You are on page 1of 10

Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy and Society 2009, 2, 312

doi:10.1093/cjres/rsp001 Advance Access publication 2 February 2009

Editorial: Rescaling the state: new modes of institutionalterritorial organization

Linda Lobaoa, Ron Martinb and Andre s Rodr guez-Posec


a

Departments of Rural Sociology, Sociology, and Geography, The Ohio State University, Columbus, Ohio 43210, USA. lobao.1@osu.edu b Department of Geography, University of Cambridge, Downing Place, Cambridge CB2 3EN, UK. rlm1@cam.ac.uk c Department of Geography and Environment, London School of Economics and Political Science, Houghton Street, London WC2A 2AE, UK. a.rodriguez-pose@lse.ac.uk
Downloaded from cjres.oxfordjournals.org by guest on July 5, 2011

The modern state in transformation


Over the past 100 years, modern Western states have undergone two historic transformations. The rst occurred between the 1920s and the 1940s, when the liberal, non-interventionist form that had dominated the 19th and earlier centuries gave way to the Keynesian welfare interventionist (or Fordist) form. From its origins in the 1930s (in the UK, the USA and Sweden), the Keynesian welfare state project emerged as the dominant post-war model of social and economic regulation among many of the advanced industrialized nations. Its twin goals were the stabilization of the inherent cyclical instabilities of capitalist growth and the construction of mass societal support and cohesion through the maintenance of full employment and provision of a public welfare system. Of course, nation states pursued different variants of the basic model (Esping-Andersen, 1990; Painter, 2001). Specic policies and the degree of intervention differed according to the particular balance of socio-economic forces and historical politicalinstitutional legacies in each country. At the same time, the Keynesian welfare state project brought about changes to the territorial organization of the state. Although, again, the nature and extent of these changes varied across na-

tion states and interacted with the diverse national structures inherited from the past, involving differing degrees and forms of devolution of powers and responsibilities to subnational regional, city or local levels, the ascent of the Keynesian welfare state reinforced national or federal governments virtually everywhere at the expense of subnational governments and authorities (Brenner 2004; Donahue, 1997; Rodr guez-Pose and Gill, 2003). These common features permit some generalization as to the implications of the Keynesian welfare state model of state regulation for patterns of uneven regional development (see Martin and Sunley, 1997). For one thing, national space was the essential geographical unit of socio-economic organization, accumulation and regulation over which the state functioned as sovereign actor. As Radice (1984, 116) pointed out the national economy is privileged in Keynesian theory for the purely practical reason that the nation-state system denes geopolitical space with the necessary features convenient for the theory: a common currency, common laws, and shared institutions. Indeed, the Keynesian welfare project required a high degree of closure of the national socio-economic space in order for the states domestic policies to have their desired

The Author 2009. Published by Oxford University Press on behalf of the Cambridge Political Economy Society. All rights reserved. For permissions, please email: journals.permissions@oxfordjournals.org

