

nally, suppose that the 1970 wave has the instead may reflect innate differences in
same skills as natives; the age-earnings ability or skills across cohorts.
profiles of the two groups is given by Cohort effects may also arise as a re-
QQ. There is no wage convergence be- sult of changes in economic or political
tween immigrants and natives in this hy- conditions in the source countries and in
pothetical example. the United States. Even if the United
Suppose we have access to data drawn States had not adopted the 1965 Amend-
from the 1990 Census cross-section. ments, improving economic conditions in
These data allow us to identify only one Western Europe would have reduced the
point on each of the immigrant age-earn- number of immigrants from these tradi-
ings profiles. In particular, we can ob- tional source countries. The changing
serve the earnings of the immigrants who national origin mix of the immigrant flow
arrived in 1990 when they are 20 years generates cohort effects if skill levels
old; the earnings of the 1970 arrivals at vary across countries or if skills from dif-
age 40; and the earnings of the 1950 arri- ferent countries are not equally transfer-
vals at age 60. The age-earnings profile able to the United States. Finally, cohort
generated by the cross-section data, differences in average productivity will
therefore, is given by the line CC in Fig- be observed in a cross-section when
ure 2. The cross-section regression line there is nonrandom return migration. If
is steeper than the native age-earnings low-wage immigrant workers return to
profile, making it seem as if there is their source countries, the earlier waves
wage convergence between immigrants have been weeded out and will have
and natives, when in fact there is none. relatively higher earnings than more re-
Moreover, the cross-section regression cent waves.
line crosses the native age-earnings pro- It is evident that both the immigrant
file at age 40, making it seem as if immi- and native populations must be tracked
grant earnings overtake native earnings over time to correctly measure wage con-
after 20 years in the United States, when vergence between immigrants and na-
in fact no immigrant group experienced tives. Most longitudinal data sets either
such an overtaking. contain very few immigrants or provide
Figure 2 shows how a cross-section re- nonrandom samples of the foreign-born
gression can yield erroneous insights population. As a result, the literature has
about the adaptation process experi- pursued the alternative of creating syn-
enced by immigrants if there are intrin- thetic cohorts of immigrants by tracking
sic differences in productivity across im- specific immigrant waves across the de-
migrant cohorts (or cohort effects). cennial Censuses or across the Current
Cohort effects can arise as a result of Population Surveys (CPS). The empirical
changes in immigration policy. For ex- evidence typically found in these studies
ample, the 1965 Amendments de-empha- is summarized in Table 3, which reports
sized the role of skills in allocating entry the unadjusted percentage wage differ-
visas, and instead makes these awards ential between immigrant and native
based almost entirely on whether the ap- men in each of the decennial Censuses
plicant has family ties with current U.S. between 1970 and 1990. 4
residents. If this policy shift generated a
less-skilled immigrant flow, the cross- 4 The calculations use a 1/500 random sample of

section finding that more recent immi- native workers and a 5/100 random sample of im-
migrant workers in each Census (except in 1970
grants earn less than earlier immigrants when the immigrant extract forms a 2/100 random
says little about wage convergence, but sample). The resulting data set contains 920,700
1674 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXII (December 1994)

to 27.6 percent by 1980, and to 31.7 per-


TABLE 3
PERCENTAGE WAGE DIFFERENTIAL BETWEEN
cent by 1990.5
IMMIGRANT AND NATIVE MEN, 19701990 Because of these cohort effects, the
cross-section relationship between the
Group: 1970 1980 1990 relative wage of immigrants and years-
All Immigrants .9 9.2 15.2 since-migration overestimates the wage
Cohort: growth actually experienced by a particu-
19851989 Arrivals 31.7 lar cohort. The 1990 cross-section sug-
19801984 Arrivals 27.8 gests that over a 20-year period (1970 to
19751979 Arrivals 27.6 17.8
1990), the relative earnings of immi-
19701974 Arrivals 18.9 9.3
19651969 Arrivals 16.6 -7.8 1.1 grants grow by about 33 percentage
19601964 Arrivals 4.4 .1 9.0 points. 6 In fact, the relative wage of the
19501959 Arrivals 5.6 5.7 19.6 1965-1969 wave increased by only 18
Pre-1950 Arrivals 10.3 10.6 26.2 percentage points over the 20-year pe-
riod, or about half of the cross-section
Source: Authors tabulations from the 1970, 1980, and rate of convergence.
1990 Public Use Samples of the U.S. Census. The
statistics are calculated in the subsample of men
The implications of the data summa-
aged 2564 who work in the civilian sector, who are rized in Table 3 are clear and provoca-
not self-employed, and who do not reside in group tive. If we interpret the difference in
quarters. wages between immigrants and natives
as a measure of relative skills, more re-
cent immigrant waves are relatively less
Each Census cross-section shows that skilled than earlier waves. Moreover, im-
immigrants who have been in the United migrant wage growth is more sluggish
States for several decades have higher than suggested by the early cross-section
wages than natives, while more recent studies. It is extremely unlikely that the
arrivals have lower wages. In 1990, for earnings of more recent cohorts will ever
example, immigrants who arrived in the reach parity with (let alone overtake) the
United States between 1950 and 1960 earnings of natives.
earned 19.6 percent more than natives,
while immigrants who arrived between 5 These results differ slightly from those re-
1985 and 1989 earned 31.7 percent less. ported by Edward Funkhouser and Trejo (forth-
The data, however, also support the hy- coming), who use CPS data from various supple-
pothesis that there exist cohort effects in ments to describe the trend in immigrant skills
during the 1980s. The CPS data indicate that the
the foreign-born population, with more decline in relative skills was reversed somewhat by
recent immigrant cohorts having rela- the late 1980s. The CPS, however, contains rela-
tively lower wage rates. For example, the tively small samples of immigrants. In addition,
the national origin composition of immigrant co-
most recent cohort enumerated in the horts is extremely unstable across CPS surveys.
1970 Census (i.e., the 19651969 arri- For instance, 21 percent of the cohort that immi-
vals) earned only 16.6 percent less than grated between 1982 and 1984 in the June 1988
CPS is of Mexican origin, while the respective sta-
natives in 1970; the wage gap between tistic for the same cohort in the November 1989
the most recent arrivals and natives grew CPS is 37 percent. These statistics suggest that the
change in the relative immigrant wage across the
Current Population Surveys provides unreliable
observations. The percent wage differential be- measures of both cohort effects and of the rate of
tween immigrants and natives equals 100(e x 1), wage convergence.
where x is the difference in average log wages be- 6 This statistic is calculated by comparing the
tween the groups. See Borjas (forthcoming) for a relative wage of the immigrants who arrived in the
more detailed discussion of the data and of the late 1980s with the relative wage of the immi-
trends in immigrant earnings. grants who arrived in the late 1960s.
Borjas: The Economics of Immigration 1675

Needless to say, these findings have earnings profiles of immigrants and na-
generated a great deal of controversy tives converge if ( i + ) > n (assuming
and debate. (See, for example, Chiswick immigrants earn less than natives at the
1986; Harriet Orcutt Duleep and Mark time of arrival). 7 Finally, the coefficient
Regets 1992b; Robert LaLonde and measures the cohort effect, the rate of
Robert Topel 1992; and Andrew change in the entry wage across immi-
Yuengert 1994.) Many of these studies grant cohorts. 8
(including the original work of Borjas, It is well known that the key parame-
1985) point out that interpreting the in- ters of the regression model in equations
tercensal trend in the relative wage of (2) and (3) are not identified. The years-
immigrants as a measure of relative since-migration variable is a linear com-
changes in skills implicitly assumes that bination of the period effect and the co-
period effects influence the wage of im- hort variable:
migrants and natives by the same relative
amount. To see this point formally, con- yi i(1990 Ci) + (1 i) (1980 Ci)
sider the following generic model that = 1980 Ci + 10. (4)
characterizes the analytical framework
now used in the literature. Suppose we In order to identify the period effects,
pool all the data in two cross-sections the aging effects, and the cohort effect,
(such as the 1980 and 1990 Censuses) therefore, a restriction must be imposed
and estimate the regression equations: on the model. One possible restriction is
that the period effects are the same for
log wij = Xji + iA j + yj + Cj immigrants and natives, or:
+ ij + ij, (2)
i = n. (5)
log wnl = Xln + nA l + nl + nl, (3) Equation (5) implies that the relative
where wij gives the wage of immigrant j; wage of immigrants and natives is inde-
wnl gives the wage of native l; X gives a pendent of secular changes in the wage
vector of standardizing socioeconomic level. We implicitly imposed this restric-
characteristics; A gives the workers age tion on the data when we interpreted the
at the time of the Census; y gives the intercensal trends in Table 3 as changes
number of years that the immigrant has in the relative skills of immigrants. By
resided in the United States; C is the cal- netting out the secular trend in the na-
endar year of arrival in the United tive wage (i.e., by using a difference-in-
States; and is a dummy variable in- differences estimator), we are simply left
dicating if the observation was drawn with the trend in immigrant productivity.
from the 1990 Census. To easily illus- Note, however, that the wage is the
trate the identification problem, the product of the rate of return to skills
age, years-since-migration, and calendar times the workers human capital stock.
year-of-arrival variables are entered lin- 7 Although the regression model in (2) assumes
early. that the aging effect is the same for all immigrant
The coefficients i and n give the pe- cohorts, many of the empirical studies in the lit-
riod effects for immigrants and natives, erature relax this assumption.
8 The model assumes that there are no cohort
respectively. The coefficient n gives the effects in the native population (perhaps due to
aging effect for natives; the rate at which changes in the quality of education). Even though
native earnings increase over the life cy- this is a standard assumption in the literature, the
estimated cohort effects in the immigrant popula-
cle. The respective aging effect for im- tion may be sensitive to the existence of cohort
migrants is given by i + . The age- effects among native workers.
1676 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXII (December 1994)

TABLE 4
EDUCATIONAL ATTAINMENT OF IMMIGRANT AND NATIVE MEN, 19701990

1970 1980 1990


Percent Percent Percent Percent Percent Percent
High School College High School College High School College
Group Dropouts Graduates Dropouts Graduates Dropouts Graduates
Natives 39.6 15.4 23.1 22.9 14.8 26.6
Immigrants 48.2 18.9 37.4 25.3 36.9 26.6
Cohort:
198589 Arrivals 35.2 31.5
198084 Arrivals 40.4 24.1
197579 Arrivals 36.2 30.4 42.2 24.8
197074 Arrivals 44.0 24.9 42.7 24.1
196569 Arrivals 45.2 28.3 41.6 24.7 34.1 26.2
196064 Arrivals 44.8 21.1 34.7 24.8 27.5 27.9
195059 Arrivals 47.4 17.1 31.4 23.7 25.9 27.8
Pre-1950 Arrivals 51.7 15.0 35.3 21.6 25.2 31.8

Source: Authors tabulations from the 1970, 1980, and 1990 Public Use Samples of the U.S. Census. The statistics
are calculated in the subsample of men aged 2564 who work in the civilian sector, who are not self-employed, and
who do not reside in group quarters.

If period effects influence the price of would have fallen between 1980 and
skills differently for immigrants and na- 1990 even if immigrant skills had re-
tives, the intercensal change in relative mained constant. In other words, the
wages could be reflecting differences in changes in the wage structure could ac-
prices rather than differences in human count for both the observed decline in
capital. the relative wage of successive immi-
There were historic changes in the grant cohorts and for the sluggish wage
U.S. wage structure during the 1980s growth experienced by a particular co-
and these changes did not affect all skill hort as it entered the 1980s.
groups equally (Frank Levy and Richard It is unlikely, however, that changes in
Murnane 1992). In particular, there was the wage structure account for the down-
a sizable increase in the wage gap be- ward trend in relative wages across suc-
tween highly educated and less educated cessive immigrant cohorts or for the slow
workers; and among workers within nar- wage convergence between immigrants
rowly defined occupation and industry and natives. Consider the trends in im-
cells. It is unlikely that these changes in migrant educational attainment, a skill
the wage structure affected the earnings measure that is invariant to changes in
of immigrant and native workers by the the wage structure. Table 4 documents
same percentage amount. The immigrant the changes in the schooling distribution
population in the United States is rela- of immigrants and natives in the past two
tively unskilled (at least in terms of edu- decades. In 1970, 39.6 percent of natives
cational attainment). Because the rate of were high school dropouts; by 1990, only
return to skills increased during the 14.8 percent of natives lacked a high
1980s, the relative wage of immigrants school diploma. Among immigrants, 48.2

1 LINE SHORT
Borjas: The Economics of Immigration 1677

percent were dropouts in 1970, 37.4 per- within age and education cells, LaLonde
cent in 1980, and 36.9 percent in 1990. and Topel (1992) suggest using a defla-
Relative to natives, immigrants were tor based on an immigrants ranking in
about 21.7 percent more likely to be the native wage distribution. If all work-
high school dropouts in 1970, but are ers who fall in the pth percentile of the
now more than twice as likely to be high wage distribution are equally skilled,
school dropouts. then we can use the wage growth experi-
Moreover, even though the percentage enced by natives in the pth percentile to
of immigrant workers who are college deflate the wage growth of immigrants
graduates rose during the period, the who fall in the same percentile in the
percentage of natives who are college 19701990 period.10
graduates rose even faster. Immigrants Table 5 reports the changes in the de-
were more likely to be college gradu- flated relative wage of immigrants be-
ates in 1970 (18.9% for immigrants as tween 1970 and 1990. Regardless of
compared to 15.4% for natives). By which deflator is used, more recent im-
1990, both groups had exactly the same migrant cohorts have substantially lower
probability of being college graduates relative wages than earlier cohorts. The
(26.6%). Therefore, changes in the most recent cohort in 1970 earned 16.6
quantity of immigrants human capital percent less than natives at the time of
are partly responsible for the decline in arrival. The most recent cohort in 1990
the relative immigrant wage. earned 29.5 percent less than natives if
It is also easy to show that changes in we use the deflator based on age-educa-
the U.S. wage structure were not suffi- tion cells, and 29.4 percent less if we use
ciently large to account for a sizable part the percentile deflator. The change in
of the declining relative wage of immi- the wage structure, therefore, accounts
grants across successive waves. For ex- for only 15 percent of the drop in the
ample, we know that the wage structure relative immigrant wage between 1970
changed in different ways for various and 1990.
age-education groups, with groups with The cohort and aging effects calcu-
more education and experience having lated from the synthetic cohorts in the
larger wage growth between 1970 and Census data may be biased because the
1990. We can then use the wage growth sample composition of a particular immi-
observed in 56 age-education cells grant cohort changes systematically
among native workers to deflate the across Censuses. Perhaps one-third of
wage growth of immigrants in the same immigrants in the United States eventu-
age-education cells.9 To take into ac-
count changes in wage inequality even 10 Neither deflator fully solves the problem of
accounting for changes in the wage structure. The
9 The eight age categories are: 2529 years old; age-education deflator, for example, ignores the
3034; 3539; 4044; 4549; 5054; 5559; and increase in inequality that occurred within age-
6064. The seven education categories are: less education cells. The percentile deflator assumes
than 8 years of schooling; 9 years; 1011 years; 12 that immigrants and natives in the p th percentile
years; 1315 years; 16 years; and more than 16 are perfect substitutes. This is unlikely to be true.
years. Define D rs(t) to be the wage growth experi- Newly arrived immigrants might place badly in the
enced by the typical native worker in age group r native wage ranking not because they are un-
and education group s between 1970 and year t(t = skilled, but because they are going through an
1980, 1990). The deflated wage is then given by initial testing period. In the end, therefore, an
^ , (t) = log w , (t) (t) , where log w , (t) is
log w immigrant who initially places in the p th percentile
l rs l rs rs l rs
the log wage of person l in skill group rs in Census may have skills that are comparable to those of
year t. natives in the (p + q)th percentile, where q > 0.

