You are on page 1of 13

Journal of Retailing 81 (1, 2005) 1–13

The different faces of coupon elasticity


V. Kumar a,∗ , Srinivasan Swaminathan b
a ING Center for Financial Services, School of Business, Department of Marketing, University of Connecticut, Storrs, CT-06269-1041, USA
b Drexel University, Philadelphia, PA, USA

Abstract

Coupons account for over two-thirds of all consumer promotional efforts initiated by the manufacturers of consumer goods. In this study,
the impact of coupons on brand sales is investigated and how that impact decays over the life of the coupon is demonstrated. Specifically, we
present an econometric model that can capture coupon effects in terms of equivalent price reduction, account for coupon effects over time,
allow inference of coupon effects when retailers decide to double or triple the coupon value, and provide both self-coupon and cross-coupon
elasticities at different levels of aggregation. A widely used sales response model is adapted, and an analytical model is proposed to estimate
both the self-coupon and cross-coupon (face value) elasticities of sales at the store level. From the store-level elasticity estimates for a given
week, the authors analytically derive the coupon elasticities for the chain level by aggregating across stores, and over the life of the coupon
by aggregating over time. The proposed sales response model is estimated with the data obtained from three markets for various product
categories, and the coupon elasticities are computed. The proposed framework allows one to demonstrate the hypothetical equivalence of a
shelf-price reduction for a given coupon face value in each week. Also, the effect of doubling the face value of a coupon results in more than
a proportionate increase in elasticity. The authors find that both self and cross-coupon elasticities are much smaller in magnitude than the
average self and cross-price elasticity measures reported in the literature.
© 2005 New York University. Published by Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.

Keywords: Sales promotions; Promotional elasticity; Coupons

Introduction the impact of couponing decisions on performance measures


such as redemption rates, incremental sales, market share,
Among the various forms of consumer promotions, and profitability (Dhar, Morrison, & Raju 1996; Dhar & Raju
couponing continues to be popular among manufacturers. 1998; Raju, Dhar, & Morrison 1994). As seen in Table 1,
The total number of manufacturer coupons printed and dis- which summarizes some of the studies in the second stream
tributed by consumer packaged goods companies grew by of research, researchers have used both primary data (col-
3.8 percent to 248 billion in the United States during 2002. lected through experiments and surveys) and secondary data
Free Standing Inserts (FSIs) continue to increase their share to examine the impact of coupons on brand performance.
of coupons distributed and they account for 86 percent of Although a lot is known about the price elasticity of de-
all coupons distributed by manufacturers. Consumers saved mand (Tellis 1988), very little is known about the magni-
more than $3 billion in 2002, or $0.80 per coupon redeemed tude of coupon face value elasticity of demand. Therefore,
on average (NCH marketing services 2003). The managerial we focus on coupon face value elasticity in this study. We
importance of couponing has inspired much of the research define coupon face value elasticity as the ratio of percent-
on the topic, which can be divided into two broad streams: one age change in sales of a brand to the percentage change
that examines the profile of consumers who redeem coupons in the coupon face value of that brand. Coupons have an
(Jolson, Wiener, & Rosecky 1987; Montgomery 1971; Teel, expiration date and their impact on brand sales changes de-
Williams, & Bearden 1980), and the other that investigates pending upon their face value. Furthermore, the impact of
coupon on brand sales decays over the life of the coupon.
∗ Corresponding author. Tel.: +1 860 486 1086; fax: +1 860 486 8396. So, when investigating coupon elasticity one has to take into
E-mail address: vk@sba.uconn.edu (V. Kumar). account the time dimension also. To better manage inven-

0022-4359/$ – see front matter © 2005 New York University. Published by Elsevier Inc. All rights reserved.
doi:10.1016/j.jretai.2005.01.003
2 V. Kumar, S. Swaminathan / Journal of Retailing 81 (1, 2005) 1–13

Table 1
Summary of research studies revieweda
Authors Dependent variable Research design/data used
Bagozzi, Baumgartner, and Yi (1991) Coupon usage Survey of female staff members
Bawa and Shoemaker (1987a) Coupon proneness Scanner data
Bawa and Shoemaker (1987b) Purchase probability Field experiment
Bawa and Shoemaker (1989) Incremental purchases Field experiment
Bawa, Srinivasan, and Srivastava (1997) Likelihood of redemption Survey of shoppers
Chapman (1986) Sales per household Field experiment
Dhar and Raju (1998) Sales and profits In-store data
Dhar et al. (1996) Profits Quasi-experimental data
Dodson, Tybout, and Sternthal (1978) Likelihood of switching Panel data
Inman and McAlister (1994) Weekly coupon redemptions Analysis of scanner data
Irons, Little, and Klein (1983) Incremental sales Experimental
Klein (1981) Incremental sales Field experiment
Krishna and Zhang (1999) Coupon duration NCH coupon data
Lee and Brown (1985) Sales per household Scanner panel data
Leone and Srinivasan (1996) Brand sales and profits NCH coupon data
Narasimhan (1984) Annual purchase quantity Scanner data
Neslin (1990) Market share, percentage of category Scanner data
purchases that are made with coupons
Neslin and Shoemaker (1983) Profitability of couponing operation Managerial judgments
Neslin, Henderson, and Quelch (1985) Purchase acceleration Scanner data
Raju et al. (1994) Sales/market share Experimental data
Reibstein and Traver (1982) Coupon redemption rates Cross-sectional study of
redemptions for a single brand
Shimp and Kavas (1984) Intention to redeem Survey of consumers
Shoemaker and Tibrewala (1985) Intention to redeem Survey of shoppers
Ward and Davis (1978a) Quantity purchased by individuals Scanner data
Ward and Davis (1978b) Coupon redemptions Secondary data on redemption rates
a The list of articles is by no means exhaustive.

tory of the product at the store level retailers would like pute coupon face value elasticity at the store level for own
to know how the coupon face value elasticity varies over and competing brands. We also investigate additional dimen-
time. Managers at the chain level would like to know how sions of coupon face value elasticity, namely, how one’s own
the store level elasticities can be aggregated to obtain chain and competing brands’ coupon elasticity change on a weekly
level estimates so that they can efficiently manage their orders basis, and over the validity of the coupon. The estimation
with the manufacturers. Manufacturers of consumer goods of coupon elasticities at the chain level and/or the market
would like to obtain an aggregate market level measure of level from the store-level elasticities is also illustrated. Subse-
coupon elasticity so that they can better plan their produc- quently, the proposed model is extended to capture the effects
tion. Also, it is interesting to observe how the coupon for of multiple couponing strategy.
a given brand affects the sales of a competing brand. We, The paper is organized as follows: First, we offer a gen-
therefore, define and evaluate the magnitude of cross-coupon eralized coupon-sales response model that meets the objec-
elasticity. tives of managers who are faced with couponing decisions.
With regard to retailers, some stores offer promotions such Then, we derive the elasticity estimates for various dimen-
as doubling or tripling the face value of coupons for a certain sions. Subsequently, we use store/chain levels to estimate the
time period. A few national chains like Kroger frequently proposed sales response model and generate both self and
triple the coupon face value up to 39 cents and double it up cross-coupon face value elasticities. We then illustrate the
to 50 cents. How does such a strategy impact brand sales and effects of double couponing on sales and coupon elasticities.
coupon elasticity? Brand managers are eager to know the Finally, we discuss the managerial implications and limita-
optimum face value of a coupon that would maximize their tions of the present study.
profits. While this depends on many factors such as coupon
elasticity and coupon redemption rates, managers welcome
any insight into this issue. Background
In this paper, we adapt a known model form to estimate
the sales response to coupon face values at the store level. Despite the importance of the expiration date and face
The model allows the sales response to vary over time and value decisions, only few studies have estimated the effects
it also incorporates cross-brand sales effects. The estimated of this on brand sales over time. It should be noted that
parameters of the sales response model are then used to com- Krishna and Zhang (1999) used coupon duration as a de-
V. Kumar, S. Swaminathan / Journal of Retailing 81 (1, 2005) 1–13 3