Lobao, Martin and Rodr guez-Pose effects. At the same time, trade, money and capital ows between nation states were regulated via the international bodiessuch as the International Monetary Fund, World Bank, General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade and Bretton Woodsset up precisely to guarantee the stability of each national economy. For another, the economic and social strategies pursued by post-war Keynesian nation states necessarily involved a high degree of spatial centralization of political regulation of the domestic economy and civil society. The management of the national socio-economy itself required new centralized powers of coordination and manipulation of basic scal, monetary and welfare measures. This spatial centralization of political power unfolded across the developed world, adapting to the spatio-organizational structure of different state systems (especially whether unitary or federal). The counterpart of this centralized political regulation was spatial socio-economic integration. Under the post-war Keynesian welfare state, most countries saw dramatic growth in state spending on utilities, infrastructure, health care and other public goods. The effect of these programmes was to foster consistent standards of social welfare and social infrastructure provision across regions and localities, thereby incorporating them into an increasingly collective or public socio-economic space. This, together with progressive taxation systems, automatic social benet systems and explicit regional and urban policies, gave the Keynesian nation state a distinct spatially and socially redistributive role. As a result, in almost every advanced industrial country, social and spatial inequalities in income and general public well-being declined at least up to the early-1970s (Armstrong, 1995; Barro and Sala-I-Mart n, 1991; Lo pez-Bazo et al., 1999). But during the 1970s, the post-war Keynesian welfare state model began to unravel. Several key forces have combined to once more transform the modern state, stimulating debate about the nature, function, form and future of what is variously called the shift to a post-Keynesian, post-Fordist, Schumpeterian workfare, competition and neoliberal state (Brenner, 2004; Jessop, 1990, 1993, 2002; Martin 4 and Sunley, 1997; Peck, 2001). The argument is that over the past three decades the post-war Keynesian welfare state model has been progressively undermined both from within and externally by three interrelated developments: the exhaustion and crisis of Fordism as a regime of economic production, capital accumulation and social regulation; accelerating and deepening globalization and the shift towards pro-market neoliberalism. The result has been a new conguration of statemarket relations, the forms of welfare models pursued and the territorial code of the state as seen in the division of powers and responsibilities between the central state and subnational governments on the one hand and supranational forms of governance on the other. While the idea of the national economic space that underpinned the post-war Keynesian nation state was never as valid as it was assumed to be (Radice, 1984), the accelerating processes of globalization since the 1980s have certainly challenged or at least reconguredsuch a notion. National economies are now so interwoven with one another, in many senses borderlessas the global nancial crisis emerging in 2008 demonstrated vividlythat the room for independent domestic policy intervention for nation states has become much more circumscribed. Nation states have not, of course, been innocent bystanders in this process: the rise and diffusion of neoliberal political ideology from the 1980s onward actively involved the deregulation of markets and institutions, helping to fuel the very globalization process that has weakened the economic sovereignty of the state. In this sense, nation states have actively ceded some of their powers to global capital, the whirlwind of which they are now witnessing. At the same time, as neoliberal states sought to constrain public spending and refocus intervention from social welfare to the promotion of economic efciency and exibility (in order to better compete in global markets), increasing emphasis has been put on decentralizing, and in some cases even devolving, the administration and implementation of economic and social policies down to regional and local levels. And as nation states have lost or forfeited some of their economic

Downloaded from cjres.oxfordjournals.org by guest on July 5, 2011

Rescaling the state sovereignty to the march of globalization, regional and city authorities have not only seen their local economies become more exposed to the global economy but also sought greater autonomy to carve their own role within it. functions, hollowed out of the core elements that dened their very existence (Hirst and Thompson, 1995; Jessop, 2004). And yet the paradox was that European nation states seemed anything but dead or even moribund. Mitterrands France, Britains Thatcher, Kohls Germanyjust to mention the most signicant caseswere vibrant societies, sure of their place in the world and their respective socio-economic models. They were also engaged in the most ambitious experiment in economic and social integration ever seen in peacetime, the European Union (EU). The paradox between the challenges to the European nation state and its vitality was quickly spotted by scholars across the social sciences who grappled to understand the reasons for the ourishing European post-Keynesian, post-Fordist state in the face of apparent adversity. How could this circle be squared? The early answers came precisely from researchers analysing European integration. Leading the way was Milward (1992), who in his book The European Rescue of the Nation-State defended the thesis that European integration was revitalizing not weakening nation states by allowing them to shape activities beyond the rigid constraints of their national boundaries. The European nation state was reinventing itself as a post-Keynesian, post-Fordist entity whose role was shifting from that of an actor or a direct player in economic affairs into that of a facilitator, an enabler and a vehicle for economic governance (Hirst and Thompson, 1995, 1999). From a different perspective, Hooghe (1996) and Hooghe and Marks (2001) identied the transformation of the nation state in the emergence of dense multiagent systems operating in a multiscalar environment with the roles of different government tiers embedded within one another (Hooghe and Marks, 1997). In this complex multilevel governance system, responsibilities across different tiers of government were so enmeshed that it was becoming increasingly difcult to determine who was responsible for what (Pike et al., 2007), allowing the nation state to shape and very much remain at the heart of this new governance structure. These approaches underscored the realization that the simultaneous emergence of regions, international 5

