You are on page 1of 21

Urban Studies, Vol. 37, No.

3, 513–532, 2000

Industrial Clusters: Complexes, Agglomeration


and/or Social Networks?

Ian R. Gordon and Philip McCann


[Paper received in Ž nal form, August 1999]

Summary. The concept of industrial clusters has attracted much attention during the past
decade, both as descriptive of an increasingly important phenomenon and as a basis for effective
public intervention in the economies of lagging city-regions. However, there is much ambiguity
in the way in which this concept is used, presenting an obstacle both to empirical testing and to
realistic assessments of policy relevance. In this paper, we distinguish three ideal-typical models
of processes which may underlie spatial concentrations of related activities, with very different
implications both in terms of relevant evidence and the scope for promotional policies. Survey
data for the London conurbation are used to explore the relation between concentration and
different forms of linkage, with results which point to the dominance of pure agglomeration
effects in this context at least.

1. Introduction
Over the past decade, there has been a re- to scale provides a rationale for industrial
surgence of interest in the nature of localised clustering, as Ž rms and labour congregate in
growth in the spatial economy. Firms and order to take account of increased factor
industrial activity in general tend to be spa- rewards. Yet, these increased factor rewards
tially concentrated in certain locations. Ob- are only exhibited over a limited spatial do-
servation suggests, however, that different main at the locations where such congregat-
groups and different mixes of activities tend ing takes place. The reason for this is that the
to be clustered together in different places. transactions costs of overcoming distance,
The result is that spatial heterogeneity is to such as transport costs and spatial communi-
some extent associated with industrial cations costs, imply that there must be a
specialisation, and this observed coincidence Ž nite spatial limit over which such net
between spatial industrial clustering and re- beneŽ ts can accrue. The resulting balance
gional specialisation is fundamental to the between localised increasing returns to scale
widespread adoption of the principle of in- and spatial distance transactions costs can
creasing returns to scale in urban and re- provide an explanation of the development of
gional economic analysis (Krugman, 1991a). the types of hierarchical spatial industrial
The existence of localised increasing returns patterns typically observed (Krugman, 1993,
Ian Gordon is in the Department of Geography, University of Reading, Whiteknights, PO Box 227, Reading, RG6 6AB, UK. Fax: 0118
975 5865. Email: I.R.Gordon@rdg.ac.uk . Philip McCann is in the Centre for Spatial and Real Estate Economics, Department of
Economics, Faculty of Urban and Regional Studies, University of Reading, PO Box 219, Reading, RG6 6AW, UK. Fax: 0118 931
6533. Email: P.McCann@rdg.ac.uk . The authors are grateful for comments from participant s in the location theory session at the
RSAI York conference, together with Helen Lawton Smith and Gareth Potts. Work on the empirical section of the paper was supported
by ESRC under grant L130251027 (London: competitiveness , cohesion and the policy environment) .

0042-098 0 Print/1360-063X On-line/00/030513-2 0 Ó 2000 The Editors of Urban Studies


514 IAN R. GORDON AND PHILIP MCCANN

1995; Fujita and Krugman, 1995; Fujita and nian, 1994) and the clothing industry in
Mori, 1997). northern Italy (Piore and Sabel, 1984; Scott,
The renewed interest in localised spatial 1988). For many analysts within these Ž elds,
growth has come from a variety of disci- much of the interest in modern forms of
plines. Within neo-classical economics, the spatial clustering is motivated by a re-awak-
interest in explicitly geographical issues has ening to the possibilities for a renewed
arisen primarily from applications of modern public-policy role in local economic develop-
trade theory (Helpman and Krugman, 1985) ment issues (Castells and Hall, 1994). Within
to problems of spatial allocation (Krugman, the sociological literature, the recent interest
1991b; Venables, 1995), and this research in spatial clustering is underpinned by an
agenda has largely superceded the traditional interest in the relationship between an indi-
neo-classical model of interregional trade vidual’s environment and the development of
(Borts and Stein, 1964) or the traditional ‘embedded’ social networks of communi-
Ricardian model of international trade (Pom- cation and in uence (Granovetter, 1985,
fret, 1991). Moreover, the development of 1991, 1992) which may transcend either Ž rm
trading blocs, and in particular those within or industry boundaries. Many of these socio-
common currency regimes, has accelerated logical and geographical themes have subse-
this interest (Bliss and de Macedo, 1990). quently become somewhat entwined under
The focus of this research agenda is on the the rather vague umbrella notion of ‘innova-
role played by increasing returns to scale and tive milieux’ (Aydalot, 1986; Aydalot and
market structure in the determination of spa- Keeble, 1988; Camagni, 1995), which at-
tial investment patterns, and follows the tempts to relate questions of spatial cluster-
more general renewal of interest in the role ing to the process of innovation.
played by increasing returns to scale within This widespread appearance of new ana-
the economy (Romer, 1986, 1987; Arthur, lytical work on spatial-growth issues needs
1994). Within the business and management some explanation, given the body of earlier
literature, the issue of location is seen as part work on these questions by authors such as
of the broader question of constructing the Marshall, Hoover, Isard, Perroux, Chinitz
optimal relationship between the modern and Mills, many of whose original insights
Ž rm and its customers and suppliers (Piore still appear to be valid. In the case of main-
and Sabel, 1984; Porter, 1990). The recent stream neo-classical economists, the Krug-
focus on spatial issues essentially involves a man (1995) explanation in terms of the lack
rethinking of the relationship between the (until recently) of appropriate formal meth-
nature of the Ž rm and that of transactions ods with which to analyse the implications of
costs (Williamson and Winter, 1993; Pitelis, increasing returns presumably has some val-
1993), over space. The impetus for this re- idity, but this would hardly apply to the
thinking had come originally from a growing authors cited immediately above. A second
awareness of the changes in the spatial or- more general explanation is that substantial
ganisation of modern manufacturing and dis- changes in the economic environment over
tribution activities (Shonberger, 1982; Best, the past 25 years or so (involving internation-
1990; Nishiguchi, 1994) and the communi- alisation, greater instability in product mar-
cation possibilities provided to the service kets and more intense competition with a
sector in particular, by the advent of new greater emphasis on quality/variety, at least
information technologies. for First World producers) have increased the
Within the geography and spatial-planning importance of  exibility, encouraging greater
literature, the interest in so-called new indus- reliance on external than internal economies
trial districts arose primarily from observa- of scale. The sharpness and pervasiveness of
tions of the spatial organisation of production such a break can be much exaggerated, but
in several key industries such as the electron- there is little doubt that changes of this kind
ics industry in California (Scott, 1993; Saxe- have been occurring (however unevenly) and
INDUSTRIAL CLUSTERS 515

that these could well increase the salience of there may actually be little evidence and
spatial clustering. other elements to which the evidence more
A third signiŽ cant factor seems to be a directly relates. To encourage greater clarity
sense of the inadequacy of conventional ap- and more critical investigation, we offer a
proaches to spatial policy in the face of the framework in which a range of ideas about
macroeconomic and structural developments the signiŽ cance of spatial clustering—from
of the 1980/90s, requiring innovative strate- Isard’s historic work on industrial complex
gies to stimulate endogenous growth in re- analysis, and the Marshall–Hoover–Mills ap-
dundant or marginal areas. This has proaches to agglomeration, through to the
encouraged various attempts to draw general more recent Aydalot–GREMI ‘innovative
lessons from a rather limited number of suc- milieux’ and ‘new industrial spaces’ litera-
cess stories about possible windows of op- ture—are seen as relating to a number of
portunity and creative ways of exploiting distinct types of industrial clustering in the
these. Important though this effort is, the spatial economy. In contrast to Markusen’s
policy context has not always encouraged the (1996) essentially inductive approach to
analytical clarity which is required both for classiŽ cation of the varied forms of industrial
empirical testing of these propositions, and district, the approach here is essentially de-
for assessing the broad scale of beneŽ ts ductive, and focuses on processes rather than
which the various kinds of policy initiative structures. More or less pure examples of
might be expected to yield in different con- each of these types may be found in the real
texts. In particular, there has been a tendency world, though elements of several may occur
to use terms such as ‘agglomeration’, ‘clus- together in particular clusters, while some
ters’, ‘new industrial areas’, ‘embeddedness’, types may be more common or signiŽ cant
‘milieux’ and ‘complex’ more or less inter- than others. SpeciŽ cally, we suggest that
changeably, with little concern for questions there are three basic forms of clustering. Two
of operationalisation, which are actually far of these have developed from the (neo-)
from straightforward, and should be different classical traditions of economics: the classic
for each. Part of the difŽ culty stems from the model of pure agglomeration, and the indus-
different theoretical contexts out of which trial-complex model. The third model, which
these ideas have emerged, but even two such is that of the network (or club), was devel-
commonly linked economic concepts as in- oped initially outside mainstream economics
dustrial clustering and increasing returns to and owes rather more to sociological per-
scale within the spatial economy are not spectives.
necessarily synonymous, and distinguishing DeŽ ning analytically which of these types
between situations where this is the case and is the dominant structural characteristic of a
where it is not, becomes a major analytical particular cluster (or set of clusters) is essen-
challenge. tial, in order to be able to discuss their
The argument of our paper starts from the performance empirically, and to determine
position that discussion of industrial cluster- what more general lessons may be drawn
ing has tended to con ate ideas arising from from that. In the next three sections of this
quite different perspectives, which are some- paper, we therefore discuss in turn the logic
times complementary and sometimes contra- of each of these ideal types, starting with the
dictory. Empirical observations of industrial two economic models, and drawing out con-
clustering can then be interpreted in quite trasts between these and the ‘network’
different ways, depending on the observer’s model. The issue of how these models can be
initial perspective, with little consciousness related to evidence on patterns of linkage
of alternative ways in which these might be among spatially clustered businesses will
understood. The effect can be to buttress a then be addressed in section 5 in the context
rather generalised notion of the beneŽ ts of of data from the London region. Finally, in
clustering, by con ating elements for which section 6, we will discuss the signiŽ cance of
516 IAN R. GORDON AND PHILIP MCCANN

