You are on page 1of 20

7976 Chapter 1 p1-17.qxd 23.05.

2003 15:54 Page 1

PART 1 Foundation
European economic integration has become a specialisation in its own right. It has
developed its own terminology and concepts. Its current significance is still influenced
by its historical background and the forms of development of the European Union
since the 1950s. To understand European integration methods, the economic frame-
work implicit in the main treaties should be outlined and inspected more closely. Of
course, the given economic framework and integration methods need not be optimal.
The normative questions for an economist to ask are why regulate (or intervene) at
the EU or national level of government, as well as how to regulate.
Together, these concepts, developments, methods and basic questions form the
substance of Part 1 on Foundations. Chapter 1 asks what economic integration is,
and its significance in Europe. In answering this, it also introduces the necessary
terminology and definitions. Chapter 2 outlines the development of the European
Union up to the Maastricht Treaty, with the help of some general illustrations and
concepts. Chapter 3 provides an economic perspective of the Rome Treaty of 1957,
initiating the European Economic Community, and its three re-visions, the Single
European Act, the Maastricht Treaty and the Amsterdam Treaty. The presentation is
kept concise and accessible by means of comparable flow charts. Chapter 4 poses
the question what public economic functions the Union should exercise, and how. An
economic analysis, based on the subsidiarity principle (a decentralisation principle
prevalent in federations), provides a framework for answering these questions in
general. Moreover, a subsidiarity test is developed which will be applied throughout
the remainder of the book for all kinds of specific economic powers of the Union.
7976 Chapter 1 p1-17.qxd 23.05.2003 15:54 Page 2

CHAPTER 1 What is Economic Integration?

Topics covered Economic integration has attracted increasing attention since the early
1.1 Definition and significance postwar period. Under the names of ‘regional economic integration’ or
‘economic regionalism’, it is distinguished from worldwide integration of
1.2 Economic and political national economies. 1 Although the study of economic integration has
integration
been inspired, if not dominated, by the European example, less
1.3 Market integration and advanced forms of economic integration can now be found in all conti-
other forms nents. For analytical purposes economic integration should be defined
1.4 The stages of economic independently from the European ex-perience. Section 1.1 defines
integration economic integration and points out its fundamental significance.
Sections 1.2 and 1.3 briefly discuss the relevance of political integration
1.5 Economic integration and
the WTO
and various institutional ambitions – especially the ‘Community method’
– to economic integration in Europe. Conceptual refinements of
1.6 Economic integration economic integration are introduced in 1.4 (market integration) and 1.5
and economic federalism (the stages of economic integration). The ‘stages approach’ remains a
1.7 Summary basic tool to understand economic integration, although the substance
Appendix 1.1 European and significance of stages have been amended over time.
institutions – a brief guide Economic regionalism divides the world into preferred and discrimi-
nated partners. Therefore, the compatibility of regional integration and
Appendix 1.2 New numbering of the GATT/WTO (1.6) is crucial. Finally, there is the increasing similarity
treaty articles following
between economic integration and economic federalism, the more ambi-
Amsterdam
tious economic integration becomes. For the European Union this
implies that the economics of federalism (a specialisation first developed
in public economics) may hold lessons for the economics of integration
(1.7).

1.1. Definition and significance

Economic integration is defined as the elimination of economic frontiers


between two or more economies. In turn, an economic frontier is any
demarcation over which actual and potential mobilities of goods, serv-

1Note that ‘regions’ in this jargon refers to groupings of countries or continents.


However, in the present book, ‘regions’ will be used to refer to parts of countries,
unless stated otherwise.
7976 Chapter 1 p1-17.qxd 23.05.2003 15:54 Page 3

What is Economic Integration? 3

ices and production factors, as well as communica- or the concept of the nation state, economic integra-
tion flows, are relatively low. On both sides of an tion would boil down to pure market integration –
economic frontier, the determination of prices and presumably apolitical. In the real world, economic
quality of goods, services and factors, is influenced integration is always to some extent political. When
only marginally by the flows, over the frontier. modest ambitions prevail, the politics of economic
There is no a priori reason for assuming that integration will largely remain domestic, apart from
economic frontiers coincide with territorial frontiers: coalition formation and negotiation of the classical
countries are demarcated by territorial frontiers and intergovernmental type. Higher ambitions of
economies by economic frontiers. Thus, local economic integration tend to be accommodated by,
economies need not always add up to one regional or to result from, political integration processes.
economy, if economic frontiers between different
local communities persist. Likewise, economic
frontiers between regions may inhibit national
economic integration. European economic integra- 1.2 Economic and political integration
tion is driven by efforts to reduce or eliminate the
public role of territorial frontiers with European
neighbours as economic frontiers. But, as the defi- The relation between economic and political inte-
nition implies, this is a necessary not a sufficient gration may differ from case to case. Clearly,
condition for economic integration. Demarcations interregional economic integration within one
within and between national economies may country assumes a close correspondence between
remain, perhaps as a result of natural barriers (e.g. (national) economic and political integration.
mountains, sea) the costs of which have not been Nevertheless the Sun-belt in the US, after the Civil
sufficiently reduced by infrastructural and transport War (1861–65), remained less than fully integrated
provisions, or perhaps as a result of great dispari- in the US economy for perhaps as long as 80–90
ties in the levels of development, or perhaps as a years. Similarly, the Mezzogiorno (Italy, south of
result of business collusion in a region or country. Naples) failed to be integrated economically long
Even discrepancies in the availability, speed and after political unification of Italy was completed
quality of information might sometimes serve as an (1870). The processes of economic and political
economic frontier. integration in the European Union have been linked
The fundamental significance of economic inte- from the start. Apart from historical reasons, the
gration is the increase of actual or potential perceived threat of communism and the allied Cold
competition. From the vantage point of one region or War played a major role in blending economics and
country this competition is engendered both by politics. Efforts to forge union in Western Europe
market participants originating elsewhere in the have been numerous and several attempts
country (in case of interregional integration) or group preceding the EEC treaty of 1957 were overtly polit-
of countries (e.g. in the European Community) and ical (see chapter 2). Thus, the European Coal and
by their own participants reaching out beyond the Steel Community (ECSC) was founded in 1951,
traditional confines of the economy. following a dramatic appeal by French foreign
Competition by market participants is likely to minister Robert Schuman in May 1950 to place the
lead to lower prices for similar goods or services, to two most important sectors for war-making at the
greater quality variation and wider choice for the time – coal and steel – under one supranational
integrating area, as well as to a general impetus for authority so as to preclude another French–German
change. Product designs, services methods, war. European security was, therefore, the main
production and distribution systems and many other aim of the ECSC and sectoral market integration
aspects become subject to actual or potential chal- merely the means. In 1952–53 proposals both for a
lenge. They may induce changes in the direction European Political Union and for a European
and intensity of innovation and in working habits. Defence Community were submitted to, for
However, as will be shown in chapter 4, economic example, the French parliament – and almost
integration will also expose regional or national accepted. The EEC treaty of 1957 contains traces
governments to competition, with interesting conse- of the desire for political integration as the preamble
quences. avows to strive for ‘an ever closer union among the
In a fantasy world without national governments
7976 Chapter 1 p1-17.qxd 23.05.2003 15:54 Page 4