1 LINE SHORT
1678 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXII (December 1994)

TABLE 5
PERCENTAGE WAGE DIFFERENTIAL BETWEEN IMMIGRANT, AND NATIVE, MEN, 19701990, DEFLATED BY
CHANGES IN WAGE STRUCTURE

Using Age-Education
Deflator Using Percentile Deflator
Group: 1970 1980 1990 1980 1990
All Immigrants .9 9.4 14.4 8.6 13.9
Cohort:
19851989 Arrivals 29.5 29.4
19801984 Arrivals 25.0 25.4
19751979 Arrivals 25.2 15.8 26.2 16.0
19701974 Arrivals 17.5 8.8 17.9 -8.3
19651969 Arrivals 16.6 8.2 .2 7.2 1.1
19601964 Arrivals 4.4 1.0 6.0 .2 7.9
19501959 Arrivals 5.6 3.9 13.1 5.4 17.1
Pre-1950 Arrivals 10.3 4.7 16.0 10.2 23.2

Source: Authors tabulations from the 1970, 1980, and 1990 Public Use Samples of the U.S. Census. The statistics
are calculated in the subsample of men aged 2564 who work in the civilian sector, who are not self-employed, and
who do not reside in group quarters.

ally return to their countries of origin later Censuses includes a larger number
(Robert Warren and Jennifer Peck of persons who migrated as children.11
1980). Suppose that the return migrants The economic experiences of immigrant
are mainly composed of workers with children may resemble those faced by
lower than average wages (i.e., the fail- native workers. The inclusion of the im-
ures). The intercensal tracking of a par- migrant children in later Censuses thus
ticular cohort would reveal an improve- biases the estimated rate of wage conver-
ment in relative wages even if no wage gence upward. A better measure of wage
convergence is taking place. Alterna- convergence, therefore, is obtained by
tively, if the return migrants are suc- tracking a specific immigrant cohort, de-
cesses, the rate of wage convergence fined in terms of both year-of-migration
would be underestimated. Because data and age-at-arrival, across the various
on the size and composition of the return Censuses.
migration flow is scarce, few studies sys- Table 6 summarizes the trend in the
tematically analyze the selection mecha- percent wage differential between a par-
nism generating the return migration ticular group of immigrants and similarly
flow (the limited available evidence is aged natives, so that immigrants who ar-
discussed in the next section). As a re- rived when they were between 25 and 34
sult, the bias introduced by nonrandom years old in the late 1960s are compared
return migration is typically ignored.
11 An earlier study by Sherrie Kossoudji (1989)
Even if there were no return migra-
used the 1976 Survey of Income and Education
tion, Rachel Friedberg (1992) and James cross-section to estimate models of occupational
Smith (1992) have shown that the sample mobility which differentiate between persons who
composition of a particular immigrant migrated as children and those who migrated as
adults. She finds that controlling for age-at-migra-
cohort changes over time because the tion leads to flatter occupational mobility profiles
sample of working-aged immigrants in among immigrants than among natives.
Borjas: The Economics of Immigration 1679

TABLE 6
PERCENTAGE WAGE DIFFERENTIAL BETWEEN IMMIGRANTS AND NATIVES, BY AGE GROUP
AND YEAR OF ARRIVAL

Using Age-Education
Actual Wage Actual Wage Deflator
Cohort/Age Group: 1970 1980 1990 1980 1990
19601964 Arrivals:
1524 in 1970 1.1 4.2 .9 4.5
2534 in 1970 3.1 .3 .2 .0 .1
3544 in 1970 6.0 6.7 1.1 6.7 1.4
4554 in 1970 11.1 10.8 10.9
19651969 Arrivals:
1524 in 1970 4.6 6.9 6.2 5.5
2534 in 1970 12.0 5.9 2.5 5.4 2.3
3544 in 1970 15.9 15.3 8.8 15.5 8.3
4554 in 1970 22.5 21.1 21.6
19701974 Arrivals:
2534 in 1980 11.4 11.8 12.5 10.4
3544 in 1980 17.7 16.4 17.1 15.6
4554 in 1980 26.0 20.7 26.4 20.0
19751979 Arrivals:
2534 in 1980 21.3 15.5 21.2 14.8
3544 in 1980 24.9 24.1 24.2 23.4
4554 in 1980 29.8 26.3 29.8 26.1
19801984 Arrivals:
2534 in 1990 18.6 18.2
3544 in 1990 25.3 24.5
4554 in 1990 34.0 33.0
19851989 Arrivals:
2534 in 1990 23.0 23.5
3544 in 1990 28.6 28.3
4554 in 1990 36.2 35.7

Source: Authors tabulations from the 1970, 1980, and 1990 Public Use Samples of the U.S. Census. The statistics
are calculated in the subsample of men aged 2564 who work in the civilian sector, who are not self-employed, and
who do not reside in group quarters.

to natives aged 2534 in 1970, to natives year period, therefore, the relative wage
3544 in 1980, and to natives aged 4554 of this immigrant cohort increased by 10
in 1990. About half of the wage conver- percentage points, in contrast to the 18
gence implied by the statistics presented percent growth suggested by the inter-
in Table 5 disappears after controlling censal comparison that does not control
for age-at-migration. Consider, for exam- for age-at-migration and to the 33 per-
ple, the group of immigrants who arrived cent growth implied by the 1990 cross-
between 1965 and 1969 and who were section.
2534 years old in 1970. They earned Table 6 reveals that practically all im-
12.0 percent less than natives in 1970 migrants, regardless of when they ar-
and 2.5 percent less in 1990. Over a 20- rived in the country, experience the
1680 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXII (December 1994)

same sluggish relative wage growth. This sus that much of the decline is due to
result is significant because it suggests changes in observables. Both Funk-
that more recent immigrant cohorts have houser and Trejo (forthcoming, Table 6)
not had faster wage growth despite their and LaLonde and Topel (1992, p. 89)
lower starting positions.12 In fact, immi- conclude that at least two-thirds of the
grants who arrived during the 1970s ex- decline can be attributed to changes in
perienced the same wage growth as the educational attainment of immi-
those who arrived during the 1960s dur- grants relative to natives. Some studies
ing their first decade in the United also show that the changing national ori-
States. Immigrants who arrived between gin mix of the immigrant flow (which ob-
1975 and 1979 and were around age 30 viously implies changes in the observable
at the time of arrival earned 21.3 percent skills of immigrants) accounts for much
less than natives in 1980 and 15.5 per- of the decline in skills across successive
cent less than natives in 1990, an in- cohorts. This result will be discussed in
crease of only 5.8 percentage points. detail below.
This wage growth is similar to that expe-
rienced by similarly aged immigrants B. Wage Convergence Between
who arrived between 1965 and 1969; Immigrants and Ethnically Similar
they earned 12.0 percent less than na- Natives
tives in 1970 and 5.9 percent less in
1980. The data summarized in the previous
Many studies have confirmed that section describe how the immigrant
there has been an overall decline in the wage adjusts relative to that of the typi-
relative skills of successive immigrant co- cal native worker. Because recent immi-
horts. For example, Yuengert (1994, p. grant waves start off at such a disadvan-
86) finds that the relative wage of the tage, it is not too surprising that their
immigrants who migrated in the late earnings fail to reach parity with the
1960s was about 9 percentage points earnings of the average U.S.-born worker
lower than the relative wage of those (who is typically a white person of Euro-
who arrived in the 1950s; LaLonde and pean ancestry). A number of studies thus
Topel (1992, p. 89) report a 22 percent- investigate if immigrant earnings con-
age point drop in the relative wage of verge to the earnings of U.S.-born work-
immigrants cohorts between the late ers who share the same ethnic back-
1960s and the late 1970s; and Funk- ground. These intra-ethnic comparisons
houser and Trejo (forthcoming, Table 6) can help assess if the new immigration
report a 10 percentage point drop during will exacerbate the ethnic differences al-
the same period. There is also a consen- ready prevalent in the U.S. labor market.
There is, however, little consensus on
12 Duleep and Regets (1992b) use the 1970 and
whether the relative skills of immigrants
1980 Censuses to estimate correlations between
wage growth and entry wages across national ori- declined within specific ethnic groups,
gin groups. These correlations tend to be negative, or on whether the wage of immigrants
leading them to conclude that the low entry wage converges to that of ethnically similar na-
of the immigrants who arrived in the late 1970s
did not represent their true quality because they tives. Most studies typically focus on
would have faster wage growth than earlier immi- four large ethnic groups: Mexican immi-
grants. The additional data provided by the 1990 grants, other Hispanic immigrants, Asian
Census indicates that the less-skilled cohorts who
migrated in the 1970s did not, in fact, experience immigrants (excluding the Middle East),
faster wage growth than earlier waves. and white immigrants (defined as per-

1 LINE SHORT
Borjas: The Economics of Immigration 1681

TABLE 7
PERCENTAGE WAGE DIFFERENTIAL BETWEEN IMMIGRANTS AND NATIVES OF SAME ETHNIC BACKGROUND
(Using Age/Education Deflator)

Mexican Other Hispanics Asian White


Cohort/Age Group 1970 1980 1990 1970 1980 1990 1970 1980 1990 1970 1980 1990
196064 Arrivals
1524 in 1970 1.8 5.1 20.3 29.2 1.9 .2 2.7 10.3
2534 in 1970 5.8 9.6 16.0 9.0 16.9 19.1 6.9 15.0 11.7 9.5 7.9 10.3
3544 in 1970 22.4 19.7 14.2 8.0 8.5 13.7 15.3 4.1 17.1 4.5 3.9 14.3
196569 Arrivals
1524 in 1970 11.7 13.0 .6 3.1 9.0 3.0 .5 7.1
2534 in 1970 26.5 16.5 19.5 15.8 3.4 .1 17.6 9.1 8.5 .3 2.9 12.3
3544 in 1970 32.5 23.0 -29.2 15.9 9.8 6.5 15.2 13.1 5.6 5.4 6.2 9.4
197074 Arrivals
2534 in 1980 19.5 21.2 7.1 1.0 2.7 5.3 2.9 8.1
3544 in 1980 23.8 29.3 11.7 6.8 9.9 3.9 6.9 3.0
197579 Arrivals
2534 in 1980 33.8 29.5 21.5 16.7 19.7 10.2 .6 11.7
3544 in 1980 38.3 36.7 22.4 15.2 28.1 25.8 1.8 4.2
198084 Arrivals
2534 in 1990 25.0 19.7 14.9 12.4
3544 in 1990 39.6 27.3 28.8 10.1
198589 Arrivals
2534 in 1990 33.9 28.2 24.3 4.0
3544 in 1990 45.1 36.2 30.6 1.2
Percent of Immigrant
Population Belonging
to Particular Ethnic
Group 9.7 18.5 26.2 11.4 13.1 16.1 8.6 16.4 21.7 62.4 36.8 21.5

Source: Authors tabulations from the 1970, 1980, and 1990 Public Use Samples of the U.S. Census. The statistics
are calculated in the subsample of men aged 2564 who work in the civilian sector, who are not self-employed, and
who do not reside in group quarters.

sons originating in Europe or Canada). 13 panic ancestry); Asian-American natives


The four native base groups are: Mexi- (non-Hispanic persons whose race is
can-American natives (i.e., U.S.-born Asian); and white natives (non-Hispanic
persons of Mexican ancestry); other His- whites).
panic-American natives (all other U.S.- Table 7 summarizes the trends in the
born persons who report being of His- wage of immigrants in particular cohorts
and age groups relative to ethnically
13 Kristin Butcher (1994) describes the process similar natives in the same age group, so
of wage convergence between black immigrants that Mexican immigrants aged 2534 in
and U.S.-born black workers, and finds that the 1970 are contrasted with Mexican-
labor market experience of black immigrants re-
sembles that of black natives who had moved out American natives aged 2534 in 1970,
of their state of birth. with Mexican-American natives aged 35

1 LINE SHORT
1682 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXII (December 1994)

44 in 1980, and with Mexican-American 7 percentage points. Similarly, the typi-


natives aged 4554 in 1990. There are cal white immigrant in the same age
interesting differences in the direction group who had just arrived in the United
and magnitude of cohort effects across States in 1970 earned .3 percent more
the various groups. The relative wage of than white natives, and this wage gap
successive waves of Mexican immigrants grew to 12.3 percent by 1990. This rate
declined during the past two decades. In of wage convergence allows white immi-
1970, the typical Mexican immigrant grants to substantially outperform white
aged 2534 who had just arrived in the natives after 20 years in the United
United States earned 26.5 percent less States, but prevents Mexican immigrants
than the typical Mexican-American na- from reaching wage parity with Mexican-
tive; by 1990, the latest wave of Mexican American natives.
immigrants earned 33.9 percent less than Finally, there seems to be a structural
their native counterparts. Note, how- shift in the rate of wage convergence for
ever, that the wage gap between Mexican Asian immigrants who migrated after
immigrants and Mexican-American na- 1970. Asian immigrants who migrated in
tives underestimates the true economic the 1960s experienced a very high rate of
status of Mexican immigrants in the wage convergence. The typical Asian im-
United States. After all, Mexican-Ameri- migrant who arrived in the late 1960s
can natives are themselves a relatively (and was 2534 years old at the time of
disadvantaged group, earning 16 percent arrival) earned 17.6 percent less than
less than the typical U.S.-born worker in Asian-American natives in 1970, and
1990. about 9 percent more in both 1980 and
The relative wage of other Hispanic 1990. In contrast, a similarly aged Asian
immigrants and Asian immigrants also immigrant who arrived in the late 1970s
fell across successive cohorts. In contrast earned 19.7 percent less than Asian-
to these groups, the relative wage of suc- American natives in 1980, and 10.2 per-
cessive waves of European and Canadian cent less in 1990. In effect, this later co-
immigrants rose slightly between 1970 hort of Asian immigrants has a rate of
and 1990. The most recent white arri- wage convergence which is half of that
vals (aged 2534 at the time of arrival) experienced by earlier immigrant waves.
earned .3 percent more than white na- Table 7 thus suggests that there is a
tives in 1970, but by 1990 they earned 4 great deal of diversity in the economic
percent more. experiences of various immigrant groups
The raw data thus suggest that some in the United States. In view of this di-
groups experienced a decline in relative versity, it is not surprising that there is a
wages across successive cohorts, while great deal of disagreement in the litera-
white immigrants experienced an in- ture (which is mostly based on compari-
crease. The data also indicate that most sons of the 1970 and 1980 Censuses) as
non-Asian cohorts experienced a 5 to 10 to whether there has been a decline in
percentage point increase in their rela- the average skill level of successive im-
tive wage between 1970 and 1990. For migrant waves within ethnic group, and
instance, the Mexican immigrant who on whether there is wage convergence
had just arrived in the United States in with ethnically similar natives. For exam-
1970 and was between 25 and 34 years ple, Smith (1992, p. 79) concludes that
old earned 26.5 percent less than the there is very little within-cohort wage
typical Mexican-American native. By assimilation for [Mexican] immigrants
1990, the wage gap had narrowed by only across their labor market careers, and
Borjas: The Economics of Immigration 1683

that there is strong evidence of declin- able changes in the national origin mix of
ing labor market quality. In contrast, the immigrant flow over very short time
LaLonde and Topel (1992, p. 82) con- periods even within a particular ethnic
clude that Mexican immigrants show group. As a result, we do not know how
substantial assimilation with no signifi- to interpret the cohort effects or the
cant evidence of a decline in immigrant changes in the rate of wage convergence
quality. Even more striking, Yuengerts among Asians or other Hispanics unless
(1994, p. 86) examination of the same we deal directly with a more primitive
data reveals an increase in the skill level definition of ethnicity (i.e., the one that
of Mexican immigrant cohorts over time, coincides with national origin).
with Mexicans who arrived between 1965 Moreover, the composition of the na-
and 1969 having 13 percent higher rela- tive base in these broadly defined ethnic
tive earnings than those who arrived in groups is changing systematically over
the 1950s. time. In 1970, for example, there were
There are many differences across few adult Cubans in the other Hispanic-
these studies which can potentially ex- American native sample. By 1990, as the
plain the disparity in results. Smith, for U.S.-born children of the early Cuban
example, stresses the importance of con- waves enter the labor market, the wage
trolling for age-at-migration when esti- of the other Hispanic native base is
mating the rate of wage convergence, a partly determined by the skill endow-
variable that LaLonde and Topel and ment of immigrant flows that arrived a
Yuengert ignore. In contrast, LaLonde generation earlier. The comparison of
and Topel stress the importance of con- Hispanic immigrants to Hispanic-Ameri-
trolling for the impact of changes in the can natives in 1970 thus differs funda-
wage structure on the wage of different mentally from the comparison of His-
skill groups, a factor that Smith ignores. panic immigrants to Hispanic-American
The data summarized in Table 7 con- natives in 1990.
trols both for age-at-migration and for Most importantly, there is a sense in
changes in the wage structure, as well as which these intra-group comparisons
extends the span of time studied by an- miss the point. What would we conclude
other decade (using the 1990 Census). if the relative wage of Mexican immi-
Although intra-ethnic comparisons are grants converged to that of Mexican-
common in the literature, there are a American natives, or the relative wage of
number of conceptual problems in these Asian immigrants converged to that of
studies that have not been sufficiently Asian-American natives? The fact re-
appreciated. Most obvious is the aggre- mains that the wage of Mexican-Ameri-
gation bias introduced by pooling immi- can natives is itself 16 percent below that
grants from different countries into a of the typical U.S.-born worker, while
particular ethnicity (such as creating the wage of Asian-American natives is 12
the Asian group by combining persons percent above. Intra-group convergence
from countries as diverse as India, Ja- is not an interesting phenomenon if we
pan, and Vietnam). Because immigrant want to identify the groups of native
groups from different countries differ workers who are most likely to be ad-
substantially, it is doubtful that the com- versely affected by immigration, or if we
posite other Hispanic or Asian re- are concerned about the impact of immi-
sembles the average person in any of the gration policy on poverty rates, on the
national origin groups making up the costs of welfare programs, and on the
ethnic category. Moreover, there are siz- contribution of immigrants to the econ-
1684 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXII (December 1994)

omys skill endowment. The costs and example, documents that an additional
benefits of immigration are more closely year of residence in the United States in-
related to how immigrants perform rela- creases the probability of English profi-
tive to the population average than to ciency by about 3 percentage points in a
how immigrants perform relative to a small sample of illegal aliens appre-
nonrandom subset of the population. hended in Los Angeles. Moreover, add-
ing variables measuring the workers
C. Language and the Process of Wage English skills to a cross-section earnings
Convergence function reduces the coefficient of years-
Although there are many estimates of since-migration by 10 to 20 percent
the rate of wage convergence between (Evelina Tainer 1988; Chiswick 1991).
immigrants and natives, we do not yet In 1990, 47.0 percent of the immigrant
understand why some wage convergence stock in the United States did not speak
takes place. For the most part, the stud- English very well (U.S. Department of
ies investigating the differential accumu- Commerce 1993a, p. 129). Given the ap-
lation of human capital by immigrants parent high returns to English language
and natives focus on one single factor, proficiency, it is worth asking why more
the acquisition of language capital in immigrants do not pursue this human
the host country. capital investment. The rate of return to
The early work of Gilles Grenier language capital, however, may have
(1984), and Walter McManus, William little to do with the wage differential
Gould, and Finis Welch (1983) con- between immigrants who are English-
cluded that U.S. immigrants who are proficient and immigrants who are not.
proficient in the English language have English proficiency and earnings might
higher earnings than immigrants who are be correlated simply because more able
not.14 Grenier reports that Hispanic im- workers are likely to speak English and
migrants who do not speak English pay a to earn more. Some studies correct for
17 percent wage penalty, even after ad- the endogeneity of the language variable
justing for differences in education and by using instrumental variable estima-
other socioeconomic characteristics. This tors, but these attempts are not convinc-
wage differential implies a $96,600 (in ing. For example, Chiswick and Miller
1993 dollars) increase in lifetime earn- (1992, p. 265) use such instruments as
ings for a Hispanic immigrant who be- the workers veteran status, number of
comes proficient in the English language children, and the fraction of persons in
(McManus 1985). Presumably, profi- the state who speak the same language.
ciency in the host countrys language in- It is doubtful that this set of identifying
creases immigrant earnings because bi- instruments is correlated with English
lingualism opens up many employment proficiency, but is not correlated with
opportunities. the workers earnings capacity.
There also seems to be a link between Even if language proficiency were ex-
English language proficiency and the ogenous, the returns to language capital
rate of wage convergence between immi- are affected by the clustering of immi-
grants and natives. Chiswick (1991), for grants in ethnic enclaves, such as the Cu-
bans in Miamis Little Havana and the
14 Similar findings are reported in Carliners Mexicans in East Los Angeles. Immi-
(1981) study of immigrants in Canada. David grants residing in these enclaves might
Bloom and Grenier (1992) and Chiswick and Paul
Miller (1992) compare the returns to language face low returns to language capital be-
capital in the United States and Canada. cause most of their economic exchanges
Borjas: The Economics of Immigration 1685