pendent variable while the focus of this study is on assess- A generalized coupon-sales response model
ing the impact of coupon duration and coupon face value
on sales and coupon face value elasticity. However, we in- Store-level sales of a brand are a function of a number
corporate the interactions between coupon face value and of local and global variables. We use the term local vari-
coupon duration in our framework. Although Neslin (1990) ables to refer to such variables as display and featuring ac-
modeled the effect of a coupon’s face value on market share, tivities, which are under the control of a store manager. The
he did not capture the specific effects of a coupon on brand chain/store managers can change these local variables in-
sales over the life of the coupon. As indicated in Table 1, dividually in various stores. We use the term global vari-
many studies have focused only on performance measures able to refer to the marketing variable, which is commonly
such as incremental sales and coupon redemptions. Inman set by the manufacturer. This variable normally affects sales
and McAlister (1994) modeled the effect of coupon expira- across a number of stores/chains in a market. For example,
tion on coupon redemptions and have demonstrated a small a Free Standing Insert coupon issued by the manufacturers
increase in coupon redemption toward the end of the coupon’s is a global variable because the same face value coupons
expiration date. However, the translation of this small blip in are issued for different stores in the market. It is possible to
coupon redemptions into brand sales is not direct. The in- fine-tune local variables to the needs of each of the differ-
creased coupon redemptions observed toward the expiration ent stores in a market. However, when a manufacturer issues
date do not translate into a substantially higher increase in an FSI coupon in a market, the impact of the coupon on
brand sales in this study. From the analysis of sales data dur- sales is likely to be different in different stores. Estimating a
ing the last week of the coupon’s expiration date in this study, chain/market-level response model to calculate the elasticity
we find that the contribution to sales from coupons is usu- of the global variable will lead to biased results as different
ally less than 1 percent. Given that the typical R2 values for stores in the chain/market could have different levels of re-
any brand sales model is not 100 percent, the 1 percent effect sponsiveness to the same global variable. In this research, we
is not that obvious in the sales response model. Following propose a method to estimate the chain/market-level elastic-
Dhar and Raju (1998) and Leone and Srinivasan (1996) we ity measure of a global variable by aggregating store-level
model brand sales as a monotonically decreasing function of responses to that global variable.
time. We model sales of a brand as a function of the price of
the brand, the face value of the coupon issued, the time since
Behavioral reasoning a coupon drop, and store causal variables (e.g., display and
featuring activities). The time since a coupon drop variable is
The analysis of the significance of coupon face value and included to allow for decay in response. One of the major pur-
expiration date is important for a number of reasons, some poses of a coupon drop is to price discriminate (Narasimhan
of which have behavioral implications. Although a larger 1984), and coupons as a price-discriminating device are use-
coupon face value can cause incremental sales (Bawa & less if consumers are insensitive to price. Hence, in measur-
Shoemaker 1989), Raghubir (1998) suggests that a higher ing the impact of coupons on brand sales, we use a model
face value on a coupon can have the opposite effect if con- where coupons will have an impact on brand sales only
sumers are not informed about the original price. In other when consumers are sensitive to price. During the week
words, offering coupons of larger face values to consumers when FSI coupons are dropped, customers become aware
to encourage trial (under a low price awareness scenario) and may cut the coupons. Both the advertising value of the
might lead to higher price expectations and in turn, possibly FSI coupons and the chances of the coupons being redeemed
depress trial intent. Alternatively, price expectations may be are at their peak. However, as time progresses, customers
lowered by frequent promotions, which can lead to a negative are likely to be exposed to competitors’ coupons and are
effect on sales (Mayhew & Winer 1992). However, Kumar likely to cut these coupons also. Also over time, customers
and Pereira (1995) have shown that the scheduling of pro- are likely to misplace their original coupons and hence the
motions is of critical importance and that a mere higher fre- impact of the coupon drop on brand sales is likely to decay.
quency of promotions alone does not automatically cause Hence, the model form that captures the impact of coupon
lower price expectations, and therefore, may result in lower on sales should not only account for the fact that coupons
sales. Because coupons are a form of price promotions, offer- of higher face value are likely to have a longer impact on
ing larger coupon face values at frequent time intervals can brand sales, but that this impact is likely to diminish over
have a detrimental effect on sales, and therefore, on a firm’s time since the coupon drop. We adapt a general version of
profit (Kalwani & Yim 1992). Also, a larger time frame for the log reciprocal sales response forms proposed by previ-
coupon expiration can induce consumers to purchase more ous researchers (Leone & Srinivasan 1996) and extend it in
than once with the coupon (may be from borrowed sources three ways: to include additional forms of promotions, com-
or by buying an additional newspaper). To summarize, both petition and multiple couponing strategies. To accommodate
coupon face value and coupon expiration duration are of crit- single, double, or triple couponing strategies and multiple
ical concerns to manufacturers as their effects are still largely competing brands, we have developed a generalized coupon
unknown to them. model.
4 V. Kumar, S. Swaminathan / Journal of Retailing 81 (1, 2005) 1–13