The rescaling issue


The progressive demise of the post-war Keynesian welfare nation state as a consequence of the parallel challenges of global and regional economic integration and the diffusion of neoliberal political ideology, on the one hand, and the drive towards decentralization, on the other, has directed social scientists attention to issues involving the scale of the state. Researchers rst raised questions about how factors such as the growth of supranational regulatory bodies and the importance of local subnational state responses were undermining the autonomy of the nation state (e.g. Cox, 1997). The dominant view was that nation states were rmly on the retreat (Amin and Tomaney, 1995; Tomaney and Ward, 2000). First, from above, globalization and economic integration were believed to erode the nation states power to control the traditional resorts of economic management (Cairncross, 1997; OBrien, 1992; Ohmae, 1995). Second, from below, demands for decentralization and transfers of powers and resources to subnational tiers of government were viewed as stripping the state of many of its traditional functions (Keating, 1997). Political economy analyses of capitalist regulation also questioned the trajectory of the Keynesian welfare nation state, particularly its regional unevenness, contributing to the need to attend to the state at the subnational scale (Amin, 1994; Peck and Tickell, 1994). And, nally, from within, nancial problems and the revival of free market ideologies were casting doubts on the capacity of and convenience of state intervention in the economy and about the social model associated with it. Nowhere were these challenges greater than in Europe, where the twin forces of economic integration and nationalist and regionalist trends were at their height. European statesmuch more than states elsewhereseemed to be losing traditional

Downloaded from cjres.oxfordjournals.org by guest on July 5, 2011

Lobao, Martin and Rodr guez-Pose organizations and multinational enterprises, far from limiting the capacity of the nation state to inuence economic processes, were giving a new lease on life to what many had imagined a worn out institution (Jessop, 1995). The nation state was reinventing itself, evolving from a simple institution towards a mesh of social relations in which new bases of power emerged from the capacity to broker market relationships and mediate interaction among different levels of government (Jessop, 2000). The role of the state thus shifted from simple governmental provision to constructing and articulating a complex and multiscalar governance system (Jones, 2001). This new role, while clearly different from what had existed before, was no less relevant. Far from implying the demise of the nation state, it heralded the birth of a more supple state capable of turning challenges to its authority to its advantage. These pioneering approaches have contributed to a body of literature on the rescaling of the state that has blossomed since the turn of the century. Under different labels and from different angles, this literature has analysed the forms of and factors behind the transformation of the nation state. A number of scholars from human geography, political science and sociology have contributed to a growing corpus of work on this issue (e.g. Goodwin et al., 2005; Jones, 2001; MacLeod and Goodwin, 1999). Perhaps, the chief recent contributions have come from Brenner (1999, 2003, 2004). Building on Jessops (2000) view of the nation state as an evolving body of social relationships, Brenner posits that the nation state, far from being a static territorial entity, is in constant change. It is being continuously produced and reproduced, with spatial scales essential to understanding this constant transformation. For Brenner (2004), both the Keynesian and the postKeynesian nation state have its own special forms of territorial organization. Challenges to the Keynesian welfare nation state have led to questioning of the forms of state organization, where centralized planning and top-down state-driven development have given way to multiscalar forms of governance, allowing the state to operate simultaneously in specic places and at multiple scales (Brenner, 2004). 6

The contributions
The articles featured in this journal issue aim at contributing to and extending this ongoing debate on the rescaling of the state. Most broadly, the authors contributions should be contextualized within the status of current work on the topic, still an incomplete and emergent project. Extant research has evolved from overlapping but often conceptually segmented literatures. As discussed above, the body of work emerged from a conuence of literatures on globalization and transformation of the nation state, neoliberal hegemony and political economy perspectives on the trajectory of capitalism, such as regulation theory. In addition, literatures such as the long-standing research on metropolitan regions (see Cox, 2009) and more recent governance approaches (see Buchs, 2009) inform contemporary work. Although studies on state rescaling still often respond specically to these distinct strands of literatures, they have merged more into an amalgam topical area. Brenners (2004) and Jessops (2002, 2004) work in particular have provided a more unifying thematic scope to the literature and helped dene the contours of recent debates. The articles in this issue demonstrate a common objective of building on existing conceptual, thematic and empirical aspects of the rescaling debate. Questions about the meaning and signicance of scale itself and its link to statesociety processes, the thematic issues that might be explored and the research strategies for sorting out complex empirical relationships are scrutinized by various authors in this special issue. The main contributions can be summarized as follows. First, a number of authors featured in this issue seek to introduce a more nuanced conceptualization of spatial scale into research on state transformation. Much of the literature has built on what Pike and Tomaney (2009) call a territorial approach that views scale as xed, bounded and with hierarchical levels and that juxtaposes the global, national, subnational and local. Cox (2009) also notes the persistence of this view, citing Manselds (2005) critique that statesociety