are with persons of the same ethnic (and A. National Origin and the
linguistic) background. For example, al- Decline in Immigrant Skills
most half of the Cubans who arrived in
the Mariel boatlift in 1980 worked for Table 8 illustrates the huge differ-
Cuban employers in 1986 (Alejandro ences in educational attainment and
Portes 1987). 15 McManus (1990) finds earnings across national origin groups in
that the wage gap between Hispanics 1990. Mean years of schooling range
who are English proficient and Hispanics from eight years for immigrants originat-
who are not is 26 percent for workers ing in Mexico or Portugal, to about 15
who live in a county that is only 10 per- years for immigrants originating in such
cent Hispanic, but falls to 11 percent for diverse countries as Austria, India, Ja-
workers who live in a county that is 75 pan, and the United Kingdom. Similarly,
percent Hispanic. immigrants from El Salvador or Mexico
Although many studies measure the earn 40 percent less than natives, while
correlation between language capital and immigrants from Australia or South Af-
wage convergence, there are many other rica earn 30 to 40 percent more than na-
variables which influence the assimila- tives. These differences cannot be attrib-
tion process, such as the acquisition of uted to the fact that some national origin
formal education or on-the-job training groups have lived in the United States
in the post-migration period, invest- for longer periods. There is substantial
ments in geographic mobility within the dispersion in both educational attain-
host country, and differences in job ment and relative wages even among im-
search activities. Few studies, however, migrants who have been in the country
investigate how natives and immigrants more than 10 years.
differ in these human capital invest- In view of the post-1950 changes in
ments.16 the national origin mix of immigrant
flows, it is not surprising that these
changes explain the decline in relative
4. National Origin and the wages across successive immigrant
Self-selection of Immigrants waves. Borjas (1992b, p. 41) decomposes
the skill decline into a portion due to
Why did the relative wages of succes- changes in the national origin mix and
sive immigrant cohorts arriving in the into a portion due to the changing skill
United States decline? The empirical level of immigrants from specific coun-
evidence suggests that one single factor, tries. The changing national origin mix
the changing national origin mix of the explains over 90 percent of the decline
immigrant flow, can explain much of the in educational attainment and relative
decline (Borjas 1992b; LaLonde and wages across successive waves between
Topel 1992). 1960 and 1980.
15 Borjas (1990, ch. 10) and Ivan Light and
To some extent, the inter-group vari-
Edna Bonacich (1988) provide detailed studies of ation in skills documented in Table 8
self-employment in the immigrant population. mirrors the dispersion in skills across the
16 An exception is given by Ann Bartels (1989)
populations of the various source coun-
analysis of the internal migration decisions of for-
eign-born workers in the United States. Bartel tries. There is, for example, a great deal
finds that immigrants choose to reside in areas of dispersion in educational attainment
where there are other immigrants, and that their across countries (Robert Barro and Jong-
internal migration decision are much less sensitive
to regional wage differentials than those of na- Wha Lee 1993). Even if the immigrant
tives. flow was randomly drawn from the popu-
TABLE 8
EDUCATIONAL ATTAINMENT AND WAGES OF IMMIGRANT MEN IN 1990, BY NATIONAL ORIGIN GROUP

Percentage Wage
Differential Between
Educational Attainment Immigrants and Natives
All Pre-1980 All Pre-1980
Country of Birth Immigrants Arrivals Immigrants Arrivals
Europe:
Austria 14.68 14.50 38.4 40.9
Czechoslovakia 14.46 14.49 25.9 37.4
France 14.76 14.03 25.7 27.8
Germany 13.88 13.69 24.5 25.1
Greece 11.83 11.59 .9 2.4
Hungary 13.59 13.37 27.3 31.9
Italy 10.90 10.71 16.1 17.4
Poland 12.77 12.36 .3 19.8
Portugal 8.29 8.40 3.1 .1
U.S.S.R. 14.23 14.17 6.2 20.2
United Kingdom 14.60 14.35 37.2 37.9
Yugoslavia 11.75 11.47 11.5 17.5

Asia:
Cambodia 10.22 11.71 30.8 14.6
China 12.82 13.20 21.3 1.9
India 15.94 16.61 17.6 56.2
Iran 15.52 15.90 6.8 18.6
Japan 15.18 14.67 49.3 27.5
Korea 14.25 14.87 12.0 10.8
Laos 9.98 10.49 32.4 28.3
Lebanon 14.16 13.90 2.0 10.2
Philippines 14.05 14.09 5.9 9.7
Taiwan 16.32 17.18 13.9 50.7
Vietnam 12.26 13.25 18.9 2.4
,
North and South America: ,
Argentina 13.35 13.17 4.7 17.2
Canada 13.79 13.56 24.0 23.9
Colombia 12.08 12.31 19.1 5.5
Cuba 11.74 12.26 15.3 5.3
Dominican Republic 10.28 10.46 29.2 21.7
Ecuador 11.55 11.88 20.6 9.6
El Salvador 8.61 9.60 39.7 27.5
Guatemala 9.23 10.27 38.2 21.8
Haiti 11.22 12.22 30.2 13.6
Jamaica 11.97 12.35 11.2 3.1
Mexico 7.61 7.56 39.5 32.3
Nicaragua 11.73 12.32 34.8 11.3
Panama 13.41 13.44 1.9 11.3
Peru 12.99 13.13 20.6 .3
Africa:
Egypt 15.62 15.71 12.2 41.9
Ethiopia 13.97 15.43 21.0 6.5
Nigeria 15.80 16.52 18.9 3.9
South Africa 15.91 15.93 43.6 58.4
Australia 15.21 15.10 33.0 30.5

Source: See Table 3. The educational attainment of native men in 1990 is 13.2 years.
Borjas: The Economics of Immigration 1687

lation of the source countries, the educa- $6,823 (in 1980 dollars). By contrast, the
tional attainment of immigrants who en- respective statistic for the typical immi-
tered the United States in the 1980s grant who arrived in the late 1970s is
would differ from that of earlier immi- $3,828. Because the elasticity of the
grant waves. earnings of immigrants in the United
To illustrate the importance of this States with respect to per capita GNP in
compositional effect, Borjas (1992b) cal- the source country is on the order of .04,
culated the average schooling level of immigrants who arrived in the late 1950s
the country represented by the typical will earn about 4 percent more than
immigrant for a number of immigrant those who arrived in the late 1970s, even
waves. The typical immigrant who ar- if the immigrant flow were randomly se-
rived between 1955 and 1960 originated lected from the source countries.
in a country where the average person
had 9.5 years of schooling. This statistic B. The Self-Selection of the Immigrant
declined to 7.7 years for the 19751980 Flow
flow. If immigrants were randomly The immigrant flow, however, is not
drawn from the source countrys popula- randomly selected from the population
tion and if the rate of return to schooling of the source countries. Borjas (1987) ar-
is on the order of 7 percent, the declin- gues that the self-selection of the immi-
ing educational attainment of the typical grant flow generates some of the national
source country would alone be responsi- origin differentials documented in Table
ble for a 14 percent decline in relative 8. Suppose that residents of country 0
wages across immigrant cohorts. (the source country) consider migrating
There is also a great deal of variation to country 1 (the host country). Assume
in other types of work-related skills also that migration decisions are irre-
across the various source countries, and versible so that no return migration oc-
these skills are not equally transferable curs. If they choose to remain in the
to the United States. Clearly, the kinds source country, residents of the source
of skills workers acquire in highly devel- country have an earnings distribution
oped economies differ from those ac- given by:
quired in less-developed countries. It
seems likely that skills acquired in ad- log w0 = 0 + 0, (6)
vanced economies are more easily trans-
ferable to the U.S. labor market. In fact, where w0 gives the workers earnings in
the source country; 0 is the mean log
there is a strong positive correlation be-
tween immigrant earnings in the United earnings in the source country; and the
States and the level of economic devel- random variable 0 measures deviations
from mean earnings, and is assumed to
opment in the country of origin, as mea-
sured by the countrys per capita GNP be normally distributed with mean zero
(Guillermina Jasso and Mark Rosenzweig and variance 20.
If the entire population of the source
1986).
There has been a dramatic drop in the country were to migrate to the host
per capita income of the country repre- country, they would face the earnings
distribution:
sented by the typical immigrant entering
the United States (Borjas 1992b). The log w1 = 1 + 1, (7)
average person who immigrated between
1955 and 1960 originated in a country where 1 is the mean log earnings in
which had a 1980 per capita GNP of the host country, and the random vari-
1688 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXII (December 1994)

able 1 measures deviations from mean equivalent migration costs, , are con-
earnings, and is normally distributed stant in the population (so that migration
with mean zero and variance 21. The cor- costs are proportional to wages). The
relation coefficient between the random probability that a person migrates to the
variables 0 and 1 equals . host country can then be written as:
The population mean 1 need not
equal the mean earnings of native work- P = Pr{ > (0 + 1)} = 1 (z), (9)
ers in the host country. The average
worker in the source country, for in- where = 1 0, z = (0 + 1)/v,
stance, might be less skilled than the av- and is the standard normal distribu-
erage worker in the United States. For tion function. It is easy to show that:
convenience, it is useful to assume that
P P P
the typical person in both countries is < 0, > 0, and < 0. (10)
equally skilled, so that 1 also gives the 0 1
mean earnings of natives in the host
country. This assumption helps isolate The emigration rate is negatively cor-
the impact of the selection process on related with mean earnings in the source
the skill composition of the immigrant country and with migration costs, and is
flow. positively correlated with mean earnings
Equations (6) and (7) summarize the in the host country. Although most stud-
earnings opportunities available to po- ies analyzing internal migration flows fo-
tential migrants in the source and host cus on the determinants of the size and
countries. The migration decision is de- direction of migration flows, there are
termined by a comparison of earnings other equally important questions which
opportunities across countries, net of mi- can be analyzed in the context of the in-
gration costs (C). Define the index func- come maximization model. For instance,
tion: which persons find it worthwhile to mi-
grate to the host country?
w1 ( ) + ( ), (8)
I = log This question is at the heart of Andrew
1 0 1 0
w0 + C Roys (1951) well-known model of self-
where = C/w0 gives a time-equivalent selection, which describes how workers
measure of migration costs. A worker sort themselves among employment op-
migrates to the host country if I > 0 portunities (Michael Sattinger 1993).
and remains in the source country other- The implications of the income-maximi-
wise. zation hypothesis for the selection of the
Migration costs C will differ among immigrant flow are easily grasped by
workers. For instance, newly arrived im- evaluating the conditional means E(log
migrants may be unemployed while they w0 | I > 0), which gives the earnings of
look for employment, suggesting that immigrants prior to their migration, and
high-wage migrants might have higher E(log w1 | I > 0), which gives immigrant
migration costs. High-wage migrants, earnings in the host country. Because of
however, are more likely to have prior the normality assumption, these condi-
job connections and better information tional means are given by: 17
about job opportunities, suggesting a 17 To derive equation (11), note that:
negative correlation between migration
E(log w 0 I > 0) = 0 + 0 E( 0 v > z),
costs C and wages. The immigrant also
where 0 = 0/0, v = v/v. Because the conditional
incurs transportation costs. It is instruc- expectation of a normal density is linear, we can write 0 =
tive to assume initially that the time- 0v v + , where 0v is the correlation between 0 and v,
Borjas: The Economics of Immigration 1689

E(log w0 I > 0) bution. The strong positive correlation


01 0 between earnings in the source and host
= 0 + , (11) countries ensures that skills are portable
v 1
across countries. The immigrant popula-
E(log w1 I > 0) tion is then drawn from the upper tail of
01 1 the earnings distribution because the
= 1 + , (12)
v 0
source country, in a sense, taxes high-
ability workers and insures less able
where = (z)/(1 (z)), and is the workers against poor labor market out-
density of the standard normal. The vari- comes.
able is inversely related to the emigra- Equation (14) indicates that immi-
tion rate and is positive as long as some grants are negatively selected (i.e., have
persons find it profitable to remain in below-average earnings in both the
the source country (P < 1). source and host countries) when the cor-
Let Q0 = E(e 0 | I > 0) and Q1 = E(e 1 | relation coefficient is sufficiently high
I > 0). Inspection of equations (11) and and when the earnings distribution in
(12) indicates that there are three possi- the source country has a larger variance
ble types of selection characterizing the than the earnings distribution in the host
immigrant flow: country. The immigration flow is nega-
tively selected, therefore, when the host
Q0 > 0 and Q 1 > 0
country taxes high-income workers and
0 1
if and only if > and > 1. (13) provides better insurance for low-income
1 0 workers.
Q0 < 0 and Q1 < 0
Finally, equation (15) describes the
characteristics of a refugee sorting,
1 0
if and only if > and > 1. (14) where immigrants have below-average
0 1 earnings in the source country but end
Q0 < 0 and Q1 > 0 up in the upper tail of the earnings dis-
1 0 tribution of the host country. This sort-
if and only if < min , . (15) ing occurs when is small or negative.
0 1 The correlation might be negative after
Equation (13) shows that immigrants a source country experiences a Commu-
are positively selected (i.e., have above- nist takeover. This political system (at
average earnings in both the source and least in its initial stages) redistributes in-
host countries) when the correlation be- comes by confiscating the assets of rela-
tween skills in the two countries is suffi- tively successful persons. The model sug-
ciently high and when the host country gests that immigrants from such systems
has more dispersion in its earnings distri- will be in the lower tail of the revolu-
tionary earnings distribution, but will
and is independent of v*. The mean earnings of perform well in the host countrys mar-
immigrants in the source country are then given ket economy.
by:

Note that the type of selection charac-
E(log w 0 I > 0) = 0 + 0 0v E(v v > z).
terizing the immigrant flow depends on
Equation (11) follows directly by noting that
0 v = ( 0 1 20 )/ 0 v and = E(v v > z). Equa- the second moments of the earnings dis-
tion (12) can be derived in an analogous manner. It is tributions. Put differently, because the
worth noting that the random variables 0 and 1 can be underlying distribution of skills is being
decomposed into observable and unobservable compo-
nents so that the framework applies to selection in both held constant, the variance of the earn-
types of skill characteristics. ings distribution proxies for the price of
1690 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXII (December 1994)

skills, and thus serves an allocative role Kingdom. Deborah Cobb-Clark (1993)
in the sorting of persons across coun- finds a similar negative correlation be-
tries. It is worth noting that neither the tween the earnings of immigrant women
difference in mean earnings nor the level in the United States and measures of the
of migration costs determines the type of rate of return to schooling in the source
selection that characterizes the immi- countries. Finally, Edward Taylors
grant flow. 18 Although the first moments (1987) case study of migration in a rural
determine the size and direction of the Mexican village concludes that Mexicans
flow, they do not determine if immi- who migrated illegally to the United
grants are drawn mainly from the upper States are less skilled, on average, than
or lower tails of the earnings distribu- the typical person residing in the village.
tion. This type of selection is consistent with
The empirical evidence provides some the fact that Mexico has a relatively high
support for the equilibrium skill sorting rate of return to skills.
implied by the model. Borjas (1990, ch. The discussion provides an interesting
7) reports that measures of income in- explanation of the decline in the relative
equality in the source country, which are skills of immigrant cohorts admitted to
a rough proxy for the rate of return to the United States in the postwar era.
skills, are negatively correlated with the Prior to the 1965 Amendments, the allo-
earnings of immigrant men in the United cation of visas was guided by the ethnic
States. 19 Holding constant a vector of ob- composition of the U.S. population in
servable socioeconomic characteristics 1920, and thus favored immigration from
(including educational attainment and a small number of Western European
age), the point estimates suggest that countries. The 1965 Amendments re-
Mexican immigrant men earn about 4 pealed the national-origins quota system
percent less than British immigrants and greatly increased the number of im-
simply because of the selectivity effect migrants originating in Asian and Latin
resulting from Mexico having a higher American countries. The new immigra-
rate of return to skills than the United tion, therefore, is more likely to origi-
nate in countries where the population
18 Although the discussion assumed that migra-
tends to be less skilled, where skills are
tion costs (in time-equivalent terms) are constant, less easily transferable to the United
it is not difficult to incorporate liquidity con- States, and where the rate of return to
straints or variable migration costs into the model. skills is relatively high. All these factors
For instance, economic conditions might motivate
the least-skilled to migrate, but liquidity con- contribute to a decline in the relative
straints prevent the migration of these workers. skills of successive immigrant waves. 20
The best of the worst will then move if the flow The self-selection model can be ex-
is negatively selected. Similarly, if migration costs
are correlated with earnings, the selection charac-
terizing the immigrant flow may change in either 20 Part of the national origin wage differentials
direction. If, for example, migration costs are posi- may also arise from discrimination against particu-
tively correlated with earnings, the immigrant flow lar groups. The literature has not investigated this
is more likely to be negatively selected. It is easy hypothesis seriously because the evidence on the
to show that the correlation between migration Hispanic/non-Hispanic or the Asian/white wage
costs and earnings can change the type of selec- differential among native workers does not lend
tion only if the variance in migration costs is suffi- itself to a simple discrimination interpretation.
ciently high relative to the variance in skills. Cordelia Reimers (1983) finds that much of the
19 Alan Barrett (1993) shows that immigrants Hispanic/non-Hispanic wage differential is attrib-
who enter the United States using a family reunifi- utable to differences in observable characteristics,
cation visa have relatively lower earnings when while Chiswick (1983) shows that Asian groups ac-
they originate in countries where the income dis- tually have higher wages than white workers, even
tribution has a large variance. after controlling for observable characteristics.
Borjas: The Economics of Immigration 1691