The self-coupon and cross-coupon elasticity can be de- coupon face value, then, the coupon face value (Vi and/or Vj )
rived analytically for this generalized coupon-sales response can be doubled and entered into the model. In other words, if
model and is shown in the next section. a retailer doubles the coupon face value for one brand (given
   a particular coupon value) and another store does not, then,
β  β3j
Qist = exp β0 + −  the proposed model allows a comparison of the two coupon-
1
(Pist −γi Vi β2τi ) Pjst −δj Vj β4τjj ing strategies. Thus, the model allows for an examination of
j
  double couponing strategy.
 Parameters β1 and β3j capture the impact of the shelf-
+ β5 Dist −  β6j Djst  price of brand i and that of its competitor on the sales of
j brand i. Parameter β2 captures the impact of the face value
  of the brand i coupon and time since the coupon drop on
 the sales of brand i. In the first week since the coupon drop,
+ β7 Fist −  β8j Fjst  + εist (1)
the impact of dropping a coupon of face value Vi on brand
j
sales is equivalent to that of a hypothetical temporary price
where Qist is the unit sales of brand i in store s in week t; reduction of β2 × Vi . In the following week, the impact of
Pist , price of brand i in store s in week t; Vit , face value of the coupon drop is equivalent to that of a temporary price
coupon for brand i valid in time period t; τ i , number of weeks reduction of β22 × Vi . For example, if β2 were 0.5 and if a
since coupon for brand i was dropped; Dit , dummy variable coupon of face value $1 were dropped in week 10, for a single
to indicate display activity for brand i in store s in week t; Fit , couponing strategy the coupon’s impact on brand sales would
dummy variable to indicate featuring activity for brand i in be equivalent to that of a hypothetical price reduction of 50
store s in week t; εist , error term; γ i , δj = 1 for the face value cents in week 10. The impact of the coupon drop in week 11
of the coupons for brands i and j, respectively, in week t; γ i , would be equal to that of a temporary price reduction of 25
δj = 2 for double couponing of brands i and j, respectively, in cent for that week, and so on. Similar to β2 , parameter β4j
week t, and γ i , δj = 3 for triple couponing of brands i and j, captures the impact of a competitor’s coupon drops on the
respectively, in week t. sales of brand i.
The above model formulation offers the flexibility of ac- As noted from Eq. (1), the impact of the coupon face value
commodating double or triple couponing strategies in addi- on a brand’s sales in a particular week is a function of not only
tion to the regular face value of the coupon and the possibility the price of the brand (and that of its competitors) in that week,
of this strategy varying over the coupon expiration date, and but also the time since the coupon drop.2 From this equation,
multiple competing brands (for the sake of readability we we can obtain the analytical forms for the price elasticity of
have omitted store and brand subscripts for the parameters). demand and coupon face value elasticity of demand. Once the
Therefore, we term this model the generalized coupon-sales parameters of Eq. (1) are obtained, we can get the numerical
response model.1 The validity of the exponentially decay- estimates of coupon face value elasticity of demand.
ing assumption has been tested by previous researchers (e.g., For comparison purposes, we also formulate three other
Leone & Srinivasan 1996) and we extend their model in this forms of coupon-sales response models:
study. We also compare this functional form to other model
(A) Linear: qist = β0i + β1i (Pist − γ st Vi β2i τ ) + other terms,
forms to better understand the nature of the relationship.
(B) Semi-log: log qist = β0i + β1 (Pist − γ st Vi β2i τ ) + other
The use of an exponential form for the sales response
terms, and
model and a reciprocal functional form for price is recom-
(C) Double-log: log qist = β0i + β1 (log(Pist − γ st Vi β2i τ )) +
mended by Mulhern and Leone (1991) for many reasons.
other terms.
First, the lower absolute price levels (i.e., larger price reduc-
tions) correspond to the larger elasticity measures—a result We compared the above three forms with the model proposed
that is achieved by using the reciprocals of the prices as inde- in this study.
pendent variables. Also, behavioral research has shown that
larger price changes produce relatively larger responses com-
pared with smaller price changes (Della Bitta, Monroe, & Coupon face value elasticity
McGinnis 1981). Finally, the introduction of the coupon face
value term in the denominator (along with price) facilitates Coupon face value elasticity is defined as the ratio of a
the computation of the equivalence of a hypothetical tempo- percentage change in sales to a percentage change in the face
rary shelf-price reduction for a given coupon face value in
2 While it may be interesting to model the interactions between price and
each week. Another important feature of the proposed model
form is that, if a given store has a strategy of doubling the coupon in all the model forms, the limited availability of data on the oc-
currences of different coupon face value at various price levels precludes
this possibility. However, the partial differential of the sales response func-
1 The proposed model form can be expanded to include variables that tion with respect to face value is a function of price. Hence, the interaction
capture heterogeneity in the methods of distributing coupons and the number between the price and face value of the coupon are easily captured by the
of coupons distributed. proposed inherently nonlinear functional form used in this study.
V. Kumar, S. Swaminathan / Journal of Retailing 81 (1, 2005) 1–13 5

value of the coupon. We investigate two types of coupon face Through differentiation and algebraic manipulation, we
value elasticity: (1) the percentage change in sales of brand i get
in week t as a ratio of the percentage change in coupon face
T

value for brand i, which we label as “self-coupon elasticity”, Qist
and (2) the percentage change in sales of brand i in week t niis. = ηiist
T (3)
t=1 t=1 Qist
as a ratio of the percentage change in coupon face value for
brand j, which we label as “cross-coupon elasticity.” For ease This is basically a weighted average of the weekly self-
of exposition, we consider the case of two brands i and j in coupon elasticity.
this section.

Life of the coupon (in the chain/market, over the life of


Self-coupon elasticity
the coupon)
Self-coupon elasticity in a given chain over the life of the
Short term (in store s, for week t)
coupon is defined as:
When a coupon of a particular face value, valid only
for a certain number of weeks, is issued, the impact of the percentage change in sales of brand
coupon on brand sales is likely to be different in different i in the chain over the life of the coupon
weeks. Self-coupon elasticity for week t in store s is defined ηii.. =
as: percentage change in the face
value of the coupon for brand i
percentage change in sales of brand

i in store s in week t Let Qis. = Tt=1 Qist , and Vi be the face value of the coupon
ηiist =
percentage change in the face value of for brand i in the T weeks under consideration:
the coupon for brand i
S

∂ Ss=1 Qis. Vi  Qis.
In other words, ηii.. =
S = ηiis.
S (4)
∂Vi s=1 Qis. s=1 Qis.
s=1
∂Qist /Qist ∂Qist Vi
ηiist = = ×
∂Vi /Vi ∂Vi Qist This is basically a weighted average of the self-coupon elas-
ticity across the different stores in the chain/market. In de-
For the functional form given in Eq. (1), the self-coupon riving this, we implicitly assume that sales across stores are
elasticity3 is: independent of one another.
β1 β2τi γt Vi
ηiist = (2)
(Pist − γt Vi β2τi )2 Cross-coupon elasticity

Eq. (2) not only allows for the computation of the self-coupon Short term (in store s, for week t)
elasticity for a given store s in time t, it also facilitates the Cross-coupon elasticity in store s for week t is defined as:
computation of self-coupon elasticity when double or triple
couponing occurs. Please note that γ t in Eq. (2) readily pro-
vides us with the ability to study the impact of types of coupon percentage change in sales of brand
strategy (single, double or triple couponing) in a given week i in store s in week t
ηijst =
compared with other weeks. percentage change in the face value of the
coupon for brand j
Life of the coupon (in store s, over the life of the coupon)
Self-coupon elasticity in store s over the life of the coupon
∂Qist Vj β3 δt β4τj Vj
is defined as: ηijst = = (5)
∂Vj Qist (Pjst − δt Vj β4τj )2
percentage change in sales of brand
i in store s over the life of the coupon
ηiis. = Life of the coupon (in store s, over the life of the coupon)
percentage change in Cross-coupon elasticity in store s over the life of the
the face value of the coupon for brand i coupon is defined as:

T
∂ t=1 Qist Vi
T T

=
T ∂ Vj 
∂Vi t=1 Qist Qist
t=1 Qist ηijs. =
T = ηijst
T (6)
∂Vj t=1 Qist t=1 Qist
t=1

3 Derivation of the elasticities for all the cases discussed in this paper can
This is basically a weighted average of the weekly cross-
be obtained by contacting the first author. coupon elasticity.
6 V. Kumar, S. Swaminathan / Journal of Retailing 81 (1, 2005) 1–13

Life of the coupon (in the chain/market, over the life of Each chain had different numbers of stores (ranging from 7
the coupon) to 15 per chain) for which data were available. The product
Cross-coupon elasticity in a given chain over the life of market used in this research has certain unique characteris-
the coupon is defined as: tics, such as the absence of double couponing activities in
the chains that were considered, the absence of store coupon-
percentage change in sales of brand
ing activities, and the absence of display and featuring ac-
i in a chain over the life of the coupon
ηij.. = tivities. All coupons dropped for the product category were
percentage change in the face value of freestanding inserts in Sunday newspapers and did not have
the coupon for brand j any restrictions on the particular sizes for which they could

T be redeemed.6 The face value of the coupons for this product
Let Qis = t=1 Qist , and Vj be the face value of the coupon
category ranged from 35 cents to $1.00 in the analysis time
for brand j for the T weeks under consideration.
 period. Also, the coupons were dropped on four different oc-

S
∂ Ss=1 Qis. Vj  Qis. casions for one brand and on three different occasions for the
ηij.. =
S = ηijs.
S (7) other brand. Each time the coupons were valid for a period of
∂Vj s=1 Qis. s=1 Qis.
s=1 eight weeks. While one would argue that not all the variables
This is basically a weighted average of the cross-coupon elas- described in Eq. (1) are included here, it is quite difficult to
ticity across the different stores in the chain/market. Simi- obtain a dataset, which exhibits variation in coupon face val-
larly, elasticity measures can be derived for the three other ues over time (the primary focus of this paper). For a two
competing functional forms4 proposed in this study. In the brand case, in the absence of featuring and display activities,
next section, we empirically demonstrate the value of the Eq. (1) reduces to (assuming γ t and δt are equal to 1 for single
proposed modeling effect. couponing strategy):
 