Downloaded from cjres.oxfordjournals.org by guest on July 5, 2011

Rescaling the state changes span scales, making it problematic (if not incorrect) to assign such changes to distinct scales. Part of the tendency towards a territorial perspective on scale arises from conventional Marxian political economy approaches that inform much of the state-rescaling literature. Here scale is seen more as structuring the material activity of states and less as being constructed by them, particularly in a cultural, discursive sense, such as through rhetoric justifying devolution. Cox (2009), Keating et al. (2009) and Pike and Tomaney (2009) argue for the greater need to integrate the material or territorial approach with more relational accounts that take into consideration the uidity of scale and its cultural construction by state actors. Second, in terms of thematic issues, all the articles identify decentralization as a pivotal research question for it directly links state action with spatial scale. Mart nez-Va zquez and Timofeev (2009), starting from a scal decentralization perspective, note that state rescaling itself . can be interpreted as cyclical variations in decentralization over time. Although analysts have long addressed decentralization particularly in the U.S. case as Cox (2009) notes, over the last decade or so it has become a key state process of concern globally. Questions about decentralization are situated into wider debates about the relative decline of the nation state, the rise of neoliberal governance, uneven development and variations in the welfare state. Since growth and redistribution are core functions of the nation state, attention also is given to theorizing how economic development (Pike and Tomaney, 2009) and social welfare activities (Scarpa, 2009) are diffused downward to subnational states. In sum, by focusing on decentralization, the authors theoretical concern is to speak to central political economic and governance questions, framing them in light of spatial scale. In addition to extending the study of state decentralization processes theoretically, the authors also seek to advance its empirical exploration. Mart nezVa zquez and Timofeev (2009) argue for the need to examine multiple measures of decentralization. Their cross-national study nds that patterns of scal decentralization unfold differently over time depending upon whether measures of expenditures, revenues and size are used. Keating et al. (2009) note that past research on decentralization has neglected the manner by which it gives rise to different forms of interest articulation. They examine this issue, developing hypotheses about territorial policy communities which they explore empirically using four regional devolutionary contexts in the UK. Scarpa (2009) explains how the comparative welfare states literature has tended to homogenize the decentralization experiences of the Nordic nations. His comparative study of Sweden and Finland demonstrates that different patterns of internal, regional labour market conditions in each country resulted in variations in social insurance schemes, including the establishment of different programmes in different time periods. In the contemporary period, employment activation programmes are decentralized to municipalities in both nations but these programmes are tailored to different regional labour market needs and orchestrated largely by the central state which still plays a strong role in reducing subnational inequality. Another thematic issue pushed forward by the articles concerns the emerging forms of governance that introduce a greater role for non-state actors. Buchs (2009) refer to this aspect of state rescaling as its horizontal dimension. Business interests and unions, for example, gure importantly in the account of Keating et al. (2009) of the development of territorial policy communities in the UK. Pike and Tomaney (2009) see a messy, unfolding landscape of economic governance that has emerged from the action and rhetoric of state and non-state actors as they seek to deal with uneven development across the UK. More sinisterly, according to these authors the pushing down of responsibility for growth and redistribution to local public and private sector actors reects the central states interest in abdicating responsibility for ameliorating spatial inequality. In their different ways, the articles also confront the conceptual protocols by which state transformation should be studied. All the articles point out the complexity of analysing statesociety processes across space. There is a need to deal with 7