tended to incorporate the fact that mi- Negatively-Selected Positively-Selected


Immigrant Flow Immigrant Flow
gration decisions are reversible. Return
migration can arise for two distinct rea-
sons. First, it may be the optimal resi-
dential location plan over the life cycle.
In other words, workers reside in the
host country for a few years and then re- nL nH Skills
turn to their home countries after accu- Figure 3. The Self-selection of Return Migrants
mulating sufficiently large levels of hu-
man capital or wealth. This mobility the immigrant flow is positively selected
pattern allows some workers to attain so that all workers with skill level ex-
higher utility or wealth than if the migra- ceeding vH emigrate. The worker with
tion decision was permanent. Alterna- skill level vH is the marginal immi-
tively, return migration flows may result grant; he is indifferent between migrat-
from mistakes in the initial migration de- ing and not migrating. As a result, the
cision.21 Potential immigrants are uncer- immigrants with skill level in the neigh-
tain about the economic conditions avail- borhood of vH are most susceptible to
able to them in the destination. As a improved opportunities in the source
result, the actual outcomes experienced country or to adverse random shocks in
in the host countrys labor market differ the host countrys labor market. The re-
from the expected outcomes that guided turn migrants are the worst of the best.
the immigration decision. As long as re- If the return migration flow is negatively
turn migration costs are relatively low, selected, the immigrants have skills be-
immigrants who experience worse-than- low vL. The persons in the neighborhood
expected outcomes will return to their of vL are the marginal immigrants, and
home country. the return migrants are the best of the
Borjas and Bernt Bratsberg (forthcom- worst.
ing) argue that regardless of which of The limited empirical evidence sup-
these two factors generates return migra- ports these theoretical implications. Fer-
tion, the implications for the skill com- nando Ramos (1992) analyzes the return
position of the surviving immigrant migration decisions of Puerto Ricans liv-
stock are the same: return migration ac- ing in the United States. The joint study
centuates the selection that characterizes of the Puerto Rican and U.S. Censuses
the initial migration flow. The intuition provides valuable information on the
is illustrated in Figure 3 for the special characteristics of Puerto Ricans living in
case where earnings are perfectly corre- the United States, of Puerto Ricans who
lated across countries.22 Suppose that remained in their homeland, and of
Puerto Ricans who returned to Puerto
21 Eliakim Katz and Oded Stark (1987) present
Rico after living in the United States for
a model of how the immigrant flow is selected
based on the assumption that there is asymmetric a brief period. The data indicate that
information in the migration decision (workers Puerto Rican immigrants in the United
know their skills and earnings in the source coun- States are relatively unskilled, but that
try, but not in the host country).
22 The assumption that earnings are perfectly
correlated across countries implies that we can h 1s > 0 + h0s. We can rewrite this decision rule as
write the wage structure for country i (i = 0,1) as (h1 h0) s > (0 1). Thus, there exists a thresh-
log wi = i + hi s, where s is a random variable old level of skills that separates out the migrants
describing a workers skills; and hi is the rate of from the nonmigrants. Note that this result does
return to skills. Ignoring migration costs, a resi- not depend on the distribution of the random vari-
dent of the source country migrates when 1 + able s.
1692 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXII (December 1994)

the return migrants are relatively more migration decisions are made in a family
skilled than the typical immigrant. The context (Cobb-Clark 1990; Borjas and
typical Puerto Rican who migrated to the Stephen Bronars 1991). The maximiza-
United States prior to 1975 had 9.4 years tion of family income implies that the
of schooling, as compared to 10.8 years immigrant flow contains some tied mov-
for a Puerto Rican who never left Puerto ers, persons who would not have mi-
Rico. The Puerto Rican migration flow, grated on their own but who migrate as
therefore, is negatively selected. In con- part of the household. This approach will
trast, the typical Puerto Rican who re- likely play a crucial role in under-
turned to Puerto Rico after a stint in the standing skill trends among immigrant
United States had 9.8 years of schooling. women, both in terms of cohort effects
Borjas and Bratsberg (forthcoming) and wage convergence. The early work
find a relationship between the rate of of James Long (1980), based on the 1970
return migration for a particular national Census cross-section, suggests that the
origin group and the average earnings of labor market experiences of immigrant
the surviving stock of immigrants in the women in the United States differ sub-
United States. In particular, a high rate stantially from those of men. For exam-
of return migration for the national ori- ple, the earnings of immigrant women
gin group increases the average earnings are negatively correlated with years-
of the surviving immigrants when the im- since-migration. Remarkably, there has
migrant flow is positively selected (i.e., been little empirical research document-
originates in a country with a low rate of ing the skill trends among immigrant
return to skills), and reduces the average women since that early study.
earnings of the surviving stock when the
immigrant flow is negatively selected C. The Host Countrys Demand for
(i.e., originates in a country with a high Immigrants
rate of return to skills). Even though the
return migration rates in the Borjas- Even though Roys self-selection
Bratsberg study are measured with a model has influenced our thinking about
great deal of error, the empirical evi- how the immigrant flow is chosen from
dence suggests that return migration the source countrys population, it is im-
does accentuate the selection of immi- portant to stress that the model only
grants at either tail of the skill distribu- gives the supply side of the immigra-
tion. Bratsberg (1993) shows that the re- tion market. Workers who wish to mi-
turn migration rate of foreign students in grate to a particular host country can do
the United States differs substantially so only if the host countrys government
across source countries. For example, allows it. The immigration market is
only about 3 percent of students origi- highly regulated. Most countries have
nating in Mexico or Germany choose to strict policies describing the demo-
remain in the United States, as opposed graphic characteristics of persons who
to nearly 30 percent of students originat- are allowed to enter the country (such as
ing in Israel, Poland, and Kenya. The skills, national origin, or family ties with
data indicate that foreign students are current residents). The size and skill
more likely to return to wealthier coun- composition of the immigrant flow,
tries and to countries which offer high therefore, are jointly determined by the
rates of return to schooling. supply-side considerations stressed in
Roys framework has also been ex- the self-selection model as well as by fac-
panded to incorporate the idea that im- tors which influence the host countrys
Borjas: The Economics of Immigration 1693

demand for immigrants (or, equivalently, sons veto (suggesting that their immi-
the supply of visas). grant constituents did not support a re-
In general, the supply of visas is deter- strictionist policy towards unskilled
mined by the host countrys political and workers). 23 In contrast, legislators repre-
economic gains from immigration. For senting districts where wages were stag-
instance, the returns to immigration will nant voted to override the veto (implying
depend partly on the benefits accruing that their constituents had little to gain,
from admitting workers who can special- and perhaps much to lose, from admit-
ize in particular industries and occupa- ting more immigrants). Therefore, it
tions, and will also be determined by the seems as if further research on the politi-
impact of immigrant flows on the em- cal economy of immigration policy might
ployment opportunities of natives as well greatly improve our understanding of the
as on the social fabric of the host coun- properties of equilibrium in the immi-
try. It is also clear that there will be dif- gration market.
ferential benefits from admitting skilled
or unskilled immigrant flows, depending 5. International Differences in
on the skill composition of the native Immigrant Performance
work force and on the generosity of so-
cial insurance programs. The performance of immigrants in the
Unfortunately, the literature does not host countrys labor market has been
yet provide a systematic analysis of the documented in a number of other coun-
factors that generate the host countrys tries, including Australia (John Beggs
demand function for immigrants. Recent and Bruce Chapman 1991); Britain
work by Jess Benhabib (1993) constructs (Chiswick 1980); Germany (Christian
a demand curve by noting that natives Dustmann 1993; Jrn-Steffen Pischke
differ in their wealth, so that there will 1993); and Israel (Friedberg 1993).
be both winners and losers from the These international comparisons help as-
choice of a particular immigration policy. sess the impact of differences in immi-
The demand function for immigrants is gration policy. The most extensive re-
then an exercise in political economy, search has been conducted on the
and depends on the extent to which the immigrant experience in Canada, which
winners can compensate the losers. Rich- by the early 1990s had an annual immi-
ard Freeman (1993) conjectures that the grant flow on the order of one percent of
demand curve for immigrants might be its population (Michael Baker and
mostly determined by discrimination Dwayne Benjamin 1994; Bloom,
against some national origin groups. Grenier, and Morley Gunderson forth-
A promising exploration of the factors coming; and Robert Wright and Paul
that shift the U.S. demand for immi- Maxim 1993).
grants is given by Claudia Goldins Until 1961, Canadian immigration pol-
(1994) study of the origins of the na- icy, like that of the United States, per-
tional-origins quota system. In 1915, mitted the entry of persons originating in
Congress enacted legislation requiring only a few countries, such as the United
immigrants to pass a literacy test, effec- 23 Lindsay Lowell, Frank Bean, and Rodolfo De
tively reducing the demand for unskilled La Garza (1986) report that Congressmen repre-
immigrants. President Woodrow Wilson senting districts with large Hispanic populations
vetoed the legislation. Legislators repre- were more likely to oppose enactment of an early
version of the 1986 Immigration Reform and Con-
senting districts with large immigrant trol Act (which made it illegal for employers to
populations voted not to override Wil- hire illegal aliens).
1694 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXII (December 1994)

TABLE 9
EDUCATIONAL ATTAINMENT AND WAGES OF IMMIGRANTS IN CANADA AND THE UNITED STATES

Host Country
Cohort/Census Year Canada United States
Educational Attainment:
196064 Cohort as of 1970 10.5 10.9
197580 Cohort as of 1980 12.6 11.8
Natives as of 1970 9.9 11.5
Natives as of 1980 11.3 12.7
Percentage Wage Differential Between Immigrants
and Natives in Host Country:
196064 Cohort as of 1970 .8 4.4
197580 Cohort as of 1980 15.8 27.6

Source: Borjas (1993b, p. 28). The statistics are calculated in the subsample of men aged 2564 who work in the
civilian sector, who are not self-employed, and who do not reside in group quarters. The Canadian data are drawn
from the 1971 and 1981 Public Use Samples of the Canadian Census, while the U.S. data are drawn from the 1970
and 1980 Public Use Samples of the U.S. Census.

Kingdom, or of persons who were de- schooling than the typical immigrant en-
pendents of Canadian residents. Major tering the United States. In addition, the
policy changes in 1962 and 1967 re- typical immigrant entering Canada in the
pealed the national origin restrictions, late 1970s earned 16 percent less than
and shifted the emphasis towards skills Canadian-born workers, while the typical
requirements. Under current regula- immigrant entering the United States
tions, applicants for entry into Canada earned about 28 percent less than U.S.-
are classified into three classes: the fam- born workers.24
ily class (which includes close relatives of A number of recent studies attempt to
Canadian residents), assisted relatives determine why Canada attracts rela-
(which includes more distant relatives of tively more skilled immigrants than the
Canadian residents), and independent United States. Surprisingly, there is little
immigrants. Visa applicants in the last difference in average skills between im-
two classes are screened by means of a migrants in Canada and in the United
point system. Points are awarded ac- States for given national origin groups
cording to such factors as the applicants (Borjas 1993b; Duleep and Regets
education, age, and occupation. Appli- 1992a). In other words, the typical Ital-
cants who get a passing score are ian immigrant in Canada has about as
awarded an entry visa. much schooling and does about as well in
As Table 9 shows, the point system
seems to have had a major impact on the 24 The evidence also indicates that Canada ex-
skill level of immigrants in Canada. In perienced a decline in relative wages across suc-
the early 1960s, the typical immigrant cessive immigrant waves, although not as steep as
the decline observed in the United States. Wright
entering Canada had about half-a-year and Maxim (1993) suggest that the Canadian de-
less schooling than the typical immigrant cline occurred both because of a change in the
entering the United States. By the late national origin mix of immigrants and because of a
decrease in the share of independent class immi-
1970s, the typical immigrant entering grants (so that the point system became less rele-
Canada had almost one more year of vant over time).
Borjas: The Economics of Immigration 1695

the labor market as the typical Italian The experience of immigrants in Can-
immigrant in the United States. The na- ada differs from the experience of their
tional origin mix of immigrants in Can- U.S. counterparts in one other notable
ada and the United States, however, dif- way. Baker and Benjamin (1994) docu-
fers substantially, with a larger fraction ment that over a 10 year period, the rela-
of the Canadian immigrant flow originat- tive wage of immigrants in Canada might
ing in European countries. During the increase by at most 3 percentage points,
1980s, 27 percent of the immigrant flow less than half of the wage growth experi-
entering Canada originated in Europe, as enced by immigrants in the United
compared to only 10.4 percent for the States. This finding suggests that a fruit-
United States. Therefore, part of the dif- ful avenue for future research might be
ference between the average skill level to investigate why the adjustment pro-
of immigrants in Canada and the United cess of immigrants differs across host
States is attributable to the different na- countries.
tional origin mix of immigrants in the As noted above, a number of studies
two host countries. analyze immigrant labor market perform-
This finding raises important questions ance in other host countries. There is a
about how a Canadian-style point system great deal of diversity in the results of
works. It would be a mistake to claim these studies, but the evidence generally
that the point system is ineffective be- suggests that countries which have skill
cause it seems to have little impact on filters attract a relatively more skilled
the education level or relative wages of immigrant flow. Australia, for example,
specific national origin groups. An alter- has a point system similar to the Cana-
native, though little discussed, effect of dian one. Beggs and Chapman (1991) re-
the point system is to reallocate visas port that immigrants in Australia have
across source countries. Consider, for in- high relative wages. In contrast, Pischke
stance, the implications of how educa- (1993) finds that immigrants in Germany
tion is rewarded in the point system. In (who for the most part were Turkish
the late 1960s, a visa applicant was given guest workers admitted in the 1960s)
1 point per year of education, and only have lower wages than native Germans
50 out of 100 points were needed to and do not experience any wage conver-
pass the test. Persons originating in gence over the life cycle.
countries that have a high level of educa-
tional attainment are more likely to qual- 6. The Impact of Immigrants on Native
ify for entry than persons originating in Earnings and Employment
countries where the typical person has
Do immigrants have an adverse impact
little schooling. It is likely, therefore,
on native earnings and employment op-
that the point system plays an important
portunities? If so, how large is the loss in
role in determining the national origin
the economic welfare of native workers?
mix of the immigrant flow. 25
Are all native groups equally affected by
the entry of immigrants into the labor
25 Allan Green and David Green (1994) argue market? A rapidly growing literature now
that the point system affects the skill level of im- purports to document the impact of im-
migrants because it influences the occupational migrants on the native labor market in a
distribution of the immigrant flow, with occupa-
tions that are in demand being much more rep-
resented in the immigrant flow. The point system distribution is more compatible with the one de-
thus alters the national origin mix because workers sired by Canada have a larger probability of ob-
originating in countries where the occupational taining a visa.
1696 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXII (December 1994)

number of host countries. As we will see 05) show that the resulting change in the
below, however, a number of conceptual wage of skilled and unskilled workers is
problems plague this literature. As a re- given by: 26
sult, the accumulated empirical evidence
b N
has little to say about the underlying log ws =
questions. s s b(1 b) N
To understand the impact of immigra- N
= s , (19)
tion on native employment opportuni- N
ties, suppose we view a labor market as a
closed economy where a single competi- 1 b N
log wu =
tive industry uses a linear homogeneous u u b(1 b) N
production function to produce Q units N
of a good (Joseph Altonji and David Card = u , (20)
N
1991). The production process uses both
skilled and unskilled workers. The wage where = Nu Du (wu, p)/Q; i $ 0 is the la-
rates of skilled and unskilled workers are bor supply elasticity of type-i workers;
ws and wu, respectively. The cost func- and i < 0 is the labor demand elasticity
tion in this industry is then given by for type-i workers.
Qc(ws, wu), where c(ws, wu) is the unit Equations (19) and (20) give the re-
cost function. Perfect competition im- duced-form impact of immigration on
plies that the price of the output, p, the skilled and unskilled wage. Suppose
equals the unit cost of production, so that the fraction of unskilled workers in
that p = c(ws, wu). the immigrant flow () equals the frac-
Both skilled and unskilled workers tion of unskilled workers in the native
purchase the good. Each type-i worker population (b). The linear homogeneity
(i = s, u) has an output demand function of the production function then implies
given by Di(wi, p). There are Ns skilled that neither the skilled nor the unskilled
workers and Nu unskilled workers, and wage changes as a result of immigration.
the fraction of unskilled workers in the Alternatively, if the fraction of unskilled
population is b. Product market equilib- workers in the immigrant flow exceeds
rium requires: the respective fraction among natives
( > b), immigration increases the skilled
Q = Ns Ds (ws, p) + Nu Du (wu , p). (16) wage and decreases the unskilled wage.
To close the model, suppose the labor This conceptual experiment, there-
supply function of each type-i worker is fore, indicates precisely how the impact
L i(wi, p). Labor market equilibrium im- of immigration on native employment
plies: opportunities can be measured. If we
could observe a number of closed labor
Ns Ls (ws, p) = Q cs(ws,wu) (17) markets which immigrants penetrate ran-
domly, we can then relate the change in
Nu Lu (wu, p) = Q cu (ws,wu), (18) the wage of skilled and unskilled workers
where c i = ]c/]wi.
26 To derive these equations, differentiate the
Consider now what would happen if
labor market equilibrium conditions, the product
N immigrants enter the labor market market equilibrium condition, and the zero profit
exogenously. Suppose that the fraction of condition, assuming that ]D i/]wi = 0, ]L i/]p = 0,
unskilled workers in the immigrant flow and that the cross-elasticities of factor demand are
zero, so that the demand for skilled (unskilled)
equals . Under some simplifying condi- workers is independent of the unskilled (skilled)
tions, Altonji and Card (1991, pp. 204 wage.
Borjas: The Economics of Immigration 1697