4 Foundation

peoples of Europe’. some neutral, non-socialist countries not joining


There is little doubt that the implicit desire to the final EEC negotiations in 1956 (see chapter 2).
pursue political integration via the economic means Although these conclusions are hardly
specified in the Rome Treaty was a major reason contested, their meaning for the nature and
for the United Kingdom, Denmark, Norway and process of economic integration is unclear. Political

Community method moves distinctly beyond this


ADDITIONAL READING conditional approach. The ECSC and EEC treaties,
and the three revisions of the latter,4 assign certain
competences exclusively to the Community level; both
Institutional aspects of economic
also establish a common Court, the rulings of which
integration**
override national law or court rulings. This ambitious
approach affects national sovereignty, of course, but
This book will not analyse the institutions and de-cision it does not imply a ‘loss’ of sovereignty: through
making methods of the EU and, more narrowly, the EC. ‘pooling’, sovereignty is jointly exercised in the rele-
A summary is provided in Appendix 1.1 to this chapter. vant policy areas. The preparedness to go so far
But in two related aspects the so-called ‘Community removes a major and obstinate political barrier to the
method’ implies unique properties which have prob- pursuit of economic integration. But it is a two-edged
ably helped the EC to pursue economic integration sword, as the ambition may, at times, develop from a
further than anywhere else in the world and hence facilitating factor into a source of profound political
ought to be mentioned specifically: supranationality discord. This may happen when domestic politics in
and pooling of sovereignty. Virtually all efforts in the one or more of the Member States develops extreme
world economy to pursue economic integration in a sensitivities to the adjustment costs of integration. It
group of countries, including multilateral reduction of is also bound to occur when some countries do not
economic frontiers worldwide, are subject to severe wish to accept the full regulatory or policy conse-
constraints imposed by national sovereignty. Countries quences of the integration they pledged to pursue.
may, of course, voluntarily limit their exercise of certain The discord may even go so far as to disrupt
sovereign rights in treaties or agreements, for example economic integration.
to liberalise trade in a group or worldwide. But such Supranationality is closely intertwined with the
treaties will always be conditional and all important pooling of sovereignty. The former is associated with
decisions other than implementation will be taken the establishment of common institutions, such as
unanimously. In other words, a country can always the High Authority (in the ECSC), the Commission (in
exercise their right of veto or opt out. the EEC and Euratom treaties) and the EC Court of
Also, judicial review of suspected infringements of Justice, in all of which powers are vested far beyond
the commonly agreed rules will either not exist or not those normally assigned to international secretariats.
be binding. Lacking judicial review, all that remains For instance, the European Commission has the sole
are political, quasi-legal or bureaucratic dispute- right of initiative in proposing EC legislation. In other
settlement procedures which carefully avoid touching words, although the Council of Ministers will dispose,
the sovereignty of the countries involved. The it cannot propose draft legislation. In addition, the

**See ‘How the Read this Book’ on page xxii.


4The Single European Act, in force since July 1987, the Maastricht Treaty, in force since November 1993,

and the Amsterdam Treaty, in force since May 1999. See chapters 2 and 3.

2As explained in chapters 2 and 3 the EC and the European Union (EU) are not synonymous. In this book the EU

will generally be used to indicate the Union in past and present, although formally the Union has only existed since the
Maastricht Treaty. EC is only used where legally this is required. Both the EU and the EC refer to treaty articles as well
(see Appendix 1.2)
3A significant exception was that only democratic European countries with an acceptable human rights record can
7976 Chapter 1 p1-17.qxd 23.05.2003 15:54 Page 5

What is Economic Integration? 5

avowed aim.
ADDITIONAL READING continued At the same time, one should acknowledge that in
the actual operation of the Community the notions of
Commission has considerable monitoring powers, as pooled sovereignty and supranationality have become
the ‘guardian of the treaty’, for implementation and as blurred. In this respect two relevant characteristics of
the executive branch at the EC level for today’s process are ‘intergovernmentalism’ and ‘coop-
selected EC policy areas (for example, competi- erative federalism’. Both properties are blended with
tion). The other important aspect of supra-nationality is the old ones into a complex and subtle system of deci-
the possibility of being outvoted in the Council of sion making that probably increases the legitimacy of
Ministers, by simple or qualified majority voting. On the the European integration process.
face of it, this is merely a matter of degree since quali- Intergovernmentalism refers to classical bargaining
fied majority voting is not entirely unknown in and coalition formation among national governments
international organisations. There is a significant quali- seeking consensus, if not explicit unanimity. As a
tative difference, however. Its importance in the Union result of a strong tendency in the Council of Ministers
derives from two characteristics. First, the economic to work intergovernmentally, the scope for (qualified)
importance and range of policy areas subject to (quali- majority voting in the original Rome Treaty was hardly
fied) majority voting has always been much larger than used. The so-called Luxemburg compromise of 19667
in any other inter-national body, and the three treaty led some Union countries to practice a veto policy and
revisions have drastically increased the weight of these thereby undermine this aspect of supranationality.
policy areas.5 Second, unlike in other international Only after 1985 did majority voting actually become
bodies, the Union has no general opt-out provisions prominent: the old majority-voting articles were regu-
and no recognised right of exit (’secession’), while the larly applied, once consensus proved impossible, and
(Amsterdam) Treaty itself does not have an expiry several important policy areas – including many
date,6 all elements which greatly increase the sensi- internal market issues – were newly subjected to
tivity to possibilities of being outvoted. majority procedures. Intergovernmentalism also
It is not the task of this book to assess or quantify raised its head where powers had been assigned to
the impact of these institutional properties on economic the European Commission. By what has become
integration in general. It will be obvious to the reader known as ‘comitology’, the Commission sought, or was
that when political views differ fundamentally among forced, to consult the Member States on numerous
Member States, even these properties will become less details of implementation decisions. Having become
important. However, as will be shown throughout the constricted in a huge web of advisory and other
text, the Community has actually been able to accom- committees composed of civil servants from the
modate a considerable divergence of perspectives and Member States, the actual exercise of Commission
simultaneously achieved far-reaching progress in competences became more and more dependent on
economic integration. Moreover, the stability of the processes akin to intergovernmental bargaining.
accomplishments has proved to be robust, despite The developments are also related to substance
several upheavals, crises and several enlargements and not merely to procedure. From an economic
from six to fifteen Member States. It is hardly conceiv- perspective, the institutional design of the
able that such impressive results could have been had Community is critical for the efficiency and effective-
without the ‘Community method’, facilitated by a polit- ness of the public economic functions exercised at EC
ical climate in which ambitious integration was an level. Chapter 4 discusses not only the economic