β1 β3
Qist = exp β0 + − + εist
(Pit − Vi β2τi ) (Pjt − Vj β4τj )
Single couponing strategy
(8)
Empirical demonstration
We obtained another data set from one of the largest re-
Data tail chains in a Southwestern city in the United States for a
The A.C. Nielsen Company provided us with two sets of different product category. This chain had data for two sub-
data for a major city (Market 1) in the Northeastern United urbs (Markets 2 and 3) within a large city. The data were
States, which we used to estimate the model in Eq. (1). One available for a period of 52 weeks for a different product
set contained store-level data capturing details on weekly category, in which two major brands dominated the market
sales (for 65 weeks) in the various stores and the store causal place. Although this product category has different package
variables (e.g., display and featuring activities). The second sizes, one size dominated the category. The typical interpur-
set was a coupon database capturing details of all coupons chase time for this product category was three weeks, and
dropped in the stores’ market.5 The details of the coupon the price for the popular size for the two brands ranges from
drops include the face value, method of distribution, expira- $3.00 to $4.00 across stores and chains in the marketplace.
tion date, number of coupons distributed, and any restrictions The market share for these two brands in the chosen markets
on the use of the coupon. exceeded 70 percent. However, in this category, featuring (6
To estimate the sales response model, we chose a com- weeks on average for each brand) and display (5 weeks on
monly used consumer product category. Two brands (labeled average for each brand) activities occurred to some extent,
A and B) dominated the market, and they accounted for over and therefore, the model form shown in Eq. (1) is estimated.
75 percent of the market share during the time period of the The nature of the second product category used in this
analysis. As in the study by Reibstein and Traver (1982), our study is such that the coupon face values typically range from
analysis is focused on one size of the brand that accounts 55 cents to $1.00. Coupons were dropped on three different
for a major portion of sales (over 80 percent) in the market. occasions for both brands, and each time the coupons were
Thus, the competition from other package sizes is minimal. valid for a period of eight weeks. Because retailers double
For the popular size, the prices of the two brands in the prod- the face value of coupons up to 50 cents, a double couponing
uct category ranged from $4.00 to $5.00 across stores and strategy should not affect the results of the study. However,
chains. Data were provided for three chains in this market. as stated earlier, a double couponing strategy can easily be
incorporated into the framework.
4 The self-coupon elasticity formulations for the three other models

formulated—linear, semi-log and double-log—can be obtained from the au-


thors. 6 If data are available for on-pack coupons or other methods of distribution,
5 Because of the confidentiality agreement with the data suppliers, we then one can use a dummy variable in the present framework to capture the
cannot reveal the product category, brand names, or chain names. effect of coupon distribution source.
V. Kumar, S. Swaminathan / Journal of Retailing 81 (1, 2005) 1–13 7

Table 2
Parameter estimates of the sales response model given by Eq. (2)a
Chain Brand β1 β2 β3 β4 β5 × 102 β6 × 102 β7 × 102 β8 × 102 Adjusted R2
Market 1 1 (n = 7) A 1108.10** (4.70) 0.82** (5.5) 520.8** (3.10) 0.69** (3.87) – – – – .82
B 2144.2** (11.2) 0.79** (7.8) 1248.11** (8.6) 0.46** (2.45) – – – – .77
2 (n = 8) A 1441.2** (8.4) 0.71** (5.4) 460.31** (3.2) 0.61** (2.4) – – – – .75
B 1350.1** (5.2) 0.74** (3.8) 462.4** (3.6) 0.59** (2.9) – – – – .81
3 (n = 15) A 1412.6** (9.3) 0.70** (4.8) 768.60** (10.8) 0.58** (2.9) – – – – .76
B 978.3** (3.3) 0.62** (3.1) 221.3* (1.8) 0.51** (2.6) – – – – .74

Market 2 4 (n = 4) X 1103.7** (4.1) 0.86** (7.1) 381.2** (2.7) 0.69** (3.2) 280.2** (3.1) 110.1* (1.9) 152.3** (2.8) 92.4* (1.8) .83
Y 1420.8** 5.1 0.65** (6.1) 358.2** (2.9)** 0.48** (2.4) 261.4** (3.5) 102.8** (2.2) 171.4** (3.0) 81.8* (1.9) .79

Market 3 4 (n = 6) X 782.4** (4.2) 0.81** (5.6) 496.8** (4.2)** 0.66** (3.6) 320.1** (4.1) 150.2** (2.1) 185.6** (2.7) 84.7* (1.7) .81
Y 1389.1** (7.4) 0.62** (4.1) 916.3** (5.1) 0.48** (3.1) 290.3** (3.7) 105.6* (1.9) 142.8** (2.4) NS .79
n indicates the number of stores within each chain. NS: not significant.
a t-values are in parentheses.
∗∗ Significant at .05 level.
∗ Significant at .10 level.

Model estimation variable (sales) as opposed to the model specific dependent


The effect of price and promotions on brand sales could variable. In other words, if the dependent variable is ln(sales),
differ across the different stores in a market, depending on then, we take the exponent of it to convert it to the original
the demographic characteristics of shoppers and the image of variable and then compare the actual values with the fitted
the chains. Consequently, aggregating sales and price across values and obtain a measure of R2 . The R2 values in the orig-
different stores in a market and modeling the sales response inal variable space range from .51 to .60. The AIC value for
at the market level could produce biased estimates of the our proposed model is 514 as compared to the values of 559,
parameters. The estimated coefficients may not pertain to 572, and 581 for the linear, semi-log, and double-log models,
any particular store or even to the average effect across all respectively. Thus, it is evident that our proposed model form
stores (Neslin 1990). Thus, it is appropriate to estimate the provides the best fit. For the sake of brevity, we only discuss
sales response model at the store level. However, we did the the estimation results for Brand B in Chain 1. Parameter esti-
pooling test (Bass & Wittink 1975) to determine if the stores mates for other brands in other chains can be interpreted in a
belonging to a particular chain could be pooled. The results similar manner. Parameter β1 captures the impact of price of
of the pooling test for the slope coefficients indicated that the Brand B on its sales, and parameter β3 captures the impact
stores could be pooled within a chain for the chosen product of price of Brand A on sales of Brand B. Both β1 and β3
categories at α = .01. We, therefore, model the sales response are significant and of the proper sign, indicating that sales of
to the price and promotional variables at the chain level but Brand B are affected by both the price of Brand B and that
allow for store-specific intercepts. If the stores could not be of its competing brand. Parameter β2 captures the impact of
pooled, then, one could estimate the model for each store, coupon face value (of Brand B) on sales of Brand B. Param-
compute the elasticity for each store and then aggregate it to eter β2 has a value of 0.79 and is significant at the .05 level.9
the chain level. This parameter helps us estimate the temporary reduction in
We estimated the parameters7 of Eq. (1) by the nonlinear shelf-price needed to achieve a similar impact on brand sales
least squares (NLS) method. These parameter estimates are as that of dropping a coupon of a particular face value.
reported in Table 2. We estimated Eq. (1) without restrict- Assume that in week 10, Brand B drops a coupon with
ing the range of β2 (to see if it would converge to values a $1 face value. The impact of this coupon drop on Brand
less of than 1) and β4 . The data provides an excellent fit8 to B sales is equivalent to the impact of temporarily reducing
the model, as indicated by the high values of adjusted R2 , Brand B’s shelf-price by 79 cents in week 10, $0.62 (0.792 )
which range from .74 to .83 across chains and markets. We in week 11, and so on. Parameter β4 captures the impact of a
also estimated the three other model forms—linear, semi-log, competitor’s coupon drop on the sales of Brand B. If Brand
double-log—and found that our chosen model form performs A drops a coupon worth $1.00 in week 15, the impact of the
better, in terms of fit and predictive criteria, than these alter- coupon drop on sales of Brand B in week 15 is equivalent
nate formulations, anywhere from 10 to 25 percent (i.e., R2 to the impact of a hypothetical temporary price reduction
of .56–.64). We also compute R2 on the original dependent of $0.46 by Brand A in week 15. In week 16, the impact
on Brand B’s sales is equivalent to that of a hypothetical
7 Autocorrelation in the residuals, when present was corrected with the temporary price reduction of $0.21 (0.462 ) by Brand A.
iterative two-stage estimation procedure described in Non-linear Regression The estimation results for Markets 2 and 3 indicate that the
(1989) by G.A.F. Seber and C.J. Wild, pp. 274–280. parameter estimates have face validity and that the findings
8 We fitted a power transformation to the terms with price variable in