TABLE 10
ELASTICITY OF NATIVE WAGES WITH RESPECT TO THE NUMBER OF IMMIGRANTS IN LOCALITY

Impact of Elasticity
Study Immigrants on: Dependent Variable Estimate
Altonji and Card (1991, Less Skilled Natives Weekly wages +.01
p. 220)
Bean, Lowell, and Native Mexican Men Annual earnings .005 to + .05
Taylor (1988, p. 44) Black Men Annual earnings
.003 to + .06
Borjas (1990, p. 87) White Native Men Annual earnings -.01
Black Native Men Annual earnings .02
Grossman (1982, All Natives Factor share of native
p. 600) workers .02
LaLonde and Topel Young Black Natives Annual earnings .06
(1991, p. 186) Young Hispanic Natives Annual earnings .01

to the proportion of immigrants in the Table 10 summarizes the results of


population (after adjusting for the skill representative studies in this literature.
composition of both the native popula- The across-city correlations in the
tion and the immigrant flow). The esti- United States generally indicate that the
mated parameters would summarize the average native wage is slightly lower in
impact of immigrants on native employ- labor markets where immigrants tend to
ment opportunities. reside. 27 The point estimates of the elas-
Practically all empirical studies in the ticity of the native wage with respect to
literature, beginning with Jean Grossman the number of immigrants cluster
(1982), attempt to replicate this experi- around .01 to .02, so that if one city
ment by treating a city or metropolitan has 10 percent more immigrants than an-
area as the empirical counterpart of the other, the native wage in the city with
closed labor market in the theoretical more immigrants is only about .2 percent
analysis. The typical study then regresses lower. The evidence also indicates that
a measure of the native wage in the lo- the numerically weak relationship be-
cality on the relative quantity of immi- tween native wages and immigration is
grants in that locality (or the change in observed across all types of native work-
the wage in the locality over a specified ers, white or black, skilled or unskilled,
time period on the change in the number male or female. 28 In terms of the pa-
of immigrants in the locality). Equations
(19) and (20) show that the impact of im- 27 Many of these studies also find a significant

migration will also depend on the skill negative correlation between immigration and the
immigrant wage. For instance, Grossman (1982)
distribution of immigrants relative to reports that a 10 percent increase in the number
that of natives. The empirical studies, of immigrants reduces the immigrant wage by 2
however, typically ignore the skill differ- percent, while Altonji and Card (1991) conclude
that a 10 percent increase in the number of immi-
entials that exist in both the native and grants reduces the immigrant wage by at least 4
immigrant populations across metropoli- percent.
28 An exception to this result is given by Altonji
tan areas, and simply calculate the corre-
and Card (1991), who relate the wage change ex-
lation between the immigrant share and perienced by natives in a particular metropolitan
the native wage. area between 1970 and 1980 to the change in the
1698 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXII (December 1994)

TABLE 11
ELASTICITY OF NATIVE EMPLOYMENT WITH RESPECT TO THE NUMBER OF IMMIGRANTS IN LOCALITY

Impact of Elasticity
Study Immigrants on: Dependent Variable/Remarks Estimate
Altonji and Less Skilled Natives Employment-population ratio .038
Card (1991, p. 220) Weeks worked .062

Borjas (1990, p. 92) White Native Men Labor force participation rate -.01
Black Native Men Labor force participation rate +.04
Thomas Muller and
Thomas Espenshade
(1985, p. 100) Black Natives Unemployment rate .01
Julian Simon, Stephen Natives Unemployment rate +.001
Moore, and Richard
Sullivan (1993)
C. Winegarden and Lay Young White Natives Unemployment rate .01
Khor (1991, p. 109) Young Black Natives Unemployment rate .003

rameters of equations (19) and (20), the United States could leave freely from
therefore, the literature concludes that the port of Mariel. By September 1980,
s u .02. about 125,000 Cubans, mostly unskilled
Though most of the studies focus on workers, had chosen to undertake the
the relationship between native earnings journey. Almost overnight, Miamis labor
and the immigrant share in the local la- force had unexpectedly grown by 7 per-
bor market, some studies also estimate cent. Cards (1990) influential analysis of
the correlation between immigration and the data indicates that the time-series
native labor force participation rates, trend in wages and employment opportu-
hours worked, and unemployment rates. nities for Miamis workers, including its
Table 11 summarizes representative re- black population, was barely nudged by
sults in the literature. It is evident that the Mariel flow. The trend in the wage
immigration has a weak effect on the em- and unemployment rates of Miamis
ployment of natives. workers between 1980 and 1985 was
Studies of specific labor markets con- similar to that experienced by workers in
firm the finding that immigration seems such cities as Los Angeles, Houston, and
to have little impact even when the mar- Atlanta, cities which did not experience
ket receives very large immigrant flows. the Mariel flow.
On April 20, 1980, Fidel Castro declared In short, the estimated correlations
that Cuban nationals wishing to move to between native wages and the immigrant
share in local labor markets do not sup-
port the hypothesis that the employment
share of immigrant workers in that locality. When opportunities of U.S.-born workers are
they instrument the change in the localitys immi-
grant share with a second-order polynomial in the
strongly and adversely affected by immi-
fraction of the work force that was foreign-born in gration. Moreover, the evidence for
1970, the estimated elasticity is .8. It is doubtful, other host countries is similar. Pischke
however, that the immigrant share in 1970 is a
valid instrument for the growth in the immigrant
and Johannes Vellings (1994) study of
share. the German labor market relies on the
Borjas: The Economics of Immigration 1699

same across-city comparisons that domi- which provide them the best opportuni-
nate the U.S. literature, and finds a weak ties. Therefore, the correlations typically
negative correlation between the native estimated in the literature have no struc-
wage and the fraction of immigrants in tural interpretation; they do not estimate
the work force; and Jennifer Hunt (1992) the demand function for native workers,
reports that, even though 900,000 per- nor do they estimate the reduced-form
sons returned to France within one year impact of immigrants on native employ-
after the 1962 independence of Algeria ment opportunities. 30
(increasing the French labor force by 2 A recent study of time-series data
percent), there was little impact on the drawn from the CPS by Borjas, Free-
affected localities.29 man, and L. Katz (1992) provides indi-
The correlations estimated in this ex- rect evidence of the macro impact of im-
tensive literature, however, misspecify migration. As noted earlier, the 1980s
the theoretical experiment described witnessed a substantial increase in the
earlier and hence do not answer the wage gap between workers who do not
question of whether native workers are have a high school diploma and workers
adversely affected by immigration. In with more education. The decade also
particular, the comparison of economic witnessed the entry of large numbers of
conditions in different metropolitan ar- less skilled immigrants. Given reasonable
eas, as well as the pre- and post-immi- estimates of labor demand elasticities,
gration comparison in a particular metro- Borjas, Freeman, and L. Katz conclude
politan area, presumes that the labor that perhaps a third of the 10 percentage
markets are closed (once immigration point decline in the relative wage of high
takes place) and that the migration flow school dropouts between 1980 and 1988
is exogenous. can be attributed to the less skilled im-
Metropolitan areas in the United migration flow.31
States (and abroad) are not closed econo- To reconcile the finding that local la-
mies; labor, capital, and goods flow bor markets do not seem to be affected
freely across localities and tend to equal- by immigration with the possible exist-
ize factor prices in the process. As long ence of an economy-wide impact, Ran-
as native workers and firms respond to
the entry of immigrants by moving to ar- 30 Some studies use the industry, rather than
eas offering better opportunities, there is the local labor market, as the unit of observation
no reason to expect a correlation be- and analyze native employment and wages as im-
migrants penetrate a particular industry (Thomas
tween the wage of natives and the pres- Bailey 1987; John DeNew and Klaus Zimmermann
ence of immigrants. As a result, the com- 1994; Roger Waldinger 1993). The correlations are
parison of local labor markets may be sometimes interpreted in terms of a displacement
effect. As with studies of local labor markets, these
masking the macro effect of immigra- correlations have no structural interpretation as
tion. Moreover, immigrants do not sim- long as workers and firms can move across indus-
ply land in a randomly chosen metropoli- tries.
31 Using CPS data, Topel (1994) also finds that
tan area; presumably they choose areas the relative decline in the wage of less skilled
workers during the 1980s was steepest in labor
markets which had a sizable immigrant presence.
29 William Carrington and Pedro de Lima It is important to stress, however, that the CPS
(1994) report inconclusive results when they ana- data do not identify persons by nativity status, so
lyze the impact of the 600,000 refugees who en- that the decline in the relative wage of unskilled
tered Portugal after the country lost the African workers could be attributable to the fact that the
colonies of Mozambique and Angola in the mid- unskilled wage fell because the new immigrants
1970s, increasing Portugals population by almost earn even lower wages than the unskilled native
7 percent. population.
1700 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXII (December 1994)

dall Filer (1992) and Michael White and Blanchard and L. Katzs (1992) empirical
Lori Hunter (1993) analyze how the in- study of regional labor market adjust-
ternal migration flows of U.S.-born ments in the United States is quite in-
workers respond to immigration. Using structive. They find that a one-time ad-
1980 Census data, they find that metro- verse economic shock to a state (on the
politan areas where immigrants cluster order of a 1 percent demand shock on
experienced lower rates of native in-mi- employment) reduces the states real
gration and somewhat higher rates of na- wage for up to 10 years before the inter-
tives out-migration. This pattern of na- nal migration of workers reequilibrates
tive mobility, of course, dissipates the the wage across regions. The unresolved
impact of immigration over the entire puzzle facing those who interpret the
economy. The evidence for more recent lack of correlation between immigration
time periods, however, seems to be and native wages in the local labor mar-
mixed. Using various CPS supplements ket in terms of an economy-wide equilib-
from the 1980s, Butcher and Card (1991) rium process is clear: Why should it be
and White and Zai Liang (1993) estimate that many other regional variations per-
a positive correlation between immigra- sist over time, but that the impact of im-
tion flows and the in-migration rates of migration on native workers is arbitraged
natives to particular cities, while William away immediately?
Freys (1994) study of the 1990 Census A fair appraisal of the literature thus
reveals that less skilled native workers suggests that we still do not fully under-
residing in states which received large stand how immigrants affect the employ-
immigrant flows in the late 1980s had ment opportunities of natives in local la-
relatively high probabilities of out-migra- bor markets; nor do we understand the
tion. dynamic process through which natives
Although native workers and firms respond to these supply shocks and rees-
probably vote with their feet and at- tablish labor market equilibrium.
tenuate the negative or positive impact
of immigration on local labor markets, 7. Immigration and Welfare
this argument does not fully explain why
immigration has little impact on local la- Historically, the debate over immigra-
bor markets. Cards Mariel study, in tion policy in the United States has re-
particular, raises a number of puzzling volved around the questions of whether
questions. The Marielitos had no im- immigrants assimilate in the United
pact on Miamis labor market even in States and whether they take jobs away
the year when the large migration took from natives. The rapid growth of enti-
place. As a result, the internal flows of tlement programs in the past three de-
labor, capital, and goods can explain the cades introduces an additional explosive
apparent lack of correlation between na- question into the political arena: Do im-
tive earnings and the presence of immi- migrants pay their way in the welfare
grants only if markets adjust instanta- state?
neously. A. Trends in Immigrant Welfare
There exists a great deal of regional Participation
variation in many labor market charac-
teristics and these differences are often The early work of Blau (1984) used the
viewed as the result of equilibrium pro- 1976 Survey of Income and Education to
cesses that are specific to the locality and assess if immigrants and natives had the
that do not disappear quickly. Olivier same propensity for receiving public as-
Borjas: The Economics of Immigration 1701

ment how immigrant participation in


TABLE 12
WELFARE PARTICIPATION RATES OF NATIVE AND
cash-benefit welfare programs changed
IMMIGRANT HOUSEHOLDS, 19701990 over the past twenty years.32 Immigrants
(Percentage of Households Receiving Public were slightly less likely than natives to
Assistance) receive cash benefits in 1970. By 1990,
the fraction of immigrant households
All Households on welfare was 1.7 percentage points
Group 1970 1980 1990 higher than the fraction of native house-
Natives 6.0 7.9 7.4 holds.
All Immigrants 5.9 8.7 9.1 Two distinct factors account for the
Cohort: disproportionate increase in welfare par-
19851989 Arrivals 8.3 ticipation among immigrant households.
19801984 Arrivals 10.7 Recent immigrant waves are more likely
19751979 Arrivals 8.3 10.0 to use welfare than earlier waves, both
19701974 Arrivals 8.4 9.7 relative to natives and in absolute terms.
19651969 Arrivals 5.5 10.1 9.8
19601964 Arrivals 6.5 9.2 8.4 In 1970, only 5.5 percent of the most re-
19501959 Arrivals 4.9 7.1 6.7 cent immigrant households (i.e., house-
Pre-1950 Arrivals 6.2 9.3 8.1 holds that have been in the United
States fewer than five years) received
Source: Authors tabulations from the 1970, 1980, and welfare as compared to 6.0 percent for
1990 Public Use Samples of the U.S. Census. The sta- native households. By 1990, 8.3 percent
tistics are calculated in the subsample of households
where the household head is at least 18 years of age
of the newly arrived immigrant house-
and does not reside in group quarters. holds received public assistance as com-
pared to 7.4 percent of native house-
holds. There are, therefore, significant
cohort effects in welfare participation
sistance (see also Leif Jensen 1988). Blau rates among immigrants.
concluded that immigrant households In addition, the welfare participation
had roughly the same probability of par- rate for a specific immigrant wave in-
ticipating in public assistance programs creases over time. Even though only 5.5
as native households, but that immi- percent of the households that migrated
grants had lower participation rates between 1965 and 1969 received public
when compared to natives who had the assistance in 1970, the welfare participa-
same socioeconomic characteristics (such tion rate of this group increased to about
as household composition and educa- 10 percent in both 1980 and 1990. Immi-
tional attainment of the household grant households, therefore, assimilate
head).
As with the early studies analyzing the 32 The Census data report participation only in
evolution of immigrant earnings, these cash benefits programs, such as Aid to Families
findings were based on studies of cross- with Dependent Children (AFDC) and Supple-
mental Security Income (SSI). The data do not
section data sets. Beginning with Borjas contain any information on participation in non-
and Trejo (1991), recent work analyzes cash programs such as Food Stamps and Medicaid.
the trends in immigrant welfare partici- The statistics are calculated using a 1/1000 ran-
dom sample of native households in each of the
pation using synthetic cohorts created by Censuses and a 5/100 random sample of immi-
pooling Census cross-sections. The re- grant households (except in 1970 when the immi-
sults of this type of research are summa- grant extract forms a 2/100 random sample, and in
1990 when the native extract forms a 5/1000 ran-
rized in Table 12, which uses the 1970, dom sample). The resulting data set contains
1980, and 1990 U.S. Censuses to docu- 1,296,699 observations.
1702 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXII (December 1994)

into welfare.33 This perverse pattern of States. Refugee groups that are typically
adaptation might arise because newly ar- thought of as being economically suc-
rived immigrants fear that they jeopard- cessful, such as the pre-1980 Cubans
ize their chances for naturalization if (who migrated prior to the Mariel flow),
they receive public assistance, or be- have a welfare participation rate of over
cause immigrants learn about welfare 15 percent in 1990.
programs the longer they reside in the The high propensity of refugee house-
United States.34 holds to enter and stay in the welfare
Not surprisingly, there are huge differ- system may be the result of government
ences in welfare participation propensi- policies which supposedly ease the tran-
ties among national origin groups. Table sition of refugees into the United States.
13 reports the welfare participation rates Persons who enter the country as refu-
for selected groups. Only about 2 to 4 gees have immediate access to a wide ar-
percent of the households originating in ray of social services that neither other
South Africa, Taiwan, or the United legal immigrants nor natives qualify for.
Kingdom receive public assistance, as The early introduction of refugees to
opposed to 11 to 12 percent of the public assistance programs seems to have
households originating in Ecuador or a profound and long-term impact.
Mexico, and nearly 50 percent of the The Census data indicate that not only
households originating in Laos or Cam- are the recipiency rates of immigrant
bodia. households rising over time, but that the
The statistics presented in Table 13 dollar costs of immigrant welfare partici-
suggest a major structural shift be- pation are also rising. Table 14 docu-
tween two types of national origin ments that the typical native household
groups. In particular, refugee groups on welfare received roughly $4,000 in
tend to exhibit much higher rates of cash benefits (in 1989 dollars) in all
welfare participation than non-refugee three Census years under study. In con-
groups. As noted earlier, households trast, the typical immigrant household on
originating in Cambodia or Laos had a welfare received about $3,800 in 1970,
welfare participation rate of near 50 per- nearly $4,700 in 1980, and about $5,400
cent; those originating in Vietnam have a in 1990. There are sizable cohort effects
welfare participation rate of 25.8 per- in the welfare income received by immi-
cent; while those originating in Cuba or grant households. In 1970, households
the Soviet Union have a participation who had just entered the country and
rate of 16 percent. Moreover, the partici- were on welfare received an average of
pation rate of refugee groups remains $3,800 in cash benefits. By 1990, the
high even after a decade in the United newly arrived immigrant households on
welfare received an average of $6,400.
33 Borjas and Trejo (1991) show that immigrant Unfortunately, few studies document
households assimilate into welfare programs even immigrant participation in public assis-
when particular age groups are tracked across
Censuses. tance programs for other host countries.
34 Even in 1990, the gap in welfare participation An important exception is the work of
rates between immigrants and natives can be at- Baker and Benjamin (1993), who find
tributed to differences in observable socioeco-
nomic characteristics, such as educational attain- that the typical immigrant in Canada had
ment and household composition. In other words, a lower probability of participating in
it is not immigrant-ness that generates high wel- welfare programs than the typical native.
fare participation rates in the immigrant popula-
tion. Rather, it is the socioeconomic charac- In 1991, the typical native household in
teristics of the immigrant population. Canada had a 9.4 percent welfare partici-
TABLE 13
WELFARE PARTICIPATION RATES IN 1990, BY NATIONAL ORIGIN GROUP