5When the second edition went to press, a fourth revision of the treaty was expected to be signed in Nice,

December 2000. Once again, the range of provisions to be subject to qualified majority voting was proposed to
increase further.
6The ECSC treaty does expire in 2002. However, it will be absorbed into the EC treaty, as part of the

Amsterdam (or perhaps the expected Nice) Treaty on European Union. A new Art. 7, EU (note, not EC) enables
the Union to suspend certain rights (including voting rights) of a Member State in the event of a ‘serious and
persistent breach’ of basic EU principles. However, it cannot be expelled.
7After an institutional and political crisis about proposed new powers for the Commission and the right of veto

in case of a ‘vital’ interest, Member States ‘agreed to disagree’ on vetoing in 1966. Of course, the core of the
7976 Chapter 1 p1-17.qxd 23.05.2003 15:54 Page 6

6 Foundation

‘guardian’ function and the EC Court as guarantees


ADDITIONAL READING continued for market integration and the desired minimum of
communality. At the same time, Union policies
rationale for assigning certain economic functions to and regulation can be based on principles
the Community level, but also to some extent how respecting the remaining autonomy of Member
these functions ought to be exercised. Least-cost States as much as possible, while inducing the same
methods of joint regulation and adequate solutions Member States to cooperate among themselves
for accountability and legitimacy of public policy will and/or with the Commission so as to facilitate
foster efficiency and effectiveness. In this sense inter- the achieved market integration.
governmentalism has a Janus-like face. In some It may be very misleading to assess institutional
cases it may result in inefficient decision making and aspects of European integration without explicit refer-
excessive Member States’ control of the Commission, ence to the achieved degree of economic integration.
thereby undermining an asset of the Community It is precisely due to the Community method that the
method. In other cases it may justifiably express ‘acquis communautaire’ – the accomplishments at
concerns of accountability (at least, to Member EC level in Community law and jurisprudence – is
States’ administrations) or legitimacy, and serve as a
robust and not subject to erosion.
channel to reveal the spectrum of preferences and
Intergovernmentalism and far-reaching involvement
improve information flows about experiences and
of the Member States do not change that. Rather,
problems. If construed in the latter way, it may help
given today’s acquis as well as the ‘Community
the Community achieve better rules and policies.
method’, intergovernmentalism which adds coopera-
There is, in other words, an efficiency case for the
enmeshing of Member States with Union powers and tion to the acquis, may even enhance European
their exercise. Nevertheless, the case has to be made integration significantly. The EC treaty has been
every time because it is easily abused by the Member revised three times and this constitutional process is,
States. by definition, a matter of intergovernmentalism par
Cooperative federalism strengthens the view that excellence, made more difficult still by ratification in
Member States’ involvement with Union competences all the Member States. Yet, major break-throughs
need not necessarily imply a breakdown of suprana- were adopted (see chapter 3).
tionality. It holds, on the contrary, that once a high
degree of market integration has been accomplished,
the Union level may find it more effective to share the
enforcement and executive functions with the institu-
tions of the Member States. In cooperative
federalism, this would work for four reasons: common
principles, Commission monitoring, the Commission’s

motives may explain the institutional set-up of the the political aim(s) of the Community have influ-
original EEC. But the subsequent development of enced the nature and process of economic
the Community was almost entirely driven by integration in the EC. Some landmark de-cisions in
market integration and selective common EU history are impossible to explain, however,
economic policies, not by foreign policy coopera- without recourse to elusive, but persistent feelings
tion, or matters of security or defence until the late of pursuing common political aims, especially in
1980s and early 1990s. Also, key political issues in times of perceived crisis (see chapter 2).
domestic political processes of the Member States
such as employment, inflation, social security,
domestic security or societal values were hardly
affected by the European Community (EC)2 for
several decades.3 In actual practice, therefore, it is 1.3 Market integration and other forms
exceedingly hard to trace how and to what extent
7976 Chapter 1 p1-17.qxd 23.05.2003 15:54 Page 7

What is Economic Integration? 7

Economic integration refers both to market integra- together. The often heard claim that less ambitious
tion and (economic) policy integration. Market forms of economic integration can solely rely on
integration is and remains the essence of economic negative integration is not borne out in actual prac-
integration, as is clear from the definition of the tice. Of course, weak and incomplete preferential
latter. Most economic policies directly relate to trade arrangements will at most allow joint moni-
market conduct, or to structure, performance or toring and perhaps an attempt at
distributive outcomes of markets. Market integration dispute-settlement. If these (very modest) common
is a behaviourial notion indicating that activities of powers are not exercised, one can scarcely expect
market participants in different regions or Member regional trade liberalisation to work well. The EU
States are geared to supply-and-demand conditions engages in ambitious forms of economic integration
in the entire Union (or other relevant area). Usually, and they require an appropriate combination of
this will also show up in significant cross-frontier positive and negative integration. However, there
movements of goods, services and factors. Potential, are no unique solutions or hard and fast rules. This
but not actually observed, flows may also be impor- is true even for economic federalism, a level of
tant in constraining suppliers’ price conduct or in accomplishment the Union has not fully achieved:
consumer behaviour. In a market of perfectly homog- the combinations of negative and positive integra-
enous goods or services or one type of financial tion in the Canadian, the US and the EU internal
capital, market integration can be mea-sured by the markets – as currently achieved – are all distinct
degree of price convergence. (Pelkmans & Vanheukelen, 1988).
Compared to market integration, policy integra-
tion is a less precise concept. It may cover very
different types of economic policies, using different
kinds of instruments. Moreover, the degree of 1.4 The stages of economic integration
‘binding’ and commonness may vary, from consulta-
tion and cooperation via coordination and
‘approximated’ national rules to common policies or The complexity of economic integration, and the
fully fledged centralisation. To make matters even radically diverging degrees of intensity, have led
more complicated, some elements of policy will be analysts to distinguish several stages of economic
expressed in specific regulation and others in integration. The stages approach dates back to
powers leaving a large degree of discretion, the Balassa (1961) and its usage is widespread.
use of which may vary over time and also involve Though the original Balassa-stages have to be
non-regulatory means such as budgetary expendi- amended in various ways, the approach is indis-
ture. Policy integration cannot, therefore, be pensable for an understanding of the literature and
measured in any straightforward way. Indeed, of key-issues in policy making. In addressing the
whereas there is a strong presumption that market drawbacks one can gain some insight into the
integration (if not distorted) is generally welfare- learning process which the study of European
increasing, more policy integration may or may not economic integration has gone through since the
be good for aggregate welfare. early 1960s. Table 1.1 provides the five Balassa
Another important distinction is that between stages and describes a few of their characteristics.
positive and negative integration, originated by The stages are presented sequentially for analyt-
Tinbergen (1954). Negative integration denotes the ical reasons. However, there is no compelling
removal of discrimination in national economic rules reason to follow the sequence rigidly. For instance,
and policies under joint surveillance. Positive inte- the EEC started with a customs union, not a free
gration refers to the transfer to common institutions, trade area. The sequence is helpful for under-
or the joint exercise, of at least some powers. 8 In standing the additionality in each stage when
practice, negative and positive integration will go