the distinction between these models in rela- The key to Marshall’s approach is that what
tion to the policy attention currently given to links each source of economic beneŽ ts is the
the promotion of clusters and industrial fact that this accrues to Ž rms within the local
milieux as a strategy of regional develop- area primarily because of their geographical
ment and urban regeneration. proximity. None of the sources or results of
these beneŽ ts is internal to a particular Ž rm,
but each is external to all the Ž rms. The
2. The Model of Pure Agglomeration
actual sources of such beneŽ ts are quite dif-
Although early spatial analytical systems ferent, and the mechanisms by which these
(Weber, 1909/1929) acknowledged the exist- are transmitted also differ substantially. It is
ence of industrial clustering, the Ž rst attempt solely the issue of geographical proximity
at a formal classiŽ cation of the reasons for which is the common element determining
this phenomenon was made by Marshall their being grouped together under the gen-
(1925) whose analysis followed directly from eral heading of ‘external economies’ of in-
Adam Smith’s initial observation of labour dustrial clustering, more commonly referred
specialisation (Blaug, 1985). Marshall pro- to as ‘economies of agglomeration’.
posed three reasons why Ž rms would con- More modern descriptions of agglomer-
tinue to be localised within the same area. ation generally tend to follow the
These related to the development of a local classiŽ cation proposed by Hoover (1937,
pool of specialised labour, the increased local 1948), in which the sources of agglomeration
provision of non-traded input speciŽ c to an advantages are grouped together under three
industry, and the maximum  ow of infor- headings—namely, internal returns to scale,
mation and ideas (Krugman, 1991a). In terms localisation economies and urbanisation
of modern thinking, Marshall’s observation economies. The key feature of this method of
of the advantage of a specialised local labour classiŽ cation is that the external economies
pool can be described in terms of a labour- are deŽ ned according to the industrial sector
market system which maximises the job- in which they occur, with the scale of the
matching opportunities between the local economy being the only explicitly ob-
individual worker and the individual Ž rm servable variable. Internal returns to scale
(Simpson, 1992) and thus reduces the search may accrue to a single Ž rm due to pro-
costs for both parties. This implies that local duction-cost efŽ ciencies realised by serving a
Ž rms are able to hire workers and adjust their large market. There is nothing inherently
labour-employment levels in response to spatial in this concept other than that the
market conditions in a more efŽ cient manner existence of a single large Ž rm in space
than would be the case if the Ž rm was more implies a large local concentration of factor
locationally isolated. The extensive local employment. Whether due to Ž rm size or the
provision of non-traded inputs implies that number of local Ž rms, this high level of local
the area experiences economies of scale in factor employment may allow the develop-
the employment of particular capital infra- ment of external economies within the group
structure, while the maximised  ow of infor- of local Ž rms in the sector concerned, these
mation and ideas implies that product and being termed ‘localisation’ economies, and/
market knowledge can be shared more easily or the development of external economies
between agents in the same spatial grouping available to all local Ž rms irrespective of
than would be the case if the Ž rms were sector, known as ‘urbanisation’ economies.
dispersed. This classiŽ cation of the sectoral range of
Nowadays, these two advantages would be external economies cuts across Marshall’s
described, respectively, as the achievement more functional typology, with each of his
of service economies of scale or scope in the three potential sources of local external econ-
employment of either public or private capi- omies potentially obtaining within one or
tal, and the efŽ cient transfer of technology. more groups of sectors, or across the whole
INDUSTRIAL CLUSTERS 517

of a local economy. Since the spatial scales iety of mechanisms by which the external
over which these externalities are potentially economies are achieved (alongside various
available may also vary by sector, type and off-setting diseconomies) operate simul-
area, there can be a complex combination of taneously, often indirectly and cumulatively,
agglomeration economies operating within so that individual sources of the agglomer-
any city-region (Jacobs, 1960). And within ation process cannot be isolated or individu-
each of Marshall’s broad groupings, various ally identiŽ ed (Glaeser et al., 1992;
more speciŽ c sources of external economy Henderson et al., 1995). The only observable
may potentially operate at any of these manifestation of their existence may thus be
scales. the realised effects on productivity, growth
Within this Ž rst category, these include the and local factor prices. A continuing growth
beneŽ cial local labour-market effects of in local land and expected labour prices
efŽ cient search and job-match possibilities (Harris and Todaro, 1970) relative to other
(Simpson, 1992), the impacts of human capi- locations, which takes place simultaneously
tal-accumulation on labour skills (Arrow, with relatively higher localised capital re-
1962) and Ž rm productivity (Romer, 1987; turns, would be the only conŽ rmation of the
Scott, 1988), and the consequences of these existence of local agglomeration economies.
for local efŽ ciency-wage levels (Akerloff This pure model of agglomeration pre-
and Yellen, 1986; Blanch ower and Oswald, sumes no form of co-operation between ac-
1994). Within Marshall’s category of non- tors beyond what is in their individual
traded inputs are the various ways in which interests in an atomised and competitive en-
businesses can beneŽ t from the greater avail- vironment. ProŽ table local interaction is
ability and efŽ ciency of particular local ser- made possible through a combination of
vices, these representing local pecuniary chance, the law of large numbers (increasing
externalities in Scitovsky’s (1954) terms, or the probability of suitable partners being
from more favourable local availability of available) and the natural selection of busi-
capital Ž nance, including property-based as- nesses beneŽ ting from the opportunities on
set appreciation in the small-Ž rm sector offer. Relevant measures of scale will thus
(Barkham et al., 1996). The emergence of a re ect not simply the level of economic ac-
discriminating local clientèle and/or a spirit tivity (sectorally or overall), but also the
of rivalry among competing Ž rms, which number of independent economic units
Ž gure among the contributors to competitive (Chinitz, 1961). Since not all Ž rms will
advantage for successful regional clusters in beneŽ t from every type of externality, there
Porter’s (1990) analysis, also belong in this will be a variety of distribution and displace-
category. Finally, within Marshall’s third cat- ment effects between groups of agents with
egory of potential local external economies, different characteristics. However, the actual
are a variety of ways in which information relations between the Ž rms and between
 ows are mediated, including interŽ rm Ž rms and mobile factors are neither
labour migration (Angel, 1991), informal identiŽ able nor static. Firms and other actors
contacts between members of different Ž rms will change suppliers, customers, products
(Jaffe et al., 1993) and restructuring of local and inputs, simply in response to current
businesses. Together, these may all contrib- advantage and to their very speciŽ c require-
ute to an evolving localised environment of ments. The system is without any particular
learning (Nelson and Winter, 1982; Dosi et observable organisation or interagent loyalty,
al., 1987; Dosi, 1988), but may well differ and simply functions as an ecology of
substantially in their salience not only be- activities beneŽ ting from proximity, and de-
tween sectors, but also between Ž rms with veloping emergent forms of specialisation—
different national origins or particular de- possibly including distinct forms of
cision-making structures (Cantwell, 1991). economic culture.
The fundamental point here is that a var- Traditionally, agglomeration economies
518 IAN R. GORDON AND PHILIP MCCANN