All Pre-1980
Country of Birth Immigrants Arrivals
Europe:
Austria 4.3 4.5
Czechoslovakia 4.9 4.9
France 4.8 5.9
Germany 4.1 4.2
Greece 5.5 5.6
Hungary 5.1 5.1
Italy 5.4 5.6
Poland 5.7 5.9
Portugal 7.1 7.6
U.S.S.R. 16.3 10.1
United Kingdom 3.7 4.1
Yugoslavia 5.3 5.7
Asia:
Cambodia 48.8 24.4
China 10.4 11.1
India 3.4 4.2
Iran 7.5 4.1
Japan 2.3 3.7
Korea 8.1 8.6
Laos 46.3 34.1
Lebanon 7.3 8.8
Philippines 9.8 10.5
Taiwan 3.3 4.2
Vietnam 25.8 15.9
North and South America:
Argentina 4.8 5.7
Canada 4.8 5.1
Colombia 7.5 8.9
Cuba 16.0 15.3
Dominican Republic 27.9 29.9
Ecuador 11.9 13.8
El Salvador 7.3 10.2
Guatemala 8.7 11.4
Haiti 9.1 9.7
Jamaica 7.5 8.7
Mexico 11.3 12.8
Nicaragua 7.8 11.8
Panama 9.0 8.7
Peru 5.9 7.8
,
Africa:
Egypt 5.5 6.7
Ethiopia 5.9 3.0
Nigeria 3.2 3.3
South Africa 1.6 1.6
Australia 3.7 3.8

Source: Authors tabulations from the 1990 Public Use Sample of the U.S.
Census. The statistics are calculated in the subsample of households where
the household head is at least 18 years of age and does not reside in group
quarters.
1704 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXII (December 1994)

fare system than they put in. Jeffrey


TABLE 14
MEAN WELFARE INCOME OF NATIVE AND
Passel and Rebecca Clark (1994), for ex-
IMMIGRANT HOUSEHOLDS, 19701990 ample, conclude that immigrants pay $27
(Calculated in Subsample of Households Receiving billion more in taxes than they take out
Public Assistance, 1989 dollars) of the system, while Donald Huddle
(1993) claims that immigration increases
Group 1970 1980 1990 the native tax burden by about $40 bil-
Natives 3,837 4,248 4,017 lion annually.
All Immigrants 3,806 4,662 5,363 As with all accounting exercises, these
Cohort: studies make many disputable assump-
19851989 Arrivals 6,385 tions which effectively determine the an-
19801984 Arrivals 6,571 swer to the question. There are, how-
19751979 Arrivals 5,228 5,652
19701974 Arrivals 5,220 4,884
ever, a few facts that are directly
19651969 Arrivals 3,830 5,044 4,796 relevant to the debate and that do not
19601964 Arrivals 4,144 5,050 4,480 depend on accounting assumptions. Ta-
19501959 Arrivals 4,402 4,680 4,514 ble 15 summarizes the data for the 1970
Pre-1950 Arrivals 3,629 4,022 4,262 1990 period. The first row of the table
reports the fraction of households in the
Source: Authors tabulations from the 1970, 1980, and
United States that have an immigrant
1990 Public Use Samples of the U.S. Census. The sta-
tistics are calculated in the subsample of households head. This fraction rose from 6.8 percent
where the household head is at least 18 years of age in 1970 to 8.4 percent in 1990. Using
and does not reside in group quarters. Census data it is easy to calculate the
fraction of immigrant households in the
population of welfare households (i.e.,
pation rate, as compared to only 7.4 per- households that receive public assis-
cent for the typical immigrant household tance). In 1970, 6.7 percent of welfare
(Baker and Benjamin 1993, Table 1). households had an immigrant head, so
The lower propensities of immigrants in that immigrants were slightly under-rep-
Canada to enter the welfare system may resented among welfare households. By
be the result of the screen filters which 1990, the situation had changed dramati-
hinder relatively unskilled immigrants cally: 10.4 percent of welfare households
from entering Canada (although Baker had a foreign-born head, so that immi-
and Benjamin do not provide any direct grants were substantially over-repre-
evidence to indicate that the point sys- sented among welfare households.
tem reduces expenditures in welfare pro- The Census data also indicate that in
grams). 35 1970, a total of $14.6 billion in cash
benefits was distributed to households;
B. Do Immigrants Pay Their Way? by 1980, this expenditure had risen to
$26.8 billion; and by 1990, to $28.6 bil-
There has been a great deal of discus- lion (all in 1989 dollars). The third row
sion in recent years about whether immi- of Table 15 reports the fraction of wel-
grants take more out of the social wel- fare income that was distributed to for-
35 The evidence also indicates that immigrants
eign-born households. In 1970, 6.7 per-
in Canada, like their counterparts in the United cent of cash benefits were distributed to
States, assimilate into the welfare system. Over a immigrant households, again indicating
10-year period, the probability of participating in that immigrant were slightly under-rep-
public assistance programs for the typical immi-
grant in Canada rises by about 5 percentage points resented in the distribution of welfare
(relative to natives). benefits. By 1990, the situation had
Borjas: The Economics of Immigration 1705

TABLE 15
IMMIGRANT CONTRIBUTION TO WELFARE EXPENDITURES

1970 1980 1990


1. Percentage of Households with 6.8 7.6 8.4
Immigrant Heads
2. Percentage of Households with Immigrant 6.7 8.3 10.1
Heads in Population of Households
Receiving Public Assistance
3. Percentage of Public Assistance Income 6.7 9.1 13.1
Distributed to Households with
Immigrant Heads
4. Percentage of NonWelfare Income 6.3 7.0 8.3
Received by Households with
Immigrant Heads

Source: Authors tabulations from the 1970, 1980, and 1990 Public Use Samples of the U.S.
Census.

changed drastically: 13.1 percent of all den imposed by immigration inevitably


cash benefits were distributed to immi- incorporate a number of hidden and
grant households, indicating a substantial questionable assumptions. Table 16 illus-
over-representation of immigrants in trates the problem by presenting a back-
welfare expenditures. Put differently, of-the-envelope calculation of the tax
the total amount of cash benefits re- burden in 1990. The first row reports
ceived by immigrant households was 56 that immigrants received $3.7 billion
percent higher than would have been the dollars in cash welfare benefits in 1990,
case if immigrants used the welfare sys- or as noted earlier, 13.1 percent of ex-
tem to the same extent as natives. penditures in cash benefit programs. At
Immigrants, therefore, now receive a that time, expenditures on all means-
disproportionately high share of cash tested entitlement programs was $181.3
benefits. Moreover, they do not receive a (U.S. Bureau of the Census, 1992, p.
disproportionately high share of non- 357).37 If we assume that immigrants also
welfare income. In 1990, immigrants re- account for 13.1 percent of these expen-
ceived 8.3 percent of all non-welfare ditures, immigrants increase expendi-
income (about the same as their popula- tures on all means-tested entitlement
tion proportion).36 Because immigrants programs by $23.8 billion.
do not receive a disproportionately high The next step in the calculation is to
share of income, they also do not pay a compute the taxes that immigrants pay.
disproportionately high share of taxes. According to the 1990 Census, immi-
As noted earlier, accounting exercises
that assign a dollar figure to the tax bur- 37 The means-tested entitlement programs in-
clude such programs as Food Stamps, Medicaid,
low-income housing assistance, and Head Start.
36 Even though the typical immigrant worker Expenditures on means-tested entitlement pro-
earns less than the typical native, immigrants as a grams totaled $186.4 billion. The figure reported
group do not have a disproportionately low share in the text nets out expenditures on Indian Health
of non-welfare income. This discrepancy is ex- Services and on pensions for needy veterans from
plained by the fact that immigrants have larger la- the total because few immigrants are likely to
bor force participation rates than natives. qualify for these programs.
1706 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXII (December 1994)

TABLE 16
ACCOUNTING OF WELFARE EXPENDITURES AND TAXES PAID BY IMMIGRANT
HOUSEHOLDS IN 1990
(in billions of dollars)

Tax Rate
30% 40%
1. Cash Benefits Received by Immigrant
Households (= 698, 071 Households x $5,363) $3.7 $3.7
2. Dollar Value of Benefits from Means-Tested
Programs Received by Immigrant Households
(13.1% of $181.3 Billion) $23.8 $23.8
3. Non-Welfare Income Received
by Immigrant Households $284.7 $284.7
4. Taxes Paid by Immigrant Households $85.4 $113.9
5. Taxes Allocated to Means-Tested Entitlement
Programs (8.9% of Taxes Paid) $7.6 $10.1
6. Fiscal Burden on Native Taxpayers Imposed by
Immigrant Households $16.2 $13.7

Source: Authors tabulations from the 1990 Public Use Sample of the U.S. Census.

grant households received a total income ated with the provision of many of these
(net of welfare payments) of $284.7 bil- public goods (e.g., more crowded parks,
lion. Richard Kasten, Frank Sammartino, schools, and roads). In other words, the
and Eric Toder (1993) have recently cal- marginal cost of providing these public
culated the federal tax burden for U.S. goods to the immigrant population is not
households at various points in the in- zero. Immigrants, therefore, should be
come distribution. Applying their esti- charged a user fee for the various gov-
mated tax rates to the immigrant income ernment services.
distribution suggests that the federal tax It is obviously very difficult to deter-
burden for immigrants is on the order of mine the correct user fee schedule for
22 percent. If the total tax rate (includ- the services provided to immigrants. We
ing state and local taxes) is 30 percent, do not even know, for instance, if the
immigrant households then pay about marginal cost of providing many of the
$85.4 billion in taxes. public services to immigrants (such as an
The calculations thus indicate that im- expansion of the public school system or
migrants pay more in taxes ($85.4 bil- the construction of additional roads) is
lion) than they take out of the system less than or greater than the average
($23.8 billion). But this comparison is cost. Obviously, different assumptions
misleading. It is, in effect, saying that about the marginal cost of providing
immigrant taxes are only used to fund services will lead to very different con-
their use of means-tested entitlement clusions about whether immigrants pay
programs. This assumption is justifiable their way in the welfare state. For exam-
if all other government programs provide ple, a revenue-neutral immigration
pure public goods, so that expenditures policy (i.e., one that would neither subsi-
in these programs are unaffected by im- dize nor penalize natives for the provi-
migration. It is likely, however, that im- sion of government services to the immi-
migrants increase the congestion associ- grant population) requires that the
Borjas: The Economics of Immigration 1707

average tax rate for immigrants be set of-the-envelope calculation suggests,


equal to: therefore, accounting exercises can lead
to radically different conclusions about
Gi whether immigrants pay their way.
ti = , (21)
Yi The calculation reported in Table 16
illustrates why the studies of Passel and
where Gi gives the increase in govern-
Clark (1994) and Huddle (1993) reach
ment expenditures attributable to immi-
such different conclusions. Passel and
gration, and Yi is the income received by
Clark estimate that immigrants pay
immigrants. This tax rate depends not
about $70 billion in taxes, but increase
only on the increase in expenditures, but
expenditures in such programs as welfare
also on the mean income and labor force
and education by $43 billion, thus gener-
participation rate of immigrant workers
ating a net surplus of $27 billion. This
because less-skilled immigrant popula-
calculation, of course, assumes that the
tions with low rates of work attachment
marginal cost of providing all other pro-
would have to be taxed at a higher rate
grams to immigrants is zero. In contrast,
(for a given increase in government ex-
Huddle simply concludes that immi-
penditures).
grants pay less in total taxes than they
Suppose that the marginal cost of pro-
take out of the system. Huddles calcula-
viding services to immigrants equals the
tions, however, assume that immigrants
average cost and that per capita income
pay only 7 percent of their income in
in the immigrant population equals that
taxes (net of payments to the Social Se-
of natives. These assumptions imply that
curity system), and overestimate the
immigrants should be charged for the
costs of immigration by claiming that for
costs of the various government pro-
every six immigrants who enter the coun-
grams as if they were natives. In other
try, one native is displaced from his job
words, if x percent of a native workers
and joins the welfare rolls.
taxes pay for defense, then x percent of
The cost-benefit calculation presented
an immigrants taxes should also be allo-
here focuses exclusively on immigrant
cated to pay for defense. In 1990, 91.1
participation in means-tested entitle-
percent of taxes were used to pay for
ment programs. Adding other govern-
programs other than means-tested enti-
ment programs, such as Social Security,
tlement programs. If we charge immi-
could change the results substantially.
grants 91.1 percent of their tax payments
For example, it is often argued that im-
for using these other programs, then
migrants make a net contribution to the
only 8.9 percent of immigrants taxes are
Social Security system because many im-
left to fund their use of means-tested en-
migrants leave the United States prior to
titlement programs. As reported in row 5
retiring and do not collect benefits, de-
of Table 16, immigrants would then con-
spite their having contributed to the sys-
tribute only $7.6 billion to the funding of
tem. It is important to realize, however,
the entitlement programs. The annual
that the median age of immigration is 30,
loss associated with immigration is on
so that many immigrants pay into the So-
the order of $16 billion. 38 As this back-
cial Security system for a much shorter
38 To determine if there is a net benefit from time span than natives, yet collect
immigration, these fiscal costs must be contrasted roughly the same benefits (the benefits
with an estimate of the benefits from immigration.
Consumers, for example, may be able to buy
cheaper goods and employers can hire some work- does not provide a systematic accounting of these
ers at lower wage rates. The literature, however, benefits.
1708 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXII (December 1994)

of a person who works for 30 years are impact of immigration obviously depends
not much greater than those of a person not only on how immigrants adapt to the
who works for only 15 years). Despite labor market, but also on the adjustment
the potential importance of the Social process experienced by their offspring.
Security program for any cost-benefit The traditional view of this intergen-
calculation, no studies exist which incor- erational adjustment is vividly depicted
porate the long-run impact of immigra- by the melting pot metaphor. Over the
tion on the Social Security system. course of two or three generations, im-
The calculation also ignores the costs migrants are transformed from a collec-
and benefits of providing schooling to tion of diverse national origin groups
immigrant children. The expenditures into a homogeneous native population.
associated with putting the children Beginning with Nathan Glazer and
through the public school system are Daniel Moynihan (1963), modern socio-
substantial. In California alone, it is esti- logical research argues that this meta-
mated that roughly $1.7 billion was spent phor does not correctly portray the eth-
on educating the children of illegal nic experience in the United States. In
aliens in 1993 (California Department of fact, Glazer and Moynihan (1963, p.
Finance 1994). These costs, however, xcvii) conclude that the American ethos
must be contrasted with the benefits of is nowhere better perceived than in the
having a more educated work force later disinclination of the third and fourth
on in the life cycle. It is also the case generation of newcomers to blend into a
that immigrants who enter the United standard, uniform national type. The re-
States after they complete their educa- visionist literature suggests that many of
tion import free human capital into the the cultural and economic differences
United States. To the extent that immi- among immigrant groups are transmitted
grants do not receive their entire prod- to their children, so that the heterogene-
uct as wages, substantial benefits might ity found among todays immigrants be-
accrue from this infusion of human capi- comes the heterogeneity found among
tal. 39 tomorrows ethnic groups.
The modern economic literature on
8. The Second Generation the intergenerational mobility experi-
In 1990, 9.7 percent of the U.S. popu- enced by immigrant households is domi-
lation was native-born with foreign par- nated by two questions. First, is there a
entage (or second-generation). By the significant improvement in economic
year 2050, the share of second-genera- status between the first and second gen-
tion persons will increase to 13.9 per- erations? Second, do the national origin
cent, and an additional 8.5 percent will differentials in skills and earnings evi-
be composed of the grandchildren of dent in the immigrant generation disap-
current immigrants (Barry Edmonston pear over time?
and Passel 1992, p. 471). The economic In contrast to the voluminous litera-
ture analyzing the economic status of im-
39 Calculations conducted in particular locali- migrants, few studies document the skills
ties, such as Los Angeles and San Diego, suggest and labor market performance of their
that the costs imposed by immigration on the
criminal justice system can also be substantial. American-born children. Early work by
There is, however, little systematic study of the Chiswick (1977) and Carliner (1980)
extent to which immigrants participate in criminal used the 1970 Census cross-section to
activities. John Tanton and Wayne Lutton (1993)
report that 20 percent of federal inmates in the calculate the relative wage of various
United States are non-citizens. generations of Americans. The 1970
Borjas: The Economics of Immigration 1709

TABLE 17
RELATIVE WAGES OF FIRST AND SECOND GENERATIONS IN 1940 AND 1970
(Percentage Wage Differential Relative to Third Generation)

Variable/Group 1940 1970


Log Wage
First Generation 20.3 4.0
Second Generation 26.4 16.3
Log Wage, Adjusting for Education and Age
First Generation 20.6 7.8
Second Generation 26.0 11.7

Source: Borjas (1993a, p. 119). The statistics are calculated in the subsample
of men aged 2564 who work in the civilian sector, who are not self-employed,
and who do not reside in group quarters.