8The words positive and negative do not have any normative value with respect to ‘welfare’ or otherwise. They have

become mere jargon.


9CER, also called ANZCERTA, is the Australia/New Zealand Closer Economic Relations Trade Agreement, in force

since 1983. For a summary view, see GATT (1994) Trade Policy Review–Australia, Vol.1, pp. 30–33.
10NAFTA is the North American free trade area, between Canada, the USA and Mexico, concluded in 1992. For an

authoriative survey, see Hufbauer & Schott, 1992. In fact, both CER and NAFTA contain some elements of a common
market in that they deal with intellectual property rights and the right of establishment (without going very far, as yet).
7976 Chapter 1 p1-17.qxd 23.05.2003 15:54 Page 8

8 Foundation

Stage Definition Characteristics/comments

Free trade area (FTA) * tariffs and quotas abolished essence of GATT definition;
for imports from area members no positive integration
* area members retain
national tariffs (and quotas)
against third countries

Customs union (CU) * suppressing discrimination for essence of GATT definition:


CU members in product markets no positive integration
* equalisation of tariffs (and no
or common quotas) in trade
with non-members

Common market (CM) * a CU which also abolishes is ‘beyond’ GATT; definition should
restrictions on factor movements also include services; no positive
integration

Economic union * a CM with ‘some degree of positive integration introduced;


harmonisation of national economic extremely vague
policies in order to remove
discrimination ... due to disparities
in these policies’

Total economic integration * ‘unification of monetary, fiscal, social centralist; vision of unitary state;
and counter cyclical policies’ supranationality only introduced
here
* ‘setting up of a supranational authority
where decisions are binding for the

Source: Balassa, 1961

increasing ambitions in economic integration. tive integration deprives these notions of practical
It is important to reflect upon the limitations and applicability. This drawback is less severe in the
problems of this classical view. First, in the world case of an FTA as an FTA does not even have a
economy today there are a number of preferential common external tariff. A simple FTA is the one
trading arrangements whose ambitions do not between the EC and the respective EFTA
match even the first stage of Table 1.1. These pref- (European Free Trade Association) countries,
erential arrangements may be limited in the scope established in 1972: positive integration is confined
of products covered, and tariffs (and quotas) for to origin and other customs matters. However, the
intra-group imports are not fully removed. GATT Stockholm Treaty (1960) establishing EFTA does
allows this for developing countries, not for devel- include modest forms of joint management and, for
oped ones. A special case is sectoral integration, example, occasional harmonisation in selected
such as the ECSC for coal and steel or the 1965 cases (Curzon Price, 1974). Recent free trade
US–Canada automotive agreement. For developed areas among developed countries go much further
countries such sectoral initiatives require a so- in product scope (for example, including some
called waiver, that is, a derogation from GATT. aspects of services) and in approximation of
Second, although the FTA and the CU defini- certain forms of economic regulation. This is true
tions capture the essence of the GATT definitions for the CER agreement between Australia and New
and are therefore widely used, the absence of posi- Zealand 9 and NAFTA.10 The Free trade area that

11Assuming quotas to be reconverted into tariff equivalents


12In Balassa (1976) the author revisits his former classification and acknowledges particularly the problem of
including the appropriate degree of positive integration for the CM.
7976 Chapter 1 p1-17.qxd 23.05.2003 15:54 Page 9

What is Economic Integration? 9

goes furthest is the European Economic Area does not answer the question of what that ‘neces-
(EEA) concluded between the EC and most EFTA sary positive integration for the common market to
countries in 1992: the EEA is a hybrid of a free trade function properly’ is. This question will be tackled in
area for industrial goods and for services with far- chapter 4, with the principle of subsidiarity – a
reaching approximation (that is, making more derivative of the economic theory of federalism.
uniform) of economic regulation, plus a common Chapters 7 and 9 deal with the free movement of
court (see chapter 18). services and factors respectively, in light
In the case of customs unions, however, the of this adapted definition of a CM.
absence of positive integration is simply Fourth, there is a conceptual problem about
misleading. It is possible to conceive of a customs how to distinguish Balassa’s common market and
union as a tariff union11 only. Even in that event, economic union. Balassa’s economic union comes
however, tariff classifications have to be unified, close to our adapted definition of a CM, combining
customs rules harmonised to a large extent and the positive and negative integration. The
issue of the distribution of tariff revenues has to be Balassa definitions in Table 1.1, however, lead to
addressed. In actual practice, many more elements an unhelpful dichotomy between, on the one hand,
of trade policy will be under pressure to be approxi- the CM as confined to free movements without
mated, made compatible or transferred to common attention to discrimination and distortions, and, on
institutions. So, positive integration is already of
the other hand, the ‘higher’ stage of economic
some importance in a tariff union. This might
union, where the liberalisation leading to the free
include anti-dumping, the conclusion of trade
movements is duly accompanied by positive in-
treaties and negotiations in GATT. The EC customs
tegration with a view to reducing or preventing
union, and the older Benelux customs union, have
gone much further than a mere tariff union. The discrimination and distortions. Unless one is willing
Community included a common agricultural policy to make extreme assumptions about the role of
so as to allow for intra-union agricultural trade to be governments in the economy, it is inconceivable
free (see chapter 11). It also established a common that the Balassa CM can exist in its own right.13 In
competition policy so that intra-EC trade would not actual practice, therefore, his third and fourth
be distorted by adverse business conduct (see stages should be taken together, as is done in our
chapter 12). Furthermore, the Community relied definition of the CM. It prompts the question
upon open-ended provisions for the approximation whether there remains a place for such a thing as
or uniformity of economic regulation (see chapters an economic union in Union practice. This is not a
4 and 5) and some indirect taxation (see 5.4.3). semantic problem. The EC Treaty includes an
Third, the Balassa CM suffers also from the ‘economic union’, without defining it, however.
absence of positive integration. It ignores the Chapter 17 explains the importance of this
cross-border pro-vision of services, too. Taking economic union and provides a conceptual discus-
Balassa literally, the CM would neither imply sion.
approximation of national economic regulation nor Fifth, defining the final stage as total economic
any transfer of regulatory powers to the Union, nor integration is unwarranted. The framework of refer-
any harmonisation of direct or indirect taxation, let ence would appear to be that of a unitary state,
alone any transfer of tax powers or, for instance, which is unlikely to be appropriate both on
Union competences for a common competition economic and political grounds. One could
policy.12 The shortcomings of this CM concept are envisage several partial ‘unions’ beyond the
so serious that an adapted definition should be economic union, such as a tax union, a social
used to prevent misunderstandings: a common union, a monetary union and a political union (with
market attains the free movement of products, the relevant budgetary and economic policy
services and factors of production accompanied by aspects). Whether and why they should be
the necessary positive integration for the common embraced can be analysed with the help of the
market to function properly. The stages theory economic theory of federalism, given alternative