are seen as being particularly important to need for regulation of external diseconomies,
businesses unable to exploit internal econom- the system is thus not generally prone to
ies of scale, whether because of constraints subversion through the attraction of free-
on growth or unwillingness to incur sunk riders.
costs in an uncertain market situation. How- The pure form of agglomeration depicted
ever, the availability of external economies here is evidently the model underlying mod-
may itself discourage certain forms of invest- ern urban economic theory (Fujita, 1989),
ment by businesses or individuals. but many of its key elements are also recog-
SpeciŽ cally, this is likely to apply where nisable features of the economies of metro-
investments imply a commitment to a par- politan areas and other cities producing
ticular employment or business relationship high-order services. Moreover, these are fea-
beyond what is proŽ table in the short term. tures which are widely supposed to be of
Where beneŽ ts are easily externalised, there enhanced importance to businesses seeking
will be limited incentive to develop human to maintain  exibility in an era of increased
capital, for example, beyond that required by uncertainty and change.
workers themselves to gain access to better
jobs, though more investment may be made
3. The Industrial-complex Model
in job- and labour-search activities. Space is
fundamental to the efŽ cient working of this The second type of model of spatial cluster-
system which relies on co-location increasing ing to emerge from the classical and neo-
the probability of trading linkages and em- classical economic tradition is that of the
ployment matches being realised. However, industrial complex. These industrial com-
none of these linkages and matches is perma- plexes are characterised by sets of
nent and each can be broken, substituted and identiŽ able and stable relations among Ž rms
re-formed an inŽ nite number of times in which are in part manifested in their spatial
response to any information or price shocks behaviour. The relations are conceived pri-
to the system. To the extent that random marily in terms of trading links, and it is
sectoral shocks in diverse activities are un- these patterns of sales and purchases which
correlated, this type of spatial clustering of are seen as principally governing their loca-
activity also acts as a hedge against uncer- tional behaviour. The earliest insights into
tainty for all contracting agents (Mills, the relationship between production and the
1980). From the perspective of both the ob- spatial organisation of industry discussed the
server and the actor, therefore, agglomeration question of the relationship between the opti-
fundamentally serves to increase the opportu- mal location of the Ž rm, the level of transport
nities for exchange and to reduce the inci- costs and the price of local production factors
dence of missing markets. (Weber, 1909/1929). The focus of the analy-
The absence of formal structures or strong sis here is on how the location of the Ž rm is
long-term relations between businesses in related to the spatial transactions costs faced
this model means that the local system (or by the Ž rm, which are perceived to be clearly
cluster) has essentially ‘open membership’, identiŽ able. In the 19th-century literature,
for any business establishment located in the these spatial transactions costs were assumed
area—i.e. for all those willing to pay a mar- to be solely transport costs, although in more
ket rent level which re ects the net value of modern thinking it is quite possible to adapt
spatial externalities (as well as other inherent these approaches to include also telecommu-
locational advantages). The assumption is, nications costs (Salomon and Schofer, 1990)
however, that those willing to incur this cost, and a broader deŽ nition of shipment costs
because of the value which they attach to such as logistics-costs (McCann, 1998).
potential interaction, are ipso facto likely to Since in this type of approach, the character-
be producers as well as consumers of these istics of the products being produced and
external economies. Though there may be consumed by each Ž rm are known, the only
INDUSTRIAL CLUSTERS 519

information requirements for analytical pur- each of the actors. All the Ž rms in the com-
poses concern the relationship between spa- plex will have made substantial capital in-
tial transactions costs and geographical vestments in order to set up the appropriate
distance, as well as the nature of the pro- trading links, and these will be in the form of
duction function characteristics of the Ž rms Ž xed-capital expenditure and possibly also
in question, deŽ ned in terms of their input– research-capital expenditure. However, the
output requirements. system in principle is not reducible to the
All of the subsequent development of neo- smallest units possible, and no subset of ac-
classical location theory has been entirely tors can recreate the system, because they do
within this general framework (Isard, 1951; not have all of the necessary information
Moses, 1958; Miller and Jensen, 1978). The about technology, labour specialisation,
reason for this is that these models formed product innovation and markets. The com-
the spatial counterpart to the aspatial input– plex is in effect a ‘closed club’, and in the
output models of regional structures (Isard same way that the individual organisation
and Kuenne, 1953), and the purpose of these monopolises the ability to innovate in certain
models was to provide insights into how the products or processes, the organisation of the
expenditure patterns and the spatial behav- complex monopolises the ability of the Ž rm
iour of Ž rms are interrelated. Within this to realise the beneŽ ts of those innovations.
approach, the only reason why we might The monopoly proŽ ts generated by this co-
observe spatial industrial clustering is that location of the Ž rms will be more or less
the individual Ž rms, in aiming to minimise symmetrically distributed between all agents
their observable spatial transactions costs, within the complex, although the existence of
have implicitly or explicitly determined that the complex will not in any way discourage
this is best achieved by locating close to individual Ž rms from making investments in
other Ž rms within the particular inout–output research or human capital in order to boost
production and consumption hierarchy of their own proŽ ts. There should be no prob-
which they are part (Isard and Vietorisz, lem of search costs and the internal mon-
1955; McCann, 1995). This outcome may opoly proŽ ts due to existence of the complex
emerge incrementally, but where there are should not affect local land values, given that
strategic interactions among the locational there is no incentive for the Ž rms in the
decisions of a few Ž rms, and/or where vi- complex to encourage the immigration of
ability depends on co-location, concerted other Ž rms, which would generate compe-
planning of these decisions by the Ž rms con- tition and in ation in the local real-estate
cerned (and long-term production/contracting markets. Oil reŽ ning, chemicals and pharma-
arrangements) is necessary, with or without ceuticals complexes are typically of this type,
state encouragement. but there are also important examples in
This type of model is essentially static and automotive engineering, including the
predictable in nature, and is primarily con- Japanese JIT complexes, notably Toyota
cerned with cost-saving in relation to pro- City.
duction links. The notion of space in these
models is not explicitly urban or related to
4. The Social-network Model
the potential for new forms of exchange, but
is rather concerned with the minimisation of The social-network model developed within
distance costs in the formation of crucial, the sociological literature (Granovetter,
pre-planned (and hence identiŽ able) link- 1985, 1991, 1992) was primarily a critique of
ages. In this model of the industrial complex, the neo-classical approach to the existence
the principal actors are also identiŽ able, and development of institutions (Williamson,
since this is an essentially privately or- 1975, 1985). The ‘neo-institutionalist ’ school
ganised system which is constructed in order had perceived the creation of hierarchical
to generate internal monopoly proŽ ts for organisations and institutions to be a rational
520 IAN R. GORDON AND PHILIP MCCANN

response to the transactions-costs problems private relationships in situations where nei-


caused by bounded rationality and oppor- ther price signals nor monitoring are
tunism in a pure market-contracting economy sufŽ cient to ensure the implementation of a
(Pitelis, 1993). From this perspective, the particular project or activity. The strength of
development of organisations which allow these relationships is described as the level of
transactions to be internalised and co- ‘embeddedness’ of the social network. In
ordinated, means that trust (i.e. non- fact, all economic relations (even the ‘pure’
opportunism) becomes institutionalised market relations of the agglomeration model)
within the economic system. For sociolo- are socially embedded in the sense that these
gists, however, the implicit and explicit con- depend upon norms, institutions and sets of
tracts between agents within the individual assumptions shared among a group of actors
organisation primarily act as a substitute for and are not, in themselves, simply the out-
trust (Harrison, 1992), as evidenced by the come of economic decisions. But the size of
existence of internal incentive and penalty these groups, the strengths of the norms and
schemes. The sociological response to the the nature of the shared beliefs vary, leading
institutional school is the ‘social-network to unevennesses in the kinds of economic
model’, in which it is argued that there is relations which can be sustained, the inten-
more order to interŽ rm interactions and less sity of interaction and the willingness to take
order to intraŽ rm interactions than the econ- certain kinds of risk. Industrial clusters
omic models would imply (Granovetter, (whether spatial or not) differ from the ag-
1985). The reason for this is that social net- glomeration model in that there is a belief
works of certain strong interpersonal rela- that such clusters re ect not simply econ-
tionships can transcend Ž rm boundaries, with omic responses to the pattern of available
the result that many interŽ rm social interac- opportunities and complementarities, but also
tions may be stronger than their intraŽ rm an unusual level of embeddedness and social
counterparts. integration.
These interpersonal relationships depend There is nothing inherently spatial about
crucially on interpersonal trust, and the infor- the social-network model although it has ex-
mality of these relationships is viewed as plicit spatial applications. This is because
being a potential strength rather than a weak- social networks are a form of durable social
ness, as in the case of incomplete contracts. capital, created (and maintained) through a
Where there are relationships among individ- combination of social history and ongoing
uals who have decision-making power in a collective action. In this sense, their strength
group of different Ž rms or organisations, the is inherently problematic, depending upon a
existence of these trust relationships will prior accumulation of trust, circumstances
mean that the individual or collective actions which facilitate monitoring of others’ behav-
of the group differ from the behaviour asso- iour, a source of leadership and/or a sense of
ciated with either pure market-contracting or common interest, as well as the expectation
hierarchically organised relationships. There of signiŽ cant gains (Olsen, 1965). Many of
are three key features of this trust-based be- these pre-conditions are made possible by
haviour: the Ž rst is that Ž rms within the propinquity, particularly where economic re-
social network are willing to undertake risky lations have historically been more localised
co-operative and joint-ventures without fear and/or there is a distinctive local economic
of opportunism; the second is that Ž rms are base and cultural or personal links among
willing to reorganise their relationships with- key actors. Past links tend to persist since,
out fear of reprisals; and the third is that within this model, economic networks rep-
Ž rms are willing to act as a group in support resent a form of club which is neither com-
of common mutually beneŽ cial goals. These pletely open nor fully closed. Access to the
behavioural features imply that the social club will depend on past experience and
network is comprised of a set of transitive routine interaction as well as on investments
INDUSTRIAL CLUSTERS 521