Eq. (1) to test if the coefficient estimate is statistically different from −1.
The analysis as described in Plots, Transformations and Regression by A.C. 9 A test of whether β = 1 and β = 1 indicates that the null hypothesis is
2 4
Atkinson, indicates that we could not reject the null hypothesis of −1, and rejected at α = .05 for both β2 and β4 . This implies that the effect of coupon
therefore, the reciprocal relationship proposed in this study holds good. is not constant over time.
8 V. Kumar, S. Swaminathan / Journal of Retailing 81 (1, 2005) 1–13

are similar to that of Market 1. The self and cross-coupon corresponding decreases are from 0.23 to 0.04 for store 2.
face value elasticities were computed for all the stores and the Similarly, the cross-coupon face value elasticity decreases
chains with the parameters from Table 2. To aid in computing from 0.05 in week 1 to 0.01 in week 6 for store 1, while
the elasticities, the prices of Brands A and B were used as the corresponding decreases are from 0.06 in week 1 to
$4.00 and $4.50, respectively. Similarly, a coupon that had 0.01 in week 4 for store 2. At the chain level (computed
a face value of 75 cents was used for each week since the with Eq. (4)), self-coupon elasticity decreases from 0.18 in
coupon drop (for up to 8 weeks). The value for the self-coupon week 1 to 0.03 in week 8, while the cross-coupon elas-
face value elasticity ranged from 0.3 to 0.83 for week 1, and ticity changes from −0.05 in week 1 to −0.01 in week 6
the value for the cross-coupon face value elasticity ranged and has a negligible effect thereafter. The chain level self-
from 0.1 to 0.35 for week 1 across all stores, chains, and coupon and cross-coupon elasticities (computed with Eqs.
markets.10 For week 8, the value for self-coupon face value (4) and (7)) are 0.09 and 0.02, respectively, over the life of the
elasticity ranged from 0.05 to 0.20 and, the value for cross- coupon.
coupon face value elasticity ranged from practically zero to The impact of different coupon face values and time since
0.08 across all stores, chains, and markets. Thus, the results coupon drop on self-coupon elasticity at the chain level is
are not market-specific, product-specific, or chain-specific in shown in Table 4. Assume that Brand B has a coupon value
nature. of 100 cents. As illustrated in Table 4, when Brand A’s coupon
value is changed to 75 cents, the chain level self-coupon elas-
Simulation ticity decreases from 0.40 in week 1 to 0.05 in week 8 for
brand A. The self-coupon elasticity is more than twice for
For the purpose of understanding the differential impact Brand A’s coupon value of 75 cents than it is for a coupon
of the face values of coupons and coupon expiration, the self- value of 40 cents. Similarly, when Brand A’s coupon value is
coupon face value elasticity and the cross-coupon face value changed to 100 cents, the chain level self-coupon elasticity
elasticity were generated for a brand (Brand A) in a market decreases from 0.59 in week 1 to 0.07 in week 8 for brand
with two stores. We simulated the results for three different A. The self-coupon elasticities are 0.09, 0.18, and 0.27 over
levels of coupon face values (40 cents, 75 cents, 100 cents) the life of the coupon for Brand A’s coupon values of 40, 75,
for Brand A as well as for three different levels of coupon face and 100 cents, respectively. The above findings indicate that
values (40 cents, 75 cents, 100 cents) for Brand B. Thus, we Brand A’s self-coupon elasticities increase more than pro-
simulated the results for nine (3 × 3) scenarios when Brands portionately to the increase in coupon face values. Similarly,
A and B dropped coupons of different face values in each of over the life of the coupon, the cross-coupon elasticities are
the two stores in a market. Also, the validity of the coupon −0.02, −0.03, and −0.05 for Brand B’s coupon face value of
was restricted to 8 weeks. The coupon face values and the 40, 75, and 100 cents, respectively, when Brand A has coupon
expiration date chosen for this study reflect the market con- value of 75 cents.
ditions for the product category analyzed. The model param- As one can see from these tables, the elasticity for the
eter values chosen for the simulation correspond to the range self-coupon face value and the cross-coupon face value decay
of values observed in our data set. For illustrative purposes, over the life of the coupon. The largest value for self-coupon
we chose the following parameters for two stores (deliber- elasticity is about 0.59 and for the cross-coupon elasticity it is
ately to show the differences across stores) in our simulation: about −0.16. As a point of comparison, the mean of the self-
price elasticity of demand reported by Tellis (1988) is −1.76
Store 1 Store 2 and the mean of cross-price elasticity found by Karande and
Brand A Brand B Brand A Brand B Kumar (1995) is 1.10. While price reduction is likely to have
β0 3 2 4 1.2
a broader appeal to all the shoppers, an increase in face value
β1 745 2421 1311 2657 of the coupon is likely to appeal only to coupon prone people.
β2 0.75 0.35 0.8 0.4 Further the increased attractiveness due to an increase in face
β3 397 264 603 1689 value may not translate into an equivalent increase in sales as
β4 0.65 0.20 0.5 0.2 only a fraction of the customers who see the coupon might
Price (cents) 404 463 460 485
actually end up redeeming it.
A summary of the results is presented in Tables 3 and 4. As one can see from the above tables, the coupon face
When both Brands A and B have a coupon for 40 cents, the value elasticity is a function of both the face value of the
self-coupon face value elasticity for Brand A decreases from coupon and time since the coupon drop. We illustrate the
0.16 in week 1 to 0.02 in week 8 for store 1, whereas the impact of coupon face value and time since coupon drop
through a 3D graph (see Fig. 1) that depicts the changes in
self-coupon face value as a function of both the face value
10 For the linear model, the value of self-coupon face value elasticity ranged
of the coupon and time since the coupon drop. In Fig. 1, we
from 0.21 to 0.66 for week 1, and the value for the cross-coupon face value
elasticity ranged from 0.04 to 0.26 for week 1 across stores, chains, and
assume the face value of competing brand’s coupon to be
markets. Similar values are obtained for the semi-log and the double-log 40 cents. We next discuss the effect of a double couponing
models. strategy.
V. Kumar, S. Swaminathan / Journal of Retailing 81 (1, 2005) 1–13 9