13Moreover, as chapter 16 will show, a pure CM à la Balassa would be unstable for reasons having to do with

financial capital mobility and the autonomy of national monetary and exchange rate policies.
14The reader is referred to well-known works on the GATT, e.g. Jackson (1990), or Hoekman & Kostecki (1995); for

the Marrakesh (Uruguay Round) package, see GATT (1994).


7976 Chapter 1 p1-17.qxd 23.05.2003 15:54 Page 10

10 Foundation

political assumptions about the readiness to pool Sixth, the introduction of supranationality only in
sovereignty. Such an approach rejects the Balassa the final stage cannot be justified either on
presumption of ‘unification’ and seeks to justify the economic or empirical grounds.
proper degree of (de)centralisation within such
‘unions’ on economic grounds.

complied with announced timetables for FTAs .


ADDITIONAL READING
Third, developing countries have obtained a special
‘enabling clause’ of ‘special and differentiated treat-
Article 24, para. 8 says: ‘A free trade area shall be ment’ in the GATT. The relation between the enabling
understood to mean a group of two or more customs clause and Art. 24 is controversial (Hoekman &
territories in which the duties and other restrictive Kostecki, 1995, p. 221) and this has given developing
regulations of commerce ... are elimin- ated on countries de facto unlimited discretion to conclude
substantially all the trade between the constituent incomplete preferential agreements or any kind of
territories in products originating in such territories’. (partial) FTAs. It would seem that this discretion has
This is essentially the same as the FTA in Table 1.1 reduced under GATT/WTO agreements, concluded in
but some interesting specifications are added. First, Marrakesh in 1994.
rather than quotas, the GATT speaks of a much more Finally, there is reference to products ‘originating’
encompassing category of ‘other restrictive regula- from FTA countries. In other words, since products
tions of commerce’. In actual GATT practice, this has from third countries are subjected to national trade
covered little more than quotas and import licences policies in an FTA, and since these will differ, the FTA
for product trade. There is no economic reason why will need certificates-of-origin. Without such adminis-
‘other restrictive regulations’ could not include a host trative controls, trade would be deflected via low-tariff
of other economic regulations which somehow FTA members, before enjoying zero-tariff access to
restrict exchange in the FTA. As noted, some recently high-tariff FTA members. The certificates enable
concluded or upgraded FTAs tend to go far beyond customs officers to prevent this trade deflection.
the traditional FTAs in these respects. At the same These certificates will accompany any intra-FTA
time, many FTAs have kept numerous exceptions in import and export of goods. There is an administra-
place, given the vagueness of the GATT definition. tive and an economic problem here. The former may
Second, there are ways FTAs can remain economi- become a burden for complex goods with multi-
cally incomplete, even when only tariffs and quotas country origin, which is a frequent phenomenon in
are considered: today’s world trade with refined specialisation and
global networks of subcontractors. The latter may
1 ‘substantially all the trade’ should be covered: it
arise from attempts to reduce the complications of
has been commonly accepted that agriculture is
establishing origin, whenever origin from FTA
excluded (for example in EFTA) or only included
members is not close to 100 per cent. In these cases,
selectively (for example, the Union’s FTAs with
usually a simple cut-off rule is applied, say, intra-FTA
Mediterranean countries), since the GATT
free trade applies to all goods with at least 50 per
obligations on agriculture were minimal before
cent origin in FTA members. However, such simple
the conclusion of the Uruguay Round; however,
origin rules can conceal protectionist attitudes, if the
many FTAs also employ ‘exclusion lists’ (for
cut-off share is high (for example, 65 per cent for cars
example the ASEAN Free Trade Area).
in NAFTA), if the methods for establishing the origin
2 interim agreements (para. 5, Art. 24) are also share are costly and discretionary, or if there is no
possible, provided they lead to a FTA (or CU) cumulative origin for the FTA as a whole but only
within a ‘reasonable’ time; since many FTAs origin per individual FTA member. Of course, the incli-
among developing countries in the 1960s and nation to employ these technicalities for
1970s failed to progress, this provision has not trade-restrictive purposes will be higher, the wider the
been taken seriously; the EU has broadly absolute and relative discrepancies are among the
7976 Chapter 1 p1-17.qxd 23.05.2003 15:54 Page 11