of effort in developing personal relations and network model has been viewed as largely
trust. These factors may favour the develop- applicable to particular observations of spa-
ment and reproduction of location-speciŽ c tial industrial clustering, such as those for
networks, in which case co-location will be a Italy’s Emilia-Romagna (Scott, 1988) and
necessary but not sufŽ cient condition for ac- California’s Santa Clara County (Larsen and
cess. Under these circumstances, the beneŽ ts Rogers, 1984; Saxenian, 1994). Moreover,
of admission will be to some extent capi- this interest is driven by a belief that such a
talised in local rental values, though this model may provide, analytically and empiri-
form of rationing will not ensure the repro- cally, both a new and a renewed focus for the
duction of local networks, which are vulner- role of space in more general questions of
able to growth in the non-member element of contemporary economic growth. Empirically,
the local economy or to any incursion of the applicability of this model is open to
opportunists into membership. question in the case of both Silicon Valley
The incentives for investing heavily in (Suarez-Villa and Walrod, 1997; Arita and
purely local networks may be rather limited McCann, 1998) and the Third Italy (Amin,
in a world where competitiveness in inter- 1989; Trau, 1997, 1998). But, where the
national markets is thought to require a high development of the social network is associ-
degree of  exibility in business strategies as ated with the development of a place-speciŽ c
well as the cultivation of partners/suppliers industrial cluster, it is possible to view this
with very specialised capabilities. This con- model as exhibiting some of the characteris-
text seems to favour network development tics of each of the two previous models of
within agglomerations (whether specialised spatial industrial clustering. For example, the
or diversiŽ ed) offering a wide range of part- social network allows many of the external
ners, as well as the neo-Marshallian nodes beneŽ ts to be internalised within the group,
whose local members gain superior access to as in the case of the complex, although some
communication and potential links with other of the beneŽ ts may be capitalised into local
nodes within national and international net- rental values, as in the case of a pure ag-
works (Amin and Thrift, 1992). More gener- glomeration. Similarly, both the mutual-
ally, it reinforces the importance of ‘weak trading linkages and the investment linkages
ties’ (Granovetter, 1973), both direct and of the Ž rms within the social network will
indirect, and more pluralistic and open-ended exhibit more stability than those of the pure
network-building strategies in which actors agglomeration, but less than those of the
cultivate more extensive sets of links, partic- complex. However, it would be wrong to see
ularly with better-connected actors, which the social network as simply located some-
may prove to be more useful than commit- where between the other two models, since
ting to any single ‘club’ (local or not). Such the fundamental basis of the network rela-
a tendency is encouraged by spatial agglom- tionships is articulated neither through price
eration, with the notion of weak ties repre- signals nor organisational structures.
senting the micro-structure of such
agglomerations more plausibly than pure
5. Patterns of Linkage and Specialisation
atomism. Hence, we would expect that con-
in the London Region
centration of investment in particular part-
ners and the emergence of strong local The signiŽ cance of the distinction between
economic clubs (or communities) are more different types of clustering and the external-
likely to be pursued where agglomeration ities which these generate can be illustrated
economies are unavailable. with evidence on patterns of concentration
Much of the recent interest in embedded- and interaction in the London region. This
ness and in social capital as a productive region, comprising Greater London and the
asset, particularly within the Ž eld of spatial surrounding Outer Metropolitan Area
planning, arises from the fact that the social- (OMA) is the primary location for most of
522 IAN R. GORDON AND PHILIP MCCANN

the successful British sectoral clusters recog- The city’s pattern of specialisation has
nised by Porter (1990), notably in luxury several dimensions other than that of the
consumer goods and services, Ž nance, infor- standard industrial classiŽ cation. A canonical
mation, general business services and health- regression analysis of location against estab-
care goods. lishment characteristics (using data from the
TeCSEM-group surveys of ‘locationally sen-
sitive’ sectors in Birmingham, Cardiff, Read-
5.1 Activity Clusters in the Region
ing, Swindon and more/less central parts of
In terms of conventional sectors of employ- London) showed that inner-London locations
ment, relative to the country as a whole, the in particular were associated not only with a
region displays a particular specialisation in: distinctive set of industries, but also with
printing, publishing and reproduction of particular functions (administration and di-
recorded media; some types of wholesaling rect service provision), establishment types
(household goods and goods sold on a fee (single-plant enterprises, HQs and foreign-
basis); hotels and catering; air, rail and sea owned branches) and market areas (notably
transport and supporting services; money, European) (Gordon, 1996a).
Ž nance and insurance; IT/computing; pro-
fessional services; other business services;
5.2 Evidence on Business Linkages
cultural and entertainment services; central
administration and representative organisa- In London, as elsewhere, the views of busi-
tions. nesses about the key location factors for their
Concentrations of these metropolitan ac- type of activity tend to emphasise basic is-
tivities are most marked in central London sues of accessibility and the cost/availability
and the adjoining boroughs, though there are of relevant kinds of labour and premises,
secondary concentrations around Heathrow rather than more sophisticated aspects of the
airport (with extensions to Reading and business milieux, which tend to be signiŽ cant
Basingstoke along the M3 and M4 motor- only for small minorities of businesses. Thus,
ways) and a more local one around Gatwick in the TeCSEM surveys of London, Reading
airport, mainly concerned with airport- (in the OMA) and Swindon (in the more
related activities. In fact, most of London extensive Greater South East region), factors
(apart from the outer east) and much of the cited as important by over 25 per cent of
OMA (apart from Thames-side) exhibit some businesses involved 4 types of accessibility
specialisation in the sectors listed above, (to the motorway network, to good rail con-
though outside the central areas this is much nections, to major airports and to London), as
more likely to involve IT/computing, whole- well as proximity to customers, cost of prem-
saling and air transport than money/Ž nance, ises and the availability of white-collar
governance or cultural services. The outer labour, while proximity to suppliers, com-
areas also tend to have a wider manufactur- petitors and general/specialised business ser-
ing base, including some high-tech sectors vices were each cited by less than 10 per cent
such as electronics or pharmaceuticals in (Cheshire and Gordon, 1995). In the canoni-
which the region as a whole has only a weak cal analyses referred to above, the location
specialisation. Another type of knowledge- factors predictive of an (inner) London loca-
based industry displaying a more tion were the importance of ‘good access to
‘schizophrenic’ locational pattern is book London’ and good rail connections (both
publishing, with a concentration in inner and positive), traded off against good access to
west London, but also in a ring of towns 50 the national road network and availability of
miles or so from the centre (though still premises (both negative for London).
within easy reach by rail), where the aca- Clearly, the ‘London access’ variable is very
demic sector in particular is heavily repre- broad, encompassing the whole range of ag-
sented. glomeration economies offered by the metro-
INDUSTRIAL CLUSTERS 523