Table 3
Self- and cross-coupon face value elasticity of brand A (Brand A: 40 cents, Brand B: 40 cents)
Weeks since coupon drop Store 1 Store 2 Store 1 self Store 2 self Chain self Store 1 cross Store 2 cross Chain cross
sales sales elasticity elasticity elasticity elasticity elasticity elasticity
1 61.53 33.86 0.16 0.23 0.18 −0.05 −0.06 −0.05
2 59.88 33.92 0.12 0.18 0.14 −0.03 −0.03 −0.03
3 58.35 33.05 0.08 0.14 0.10 −0.02 −0.01 −0.02
4 57.18 32.21 0.06 0.11 0.08 −0.01 −0.01 −0.01
5 56.31 31.53 0.05 0.09 0.06 −0.01 0.00 −0.01
6 55.68 31.00 0.03 0.07 0.05 −0.01 0.00 0.00
7 55.22 30.58 0.03 0.05 0.04 0.00 0.00 0.00
8 54.88 30.26 0.02 0.04 0.03 0.00 0.00 0.00
Over the life of coupon 459.02 256.41 0.07 0.12 0.09 −0.02 −0.01 −0.02

Table 4
Self-coupon and cross-coupon elasticities of brand A
Weeks since Chain self elasticity Chain self elasticity Chain self elasticity Chain cross elasticity Chain cross elasticity Chain cross elasticity
coupon drop (Brand A = 40 cents) (Brand A = 75 cents) (Brand A = 100 cents) (Brand B = 40 cents) (Brand B = 75 cents) (Brand B = 100 cents)
1 0.18 0.40 0.59 −0.05 −0.11 −0.16
2 0.14 0.29 0.42 −0.03 −0.06 −0.09
3 0.10 0.21 0.30 −0.02 −0.04 −0.05
4 0.08 0.16 0.22 −0.01 −0.02 −0.03
5 0.06 0.12 0.16 −0.01 −0.01 −0.02
6 0.05 0.09 0.12 0.00 −0.01 −0.01
7 0.04 0.07 0.09 0.00 0.00 −0.01
8 0.03 0.05 0.07 0.00 0.00 0.00
Over the life 0.09 0.18 0.27 −0.02 −0.03 −0.05
of coupon

Fig. 1. Coupon face value elasticity.


10 V. Kumar, S. Swaminathan / Journal of Retailing 81 (1, 2005) 1–13

Double couponing strategy nonexistent given the nature of the product category and fea-
turing was almost negligible during the analysis period.
To illustrate the effect of a double couponing strategy, we
use the generalized coupon-sales response model specified in Double couponing
Eq. (1) with the assumption that γ t and δt are equal to 2. We The availability of data over a single couponing period
also estimated the other competing model forms and found and a double couponing period facilitates the comparison of
that our model formulation (Eq. (1)) does better than any of the effectiveness of these two strategies. Therefore, we es-
the other three formulations. timate two models—one for single couponing and the other
for double couponing. We estimated the parameters of equa-
Empirical illustration tion 1, excluding features and displays using the NLS method
for each of the three stores. The data provides an excellent
A national retailer in the suburb of a large Southwestern fit to the proposed model as indicated by the range of ad-
city provided data for yet another product category that is justed R2 , .72 to .81 (R2 —as computed in the original vari-
different from the two product categories analyzed earlier. able space—for competing model forms vary from 0.52 to
This retailer has the policy of doubling the face values of 0.59). The results are reported in Table 5 for the two brands
coupons up to 50 cents. Store-level data capturing details on in each of the three stores.
weekly sales and store causal variables (e.g., feature and dis-
play) for the three stores in a suburb were available for a Single couponing
period of one hundred and fourteen weeks. The retailer also For this strategy, we estimate Eq. (1) excluding features
provided data on coupons that included all the details men- and displays using NLS for each of the three stores. The val-
tioned earlier. This product category was dominated by two ues for γ t and δt are assumed to be 1. Again, the data provides
major brands, which account for over 80 percent of the mar- a nice fit as indicated by the range of adjusted R2 —.69 to
ket share in the analysis time period. An interesting aspect of .81 (R2 —in the original variable space for competing model
couponing in this product category is that while the face value forms vary from 0.54 to 0.62). The estimation results are also
of coupons remained in the same range, the retailer shifted reported in Table 5 for each of the three stores.
to doubling the face value of coupons at some point in time To illustrate the power of double couponing, we discuss
during the data collection period. Thus, for the same product the estimation results for Brand M in these chain stores. The
category, data were available for a period of 59 weeks on magnitude of the coefficients indicates that a double coupon-
the actual face value of the coupon and other information. ing strategy has more effect in sales. Parameter estimates
For the subsequent 55 weeks, the data reflects the scenario for the other brand (Brand T) can be interpreted similarly.
of double couponing since the retailer started to use a double The self-coupon and cross-coupon elasticities were com-
couponing strategy. Because the maximum face value of the puted with the values shown in Table 5. For example, in
coupons for the brands of these two products did not exceed store 1, for Brand M, the self-coupon elasticities decrease
50 cents in those 55 weeks, the situation always involved from 0.54 to 0.02 from week 1 to week 8 for a coupon face
double couponing. The coupon face values ranged from 30 value of 30 cents. Similarly, the cross-coupon elasticities de-
cents to 50 cents during the analysis time period across both crease from −0.13 to −0.004 as we move from week 1 to
brands. Each brand dropped a coupon on four occasions and week 8. An interesting observation is that the elasticities are
each time the coupons were valid for a period of eight weeks. of a higher magnitude (more than double) when the coupon
The popular size for this product category was 64 fl oz and face values are doubled compared to the elasticities when the
the price ranged from $2.50 to $3.00 between the two brands. coupon face values are not doubled. This implies that sales
All the coupons dropped for the product category were free- increase more than proportionately for doubling the coupon
standing inserts in Sunday newspapers and were specific to face value. This makes intuitive sense for the following rea-
the brand size used in the analysis. Display activities were son. The two brands used in this study belong to a higher

Table 5
Parameter estimates of the sales response model given by Eq. (8)a (double and single couponing)
Store Brand β1 β2 β3 β4 Adjusted R2
1 M 960 (865)b 0.61 (0.56) 520 (510) 0.53 (0.51) .72 (0.69)
T 1120 (733) 0.63 (0.59) 708 (690) 0.53 (0.51) .74 (0.71)
2 M 1201 (1090) 0.70 (0.65) 609 (601) 0.59 (0.57) .73 (0.74)
T 1040 (990) 0.62 (0.59) 660 (646) 0.52 (0.50) .80 (0.81)
3 M 840 (810) 0.60 (0.58) 390 (377) 0.46 (0.44) .81 (0.76)
T 800 (770) 0.66 (0.65) 580 (569) 0.52 (0.50) .75 (0.77)
a All the coefficients are significant at .05 level unless otherwise indicated.
b The values in parenthesis are for single couponing strategy. All other values are for double couponing strategy.
V. Kumar, S. Swaminathan / Journal of Retailing 81 (1, 2005) 1–13 11