What is Economic Integration? 11

about ‘substantially the same duties and other regu-


ADDITIONAL READING continued lations of commerce’.15 However, the EC’s customs
union simply installed a common external tariff (CET).
national trade policies in the FTA. About ‘other regulations’, one may note that even
On customs unions, the same GATT article says: the ambitious EU had major difficulties in unifying its
external trade policy. A notorious problem (until
A customs union shall be understood to mean the
substitution of a single customs territory for two or 1992) were national quotas for third-country imports,
more customs territories so that especially in clothing and cars (see 6.5.3 and chapter
13). Once quotas are national, it may pay for traders
(i) duties and other restrictive regulations of to go for trade deflection, even in a CU. Thus, for
commerce ... are eliminated with respect to
proper quota enforcement at the national level, the
substantially all the trade between the constituent
CU will be forced to impose certificates of origin for
territories of the union ... and
intra-CU trade. In these products, the CU then func-
(ii) ... substantially the same duties and other regula- tions as if it were an FTA. The GATT does not clearly
tions of commerce are applied by each of the prohibit this inconsistency.
members of the union to the trade of territories
On the whole, however, the EC has made clear
not included in the union.
and simple choices: it set out to arrive at a CET,
The first three comments on the FTA, provided above, proclaimed a common commercial policy and covered
equally apply to the CU. In addition, the following all intra-CU trade (see chapter 5).
should be noted. With respect to extra -CU trade –
that between the CU and third countries – the notion
of a single customs territory is the crucial difference
with an FTA. Item (ii) is not very precise in speaking

15Note that the adjective ‘restrictive’ before regulations – used in item (i) – is dropped; were it not, the GATT
rules might be abused as an excuse to endow the CU with restrictive regulations vis-à-vis third countries.

the German unification in 1990), a tax union


1.5 Economic integration and the WTO and (the economic elements of) a political union
would seem to be more arbitrary.

Table 1.1. lists three forms of economic integration: The present section will briefly elaborate on the
status of FTA and CU in the GATT. Section 1.7 will
• FTA and CU, recognised in international relate the higher stages to economic federalism.
economic law since centuries (see, for example, The two most important elements of the GATT
Viner, 1950) and codified in the WTO as Art. 24, are the principle of non-discrimination and the drive
GATT; for multilateral trade liberalisation. The first one is a
• the common market and economic union not legal obligation whereas the second is an avowed
specified in international economic law; the aim, guided by reciprocity (an agreed balance of
terms are widely used, but the definition of concessions among the contracting parties) as a
economic union in particular varies greatly; negotiation principle and the ‘most favoured nation’
• total economic integration, a term fallen into (MFN) principle as an assurance of multilateral non-
disuse; however, of the ‘partial’ unions ‘beyond’ discrimination for any concession made.14 FTAs
an economic union mentioned above, the and CUs are inconsistent with the principle of non-
monetary union is often considered as a stage discrimination, as they are by definition preferential.
by itself – its essential characteristics are clearly They may, but need not, be inconsistent with the
defined, although the desirable budgetary and drive for multilateral liberalisation.
other policy integration is somewhat controver- The GATT provides various possibilities for
sial; terms such as a ‘social union’ (applied in legal compatibility of FTA and CU with the non-
7976 Chapter 1 p1-17.qxd 23.05.2003 15:54 Page 12

12 Foundation

discrimination and MFN principles. Under Article tariffs of 10 per cent before the CU, and hence the
25, para. 5, a ‘waiver’ can be obtained from those CET would be 10 per cent, too, this does not mean
obligations: this procedure was used in 1952 to that the general- incidence clause is satisfied. It
obtain GATT acceptance for the ECSC treaty. A is this crucial insight that forms the basis for CU
much more common procedure is to refer to Art. 24 theory.
(para. 4 to para. 9). It is in this article that FTA The other problem of FTAs and CUs for the
and CU are defined and minimum conditions for GATT is whether regional (product market) integra-
GATT compatibility are prescribed. tion facilitates or undermines multilateral trade
CUs and FTAs differ with respect to the compati- liberalisation. Rather than being building blocks to
bility test the GATT has come to apply over the free trade under the multilateral GATT rules, could
years. The crux of the matter for other GATT a prolification of FTAs and CUs not prove to be
contracting parties is, of course, that CUs and FTAs stumbling blocks for achieving or even maintaining
should not raise barriers for trade with third coun- multilateralism? In so far as the EU is concerned,
tries, as Art. 24, para. 4 prescribes. In para. 5, the this question is taken up in chapter 13.
FTA test to satisfy this prohibition is simple: no
higher level of duties or more restrictive regulation
of commerce may be imposed than was previously
applied by the FTA countries. Since this refers to an 1.6 Economic integration and
existing set of national trade policies, it is a straight- economic federalism
forward rule. But this straightforward test cannot
apply to CUs as they will move to a CET, coming
from different ex ante tariffs, and possibly to other The higher or more ambitious the stages of
common regulations, with different national ones economic integration, the closer is their resem-
before. Thus, the GATT says that the duties and blance to economic federalism. Since all federations
other regulations established by the CU must not in the OECD16 are not only CUs in the sense of
‘on the whole be higher or more restrictive than the GATT but also common markets as well as
general incidence of the duties and regulations of economic and monetary unions, some guidance
commerce’ previously applied by the CU Member may be had from a comparison with economic feder-
States. This general-incidence clause moves the alism.
test away from a factual verification of the CET and There is one important caveat, however.
other measures themselves, and concentrates on Federations are mature political unions with federal
the effects of the CU on trade with third countries. government. In such a polity, the ‘stage of
This economic test can, in principle, be imple- economic integration’ is essentially a product of the
mented with the help of the economic analysis of degree of decentralisation, as determined by a
customs unions (see chapter 6). Without antici- combination of historical tradition, political feasi-
pating this analysis, a warning can be formulated bility and economic costs and benefits. Whatever
about the EC’s technique to establish the CET as the chosen degree of decentralisation of public
the arithmetic average of ex ante national tariffs (as economic functions, the integrity of the federation
in the now deleted Art. 19, EC). Though seemingly and its economy are not at issue.17
neutral with respect to non-EC countries, this Processes of economic integration among inde-
average does not tell the GATT much about the pendent countries, even when they increasingly
general economic incidence of the CET as ‘pool’ their sovereignty, are governed by a radically
compared to the general incidence of ex ante tariffs. different political logic. All major steps are subject
And, even if all CU members had across-the-board to unanimity in the group and heavy ratification
procedures in each one of the Member States.