politan area, but it is still signiŽ cant that it is ceiving these as a signiŽ cant advantage,
this very general factor (rather than more while in business services and publishing,
speciŽ c questions about local customers, against our expectations, even fewer reported
suppliers or business services) which is pre- them to be relevant. Two other sets of rela-
dictive of location (Gordon, 1996a). tion with nearby Ž rms in related activities
More direct evidence on the signiŽ cance were seen by respondents in more ambiguous
of clustering and local linkages to London terms. The Ž rst of these involved competition
businesses (only) is available using unpub- in product markets, which tended to be re-
lished data from the 1996 London Employer garded more as a threat than as a route to
Survey (LES) (Feloy et al., 1997). At a enhanced performance (as expected in
descriptive level, responses to this survey Porter’s clusters), except in City and fringe
showed that just 25 per cent of private-sector Ž nancial services, and in printing and pub-
employment in London was in businesses lishing. The other is in terms of access to a
perceiving some advantage in proximity to wider pool of labour, or of competitors for
related activities, with one-quarter of these the Ž rms’ own labour force, where the bal-
also seeing disadvantages. Not surprisingly, ance of opinion was more even. The excep-
such Ž rms were more evident in the two tions were City Ž nancial services (again) and
central boroughs (the Cities of London and representative organisations, both giving
Westminster), where these represented 43 more weight to the beneŽ ts of concentration,
per cent of employment. By contrast, in and ‘other manufacturing’, where the empha-
much of outer London, businesses were as sis was on the potential for labour poaching
likely to see disadvantages (mostly from in- as a disadvantage. In terms of spatial varia-
creased competition) as advantages. tions within London, perceived opportunities
Several distinct types of advantage were for shared intelligence were the main reason
reported, but much the most important was for a more positive attitude to clustering in
shared intelligence, especially for Ž nancial the CBD; while of the disadvantages, both
services, professional activities (law, ac- competition and labour poaching were more
countancy and architecture) and for represen- frequently cited away from the centre.
tative organisations (Table 1). Within the A multivariate analysis of attitudes to clus-
Ž nance sector, this was especially signiŽ cant tering shows that Ž rms seeing advantages in
in the City and its fringe (Camden, South- terms of shared intelligence are distinguished
wark, Tower Hamlets, Hackney and Isling- principally by sector, largely because of the
ton, though not Westminster), where positive attitude of Ž nancial services. They
‘wholesale’ operations are more closely were also more likely to see advantages if
linked to money markets. On the other hand, their main market was abroad and, probably,
for retailing, hotels and catering, bringing in if they were foreign owned. Size made no
business was seen as the main advantage of signiŽ cant difference—although, in fact,
clustering, and this was signiŽ cant also for a large establishments were more positive
proportion of businesses in the culture and about clustering—and this was also the case
recreation sector. So too were increased op- for independent/branch status, innovation or
portunities for interaction or co-operation, growth perceptions/experience and competi-
which were also important to Ž nancial ser- tive strategy. Being located in the City or (to
vices in the City. These classic ‘milieux’ a lesser extent) in the extended central area
effects, which evidently operate among increased the chances of a positive attitude
smaller local clusters in other particular ar- (even when City Ž nance was treated as a
eas—such as Soho, Covent Garden or the distinct sector), but this might well be effect
White City—do, however, only seem rel- rather than cause, since for most services any
evant to a small minority of London Ž rms. beneŽ ts of clustering would be maximised
Even in Ž nancial services, only one-eighth of there. Those citing attraction of custom as an
London activity was in establishments per- advantage of clustering seem only to be dis-
524

Table 1. London business perceptions of advantages and disadvantages of proximity to related activities, by sector
(percentages)

Advantages from Net advantage from

Shared Interaction Customer Labour pool/


Sector intelligence potentiala attractionb Competitionc poachingd

Printing and publishing 7 3 — 2 1


Other manufacturing 5 3 — 2 2 2 4
Construction 1 1 — 2 10 —
Wholesale distribution 9 6 3 2 7 2
Retailing 4 5 12 2 6 —
Hotels and catering 2 6 37 2 1 —
Non-air transport 9 4 1 2 10 2 1
Air transport — — — — —
Financial services, City and fringe 37 10 3 8 6
Financial services, rest of London 18 12 — 2 9 —
Professions 26 4 — 2 4 1
IT and computing 3 3 — 2 3 1
Other business services 6 3 2 2 5 —
Education 6 — 3 2 9 —
Health 1 3 1 2 10 2 1
Representative organisations. 20 7 — — 4
IAN R. GORDON AND PHILIP MCCANN

Culture and entertainment 6 13 10 2 9 —


All private sector 11 5 4 2 4 1
a
includes perceived advantages from co-operation, sub-contracting, potential contacts and convenience for meetings.
b
includes bringing more business in and providing a greater choice for consumers.
c
represents the difference between numbers citing greater competition as an advantage and as a disadvantage of proximity.
d
numbers perceiving disadvantages in terms of poaching have been subtracted from those perceiving advantages from
proximity to a larger pool of labour.
Notes: All responses have been grossed up to re ect the actual distribution of employment across areas, industries and
establishment-size bands. The percentages relate estimated employment in each cell to totals for the sector.
Source: unpublished data from 1996 London Employers Survey (Feloy et al., 1997).
INDUSTRIAL CLUSTERS 525

tinguished by sector (as discussed above), market is local or in London as a whole, and
selling directly to the public and being in the actually a good deal more likely where the
central area. In the case of labour pools, only main supply area is further aŽ eld, notably in
being in the City is clearly signiŽ cant, continental Europe. In the case of joint-
though there also seems to be a positive ventures, in which roughly one-quarter of
association with size. Finally, in the case of Ž rms were involved, approximately 15 per
three interaction categories—potential for co- cent were with other local businesses and a
operation/sub-contracting, contacts and con- similar number with businesses elsewhere in
venience for meetings—the only signiŽ cant London. Local or London-oriented joint-
relation was with those businesses which saw ventures were rather more common where
their main competitive advantage as offering these locations were the main market areas or
a fast response (particularly against those supply areas, as they were among the small
emphasising quality or design factors). On number who saw clustering as advantageous
the negative side, disadvantages of clustering in aiding interaction. Such joint-ventures do
were most likely to be expressed by those seem to increase the probability of busi-
Ž rms: serving local markets; in the late nesses making signiŽ cant product/process in-
phases of the product cycle (i.e. those per- novations, but this applies more or less
ceiving a contraction in the market); empha- equally whatever the location of the other
sising customer care and fast response (rather parties.
than design/presentation/proximity to cus-
tomers); engaged in retailing or catering ac-
tivities; and/or located in outer east London.
5.3 The Relation between Spatial Concen-
Other evidence from this survey provides
tration and Forms of Linkage
some less direct indication of the potential
signiŽ cance of local linkages and clusters. Comparative data on the signiŽ cance of vari-
This includes information on the main mar- ous types of externality and interlinkage be-
ket areas and supply areas and whether the tween Ž rms in London and those in other UK
links of a business to its customers and sup- cities and regions are unfortunately not avail-
pliers have a signiŽ cant impact on its prod- able. However, the LES data may be used to
ucts or the way in which the business compare patterns of spatial dependence and
operates (which can be correlated, although advantage across sectors showing different
the impact of local links is not separately degrees of concentration in London. In order
distinguished) , together with the location of to do this, each of the 3800 establishments in
any Ž rms with which it has (or plans) joint- the sample was identiŽ ed with a Census of
ventures. In the Ž rst case, the scale of the Employment-based Greater London location
London economy, making it the main market quotient for the 3-digit industrial sector to
area and/or supply area for a sizeable min- which it was classiŽ ed, which was then used
ority of Ž rms, suggests that 10 per cent or so as the dependent variable in multivariate
of businesses may have signiŽ cant links with analyses with survey responses from these
local suppliers, and a similar number with establishments.
local customers. The likelihood of having These analyses included both variables re-
such links actually seems rather lower for lating to potential forms of interaction be-
those Ž rms doing business principally in tween clusters of businesses in London (or
London. In the case of customers, this is particular parts of the city) and a set of
partly explained by the fact that such Ž rms control variables for other characteristics po-
are more likely to sell directly to the public, tentially predictive of London’s specialis-
but multivariate analyses (controlling for ation in the activity concerned. Among these
such factors as the importance of product/ control variables, factors signiŽ cantly associ-
process innovation) suggest that signiŽ cant ated with a concentration of employment in
links are no more likely where the main London included:
526 IAN R. GORDON AND PHILIP MCCANN

(1) market areas (mainly outside the South London-based Ž rms (rather than either
East, particularly in Europe); the absence of such ventures or links
(2) supply areas (either mainly in London or with Ž rms elsewhere); and
else no signiŽ cant purchases from any- (4) using private consultants/professionals
where, together re ecting the absence of for external advice (rather than only
a constraint on London locations rather ofŽ cial bodies, or nobody).
than a positive location factor);
(3) market type (selling directly to Ž rms, Though clearly signiŽ cant in statistical
and not to government); terms, these potential linkage factors made
(4) establishment size (larger numbers of only a minor contribution to the explanation
employees); of the pattern of specialisation, for which the
(5) product innovation (rated as very import- control variables are substantively much
ant); more important.
(6) establishment function (not mainly en- For several reasons these data cannot pro-
gaged in production or logistics, but ad- vide clear measures of the comparative ‘Ž t’
ministration, sales or service provision); of the three ideal-typical models to the pat-
and tern of specialisation in the London econ-
(7) product cycle (market not strongly de- omy. One reason, relating to ‘social
clining). networks’, is that general survey data cannot
measure the degree of trust that businesses
Among the variables more directly linked
invest in other Ž rms, locally and elsewhere,
to interŽ rm relations in London, several
or the efforts expended in creating and vali-
proved to be entirely unrelated to the degree
dating that trust. However, the general im-
of concentration there (when other factors
pressions created by these data are consistent
were controlled for). These included:
with the Ž ndings of Llewelyn Davies’ more
(1) the existence of particular links with ei- qualitative interviews with Ž rms in new/
ther customers or suppliers that had a emerging sectors, contained in the socioeco-
signiŽ cant impact on the Ž rm’s products nomic assessment of London by Buck et al.
or operations; (1997). In particular, these emphasised the
(2) Ž rms’ perception that proximity to busi- importance of referrals and personal contacts
nesses in related activities was an advan- in developing business. Though few speciŽ c
tage because of either opportunities for links were suggested, the signiŽ cance of
interaction or the existence of a shared proximity to related businesses was down-
labour pool; and played, and more weight was given to the
(3) innovation in product or processes asso- opportunities (both casual and through exhi-
ciated with observation of or collabora- bitions, for example) which were available
tion with other businesses. for new contacts. Another qualitative study
of small business service Ž rms in central
More positive results included signiŽ cant
London by Jones (1998) found only weak
associations between concentration in Lon-
and unstable linkages, with suspicion of po-
don and:
tential collaborators, and knowledge being
(1) a perception that proximity to businesses transferred through competition rather than
in related activities was advantageous collaboration. Key advantages of a central
because of access to shared intelligence location were claimed to be accessibility for
(though this was only true for Ž nancial clients, a wider recruitment pool and a more
services in the City of London); ‘prestige’ image.
(2) not regarding such spatial clustering as A second reason, particularly relevant to
disadvantageous (in terms of compe- ‘agglomeration’, is that Ž rms may well be
tition); unconscious (or only vaguely aware) of key
(3) having or planning joint-ventures with externalities which their locality af-
INDUSTRIAL CLUSTERS 527