Downloaded from cjres.oxfordjournals.org by guest on July 5, 2011

Lobao, Martin and Rodr guez-Pose the intersection of scale along with the multifarious institutional actors reecting various arms of the state, capital, labour and civic society. There is a need to incorporate both material accounts emphasizing the constraints imposed by structural forces such as uneven development, as well as more discursive, actor-oriented constructivist accounts that emphasize interest group articulation and the states efforts to legitimate programmes and policies. State rescaling also raises the fundamental question of how to study scale itself, a concern that has generated lively debate particularly among human geographers (see Marston et al., 2005; Moore, 2008). On balance, empirical studies of state rescaling are faced with the need to examine complex, overlapping statesociety relationships, to be sensitive to a host of multiscalar processes and to recognize different strains of literatures addressing the topic. These are daunting issues for they run up against the limitations of the human mind to sort out complexity and make it difcult for analysts to provide a clear-cut storyline as well as to inform theory. To guide empirical research, the development of conceptual templates capturing both generalization and specicity ushered in by multiple, complex relationships are needed. Several of the authors propose new conceptual templates for studying state rescaling. Buchs (2009) argues that relatively independent literatures exist that focus, respectively, on the vertical (such as decentralization or globalization) and the horizontal (such as authority transfers between state and non-state actors) dimensions of rescaling. While both sets of literature at least implicitly recognize these two dimensions, they are given different weight in studies and their interaction is not well explored. Buchs (2009) develops a conceptual template for mapping state transformation that uses these dimensions separately and in combination to scrutinize policymaking, policy delivery and joint policymaking and policy delivery. Pike and Tomaney (2009) take on a similar effort to develop a framework for studying rescaling through reconciling territorial and relational approaches. They note that territorial approaches viewing scale as more xed analytical scaffolding are evident in 8 the new state spatialities or territorial governance literatures, as seen in Brenner (2004) and Jessop (2002, 2004). Relational approaches build from the interrogation of scale, their proponents challenging what they see as more essentialist and bounded views of space. Pike and Tomaney (2009) combine these approaches, putting forth a framework on the geographic political economy of the qualitative state that focuses on the states action in constructing devolution projects, designing public nance settlements and mobilizing nonstate actors in the attempt to govern subnational manifestations of uneven development. They apply their framework to the empirical case of the UK where they argue that a pattern of territorial governance of bewildering complexity has emerged that dees any analysis utilizing xed scales and conventional territorial units. Keating et al. (2009) develop a framework for examining interest articulation in response to devolution. They outline three possible outcomes as devolution proceeds: no change (or regions without regionalism), where traditional sectoral divisions predominate; partial exit, where select interest groups delink themselves from others and venue shop for special treatment, and new regionalism, where new policy communities form as subnational governance is strengthened. A broad question that confronts researchers, the manner by which the periodization of state rescaling might be studied, is addressed by Brenner (2009). He outlines two methodological approaches for analysing the intersection of time and territory in state processes. One is to start with a specic cluster of state policies such as housing and determine their spatial trajectory over time. The other is to start with a particularly territory and trace its institutional reorganization from forces within and externally, as in studies of territorial governance restructuring. Finally, the articles collectively stress the primacy that now needs to be given to the empirical side of the rescaling question. That is, while the study of state rescaling must certainly be guided by theory, overall it remains a highly empirical question whose complexity, territorial embeddedness and potential contradictions are less likely to

Downloaded from cjres.oxfordjournals.org by guest on July 5, 2011

Rescaling the state yield results that correspond with theoretical expectations as compared to the study of other state society transformations. Moreover, Pike and Tomaney (2009) argue that theorizations about rescaling processes have tended to outstrip social scientists empirical grasp of actual patterns of change. In contrast to theories assuming a strategic and conscious central state deployment of devolutionary policies, their study of the UK nds the states agenda rife with conict, uncertainty and experimentation across territories and scales. Cox (2009) similarly calls for more convincing empirical work that is needed to challenge, elaborate and push forward theory. In sum, the authors contributing to this special issue scrutinize questions about spatial scale, decentralization and governance and appropriate research strategies that advance the body of work on rescaling the state as a whole. In addition, the authors grapple with a number of issues that speak to future work. ample, while Brenners (2004) work is a foundation for the rescaling-the-state literature, several authors raise questions about national applications of his stages of the rescaling of urban governance (e.g. spatial Keynesianism, endogenous development and urban locational policy). Cox (2009) argues that these stages cannot really apply to the U.S. case which as noted above has always reected a strong decentralized state. Moreover, he takes issue with the view of a profound shift in state regulatory capacities towards the subnational scale even in the UK and France. Scarpa (2009) similarly discusses not only the strengths but also the limitations of applying Brenners framework to the case of the development of social insurance programmes in Finland and Sweden. Another challenge comes in explaining the structural and discursive forces behind state-rescaling processes, particularly as these too vary from nation to nation. Decentralization, for example, can be topdown or bottom-up driven. In the U.S. case, one of the long-standing justications for decentralization particularly from the Reagan presidency onward was to shrink government at all levels, making decentralization a cornerstone of neoliberal policy. The major U.S. welfare reform legislation of 1996 involved devolution of the programme to states and counties, in part because neoliberal advocates believed that subnational governments would engage in a race to the bottom, cutting back on social programmes for the poor to avoid becoming welfare magnets while they catered to business interests (Lobao, 2007; Schram et al., 2008). Meanwhile in the EU case, the rationale for decentralizing has also been shifting from the traditional bottom-up issues of identity, culture, language or history to the pursuit of economic efciency (Rodr guez-Pose and Sandall, 2008), although there are important national variations. For example, in the case of Nordic countries, Scarpa (2009) suggests that equity and efciency considerations have played a strong role in decentralizing social insurance schemes, while as noted above, in the case of the UK, Pike and Tomaney (2009) see neoliberal state policy as inuencing the governance of economic development and reinforcing subnational inequality. 9