Census data allow the precise identifica- have any native descendants employed in
tion of first- and second-generation the U.S. labor market. Second-genera-
workers. 40 The generation of the remain- tion workers can only be descendants of
ing workers, who had both parents born immigrants who have been in the coun-
in the United States, cannot be deter- try for at least two or three decades.41
mined, but for convenience we will call Therefore, if there are cohort differ-
them third-generation Americans. The ences among immigrants and if these dif-
last column of Table 17 summarizes the ferences are partially transmitted to their
evidence provided by the 1970 Census children, the labor market performance
cross-section. Second-generation work- of second-generation workers now par-
ers earn about 12 percent more than im- ticipating in the labor market (who are
migrants and 16 percent more than the offspring of the immigrant waves
third-generation workers. Both Chiswick that arrived 30 or 40 years ago) cannot
and Carliner concluded that there was a be used to forecast the future perform-
great deal of economic mobility among ance of the children of newly arrived im-
the ambitious children of immigrants, migrants.
but that the hunger disappeared by the We showed earlier how tracking spe-
third generation. cific immigrant waves across Censuses
This conclusion, however, is prema- yields a rate of wage convergence in the
ture (Borjas 1993a). In any cross section, immigrant generation. The intercensal
the family ties among the three genera- tracking of immigrants and their off-
tions identifiable in the data are tenuous. spring also yields an estimate of the rate
At the time of the survey, many mem- of economic mobility across generations.
bers of the first generation have just ar-
rived in the United States and cannot 41 It is also extremely unlikely that the so-called
third-generation workers are direct descendants of
the immigrants enumerated in the Census cross-
40 The first-generation includes persons born section. The persons identified as members of the
abroad, while the second generation includes per- third generation form a diverse collection of work-
sons who had at least one foreign-born parent. ers whose presence in the United States may date
Since 1970, the Census does not contain any infor- 40 or 400 years. Moreover, the cross-section com-
mation on the birthplace of the parents, but in- parison requires that working-age immigrants have
stead reports information on a persons ancestry, American-born grandchildren who are also of
regardless of parental birthplace. working age.
1710 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXII (December 1994)

TABLE 18
NATIONAL ORIGIN WAGE DIFFERENTIALS AMONG FIRST GENERATION WORKERS IN 1940,
AND SECOND GENERATION WORKERS IN 1970
(Percentage Wage Differential Relative to Third Generation)

Country of Origin: First Generation in 1940 Second Generation in 1970


Austria 32.2 23.5
Canada 28.7 12.1
Cuba .4 2.5
Czechoslovakia 31.9 14.7
Denmark 33.8 12.6
France 25.7 24.6
Germany 21.9 13.7
Greece 9.8 20.8
Hungary 28.0 22.6
Ireland 23.2 21.7
Italy 17.2 14.7
Mexico 39.1 14.9
Netherlands 11.1 17.5
Norway 31.0 15.5
Poland 24.9 16.6
Portugal 5.2 .3
Romania 34.3 39.1
Spain 6.7 11.2
Sweden 30.0 19.5
Switzerland 21.9 12.4
United Kingdom 37.3 23.1
USSR 31.8 37.7
Yugoslavia 34.9 18.9

Source: Borjas (1993a, p. 124). The statistics are calculated in the subsample of men aged 2564
who work in the civilian sector, who are not self-employed, and who do not reside in group
quarters.

It is likely, for example, that the children gression towards the mean. Because the
of the immigrant stock present in the immigrant stock present in the United
United States in 1940 show up as sec- States in 1940 had very high wages, the
ond-generation workers in the 1970 second-generation enumerated in 1970
Census. The data reported in the first had relatively lower wages than their im-
column of Table 17 indicate that immi- migrant parents.
grants in 1940 earned about 20 percent Table 18 uses the 1940 and 1970 Cen-
more than third-generation workers. As suses to document the huge wage differ-
we saw earlier, the children of these im- entials across national origin groups in
migrants, presumably the second-genera- both the first and second generations. In
tion workers enumerated in the 1970 1970, second-generation Americans of
Census, earn only about 16 percent more British ancestry earned about 23.1 per-
than the third generation. The intercen- cent more than third-generation Ameri-
sal tracking thus contradicts the percep- cans, while second-generation Mexicans
tion that second-generation workers earned 14.9 percent less. To measure
have, on average, higher earnings than both the shift in economic fortunes be-
the first. There is, instead, a slight re- tween the first and second generations as
Borjas: The Economics of Immigration 1711

well as the correlation in the mean earn- generations, the evidence suggests that
ings of an ethnic group across genera- the ethnic skill differentials introduced
tions, it is useful to contrast second-gen- by immigration will persist into the third
eration Americans in 1970 with the generation and perhaps even into the
earnings of immigrants in 1940. Let w2j fourth.
be the average log wage (in 1970) of sec- The long-run persistence of ethnic dif-
ond-generation Americans in group j ferences is evident in a recent analysis of
relative to that of third generation the children and grandchildren of the
Americans; and w1j be the average log immigrants who entered the United
wage (in 1940) of immigrants in group j States at the turn of the 20th Century.
relative to that of third generation Using data drawn from the 1910 Census,
Americans. Borjas (1993a, p. 125) re- Borjas (1994) finds sizable differences in
ports that the regression line relating the the skills and earnings of the national
relative log wage of these two genera- origin groups that made up the First
tions is given by: Great Migration. Using data drawn from
the 1940 and 1980 Censuses, and the
w2j = .070 + .447 w1j, General Social Surveys, Borjas then
(.017) (.065) (22) shows that there are sizable differences
in the skills and earnings of the children
where the standard errors are reported
and grandchildren of these immigrants.
in parentheses and the regression uses
A 20 percentage point difference in the
the 23 national origin groups listed in
literacy rate between any two groups in
Table 18. 42 The intercept reveals a 7 per-
the first generation implies a 1-year dif-
cent increase in earnings potential be-
ference in educational attainment among
tween the first and second generations
second-generation workers, and a .5-year
that is common to all national origin
difference among third generation work-
groups. The empirical evidence, there-
ers. Similarly, a 20 percent wage differ-
fore, indicates that second-generation
ential between the two groups in the
workers do experience a jump in their
first generation implies roughly a 12 per-
earnings capacity. The data, however,
cent differential in the second genera-
also reveal a strong correlation between
tion, and a 5 percent differential in the
the economic status of national origin
third. Ethnicity matters, and it seems to
groups in the first and second genera-
matter for a very long time.
tions. The slope estimate of .45 implies
This conclusion is not consistent with
that roughly half of the wage differential
the widespread perception that the cor-
between any two national origin groups
relation between parental skills and chil-
in the first generation persists into the
drens skills is small and might be on the
second. There is some regression toward
order of .2 (Gary Becker and Nigel
the mean, but national origin is still an
Tomes 1986). Recent work by Gary
important determinant of the earnings of
Solon (1992) and David Zimmerman
second generation Americans. In fact, if
(1992), however, suggests that measure-
the intergenerational correlation is on
ment error in parental background leads
the order of .5 and is constant across
to a substantial underestimate of the cor-
42 The regression reported in (22) is based on relation in earnings across generations.
the data summarized in Table 18. The regression, Correcting for this measurement error
however, uses a generalized least squares estima- increases the intergenerational correla-
tor to account for the heteroscedasticity intro-
duced by the sampling error in the dependent tion to between .3 to .4. Because the re-
variable gression reported in (22) uses the aver-
1712 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXII (December 1994)

age earnings of workers in each group, his influential study of the underclass,
the relatively high intergenerational cor- William Wilson (1987) argues that the
relation between the first and second presence of mainstream role models in
generations is partly due to the fact that poor neighborhoods serves an important
the data net out a substantial amount of social and economic function. 43
measurement error. To determine the relative importance
Recent work, however, suggests that of parental inputs and ethnic spillovers
measurement error alone does not ex- on the intergenerational transmission
plain the very high correlation in the process, Borjas (1992a) estimated the
mean earnings of ethnic groups over following regression model in the Na-
time. These studies argue that there are tional Longitudinal Surveys of Youth and
racial or ethnic externalities in the labor the General Social Surveys:
market which influence the human capi- _
tal accumulation of persons belonging to yij(t) = 1yij(t 1) + 2yj (t 1) + ij(t), (24)
particular racial or ethnic groups (Glenn where yij(t) measures the skills (such as
Loury 1977). Put differently, the rate of education or wage) of person i in ethnic
intergenerational mobility between im- group j in generation t; yij_(t 1) gives
migrants and their children is influenced the skills of his father; and yj(t 1) gives
not only by parental background, but the average skills of the ethnic group in
also by the quality of the ethnic envi- the fathers generation. All variables are
ronment where the children grow up. measured in deviations from the mean.
These ethnic effects increase the correla- It is easy to show the link between the
tion in earnings across generations and micro model in (24) and the regression
can substantially delay the convergence using the mean earnings of ethnic groups
of ethnic skill differentials. in the first and second generations re-
A simple formulation of this idea is ported in equation (22). Aggregating (24)
given by Borjas (1992a), who argues that within an ethnic group yields:
the average human capital stock in the _ _ _ _
parental generation for ethnic group j, kj, yj(t) = (1 + 2) yj(t 1) + j (t). (25)
which he calls ethnic capital, acts as an The regression estimated in aggregate
externality in the production of the hu- Census data, therefore, estimates 1 +
man capital of children. The production 2. This sum yields precisely the inter-
function for child quality is given by: generational transmission coefficient
_
Child Quality = f (parental inputs, kj). (23) relevant for determining the rate at
which the mean skills of ethnic groups
The hypothesis that ethnicity has ex- converge across generations, or mean-
ternal effects on human capital accumu- convergence. If the sum is less than
lation has been used widely in the sociol- one, ethnic differences converge over
ogy literature. For instance, James time; if not, ethnic differences diverge.
Coleman (1988) stresses that the culture The empirical evidence indicates that 1
in which the individual is raised (which is on the order of .2 to .3, and that 2 is
he calls social capital) can be thought also on the order of .2 to .3, so that the
of as a form of human capital common to rate of mean convergence is around .4 to
all members of that group. He argues
that social capital alters the opportunity 43 The rapidly growing literature on the deter-

set of workers and has significant effects minants of endogenous economic growth also
stresses the hypothesis that human capital has ex-
on behavior, human capital formation, ternal effects in production; see Robert Lucas
and labor market outcomes. Similarly, in (1988) and Paul Romer (1986).
Borjas: The Economics of Immigration 1713

.6. There is, therefore, a great deal of dence painted a very optimistic picture
persistence in ethnic skill differentials of the contribution of immigrants to the
over time, and about half of the persist- American economy.
ence is due to the effects of ethnic spill- In the past ten years, many more
overs on intergenerational mobility. brushstrokes were applied to the canvas,
We cannot yet determine if the ethnic and the theme and shape of the picture
externalities model provides a useful ap- changed. The new research established a
proach for analyzing the long-run eco- number of new stylized facts: The rela-
nomic impact of immigration. Future re- tive skills of successive immigrant waves
search will have to specify the precise declined over much of the postwar pe-
mechanism through which ethnic and ra- riod; it is unlikely that recent immigrants
cial spillovers operate, such as neighbor- will reach parity with the earnings of na-
hoods, schools, and religious institutions, tives during their working lives; although
as well as document the extent to which there is only a weak negative correlation
intra-ethnic contacts influence job search between the presence of immigrants in a
activities, occupational choice, and other local labor market and the earnings of
labor supply and labor demand deci- natives in that labor market, immigration
sions. may have been partly responsible for the
decline in the earnings of unskilled na-
9. Conclusion tive workers that occurred during the
1980s; the new immigration may have an
The literature investigating the eco- adverse fiscal impact because recent
nomic impact of immigration on the waves participate in welfare programs
United States and on other host coun- more intensively than earlier waves; im-
tries grew rapidly in the past decade. migration policy matters, so that host
This explosion of research substantially countries which filter applicants in terms
sharpened our understanding of the eco- of observable skills attract immigrants
nomics of immigration. The stylized facts who are more skilled, have higher earn-
that long dominated the discussion over ings, and are less likely to participate in
the costs and benefits of immigration public assistance programs; and, finally,
were radically altered during the 1980s, there exists a strong correlation between
and a number of new questions, issues, the skills of immigrants and the skills of
and perceptions replaced them. second-generation Americans, so that
To appreciate the magnitude of this the huge skill differentials observed
upheaval, consider the perceived wisdom among todays foreign-born groups be-
as of ten years ago. The available studies come tomorrows differences among
suggested that even though immigrants American-born ethnic groups.
generally arrived with an economic dis- An important lesson of the recent re-
advantage, their economic opportunities search is that immigration has a far-
improved rapidly over time. Within a reaching and long-lasting impact. In a
decade or two after arrival, immigrant sense, we are only beginning to observe
earnings would approach, reach parity the economic consequences of the his-
with, and overtake the earnings of na- toric changes in the size, national origin
tives of comparable socioeconomic back- mix, and skill composition of immigrants
ground. Moreover, there was little evi- admitted to the United States during the
dence to suggest that immigrants had an past three decades. The Second Great
adverse impact on native employment Migration surely will alter the skill en-
opportunities. Overall, the empirical evi- dowment of the labor force, the employ-
1714 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXII (December 1994)

ment opportunities of native workers, grants Live? J. Lab. Econ., Oct. 1989, 7(4), pp.
37191.
and the costs of social insurance pro- B EAN, F RANK D.; L OWELL, B. L INDSAY AND TAY-
grams not only in our generation, but for LOR , L OWELL J. Undocumented Mexican Im-
our children and grandchildren as well. migrants and the Earnings of Other Workers in
the United States, Demography, Feb. 1988,
In addition, current immigration in the 25(1), pp. 3552.
United States and in many other host B ECKER, GARY S. AND TOMES , N IGEL . Human
countries is setting the stage for the eth- Capital and the Rise and Fall of Families, J.
Lab. Econ., July 1986, 4(3, Part 2), pp. S139.
nic differences in economic outcomes B EGGS, J OHN J. AND C HAPMAN , B RUCE J. Male
that are likely to be a dominant feature Immigrant Wage and Unemployment Experi-
of labor markets in these countries ence in Australia, in J OHN M. A BOWD AND
R ICHARD B. F REEMAN, eds. 1991, pp. 36984.
throughout the next century. B ENHABIB, J ESS . A Note on the Political Econ-
In view of the economic, cultural, and omy of Immigration. New York U., 1993.
political significance of the issues raised B LANCHARD, OLIVIER J EAN AND K ATZ,
L AWRENCE F. Regional Evolutions, Brook-
by immigration, it is not surprising that ings Pap. Econ. Act., 1992, 1, pp. 161.
immigration policy is now a central in- B LAU, F RANCINE D. Immigration and Labor
gredient in the debate over social policy Earnings in Early Twentieth Century America,
Research in population economics. 2. Green-
in many countries. For the most part, wich, CT: JAI Press, 1979, pp. 2141.
this debate focuses on economic issues . The Use of Transfer Payments by Immi-
and uses the evidence provided by eco- grants, Ind. Lab. Relat. Rev., Jan. 1984, 37(2),
pp. 22239.
nomic research to frame and formulate B LOOM, D AVID E. AND G RENIER, GILLES . Earn-
the discussion. Because the economic ings of the French Minority in Canada and the
impact of current immigration will be Spanish Minority in the United States, in
B ARRY R. C HISWICK , ed. 1992, pp. 373409.
felt for many decades to come and be- B LOOM, D AVID E.; GRENIER, GILLES AND GUN-
cause the immigrant flow to many host DERSON , M ORLEY . The Changing Labor Mar-
countries continues unabated, the explo- ket Position of Canadian Immigrants, Can. J.
Econ., forthcoming.
sion of research that we witnessed in the B ORJAS, G EORGE J. Assimilation, Changes in Co-
past decade is sure to continue. hort Quality, and the Earnings of Immigrants,
J. Lab. Econ., Oct. 1985, 3(4), pp. 46389.
REFERENCES . Self-Selection and the Earnings of Immi-
grants, Amer. Econ. Rev., Sept. 1987, 77(4),
A BOWD, J OHN M. AND F REEMAN , R ICHARD B., pp. 53153.
eds. Immigration, trade, and the labor market. . Friends or strangers: The impact of immi-
Chicago: U. of Chicago Press, 1991. grants on the U.S. economy. New York: Basic
A LTONJI, J OSEPH G. AND CARD, D AVID. The Ef- Books, 1990.
fects of Immigration on the Labor Market Out- . Ethnic Capital and Intergenerational
comes of Less-Skilled Natives, in J OHN M. Mobility, Quart. J. Econ., Feb. 1992a, 107(1),
A BOWD AND R ICHARD B. F REEMAN, eds. 1991, pp. 12350.
pp. 20134. . National Origin and the Skills of Immi-
B AILEY , T HOMAS R. Immigrant and native work- grants in the Postwar Period, 1992b, in
ers: Contrasts and competition. Boulder, CO: GEORGE J. B ORJAS AND R ICHARD B. F REE-
Westview, 1987. MAN, eds. 1992, pp. 1747.
B AKER, M ICHAEL AND B ENJAMIN , D WAYNE . The . The Intergenerational Mobility of Immi-
Receipt of Transfer Payments by Immigrants in grants, J. Lab. Econ., Jan. 1993a, 11(1), pp.
Canada. U. of Toronto, 1993. 11335.
. The Performance of Immigrants in the . Immigration Policy, National Origin, and
Canadian Labor Market, J. Lab. Econ., July Immigrant Skills: A Comparison of Canada and
1994, 12(3), pp. 369405. the United States, in Small differences that
B ARRETT , A LAN M. Three Essays on the Labor matter: Labor markets and income maintenance
Market Characteristics of Immigrants. Ph.D. in Canada and the United States. Eds.: D AVID
Dissertation, Michigan State U., 1993. CARD AND R ICHARD B. F REEMAN . Chicago,
B ARRO, R OBERT J. AND L EE , J ONG-W HA . Inter- IL: U. of Chicago Press, 1993b, pp. 2143.
national Comparisons of Educational Attain- . Long-Run Convergence of Ethnic Skill
ment. NBER Working Paper No. 4349, Apr. Differentials: The Children and Grandchildren
1993. of the Great Migration, Ind. Lab. Rel. Rev.,
B ARTEL , A NN P. Where Do the New U.S. Immi- July 1994, 47(4), pp. 55373.
Borjas: The Economics of Immigration 1715