fords them (or fails to), relative to other services stand out from other groups of re-
places. While standard neo-classical analyses spondents to the LES in terms both of their
of location assume that proŽ t-maximising strong positive evaluation of proximity to
Ž rms would necessarily possess such com- related activities and the speciŽ c emphasis
parative information, this could only be ex- on local intelligence as the crucial external-
pected to be the case where two conditions ity. This is consistent with the Amin and
apply simultaneously: that spatial externali- Thrift (1992) view that a primary reason for
ties are a signiŽ cant in uence on the City’s competitive survival is its central
proŽ tability; and that relocation is a feasible role internationally in the construction of
and potentially proŽ table option. Typically, discourses about Ž nancial operations, sup-
however, spatial externalities imply a degree ported by its roles as a centre of interaction
of spatial dependence while, for any individ- and as a proving-ground for new products.
ual business, non-spatial in uences on Although historically the City was deeply
proŽ tability are likely to appear more rel- ‘embedded’ as much in the British class
evant. Only in relation to aggregate compari- structure as through local networks, trust
sons of growth or productivity across now appears to be something which has to be
localities do the spatial effects become cru- continually nurtured through interactions
cial, since the non-spatial in uences then with potential clients, partners and infor-
tend either to cancel out or (in the case of mants (Thrift and Leyshon, 1994). Since the
macroeconomics or government policy) to LES provides no evidence that City Ž rms are
exert similar effects everywhere. Even then, particularly likely to have strategically
differences arise more in relation to the per- signiŽ cant links with customers or suppliers
formance of representative plants in different or to be involved in local joint-ventures, their
areas than through relocations between these. main difference from other London busi-
In the London case, where movement is pre- nesses appears to be in the value attached to
dominantly outwards, the LES indicates that (sector-speciŽ c) localisation economies,
Ž rms expecting to move outside their present rather than to more general urbanisation
borough during the next 3 years accounted economies—i.e. a difference in the form of
for less than 5 per cent of employment, while agglomeration, rather than approximation to
for moves out of Greater London the corre- the complex or social-network models. Lo-
sponding Ž gure was around 1 per cent. For calisation also appears important for high-
those seeing any advantages in clustering, the order consumer services, but for the rest of
probabilities of such moves were only half as the London economy more diffuse forms of
great, while the reasons given for moving agglomeration seem to underpin the clusters
were dominated by issues related to premises of strong sectors, with very little evidence of
or physical accessibility, with only a handful more speciŽ c forms of attachment.
of Ž rms referring to customer or supplier The Coe and Townsend (1998) study of
access, support services or skill availability producer-service concentrations in the ‘west-
(Feloy et al., 1997). Outside London and to ern arc’ of the OMA comes to rather similar
the west in the Thames valley, a similar conclusions, emphasising the importance of
pattern is evident with a (limited number of) common locational logics rather than any
movers, mostly stimulated by company reor- localised (or even sub-regional) linkages in
ganisation, being concerned essentially with generating clusters of Ž nancial, business and
premises and costs, and relatively insensitive computer services. In this metropolitan ring,
to what other local Ž rms perceive as positive the relevant agglomeration seems to be the
locational attributes (Gordon, 1996b). Greater South East (some 150 miles across),
A third complicating factor is that in het- though these authors also found that formal
erogeneous urban economies the models ap- business links were quite likely to involve
ply differentially to particular sets of partners outside this region. At metropolitan-
activities. In the London case, City Ž nancial region scale, the picture approximates even
528 IAN R. GORDON AND PHILIP MCCANN

more closely to the pure agglomeration potential growth poles in areas such as
model, with little evidence for the Puerto Rico or the Mezzogiorno, which
signiŽ cance of either industrial complexes or lacked established industrial concentrations.
strong social networks. In this respect, the Subsequently, in a post-industrial or post-
London region is likely to be a rather ex- Fordist era, the milieux concept held out the
treme case, but one that is of substantial prospect that qualitatively crucial interrela-
importance in showing the social-network tions could be developed among clusters of
model to be by no means a pre-condition for (small or medium-sized) businesses, securing
the achievement of either  exibility or the both growth and innovation in lagging re-
capacity to innovate. gions and/or smaller centres in developed
regions. This relies heavily on elements of
the social-network model, though the
6. Conclusions
GREMI group’s analyses of innovative
Strong recent interest in the phenomenon of milieux (Camagni, 1995) also embraced
spatial industrial clustering from a variety of many sorts of agglomeration economy, and
disciplines with diverse analytical ap- the ‘rare’ examples which they found of such
proaches has led to a certain level of con- developments in backward regions included
fusion in the literature, as authors adopt one case of a rather pure (tourist) industrial
various concepts in a more or less inter- complex, located in the Costa Smeralda.
changeable manner. This confusion has been However, apart from specialisation (which
catalysed by the perceived policy salience of can reduce the absolute scale of agglomer-
‘clusters’, which is reinforced by a range of ation required for competitiveness) and dis-
plausible arguments and made applicable to a crimination in favour of selected centres, the
wide range of situations. The argument of prospect of stimulating such development in
this paper is that there are actually three such areas is seen as resting on investment in
analytically distinct forms (or ideal types) of networks of co-operation and information
spatial industrial clustering, each having a transfer to stimulate synergistic development.
different logic, and that it is important for SigniŽ cantly, in both cases, the basic insights
these not to be confused, even though actual were originally developed in terms of the
clusters may contain elements of more than economic space of relations among key Ž rms
one type. (Perroux, 1950; Schumpeter, 1934) and only
The signiŽ cance of the distinction between later attached to geographical space
these three interpretations lies partly in the (Boudeville, 1966; Camagni, 1995; Maillat,
implied scope for policy action to stimulate 1995).
growth and competitiveness in backward ar- Contrasts in the policy implications of
eas or to create counter-magnets to congested these three ideal types of cluster make it
metropolitan areas. In different periods and particularly important to avoid confusing fea-
economic contexts, the complex and net- tures of one with those of another, even
work models both held out the prospect that though elements of each may co-exist in
substantial spatial externalities could be gen- particular situations. In cases approximating
erated through appropriately planned devel- to the industrial-complex model, where pro-
opment in areas lacking a strong existing duction links are central to the clustering
concentration of advanced industrial or process, relevant indicators of spatial exter-
service activity. In the Ž rst case, nalities involve the level, pattern and tempo-
co-ordinating the locational decisions of ral stability of the input–output linkages for
large-scale, interlinked businesses in (high- local tradeable and factor inputs. Although it
transport-cost) sectors, such as petro- is common practice to focus just on the Ž rst
chemicals (Isard and Vietorisz, 1955), steel of these—see, for example, Turok, 1993;
or auto-engineering, was seen as a means of Phelps, 1997—this can be quite misleading
triggering viable economic development and as an indicator of the degree of integration of
INDUSTRIAL CLUSTERS 529