Downloaded from cjres.oxfordjournals.org by guest on July 5, 2011

Rescaling the state: challenges for future research


Collectively, the articles featured here raise questions and challenges for researchers. Overall the authors demonstrate that the meaning and signicance of state-rescaling processes are highly contextually dependent, particularly across nations. This poses inherent challenges for developing theory and for comparative research (see also Razin, 2000). Cox (2009), for example, notes that the USA historically has been one of the most highly decentralized nations in the world. This makes it difcult for U.S. scholars to draw from and appreciate European-oriented perspectives that appear to take the process as something new and vice versa. Scarpa (2009) also argues for the importance of national context. Even within the seemingly more homogenous Nordic welfare states, state-rescaling processes vary by historical, economic and institutional conditions distinct to each nation. In turn, the authors pose a related question: to what degree are core theoretical approaches transferable across different national contexts? For ex-

Lobao, Martin and Rodr guez-Pose As discussed earlier, debates about a relative decline of the nation state and rise of subnational (and supranational) forms of governance that framed foundational work have given way to an interrogation of the power of the nation state. This too has generated new questions and debates. Cox (2009) argues that views about a strong wave of decentralization in which EU localities have gained a great deal of autonomy relative to the past miss the bigger picture of the continued importance of central governments in local affairs. Plus, he notes that, despite the emergence of a host of regional parties and organizations, political parties in the EU continue to operate largely at the scale of the nation state and so represent yet another centralizing tendency. Other articles see more of a churning process occurring with no zero sum, rise or fall of the power of the nation state. In part this may reect the question of measurement and the point of Mart nez-Va zquez and Timofeev (2009) that different indicators can show alternative streams of decentralization/ centralization occurring across the same nations over time. However, Scarpa (2009) and Pike and Tomaney (2009) indicate more broadly that theorists have underestimated the role of central government in orchestrating and controlling subnational governance processes. Scarpa (2009) explains how the central governments of Finland and Sweden utilize municipal governments to deploy social insurance policy to achieve national goals of reducing economic inequality. Pike and Tomaney (2009) note that the rhetoric of devolution has helped the central state to pursue and achieve neoliberal goals. These and other authors demonstrate that the increasing importance of subnational governments is not incompatible with a continuing strong role of the national state. Finally, Brenner (2009) provides a capstone view of key challenges that remain. His article takes critical stock of the work to date and lays out future research directions. In brief, he argues that although research on the rescaling of the state continues to grow, there is as yet no broad consensus on exactly what this conceptual abstraction means and how it should be interpreted, theorized and empirically studied. Moreover, he cautions against the danger 10 of rescaling overload: an increasing tendency to wrap up state restructuring under the banner of rescaling in cases where this may not be applicable. He notes that in some sense, we are moving to a second round of state-rescaling research, where more systematic carving out of the topic is needed. He delineates three frontiers for this future work: developing stronger explanatory frameworks particularly at the mesolevel, more rigorous crossnational and other comparative analyses and better understanding of the scaled periodizations of contemporary capitalism. From the vantage of a body of work a decade in the making, and the challenges illustrated by and contributions of the articles featured here, broad directions for moving forward the literature on rescaling the state can be outlined. First, there is a need to overcome fragmentation and to draw together the various strands of literatures that have been brought to bear on the topic. This entails bridging more abstract theoretical perspectives on the state, such as those dealing with materialist and actor-oriented accounts as well as better integrating often disparately treated substantive literatures such as those attending to decentralization, governance, and social welfare and economic development policy. Second, as noted by a number of authors, researchers need to engage more fully with recent debates about spatial scale (Brenner, 2009; Cox, 2009; Keating et al., 2009; Pike and Tomaney, 2009). Not only may this lead to less rigid analytical treatments of scale in keeping with new developments in human geography, but more importantly it should better enable researchers to conceptually capture and understand the uidity of staterescaling processes. Third, greater attention should be given to the development of conceptual templates for studying state rescaling. This could help address challenges to research outlined above particularly with regard to comparative work. That is, theoretical generalizations need to be tempered with much more sensitivity to national context and paths of development. Cross-national work needs to more systematically attend to comparisons involving