16Canada, the USA, Australia, Germany, Switzerland, Austria and Belgium. In some respects one could add Spain

and Italy.
17With the possible exception of Quebec in Canada. However, despite recurrent threats secession has never

actually taken place. The split-up of Czechoslovakia in 1993, while keeping a customs union between the Czech
Republic and Slovakia, is a dramatic example of how ‘deep’ economic interdependence gradually becomes with the
highest stages of economic integration and how costly disentanglement can be. See Fidrmuc & Fidrmuc (2000) for the
trade effects.
7976 Chapter 1 p1-17.qxd 23.05.2003 15:54 Page 13

What is Economic Integration? 13

Political sensitivities may, and do, crop up over public opinion undermines the legitimacy of inte-
time and threats of retrogression are difficult to grationist accomplishments. Stability can be greatly
fend off if the domestic politics in a Member State strengthened and legal mechanisms and political
go against the government or a groundswell of legitimacy can be fostered by giving electoral polit-

1.7 Summary

Economic integration is the elimination of economic fron- positive integration in Balassa’s stages of the customs
tiers between two or more economies. The fundamental union and the common market. This may also blur the
significance of economic integration is the increase of difference between the common market and economic
actual or potential competition, and the benefits flowing union. Balassa’s highest stage is misconceived, inspired
from this. as it is by a centralist, rather than a federal, state model.
Economic integration in Europe should be understood Economic regionalism is inconsistent with the GATT’s
against the backdrop of recent history, political aims and non-discrimination principle. The legal compatibility of
institutional aspects, especially the ‘Community method’. free trade areas and customs unions with GATT hinges
The original Community method combined supranationality on certain specific constraints (in Art. 24, GATT). In addi-
and the pooling of sovereignty. Later, this was blended with tion, the free trade area test checks whether any more
intergovernmentalism and cooperative federalism, magni- restrictive measure is introduced whereas customs
fying the role of the Member States in decision making as unions are subjected to an economic incidence test.
well as implementation and enforcement, respectively. Understanding the higher stages of economic integra-
Besides the distinction between market and tion is facilitated by studying the economics of
(economic) policy integration, negative and positive inte- federalism. The two have in common the idea that
gration are also useful concepts when understanding ‘welfare’ is best served by the optimal combination of
economic integration processes. unity and diversity.
The Balassa stages of economic integration remain a
basic tool of study. Important insights can be gained
from several amendments prompted by the absence of

APPENDIX 1.1 European institutions – a brief guide

Nowadays, simple and clear introductions into the less comprehensive and less binding) ‘pillars’, one on
institutions and legislative processes of the foreign policy and security and another one on police
European Union are widely (and often freely) avail- and judicial cooperation in criminal matters. The latter
able in many countries of the world. The following ‘pillar’ used to be called ‘justice and home affairs’
description is kept to a minimum and merely serves (mainly, person controls) but, in the Amsterdam
as a reminder. Treaty, a considerable part of the issues surrounding
Before moving on, a few warnings. The EU person controls was integrated into the EC treaty –
system is one of multi-tier government. Thus, despite that is, the main pillar. In this book EU will be used to
some popular suggestions to the contrary, Member denote the Union in general and, when relevant, the
States themselves are just as much a part of the EU EU treaty itself with those less binding pillars. EC will
as the common bodies at EU level are part of the EU. be used when it is legally necessary in view of the
It is also worthwhile repeating the distinction between powers in the EC treaty. When referring to the pre-
EC and EU (see also Figure 2.1 in section 2.4). EC Maastricht period (see chapter 2), it is sometimes
stands for European Community, legally based on the necessary to refer to the Rome Treaty or EEC
(main and) first pillar of the European Union (or (European Economic Community). The reader should
Amsterdam) Treaty, which also incorporates two (far also not forget that the EU system comprises two
7976 Chapter 1 p1-17.qxd 23.05.2003 15:54 Page 14

14 Foundation

APPENDIX 1.1 Continued

other treaties: the ECSC (European Coal and Steel facto, by the Member States selecting their own
Community) dating back to the Paris Treaty of 1951 Commissioners,20 and even if the EP could appoint
expiring in 2002, and the Euratom Treaty of 1957, the Commission, the (main) legislator remains the
which is little used. Council – at least for now.
Figure App. 1.1 provides a quick guide to the The EC Court of Justice has a Court of First
EU-level institutions and what they do. The figure is Instance which lightens the burden of the (main)
largely self-explanatory. The European Council19 Court by focusing on, for example, anti-dumping
consists of the heads of State (only France) and of cases. National courts can (and do) refer to the EC
governments. It provides leadership and usually Court so as to obtain a ‘preliminary ruling’ on a diffi-
meets twice a year. Its presidency and that of the cult element of EC law in a national case.
Council of Ministers is performed by the same Finally, the last decade or so has witnessed the
Member State and rotates every six months. The emergence of a host of specialised agencies at EU
incumbent presidency, and the preceding and level. Usually they perform highly technical func-
following ones form what is sometimes referred to tions (for example, the European Medicinal
as the ‘troika’, ensuring continuity in agendas and Agency in London, on recognising testing and
external representation where needed. The Council approval of medicines), analytical functions (for
of Ministers (usually called the Council) is still the example, the European Environmental Agency in
EC’s legislator, although the European Parliament Copenhagen; an agency in Bilbao on safety and
has gradually acquired important powers to co- health in the workplace) or registration functions
legislate, to exercise (negative) assent and, in the (the Office for Harmonisation in Alicante, which
case of the budget, to take certain final decisions. deals with trademarks). The European Patent
The Commission has the exclusive right to initiate Office in Munich has wider membership than the
draft laws. In other words, the Commission EU but is nevertheless de facto also used as an
proposes and the Council (and, increasingly, EC agency. Independent regulatory agencies (as in
the EP) disposes. Nonetheless, the Commission the USA) do not exist at EU level, with one major
wields enormous influence because of the exception: the European Central Bank is the first
expertise it takes to draft suitable proposals and truly independent ‘agency’ (see chapter 17).
because of the intense lobbying which surrounds The legal instruments of the EC are:
this preparatory work. Moreover, the Commission
has several other functions which strengthen its • regulation: an EC law binding for all legal and
position, the most important one being that of natural persons – this is called ‘direct effect’;21
‘guardian of the treaty’. However, the EC policy- • directive: binding with respect to objectives and
making processes are not fully comparable to effect (with varying degrees of detail); the
national ones. The EP controls the Commission (it Member States are held to implement directives
can even send it home, as it did in 1999) but it via incorporation in their national laws in a way
cannot directly control the Council, and – by defini- suitable to their system;
tion – cannot force it to resign. Thus, the fact that • framework directive: binding with respect to
the EP is directly chosen by the electorate does not general objectives, and the approach(es) taken,
remove the ‘democratic deficit’, as it is called. After to be followed by a series of specific directives;
all, the Commission is not chosen by the EP (de

19Especially outside Europe, the European Council is sometimes confused with the Council of Europe. The latter

(dating back to 1949) has Europe-wide membership, and focuses on cultural cooperation and human rights, based on
the European Convention of Human Rights (1954) and its European Court for Human Rights. It also promotes forms of
specific cooperation (e.g. on pharmaceutical practices).
20Since the Amsterdam Treaty the EP has to give ‘consent’ to the appointment of the Commission’s president.
21Note that, in this book and as is customary in many economic texts, the word ‘regulation’ is often used in its generic

sense as legal interventions in markets. Thus, the EC may develop product regulation (e.g. safety, health) but need not
use an ‘EC Regulation’ as the legal instrument to do this.
7976 Chapter 1 p1-17.qxd 23.05.2003 15:54 Page 15

What is Economic Integration? 15

APPENDIX 1.1 Continued

Figure App. 1.1 What the Union institutions do


Note: Member States fulfil important EC functions such as implementation and enforcement of EC laws; application of EC law by
national courts is enmeshed in a single legal system, led by the EC Court.