key sectors in the local economy, since it is forms of spatial externalities admits the pos-
contingent on the degree of vertical sibility of ‘intellectually respectable cases’
(dis)integration of the production process. being made for selective interventions in or-
Taking factor inputs into account as well der to promote growth paths leading to
provides an indicator of something which higher local real incomes—although there is
might be (and has been) referred to as local a reasonable suspicion that most such in-
‘embeddness’, but which has nothing to do stances will prove to be unwarranted cases of
with Granovetter’s use of the term, or its special pleading on behalf of more speciŽ c
signiŽ cance in relation to the social-network interests (Krugman, 1995). More sophisti-
model. In cases approximating to ‘pure ag- cated arguments, drawing on elements of the
glomeration’, where linkages are diffuse, un- social-network model, evolutionary econom-
stable and not necessarily recognised even by ics and ‘lock-in’ effects (David, 1985), sub-
the parties involved, the only feasible ap- stantially enlarge the scope for effective
proach to the measurement of spatial exter- intervention, but also for resource misalloca-
nalities is via the estimation of aggregate tion, if their empirical and analytical bases
production functions, although the deŽ nition are not examined critically (Lovering, 1998).
of urban capital as a composite commodity One case in point is the impression created
can lead to the identity problems inherent in by research on ‘innovative milieux’ (Aydalot
both aspatial and spatial growth models (Fin- 1986; Aydalot and Keeble, 1988) that there
gleton and McCombie, 1998). Finally, in exists an ideal modern form of spatial indus-
cases approximating to the social-network trial organisation (based on a combination of
model, a more qualitative approach is re- small-Ž rm structures and local labour
quired, in order to measure the incidence of  exibility) in which innovation and growth
co-operative behaviour among Ž rms and or- are maximised. More critical recent investi-
ganisations pursuing mutually beneŽ cial ven- gations indicate that there is no well-deŽ ned
tures. In this context, direct economic links relationship between the location of innova-
or even levels of information  ow are less tive activities and regional spatial structure,
relevant indicators of embeddedness than in- which is applicable to any wide range of
volvement in joint-ventures, lobbying ac- sectors (Simmie, 1998).
tivity, mutual-support networks or common
patterns of socialisation, along with means of
controlling membership of the network. As References
the London example indicates, it cannot sim- AKERLOFF, G. A. and YELLEN , J. L. (Eds) (1986)
ply be assumed in the absence of such condi- EfŽ ciency Wage Models of the Labor Market.
tions that other measures of local integration Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
are a reasonable predictor of the applicability ALCHIAN, A. A. (1957) Uncertainty, evolution and
of this model, since availability of agglomer- economic theory, Journal of Political Econ-
omy, 58, pp. 211–221.
ation economies might, for example, actually ALIBER, R. Z. (1993) The Multinational
discourage investment in deepening social Paradigm. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press,.
networks. AMIN, A. (1989) Flexible specialisation and small
In such empirical analyses there is a need Ž rms in Italy: myths and realities, Antipode, 21,
for great care (in particular, recognising the pp. 13–34.
AMIN, A. and THRIFT, N. (1992) Neo-Marshallian
distinctions between different types of spatial nodes in global networks, International Journal
externality and seeking appropriate kinds of of Urban and Regional Research, 16, pp. 571–
evidence to test the signiŽ cance of each), 587.
especially in view of the policy signiŽ cance ANGEL , D. P. (1991) High technology agglomer-
currently being invested in the promotion of ation and the labour market: the case of Silicon
Valley, Environment and Planning A, 23,
clusters, innovative milieux and associational pp. 1501–1516.
economies (Cooke, 1998). Even for liberal ARITA, T. and MCCANN, P. (1998) Industrial al-
economists, the existence of substantial liances and Ž rm location behaviour: some evi-
530 IAN R. GORDON AND PHILIP MCCANN

dence from the US semiconductor industry. New York and Pittsburgh, American Economic
Discussion Paper No. 130. Department of Eco- Review, 51, pp. 279–289.
nomics, University of Reading. CHINITZ , B. (1964) City and suburb, in: B.
ARROW, K. J. (1962) The economic implications CHINITZ (Ed.) City and Suburb: The Economics
of learning by doing, Review of Economic Stud- of Metropolitan Growth, pp. 3–50. Englewood
ies, 29, pp. 155–173. Cliffs. NJ: Prentice-Hall.
ARTHUR, W. B. (1994) Increasing Returns and COE, N. M. and T OWNSEND, A. R.(1998) Debunk-
Path Dependence in the Economy. Ann Arbor, ing the myth of localized agglomerations: the
MI: University of Michigan Press. development of a regionalized service economy
AYDALOT , P. (1986) Milieux innovateurs en Eu- in South East England, Transactions of the
rope. Paris: GREMI. Institute of British Geographers, NS, 23,
AYDALOT , P. and KEEBLE , D. (1988) High Tech- pp. 385–404.
nology Industry and Innovative Environments. COOKE , P. (1998) The Associational Economy:
London: Routledge. Firms, Regions and Innovation. Oxford: Ox-
BARKHAM, R., GUDGIN, G., HART, M. and HAN- ford University Press.
VEY , E. (1996) The Determinants of Small Firm DAVID, P. (1985) CLIO and the Economics of
Growth: An Inter-regional Study of the Unted QWERTY, American Economic Review, 75,
Kingdom 1986–1990. London: Jessica Kings- pp. 332–337.
ley. DOSI, G. (1988) Sources, procedures, and micro-
BEST , M. H. (1990) The New Competition: Insti- economic effects of innovation, Journal of
tutions of Industrial Restructuring. Cambridge: Economic Literature, 26, pp. 1120–1171.
Polity Press. DOSI, G., FREEMAN, C., NELSON , R. ET AL . (1987)
BLANCHFLOWER , D. G. and OSWALD, A. J. (1994) Technical Change and Economic Theory. Lon-
The Wage Curve. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. don: Pinter.
BLAUG, M. (1985) Economic Theory in Retro- EVANS, A. (1985) Urban Economics. Oxford:
spect. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Blackwell.
BLISS , C. and BRAGE DE MACEDO, J. (1990) Unity FELOY, M., GORDON, I. R., LLOYD , P. E. and ROE ,
with Diversity in the European Economy. Cam- P. (1997) London Employer Survey 1996–1997.
bridge: Cambridge University Press. London: London Training and Enterprise
BORTS, G. H. and STEIN, J. L. (1964) Economic Councils.
Growth in a Free Market. New York: Colum- FINGLETON , B. and MCCOMBIE, J. S. L. (1998)
bia University Press. Increasing returns and economic growth: some
BOUDEVILLE , J. R. (1966) Problems of Regional evidence for manufacturing from the European
Economic Planning. Edinburgh: Edinburgh Union regions, Oxford Economic Papers, 50,
University Press. pp. 89–105.
BUCK, N., CROOKSTON, M., GORDON, I. and HALL , FUJITA, M. (1989) Urban Economics. Cambridge:
P. (1997) A Socio-economic Assessment of Cambridge University Press.
London. A report by Llewelyn Davies and Part- FUJITA, M and KRUGMAN, P. (1995) When is the
ners. London: Association for London Govern- economy monocentric? Von Thünen and
ment. Chamberlin uniŽ ed, Regional Science and Ur-
CAMAGNI, R. P. (1995) The concept of innovative ban Economics, 25, pp. 505–528.
milieu and its relevance for public policies in FUJITA, M. and MORI, T. (1997) Structural stabil-
European lagging regions, Papers in Regional ity and evolution of urban systems, Regional
Science, 74, pp. 317–340. Science and Urban Economics, 27, pp. 399–
CANTWELL, J. A. (1991) The international ag- 442.
glomeration of R&D, in: M. C. CASSON (Ed.) GLAESER , E., KALLAL, H. D., SCHINKMANN, J. A.
Global Research Strategy and International and SHLEIFER , A. (1992) Growth in cities, Jour-
Competitiveness, pp. 216–232. Oxford: Basil nal of Political Economy, 100, pp. 1126–1152.
Blackwell. GORDON, I. R. (1996a) Territorial competition
CASTELLS, M. and HALL , P. G. (1994) and locational advantage in the London region.
Technopoles of the World: The Making of 21st Paper presented to the American Association of
Century Industrial Complexes. New York: Geographers Annual Conference, Charlotte,
Routledge. NC.
CHESHIRE , P. C. and GORDON, I. R. (1995) Change GORDON, I. R. (1996b) Out-movers from the
and spatial specialisation within the South Thames Valley. Centre for the Study of Ad-
East’s economy, in: P. CHESHIRE and I. R. vanced European Regions, University of Read-
GORDON (Eds) Territorial Competition in an ing (mimeograph).
Integrating Europe, pp. 65–97. Aldershot: Ave- GRANOVETTER, M. (1973) The strength of weak
bury. ties, American Journal of Sociology, 78,
CHINITZ , B. (1961) Contrast in agglomeration: pp. 1360–1380.
INDUSTRIAL CLUSTERS 531