price tier in that product category. There is empirical evidence (3) The proposed method provides a hypothetical compar-
that price reductions in higher price/higher quality brands ison of how much shelf-price reduction is required to
have more influence on the sales of lower price/lower quality achieve the same effect (in sales) that would have oc-
brands than vice versa (Kumar & Leone 1988; Sethuraman curred with a coupon drop. This equivalency is demon-
& Mittelstaedt 1992). Thus, when a higher priced brand dou- strated not only for one time period but over the life of the
bles the coupon value, it becomes attractive to the buyers of coupon. If managers decide to go through with the shelf-
lower price brands resulting in a sales increase for the higher price reduction strategy, then different stores in different
price brand. This results in higher coupon elasticity. How- zones/areas can set their own prices. However, which
ever, whether this sales increase translates to profit is yet to be strategy may contribute to more profits depends on the
established. cost of the promotion program.
(4) The decay of elasticity for the coupon drop can help man-
agers make better decisions. Manufacturers can guide re-
Managerial implications tailers as to how much stock to hold during each week
of the coupon drop period. This can prevent stock-outs
Our study makes several contributions to understanding of the relevant items. In other words, a retailer can an-
the impact of coupon promotions on a brand’s total sales. ticipate the expected increase in sales for a coupon drop
Traditionally, researchers investigating the impact of coupon of a particular face value and stock the items to meet
promotions have studied the effects of coupon characteristics the demand. Also, the shelf space can be better man-
on redemption rates, market share, and incremental sales. To aged to yield higher profits (depending on the profit mar-
the best of our knowledge, this study is one of the first that gins of various product categories) at the store level. Fur-
explicitly address the issue of measuring coupon face-value ther, customer satisfaction can be preserved by not facing
elasticity. We used currently available secondary data ob- stock-out conditions. The impact of stock-out conditions
tained from A.C. Nielsen and two large retail chains in the on brand choice process has been illustrated by Kumar,
U.S. to estimate our proposed model. Three different product Karande, and Reinartz (1998). If a stock-out condition
categories—juices, household cleaners and beverages—were occurs, consumers tend to choose the brand that has the
used to study the effects of couponing. Several implica- lowest external reference price. This implies that con-
tions can be derived from the framework analyzed in this sumers may switch from the concerned brand to compet-
study: ing brands resulting in a loss of sales for the concerned
brand. Therefore, it is wise on the managers’ part to eval-
(1) The effect of coupon drop with different face values on uate the rate of decay of coupon elasticity over time to
sales is captured. Given that different stores can have better manage the inventory of items across stores, chains
different impacts (as illustrated in our data set as well and markets.
as in the simulation), this allows manufacturers to eval- (5) Our framework allows manufacturers to choose various
uate the effect of coupons at the store level as well as at combinations of coupon face values and coupon expira-
the chain/market level. The proposed framework helps tion dates to achieve a desired level of self-coupon elas-
managers to be aware of such differences across stores, ticity (see Fig. 1). In other words, the total sales increase
chains, and markets. As stated earlier, many chains realized in the first week by offering a $1.00 coupon is
are dividing their stores into different price zones for equivalent to the total sales increase realized in the first 6
implementing micro-marketing strategies (Hoch, Kim, weeks of offering a 40-cent coupon, and is also equivalent
Montgomery, & Rossi 1995). In combination with to the total sales increase realized in the first 2 weeks of
coupon drops, appropriate adjustments to the shelf-price offering a 75-cent coupon (see Table 4). Thus, whichever
can be made if necessary (for example, using the frame- combination of face value and expiration date results in a
work presented by Hoch et al. 1995) to realize maximum lower liability for the manufacturers will be the preferred
revenues/profits for manufacturers as well as for retailers. strategy.
(2) Our framework enables measurement of the effects of (6) The effect of the face values of coupons of one brand
coupon drops over time. Thus, the decaying effect of on a competing brand’s sales can be studied. The cross-
coupon elasticity is captured. This, then, allows manu- coupon elasticity illustrates that for a low face value of
facturers to choose the duration of the coupon drop. If the coupons, the switch from one brand to another is min-
decaying effect of a coupon drop shows that the effect of imal. Of course, this also depends on the product cate-
coupon really drops after say 4 weeks, then the duration gory. However, one can use the proposed model to study
can be chosen as 4 weeks for subsequent coupon drops such effects. In any case, brand managers need not be
to limit the liability. The duration of the coupon drop can concerned with coupon drops for competing brands if
be chosen in such a manner that a marginal increase in the cross-couponing elasticity is low. Given the equiva-
sales is not sufficient to offset any additional costs. This lence of temporary price reduction and a certain value of
is because manufacturers do not have to assume liability coupon face value in a given week, brand managers can
beyond a certain period. also retaliate for coupon drops for competing brands by
12 V. Kumar, S. Swaminathan / Journal of Retailing 81 (1, 2005) 1–13

temporarily reducing the price (by knowing how much (e.g., design, printing, and coupon distribution costs) or the
to reduce the shelf-price for a given coupon face value, variable coupon handling charges. The long term effects of
a result obtained in this study) of their own brands. a coupon drop can be studied along the lines of how past
(7) The empirical results from the double couponing analy- coupon usage behavior can affect future use (Kopalle, Mela,
sis illustrates that the percentage increase in sales is much & Marsh 1999). While the impact of a coupon drop on the
higher than the percentage increase in the coupon face last week of its duration is negligible in our study, future
value when the coupon face value is doubled thereby ben- research can attempt to capture the surge in coupon redemp-
efiting the retailer. If the resulting sales increase has profit tions during the last week of a coupon drop in modeling sales
implications, then a double couponing strategy may be and elasticity. Our research can be extended to investigate
a viable one. Since coupons are usually redeemed for the short-term profitability of a brand both when a coupon is
the purchase of single units, the question of stockpiling dropped and when the shelf-price is reduced, thus enabling
does not arise. Thus, manufacturers do not have to be managers to choose either of these alternatives on the ba-
concerned about the loss of purchases in future time pe- sis of brand profitability. It may be worthwhile to study the
riods. Therefore, the psychological underpinning behind interaction between price and coupon face value to better
a double couponing is worth exploring further. understand the relationship between the two on brand sales
and profitability. The analysis of double couponing strategy
shows promise for double couponing; however, the impact
Limitations and future research directions on profits is yet to be evaluated. Many of the limitations dis-
cussed here can be addressed with richer data, designed and
We did not consider the long-term effect of choosing the collected exclusively for the proposed model estimation.
couponed brand on subsequent purchases. That omission is
not a major limitation, however, as no consensus currently
exists among scholars as to the direction of such a change Acknowledgments
in preference. Moreover, coupon promotions on almost all
brands are so frequent that any long-range preference changes The authors thank the editors, the associate editor and
may offset one another (McAlister 1986). the reviewers for their suggestions on the earlier versions of
Several interesting extensions of our research are possi- the manuscript. The authors also thank Ed Blair, Jeff Inman,
ble, and these would give us a better understanding of the Robert Leone, Trichy Krishnan, George Morris, Frank Mul-
impact of promotions on brand sales and profitability. Be- hern, Scott Neslin, and John Totten for their comments; A.C.
cause display and featuring activities were negligible in the Nielsen and a large retailer in the Southwestern United States
product market investigated, we did not study the interac- for providing the data. This study was supported in part by a
tion of coupons with these store causal variables. Richer data grant from the Promotion Management Association of North
with variation in display and featuring activities would facil- America. Special thanks are owed to Renu for copyediting
itate the study of the interaction of coupon face value with the manuscript.
other store causal variables. Our generalized coupon-sales
response model captures the impact of coupon face value on
brand sales. However, the profitability of the couponing oper- References
ation depends not only on the incremental sales of the brand,
Bagozzi, R. P., Baumgartner, H., & Yi, Youjae. (1991). Coupon usage
but also on the number of coupons redeemed. The proposed and theory of reasoned action. Advances in Consumer Research, 18,
sales response model could be coupled with a coupon re- 24–27.
demption model (similar to that of Reibstein & Traver 1982) Bass, Frank M., & Wittink, Dick R. (1975, November). Pooling issues and
or the percentage of purchases that are coupon purchases (as methods in regression analysis with examples in marketing research.
used by Neslin 1990) to investigate the profitability of the Journal of Marketing Research, 12, 414–425.
Bawa, Kapil, & Shoemaker, Robert W. (1987, October). The coupon
couponing operation. prone consumer: Some findings based on purchase behavior across
The proposed model can be used to determine the price product classes. Journal of Marketing, 51, 99–110.
reduction that will result in the same level of brand sales as Bawa, Kapil, & Shoemaker, Robert W. (1987, November). The effects of
a coupon drop. However, consumers who will buy the fo- a direct mail coupon on brand choice behavior. Journal of Marketing
cal brand when a coupon is dropped could have a different Research, 24, 370–376.
Bawa, Kapil, & Shoemaker, Robert W. (1989, July). Analyzing incremen-
profile from consumers who will buy the focal brand when tal sales from a direct mail coupon promotion. Journal of Marketing,
the shelf-price is reduced. In the case of coupon drop, the 53, 66–78.
consumers might be people with high coupon proneness; in Bawa, Kapil, Srinivasan, Srini S., & Srivastava, Rajendra K. (1997,
the case of price reductions, they may be people who are November). Coupon attractiveness and coupon proneness: A frame-
price sensitive. Also, a coupon drop and a shelf-price re- work for modeling coupon redemption. Journal of Marketing Re-
search, 34, 517–525.
duction could result in different levels of brand profitabil- Chapman, Randall G. (1986, Spring). Assessing the profitability of retailer
ity even though the total sales are the same. A price reduc- couponing with a low-cost field experiment. Journal of Retailing, 62,
tion does not incur the fixed costs of a couponing operation 19–39.
V. Kumar, S. Swaminathan / Journal of Retailing 81 (1, 2005) 1–13 13