Downloaded from cjres.oxfordjournals.org by guest on July 5, 2011

Rescaling the state subnational variations in statesociety and governance processes. Finally, state rescaling as a thematic research area merits wider scrutiny than we have been able to provide in this single issue. The articles received from our call for papers have an industrialized, western nation focus and emphasize distinct state processes such as decentralization. The literature would be broadened and enriched by studies from other parts of the globe, particularly from the less industrialized nations of the South and from attending to a wider canvas of governance processes involving growth and redistribution. Insofar as nation states are adapting to the contemporary global capitalist environment by reinventing and even expanding their roles via multiscalar governing strategies, new avenues of research are sure to be on the horizon. References
Amin, A. (1994) Post-Fordism: models, fantasies, and phantoms of transition. In A. Amin (ed.). Post-Fordism: A Reader, pp. 139. Oxford: Blackwell. Amin A, Tomaney J. (1995). Behind the Myth of European Union: Prospects for Cohesion. London: Routledge. Armstrong, H. W. (1995) An appraisal of the evidence from cross-sectional analysis of the regional growth process within the European Union. In H.W. Armstrong and R.W. Vickerman (eds.). Convergence and Divergence among European Regions, pp. 4065. London: Pion. Barro, R. J. and Sala-I-Mart n, X. X. (1991) Convergence across states and regions. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1: 107182. Brenner, N. (1999) Globalisation as reterritorialisation: the re-scaling of urban governance in the European Union. Urban Studies, 36: 431451. Brenner, N. (2003) Metropolitan institutional reform and the rescaling of state space in contemporary Western Europe. European Urban and Regional Studies, 10: 297324. Brenner, N. (2004) New State Spaces: Urban Governance and the Rescaling of Statehood. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Brenner, N. (2009) Open questions on state rescaling. Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy, and Society, 2. Buchs, M. (2009) Examining the interaction between vertical and horizontal dimensions of rescaling. Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy, and Society, 2. Cairncross, F. (1997) The Death of Distance. Cambridge, MA: Harvard Business School Press. Cox, K. R. (1997) Introduction: globalization and its politics in question. In K. Cox (ed.). Spaces of globalization: reasserting the power of the local, pp. 118. New York: Guilford. Cox, K. (2009) Rescaling the state in question. Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy, and Society, 2. Donahue, J. D. (1997) Disunited States. New York: Harper Collins Publishers, Basic Books. Esping-Andersen, G. (1990) The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Goodwin, M., Jones, M. and Jones, R. (2005) Devolution, constitutional change and economic development: explaining and understanding the new institutional geographies of the British state. Regional Studies, 39: 44214436. Hirst, P. and Thompson, G. (1995) Globalization and the future of the nation-state. Economy and Society, 24: 408442. Hirst, P. and Thompson, G. (1999) Globalization in Question. Cambridge: Polity Press. Hooghe, L. (1996) Building a Europe with the regions: the changing role of the European Commission. In L. Hooghe (ed.). Cohesion Policy and European Integration: Building Multi-Level Governance. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Jessop, B. (1990) State Theory: Putting Capitalist States in Their Place. Oxford: Blackwell. Jessop, B. (1993) From the Keynesian welfare to the Schumpeterian-workfare state. In R. Burrows and B. Loader (eds.). Towards a Post-Fordist Welfare State?, pp. 1337. London: Routledge. Jessop, B. (1995) The future of the nation state in Europe: erosion or reorganization? WP50, Political Economy of Local Governance Series. Lancaster: Department of Sociology, University of Lancaster. Jessop, B. (2000) The crisis of the national spatio-temporal x and the tendential ecological dominance of globalizing capitalism. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research, 24: 323360. Jessop, B. (2002) The Future of the Capitalist State. Cambridge: Polity Press. Jessop, B. (2004) Hollowing out the nation-state and multilevel governance. In Patricia Kennett (ed.). Handbook of Comparative Social Policy. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 1125. Jones, M. (2001) The rise of the regional state in economic governance: partnerships for prosperity or new scales of state power? Environment and Planning A, 33: 11851211. Keating, M. (1997) The invention of regions: political restructuring and territorial government in Western Europe. Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy, 15: 383398.