. Assimilation and Changes in Cohort Than the Old? J. Lab. Econ., Apr. 1986, 4(2),
Quality Revisited: What Happened to Immi- pp. 16892.
grant Earnings in the 1980s? J. Lab. Econ., . Speaking, Reading, and Earnings Among
forthcoming. Low-Skilled Immigrants, J. Lab. Econ., Apr.
B ORJAS , G EORGE J. AND B RATSBERG, B ERNT . 1991, 9(2), pp. 14970.
Who Leaves? The Outmigration of the For- , ed. Immigration, language, and ethnic-
eign-Born, Rev. Econ. Statist., forthcoming. ity: Canada and the United States. Washington:
B ORJAS , G EORGE J. AND B RONARS, S TEPHEN G. American Enterprise Institute, 1992.
Immigration and the Family, J. Lab. Econ., C HISWICK , B ARRY R. AND M ILLER, P AUL W.
Apr. 1991, 9(2), pp. 12348. Language in the Immigrant Labor Market, in
B ORJAS , GEORGE J. AND F REEMAN , R ICHARD B., B ARRY R. CHISWICK , ed. 1992, pp. 22996.
eds. Immigration and the work force: Economic C OBB -C LARK , D EBORAH A. Immigrant Selectiv-
consequences for the United States and source ity: The Roles of Household Structure and U.S.
areas. Chicago: U. of Chicago Press, 1992. Immigration Policy. Ph.D. Dissertation, U. of
B ORJAS , GEORGE J.; F REEMAN , R ICHARD B. AND Michigan, 1990.
K ATZ, L AWRENCE F. On the Labor Market Ef- . Immigrant Selectivity and Wages: The
fects of Immigration and Trade, in GEORGE J. Evidence for Women, Amer. Econ. Rev., Sept.
B ORJAS AND R ICHARD B. F REEMAN , eds. 1992, 1993, 83(4), pp. 98693.
pp. 21344. C OLEMAN, J AMES S. Social Capital in the Crea-
B ORJAS , GEORGE J. AND TREJO, S TEPHEN J. Im- tion of Human Capital, Amer. J. Sociology,
migrant Participation in the Welfare System, 1988 Supplement, 94, pp. S95120.
Ind. Lab. Rel. Rev., Jan. 1991, 44(2), pp. 195 D E N EW, J OHN P. AND ZIMMERMANN , KLAUS F.
211. Native Wage Impacts of Foreign Labor: A Ran-
B RATSBERG, B ERNT . The Incidence of Non-Re- dom Effects Panel Analysis, J. Population
turn Among Foreign Students in the United Econ., June 1994, 7(2), pp. 17792,
States. Kansas State U., Sept. 1993. D OUGLAS, P AUL . Is the New Immigration More
B UTCHER, K RISTIN F. Black Immigrants in the Unskilled than the Old? J. Amer. Statist. As-
United States: A Comparison with Native Blacks soc., June 1919, 16, pp. 393403.
and Other Immigrants, Ind. Lab. Rel., Jan. D ULEEP , H ARRIET ORCUTT AND R EGETS , M ARK
1994, 47(2), pp. 26584. C. Some Evidence on the Effect of Admission
B UTCHER, K RISTIN F. AND C ARD, D AVID. Immi- Criteria on Immigrant Assimilation, in 1992a
gration and Wages: Evidence from the 1980s, B ARRY R. CHISWICK , ed. 1992, pp. 41039.
Amer. Econ. Rev., May 1991, 81(2), pp. 29296. . The Elusive Concept of Immigrant Qual-
CALIFORNIA D EPARTMENT OF F INANCE . Edu- ity. Urban Institute, 1992b.
cating Illegal Immigrants. Technical Notes to D USTMANN , C HRISTIAN . Earnings Adjustment of
Governors Budget 199495, Jan. 19, 1994. Temporary Immigrants, J. Population Econ.,
CARD, D AVID. The Impact of the Mariel Boatlift May 1993, 6(2), pp. 15368.
on the Miami Labor Market, Ind. Lab. Rel. E DMONSTON, B ARRY AND PASSEL , J EFFREY S.
Rev., Jan. 1990, 43(2), pp. 24557. Immigration and Immigrant Generations in
CARLINER, GEOFFREY . Wages, Earnings and Population Projections, Int. J. Forecasting,
Hours of First, Second and Third Generation Nov. 1992, 8(3), pp. 45976.
American Males, Econ. Inquiry, Jan. 1980, E ICHENGREEN, B ARRY AND GEMERY , H ENRY A.
18(1), pp. 87102. The Earnings of Skilled and Unskilled Immi-
. Wage Differences by Language Group grants at the End of the Nineteenth Cen-
and the Market for Language Skills in Canada, tury, J. Econ. Hist., June 1986, 46(2), pp. 441
J. Human Res., Summer 1981, 16(3), pp. 384 54.
99. F ILER, R ANDALL K. The Effect of Immigrant Ar-
CARRINGTON , W ILLIAM J. AND DE L IMA, P EDRO. rivals on Migratory Patterns of Native Workers,
Large-Scale Immigration and Labor Markets: in G EORGE J. B ORJAS AND R ICHARD B. F REE-
An Analysis of the Retornados and Their Impact MAN , eds. 1992, pp. 24569.
on Portugal. Johns Hopkins U., Jan. 1994. F REEMAN , R ICHARD B. Immigration from Poor
CHISWICK , B ARRY R. Sons of Immigrants: Are to Wealthy Countries: Experience of the United
They at an Earnings Disadvantage? Amer. States, Europ. Econ. Rev., Apr. 1993, 37(2/3),
Econ. Rev., Feb. 1977, 67(1), pp. 37680. pp. 44351.
. The Effect of Americanization on the F REY , W ILLIAM H. The New White Flight,
Earnings of Foreign-Born Men, J. Polit. Econ., American Demographics, Apr. 1994, 16(4), pp.
Oct. 1978, 86(5), pp. 897921. 4048.
. The Earnings of White and Coloured F RIEDBERG, R ACHEL M. The Labor Market As-
Male Immigrants in Britain, Economica, Feb. similation of Immigrants in the United States:
1980, 47(185), pp. 8187. The Role of Age at Arrival. Brown U., 1992.
. An Analysis of the Earnings and Employ- . You Cant Take It With You: Immigrant
ment of Asian-American Men, J. Lab. Econ., Assimilation and the Portability of Human Capi-
Apr. 1983, 1(2), pp. 197214. tal, Evidence from Israel. Brown U., Dec.
. Is the New Immigration Less Skilled 1993.
1716 Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. XXXII (December 1994)
F UNKHOUSER, EDWARD AND TREJO, S TEPHEN J. entrepreneurship: Koreans in Los Angeles,
The Labor Market Skills of Recent Male Immi- 19651982. Berkeley: U. of California Press,
grants: Evidence from the Current Population 1988.
Surveys. Ind. Lab. Rel Rev., forthcoming. L ONG, J AMES E. The Effect of Americanization
G LAZER, N ATHAN AND M OYNIHAN , D ANIEL P. on Earnings: Some Evidence for Women, J.
Beyond the melting pot: The Negroes, Puerto Ri- Polit. Econ., June 1980, 88(3), pp. 62029.
cans, Jews, Italians, and Irish of New York City. L OURY , GLENN C. A Dynamic Theory of Racial
Cambridge, MA: M.I.T. Press, 1963. Income Differences, in Women, minorities,
G OLDIN , C LAUDIA . The Political Economy of Im- and employment discrimination. Eds.: PHYLLIS
migration Restrictions in the United States, A. W ALLACE AND A NNETTE M. L AMOND. Lex-
18901921, in The regulated economy. Eds.: ington, MA: Lexington Books, 1977, pp. 15386.
C LAUDIA GOLDIN AND GARY L IBECAP . Chi- L OWELL , B. L INDSAY ; B EAN , F RANK D. AND D E
cago: U. of Chicago Press, 1994, pp. 22358. L A G ARZA , R ODOLFO O. Undocumented Im-
G REEN, A LLAN G. AND GREEN , D AVID A. Cana- migration: An Analysis of the 1984 Simpson-
dian Immigration Policy: The Effectiveness of Mazzoli Vote, Soc. Sci. Quart., Mar. 1986,
the Point System and Other Instruments. The 67(1), pp. 11827.
U. of British Columbia, Jan. 1994. L UCAS, R OBERT E., J R. On the Mechanics of
G RENIER, G ILLES. The Effects of Language Economic Development, J. Monet. Econ., July
Characteristics on the Wages of Hispanic- 1988, 22(1), pp. 342.
American Males, J. Hum. Res., Winter 1984, M C M ANUS, W ALTER S. Labor Market Costs of
19(1), pp. 3552. Language Disparity: An Interpretation of His-
G ROSSMAN , J EAN B ALDWIN . The Substitutability panic Earnings Differences, Amer. Econ. Rev.,
of Natives and Immigrants in Production, Rev. Sept. 1985, 75(4), pp. 81827.
Econ. Statist., Nov. 1982, 64(4), pp. 596603. . Labor Market Effects of Language En-
H UDDLE , D ONALD. The Costs of Immigration. claves: Hispanic Men in the United States,
Rice U., July 1993. J. Human Res., Spring 1990, 25(2), pp. 22852.
H UNT , J ENNIFER. The Impact of the 1962 Repa- M C M ANUS, W ALTER; GOULD, W ILLIAM AND
triates from Algeria on the French Labor Mar- W ELCH , F INIS. Earnings of Hispanic Men:
ket, Ind. Lab. Rel. Rev., Apr. 1992, 45(3), pp. The Role of English Language Proficiency, J.
55672. Lab. Econ., Apr. 1983, 1(2), pp. 10130.
J ASSO, GUILLERMINA AND R OSENZWEIG, M ARK M ULLER, THOMAS AND ESPENSHADE , THOMAS J.
R. Whats in a Name? Country-ofOrigin Influ- The fourth wave. Washington, DC: Urban Insti-
ences on the Earnings of Immigrants in the tute Press, 1985.
United States, in Research in human capital PASSEL J EFFREY S. AND C LARK , R EBECCA L.
and development. Vol. 4. Ed.: O DED S TARK . How Much Do Immigrants Really Cost? A Re-
Greenwich, CT: JAI Press, 1986, pp. 75106. appraisal of Huddles The Costs of Immi-
J ENSEN , L EIF . Patterns of Immigration and Pub- grants. Urban Institute, Feb. 1994.
lic Assistance Utilization, 19701980, Interna- PISCHKE , J RN -S TEFFEN. Assimilation and the
tional Migration Rev., Spring 1988, 22(1), pp. Earnings of Guestworkers in Germany. Massa-
5183. chusetts Institute of Technology, 1993.
K ASTEN , R ICHARD; S AMMARTINO, F RANK AND PISCHKE , J RN -S TEFFEN AND VELLING, J OHAN-
TODER, ERIC . Trends in Federal Tax Progres- NES . Wage and Employment Effects of Immi-
sivity: 19801993. U.S. Congressional Budget gration to Germany: An Analysis Based on Local
Office, Feb. 1993. Labor Markets. Massachusetts Institute of
K ATZ, E LIAKIM AND S TARK , ODED. International Technology, Jan. 1994.
Migration under Asymmetric Information, PORTES , A LEJANDRO. The Social Origins of the
Econ. J., Sept. 1987, 97(387), pp. 71826. Cuban Enclave in Miami, Sociological Perspec-
K OSSOUDJI , S HERRIE A. Immigrant Worker As- tives, Fall 1987, 30(3), pp. 34072.
similation: Is It a Labor Market Phenomenon? R AMOS, F ERNANDO A. Out-Migration and Re-
J. Human Res., Summer 1989, 24(3), pp. 494 turn Migration of Puerto Ricans, in G EORGE J.
527. B ORJAS AND R ICHARD B. F REEMAN , eds. 1992,
L A L ONDE , R OBERT J. AND T OPEL , R OBERT H. pp. 4966.
Labor Market Adjustments to Increased Immi- R EIMERS, C ORDELIA W. Labor Market Discrimi-
gration, in J OHN M. A BOWD AND R ICHARD B. nation against Hispanic and Black Men, Rev.
F REEMAN , eds. 1991, pp. 16799. Econ. Statist., Nov. 1983, 65(4), pp. 57079.
. The Assimilation of Immigrants in the R OMER, PAUL M. Increasing Returns and Long-
U.S. Labor Market, in GEORGE J. B ORJAS AND run Growth, J. Polit. Econ., Oct. 1986, 94(5),
R ICHARD B. F REEMAN , eds. 1992, pp. 6792. pp. 100237.
L EVY , F RANK AND M URNANE , R ICHARD J. U.S. R OY , A NDREW D. Some Thoughts on the Distri-
Earnings Levels and Earnings Inequality: A Re- bution of Earnings, Oxford Econ. Pap., N.S.,
view of Recent Trends and Proposed Explana- June 1951, 3, pp. 13546.
tions, J. Econ. Lit., Sept. 1992, 30(3), pp. S ATTINGER, M ICHAEL. Assignment Models of
133381. the Distribution of Earnings, J. Econ. Lit.,
L IGHT , I VAN AND B ONACICH, E DNA . Immigrant June 1993, 31(2), pp. 83180.
Borjas: The Economics of Immigration 1717
S IMON, J ULIAN L.; M OORE , S TEPHEN AND S ULLI- service, 1992. Washington, DC: U.S. GPO,
VAN , R ICHARD . The Effect of Immigration on 1993.
Aggregate Native Unemployment: An Across- U.S. GENERAL A CCOUNTING OFFICE . Illegal
City Estimation, J. Lab. Res., Summer 1993, aliens: Despite data limitations, current meth-
14(3), pp. 299316. ods provide better population estimates. Report
S MITH, J AMES . Hispanics and the American Number GAO/PEMD-9325, August 1993.
Dream: An Analysis of Hispanic Male Labor W ALDINGER, R OGER. Who Gets the Lousy
Market Wages, 19401980. Rand Corporation, Jobs? New Immigrants and African-Americans
1992. in New York, 19401990. U. of California, Los
S OLON , GARY R. Intergenerational Income Mo- Angeles, Oct. 1993.
bility in the United States, Amer. Econ. Rev., W ARREN , R OBERT AND PECK , J ENNIFER M ARKS .
June 1992, 82(3), pp. 393408. Foreign-Born Emigration from the United
TAINER, EVELINA . English Language Proficiency States: 19601970, Demography, Feb. 1980,
and the Determination of Earnings among For- 17(1), pp. 7184.
eign-Born Men, J. Human Res., Winter 1988, W HITE , M ICHAEL J. AND H UNTER, L ORI. The
23(1), pp. 10822. Migratory Response of Native-Born Workers to
TANTON , J OHN AND L UTTON , W AYNE . Immigra- the Presence of Immigrants in the Labor Mar-
tion and Criminality in the U.S.A., J. Social, ket. Brown U., July 1993.
Polit. Econ. Studies, Summer 1993, 18(2), pp. W HITE , M ICHAEL J. AND L IANG, ZAI . The Effect
21734. of Immigration on the Internal Migration of the
TAYLOR, J. E DWARD. Undocumented Mexico- Native-Born Population, 198190. Brown U.,
U.S. Migration and the Returns to Households Aug. 1993.
in Rural Mexico, Amer. J. Agr. Econ., Aug. W ILSON , W ILLIAM J ULIUS . The truly disadvan-
1987, 69(3), pp. 62638. taged: The inner city, the underclass, and pub-
TOPEL, R OBERT H. Regional Labor Markets and lic policy. Chicago: U. of Chicago Press, 1987.
the Determinants of Wage Inequality, Amer. W INEGARDEN, C. R. AND K HOR, L AY B OON. Un-
Econ. Rev., May 1994, 84(2), pp. 1722. documented Immigration and Unemployment
UNITED N ATIONS. World population at the of U.S. Youth and Minority Workers:
turn of the century. New York: United Nations, Econometric Evidence, Rev. Econ. Statist.,
1989. Feb. 1991, 73(1), pp. 10512.
U.S. D EPARTMENT OF COMMERCE . B UREAU OF W RIGHT , R OBERT E. AND M AXIM, PAUL S. Im-
THE CENSUS . Historical statistics of the United migration Policy and Immigrant Quality: Em-
States, colonial times to 1970. Washington, DC: pirical Evidence from Canada, J. Population
U.S. GPO, 1975. Econ., 1993, 6(4), pp. 33752.
. The foreign-born population in the United Y UENGERT , A NDREW. Immigrant Earnings, Rela-
States. Washington, DC: Bureau of the Census tive to What? The Importance of Earnings
Report 1990 CP-31, 1993a. Function Specification and Comparison Points,
. Statistical abstract of the United States, J. Applied Econometrics, Jan.-Mar. 1994, 9(1),
1993. Washington, DC: U.S. GPO, 1993b. pp. 7190.
U.S. D EPARTMENT OF J USTICE . I MMIGRATION Z IMMERMAN , D AVID J. Regression Toward Medi-
AND N ATURALIZATION S ERVICE . Statistical ocrity in Economic Stature, Amer. Econ. Rev.,
yearbook of the immigration and naturalization June 1992, 82(3), pp. 40929.

You might also like