GRANOVETTER, M. (1985) Economic action and KRUGMAN, P. (1991a) Geography and Trade.
social structure: the problem of embeddedness, Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
American Journal of Sociology, 91, pp. 481– KRUGMAN, P. (1991b) Increasing returns and
510. economic geography, Journal of Political
GRANOVETTER, M. (1991) The social construction Economy, 99, pp. 183–199.
of economic institutions, in: A. E TZONI and R. KRUGMAN, P. (1993) First nature, second nature
LAWRENCE (Eds) Socio-economics: Towards a and metropolitan location, Journal of Regional
New Synthesis, pp. 75–81. New York: Armonk. Science, 34, pp. 129–144.
GRANOVETTER, M. (1992) Problems of expla- KRUGMAN, P. (1996) Development, Geography,
nation in economic sociology, in: N. NOHRIA and Economic Theory. Cambridge, MA: MIT
and R. ECCLES (Eds) Networks and Organisa- Press.
tions: Form and Action, pp. 25–56. Cambridge, LARSEN, J. K. and ROGERS, E. M. (1984) Silicon
MA: Harvard Business School Press. Valley Fever. London: George Allen and Un-
HARRIS, J. and T ODARO, M. (1970) Migration, win.
unemployment and development: a two-sector LAWSON, C., MOORE, B., KEEBLE , D. ET AL. (1997)
Inter-Ž rm links between regionally clustered
analysis, American Economic Review, 60,
high-technology SMEs: a comparison of Cam-
pp. 126–142. bridge and Oxford innovation networks. Work-
HARRISON, B. (1992) Industrial districts: old wine ing Paper No. 65, ESRC Centre for Business
in new bottles?, Regional Studies, 26, pp. 469– Research, Cambridge.
483. LOVERING , J. (1999) Theory led by policy: The
HELPMAN , E. and KRUGMAN, P. (1985) Market inadequacies of ‘the new regionalism’ (illus-
Structure and Foreign Trade. Cambridge, MA: trated from the case of Wales), International
MIT Press. Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 23,
HENDERSON , J. V., KUNCORO, A. and T URNER, M. pp. 379–395.
(1995) Industrial development in cities, Journal MAILLAT , D. (1995) Territorial dynamic, innova-
of Political Economy, 103, pp. 1067–1085. tive milieus and regional policy, Entrepreneur-
HOOVER, E. M. (1937) Location Theory and the ship and Regional Development, 7,
Shoe and Leather Industries. Cambridge, MA: pp. 157–165.
Harvard University Press. MARKUSEN, A. (1996) Sticky places in slippery
HOOVER, E. M. (1948) The Location of Economic space: a typology of industrial districts, Econ-
Activity. New York: McGraw-Hill. omic Geography, 72, pp. 293–313.
ISARD, W. (1951) Distance inputs and the space MARSHALL, A. (1925) Principles of Economics,
economy. Part II: The locational equilibrium of 8th edn. London: Macmillan.
the Ž rm, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 65, MCCANN, P. (1995) Rethinking the economics of
pp. 373–399. location and agglomeration, Urban Studies, 32,
ISARD, W. and KUENNE , R. E. (1953) The impact pp. 563–577.
of steel upon the Greater New York– MCCANN, P. (1998) The Economics of Industrial
Philadelphia industrial region, Review of Eco- Location: A Logistics-Costs Approach. Heidel-
nomics and Statistics, 35, pp. 289–301. berg: Springer.
ISARD, W. and VIETORISZ, T. (1955) Industrial MILLER, S. M. and JENSEN , O. W. (1978) Location
complex analysis, and regional development and the theory of production, Regional Science
with particular reference to Puerto Rico, Papers and Urban Economics, 8, pp. 117–128.
and Proceedings of the Regional Science As- MILLS , E. S. (1980) Urban Economics. Glenview,
sociation, 1, pp. 229–247. IL: Scott, Foresman and Co.
MOSES, L. (1958) Location and the theory of
JACOBS, J. (1960) The Economy of Cities. New
production, Quarterly Journal of Economics,
York: Random House. 78, pp. 259–272.
JAFFE, A. B., TRAJTENBERG, M. and HENDERSON, R. NELSON, R. R. and WINTER , S. G. (1982) An
(1993) Geographic localization of knowledge Evolutionary Theory of Economic Change.
spillovers as evidenced by patent citations, Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108, pp. 577– NISHIGUCHI, T. (1994) Strategic Industrial
598. Sourcing. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
JONES , A. (1998) Local economies and business OLSEN, M. (1965) The Logic of Collective Action:
networks revisited: a case study of business and Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Cam-
professional services in London, Local Econ- bridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
omy, 14, pp. 151–165. PEARCE, R. D. (1993) The Growth and Evolution
KEEBLE , D. and LAWSON C. (Eds) (1997) Net- of Multinational Enterprise. BrookŽ eld, VT:
works, links and large Ž rm impacts on the Edward Elgar.
evolution of regional clusters of high- PERROUX, F. (1950) Economic space: theory and
technology SMEs in Europe. ESRC Centre for applications, Quarterly Journal of Economics,
Business Research, Cambridge. 64, pp. 89–104.
532 IAN R. GORDON AND PHILIP MCCANN

PHELPS , N.A. (1997) Multinationals and Eu- SIMPSON , W. (1992) Urban Structure and the
ropean Integration. London: Jessica Kingsley. Labour Market: Worker Mobility, Commuting
PIORE , M. J. and SABEL, C. F. (1984) The Second and Underemployment in Cities. Oxford:
Industrial Divide: Possibilities for Prosperity. Clarendon Press.
New York: Basic Books. SUAREZ -VILLA, L. and WALROD W. (1997) Oper-
PITELIS , C. (Ed.) (1993) Transaction Costs, Mar- ational strategy, R&D and intra-metropolitan
kets and Hierarchies. Oxford: Blackwell. clustering in a polycentric structure: the ad-
POMFRET, R. (1991) International Trade. Oxford: vanced electronics industries of the Los Ange-
Blackwell. les basin, Urban Studies, 34, pp. 1343–1380.
PORTER, M. E. (1990) The Competitive Advantage SUNLEY , P. (1992) Marshallian industrial districts:
of Nations. New York: The Free Press. the case of the Lancashire cotton industry in the
RICHARDSON, H. W. (1978) Urban Economics. inter-war years, Transactions of the Institute of
Hinsdale, IL: Dryden Press. British Geographers, NS, 17, pp. 306–320.
ROMER, P. M. (1986) Increasing returns and long THRIFT, N. and L EYSHON, A. (1994) A phantom
run growth, Journal of Political Economy, 94, state? The de-traditionalisation of money, the
pp. 1002–1037. international Ž nancial system and international
ROMER, P. M. (1987) Growth based on increasing Ž nancial centres, Political Geography, 13,
returns due to specialisation, American Econ- pp. 299–327.
omic Review, 77, 56–72. TRAU, F. (1997) Recent trends in the size structure
SALOMON , I. and SCHOFER, J. (1990) Transporta- of Italian manufacturing Ž rms, Small Business
tion and telecommunications costs: some impli- Economics, 9, pp. 273–285.
cations for small countries, in: F. DIETZ , W. TRAU, F. (1998) Structural Change and Firms’
HEIJMAN, and D. SHEFER , (Eds) Location and propensity to Grow in Italian manufacturing.
Labour Considerations for Regional Develop- Discussion Paper No. 380, Department of Eco-
ment, pp. 49–63. Aldershot: Avebury. nomics, University of Reading.
SAXENIAN, A. (1994) Regional Advantage: Cul- TUROK, I. (1993) Inward investment and local
ture and Competition in Silicon Valley and linkages: how deeply embedded is Silicon
Route 128. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Univer- Glen?, Regional Studies, 27, pp. 401–417.
sity Press. VENABLES, A. (1995) Economic integration and
SCHUMPETER , J. A. (1934) The Theory of Econ- the location of Ž rms, American Economic Re-
omic Development. Cambridge, MA: Harvard view, 85, pp. 296–300.
University Press. VERNON, R. (1960) Metropolis. Cambridge, MA:
SCITOVSKY, T. (1954) Two concepts of external Harvard University Press.
economies, Journal of Political Economy, 62, VERNON, R. (1966) International investment and
pp. 143–151. international trade in the product cycle, Quar-
SCOTT , A. J. (1988) New Industrial Spaces. Lon- terly Journal of Economics, 80, pp. 190–207.
don: Pion. WEBER, A. (1909/1929) Theory of the Location of
SCOTT , A. J. (1993) Technopolis: High- Industries, trans. by C. J. FRIEDRICH. Chicago:
technology Industry and Regional Development University of Chicago Press.
in Southern California. Berkeley, CA: Univer- WILLIAMSON , O. E. (1975) Markets and Hier-
sity of California Press. archies. New York: Free Press.
SHONBERGER, R. J. (1982) Japanese Manufactur- WILLIAMSON , O. E. (1985) The Economic Institu-
ing Techniques: Nine Hidden Lessons in Sim- tions of Capitalism. New York: Free Press.
plicity. New York: Free Press. WILLIAMSON , O. E. and WINTER , S. G. (Eds)
SIMMIE , J. (1998) Reasons for the development (1993) The Nature of the Firm: Origins, Evol-
of ‘islands of innovation’: evidence from ution and Development. Oxford: Oxford Uni-
Hertfordshire, Urban Studies, 35, pp. 1261– versity Press.
1289.

You might also like