Della Bitta, Albert J., Monroe, Kent B., & McGinnis, John M. (1981, gression analysis. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 67(3),
November). Consumer perceptions of comparative price advertise- 647–653.
ments. Journal of Marketing Research, 18, 416–427. Leone, Robert P., & Srinivasan, S. (1996). Coupon face value: Its impact
Dhar, Sanjay K., Morrison, Donald G., & Raju, Jagmohan. (1996). The on coupon redemptions, brand sales and brand profitability. Journal
effect of package coupons on brand choice: An epilogue of profits. of Retailing, 72, 273–289.
Marketing Science, 15(2), 192–203. Mayhew, Glenn E., & Winer, Russell S. (1992, June). An empirical analy-
Dhar, Sanjay K., & Raju, Jagmohan S. (1998, November). The effects sis of internal and external reference prices using scanner data. Journal
of cross-ruff coupons on sales and profits. Management Science, 44, of Consumer Research, 19, 62–70.
1501–1516. McAlister, Leigh (1986). A research report prepared for the marketing
Dodson, Joe A., Tybout, Alice M., & Sternthal, Brian. (1978, February). science institute and other sponsors.
Impact of deals and deal retraction on brand switching. Journal of Montgomery, David B. (1971, February). Consumer characteristics as-
Marketing Research, 15, 72–81. sociated with dealing: An empirical example. Journal of Marketing
Hoch, Stephen J., Kim, Byung-Do, Montgomery, Alan L., & Rossi, Pe- Research, 8, 118–120.
ter E. (1995, February). Determinants of store-level price elasticity. Mulhern, Francis J., & Leone, Robert P. (1991, October). Implicit price
Journal of Marketing Research, 32, 17–29. bundling of retail products: A multiproduct approach to maximizing
Inman, Jeffrey J., & McAlister, Leigh. (1994, August). Do coupon expira- store profitability. Journal of Marketing, 55, 63–76.
tion dates affect consumer behavior? Journal of Marketing Research, Narasimhan, Chakaravarthi. (1984, Spring). A price discrimination theory
31, 423–428. of coupons. Marketing Science, 3, 128–147.
Irons, Karl W., Little, John D. C., & Klein, Robert L. (1983). Determi- Neslin, Scott A. (1990, Spring). A market response model for coupon
nants of coupon effectiveness. In Fred Zufryden (Ed.), Proceedings of promotions. Marketing Science, 9, 125–145.
the 1983 ORSA/TIMS Marketing Science Conference (pp. 157–164). Neslin, Scott A., Henderson, Caroline, & Quelch, John. (1985, Spring).
Jolson, Marvin A., Wiener, Joshua L., & Rosecky, Richard B. (1987, Consumer promotions and the acceleration of product purchases. Mar-
February/March). Correlates of rebate proneness. Journal of Advertis- keting Science, 4, 147–165.
ing Research, 24, 33–43. Neslin, Scott A., & Shoemaker, Robert W. (1983, Fall). A model for
Kalwani, Manohar U., & Yim, Chi Kin. (1992, February). Consumer evaluating the profitability of coupon promotions. Marketing Science,
price and promotion expectations. Journal of Marketing Research, 2, 361–380.
29, 90–100. NCH NuWorld Marketing. (2000). Coupon statistics. News Release.
Karande, Kiran, & Kumar, V. (1995). The effect of brand characteristics Raghubir, Priya. (1998, August). Coupon value: A signal for price? Jour-
and retailer policies on response to retail price promotions: Implica- nal of Marketing Research, 35, 316–324.
tions for retailers. Journal of Retailing, 71(3), 249–278. Raju, Jagmohan, Dhar, Sanjay K., & Morrison, Donald G. (1994, Spring).
Klein, R. L. (1981). Using supermarket scanner panels to measure the The effect of package coupons on brand choice. Marketing Science,
effectiveness of coupon promotions. In J. W. Keon (Ed.), Mar- 13(2), 145–164.
keting measurement and analysis 1981. Proceedings Of The Third Reibstein, David J., & Traver, Phillis A. (1982, Fall). Factors affecting
ORSA/TIMS Special Interest Conference on Market Measurement and coupon redemption rates. Journal of Marketing, 46, 102–113.
Analysis (pp. 118–124). Providence: The Institute of Management Sethuraman, Raj, & Mittelstaedt, John. (1992). Coupons and private la-
Science. bels: A cross-category analysis of grocery products. Psychology and
Kopalle, Praveen K., Mela, Carl F., & Marsh, Lawrence. (1999). The dy- Marketing, 9(6), 487–500.
namic effect of discounting on sales: Empirical analysis and normative Shimp, Terence A., & Kavas, Alican. (1984, December). The theory of
pricing implications. Marketing Science, 18(3), 317–332. reasoned action applied to coupon usage. Journal of Consumer Re-
Krishna, Aradhna, & Zhang, Z. John. (1999). Short- or long-duration search, 11, 795–809.
coupons: The effect of the expiration date on the profitability of Shoemaker, Robert W., & Tibrewala, Vikas. (1985, October/November).
coupon promotions. Management Science, 45(8), 1041–1056. Relating coupon redemption rates to past purchasing of the brand.
Kumar, V., Karande, K., & Reinartz, W. (1998). The impact of inter- Journal of Advertising Research, 25, 40–47.
nal and external reference prices on brand choice: The moderat- Teel, Jesse E., Williams, Robert H., & Bearden, William O. (1980). Cor-
ing role of contextual variables. Journal of Retailing, 74(3), 401– relates of consumer susceptibility to coupons in new grocery product
426. introductions. Journal of Advertising, 9(3), 31–46.
Kumar, V., & Leone, Robert P. (1988, May). Measuring the effect of Tellis, Gerard J. (1988, November). The price elasticity of selective de-
retail store promotions on brand and store substitution. Journal of mand: A meta analysis of econometric models of sales. Journal of
Marketing Research, 25, 178–185. Marketing Research, 25, 331–341.
Kumar, V., & Pereira, Arun. (1995, Summer). Explaining the short term Ward, Richard W., & Davis, James E. (1978, August). A pooled cross-
sales response to retail price promotions. Journal of Academy of Mar- section time series model of coupon promotions. American Journal
keting Science, 23, 155–169. of Agricultural Economics, 60, 393–401.
Lee, Jonq-Ying, & Brown, Mark G. (1985, August). Coupon redemption Ward, Richard W., & Davis, James E. (1978, August). Coupon redemp-
and the demand for frozen concentrated orange juice: A switching re- tions. Journal of Advertising Research, 18, 51–58.

You might also like