Downloaded from cjres.oxfordjournals.org by guest on July 5, 2011

11

Lobao, Martin and Rodr guez-Pose


Keating, M., Cairney, P. and Hepburn, E. (2009) Territorial policy communities and devolution in the United Kingdom. Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy, and Society, 2. Lobao, L. (2007) The local state, decentralization, and neoliberal roll-out: a comparative subnational analysis of growth and redistribution responses. Research in Political Sociology, 16: 85118. Lo pez-Bazo, E., Vaya , E. and Mora, A. J., et al. (1999) Regional economic dynamics and convergence in the European Union. Annals of Regional Science, 33: 343370. MacLeod, G. and Goodwin, M. (1999) Reconstructing an urban and regional political economy: on the state, politics, scale, and explanation. Political Geography, 18: 697730. Manseld, B. (2005) Beyond rescaling: reintegrating the national as a dimension of scalar relations. Progress in Human Geography, 29: 258273. Marston, S., Jones III., J. P. and Woodward, K. (2005) Human geography without scale. Transactions of the Institute of British Geographers, 30: 416432. Martin, R. L. and Sunley, P. J. (1997) The post-Keynesian state and the space economy. In R. Lee and J. Wills (eds.). Geographies of Economies, pp. 278289. London: Arnold. Martinez-Vazquez, J. and Timofeev, T. (2009) A scal perspective of state rescaling. Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy, and Society, 2. Milward, A. S. (1992) The European Rescue of the NationState. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Moore, A. (2008) Rethinking scale as a geographical category: from analysis to practice. Progress in Human Geography, 32: 203225. OBrien, R. (1992) Global Financial Integration: The End of Geography. London: Royal Institute of International Affairs. Ohmae, K. (1995) The End of the Nation-State: The Rise of Regional Economies. New York: The Free Press. Painter, J. (2001) State and governance. In E. Sheppard and T. Barnes (eds.). A Companion to Economic Geography, pp. 359376. Oxford: Blackwell. Peck, J. (2001) Neoliberalising states. Progress in Human Geography, 25: 445455. Peck, J. and Tickell, (1994) Searching for a new institutional x: the after-Fordist crisis and the local-global disorder. In A. Amin (ed.). Post-Fordism: A Reader, pp. 280315. Oxford: Blackwell. Pike, A., Rodr guez-Pose, A. and Tomaney, J. (2007) What kind of local and regional development and for whom? Regional Studies, 41: 12531269. Pike, A. and Tomaney, J. (2009) Sub-national governance and economic development: the case of England in post-devolution UK. Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy, and Society, 2: . Radice, H. (1984) The national economy: a Keynesian myth. Capital and Class, 22: 111140. Razin, E. (2000) The impact of local government organization on development and disparities: a comparative perspective. Environment and Planning C, 18: 1731. Rodr guez-Pose, A. and Gill, N. (2003) The global trend towards devolution and its implications. Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy, 21: 333351. Rodr guez-Pose, A. and Sandall, R. (2008) From identity to the economy: analysing the evolution of the decentralisation discourse. Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy, 26: 5472. Scarpa, S. (2009) The scalar dimension of welfare state development: the case of Swedish and Finnish assistance systems. Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy, and Society, 2. Schram, S., Fording, R. C. and Soss, J. (2008) Neo-liberal poverty governance: race, place, and the punitive turn in U.S. welfare policy. Cambridge Journal of Regions, Economy, and Society, 1: 1736. Tomaney, J. and Ward, N. (2000) England and the new regionalism. Regional Studies, 34: 471478.
Received on January 6, 2009; accepted on January 6, 2009

Downloaded from cjres.oxfordjournals.org by guest on July 5, 2011

12

You might also like