• decision: binding for a firm or a Member State to communications, (Commission) White and
which it is addressed; Green Papers, and ‘opinions’ may have signifi-
• recommendations: (Council or EP) resolutions, cant influence, but are not binding.
7976 Chapter 1 p1-17.qxd 23.05.2003 15:55 Page 16

16 Foundation

APPENDIX 1.1 Continued

Decision making is complex in the EU. An under- QMV means that country votes are weighted
standable reason for that is the plurality and by size of the countries but very regressively so.
diversity (culturally; big and small countries) of the Luxembourg has two votes, countries like the
Union. Also, checks and balances between the Netherlands, Belgium, Greece and Portugal have
institutions may well have greater benefits than five votes, whereas the UK, Italy, France and (the
costs. More often than not, however, complications biggest country) Germany have ten votes. A so-
arise from stalemate in Council or compromises called ‘blocking minority’ requires 27 votes out of a
over treaty revision. The reader is referred to polit- total of 87 Council votes. During the IGC at Nice, in
ical books about the EU institutions and decision December 2000, the system of voting for QMV was
making. What should be kept in mind is that the revised, with a view to giving relatively more
Council may decide by unanimity, by qualified weight to the larger Member States. The
majority voting (QMV) and by simple majority. Two latter was perceived as counter-balancing the
basic factors have pushed the EC towards more loss of the right of the large Member States to
QMV and less unanimity: the great EC accomplish- name a second Commissioner, beginning with the
ments over time (especially with respect to the next Commission in 2005. At the same time,12
internal market and common policies – see chap- negotiating candidate countries were also assigned
ters 5 to 14), and repeated enlargements up to a voting weights, anticipating their future entry.
group now consisting of 15 Member The present voting system remains in place until
States (making unanimity more and more costly). 2005. If ratified, the Nice treaty will imply that QMV

APPENDIX 1.2 New numbering of treaty articles following Amsterdam

Apart from some substantive and institutional For students who have recently been introduced to
changes, the Treaty of Amsterdam (1997; in force European integration, the new notation should
since May 1999; see chapters 2 and 3) has also present no problems – they do not have to forget
been used to consolidate treaty articles. This is the old notation. For teachers and practitioners
crucial for the readers of this book since, using this book, the new article numbers are sure
throughout this second edition, the new consoli- to cause some confusion. To those who rely on
dated notation will be used. For a number of treaty text to any large degree, it is advisable that
reasons the consolidation was overdue: they purchase a consolidated, post-Amsterdam
Treaty text to avoid confusion. When articles are
1 a number of EEC articles in the EC treaty had
first mentioned in each chapter, both old and new
become defunct (for example, those having to do
numbers are referred to; however, a repetitive use
with initial decisions and the transition period up
of both is avoided within chapters.
to 1970);
2 three revisions (Single Act, Maastricht,
Amsterdam) had caused a range of peculiar A few hints and examples
‘inserts’ into ‘single’ articles;
The (overarching) EU treaty no longer contains
3 the EU treaty itself – in Maastricht still a small set
only common provisions, followed by the three
of overarching principles, numbered by capital
‘pillars’ – two of which were numbered using capital
letters – had grown. The EU treaty itself now
letters. Now the EU treaty comprises the common
counts 53 articles.
provisions, the pro-visions on a common foreign
7976 Chapter 1 p1-17.qxd 23.05.2003 15:55 Page 17

What is Economic Integration? 17

is reached for the EU-15 with 169 votes out of a


total of 237. Large countries now have 29 votes
(was 10), sliding down via 27 (Spain) and 13
(Netherlands) to 12 (e.g. Greece), 10 (e.g.
Austria), 7 (e.g. Denmark) and 4 (Luxembourg).
However, upon enlargement with all 12 candidates
(not including Turkey), all voting shares fall, the big
countries tumbling from 11.5% to 8.4%.
Fundamentally, the working of the QMV system
has not altered. Coalitions among Member States
to push or to block certain draft laws in Council
change all the time, although in certain policy areas
coalition formation might be more stable.
7976 Chapter 1 p1-17.qxd 23.05.2003 15:55 Page 18

18 Foundation

APPENDIX 1.2 Continued

and security policy (the old J-articles), the revision throughout. Previous revisions led to a few huge
of the old pillar 3 (justice and home affairs, now and unwieldy articles such (old) Arts 73, 100, 109,
called police and judicial cooperation in criminal 130 and 198. Readers who are familiar with the first
matters; the revision of the old K-articles) and the edition of this book are warned that, for instance, the
old articles L to S, in amended form. Art. 46, EU old Art. 30, EC has become Art. 28 and – confus-
(the revised Art. L, EU) brings (part of) the old pillar ingly! – the old Art. 36, EC now Art. 30, EC. The old
3 into the EC system, hence under the EC Court subsidiarity article (Art. 3b, EC) is now Art. 5, EC.
of Justice, subject to certain conditions spelled out The old Art. 100a, EC (approximation under QMV)
in Art. 35, EU (Art. K. 7, EU as revised now). now carries the number Art. 95, EC; which was
The EC treaty (‘pillar’ 1) was always numbered formerly the number for the tax harmonisation
but quite a few articles have now been repealed and article, which in turn has become Art. 90, EC. The
a simple consecutive numbering has been applied well-known anti-trust articles (old 85 & 86, EC) are

ical status to common leaders, but the nature and aspects. What is achieved by mere liberalisation
extent of these solutions may themselves be politi- and strict case law in one federation, might be
cally controversial. In other words, the integrity of accomplished through almost complete regulatory
the ‘union’ economy is itself the issue par excel- uniformity (harmonisation or even centralisation) in
lence and the integrity of the federation is not yet another one. Great divergencies in regional fiscal
accomplished (and may never be). autonomy can also be observed, with Switzerland
All federations in the OECD have achieved and the USA being rather decentralised, for
common markets in the sense that internal factor example, and e.g. Germany and Belgium being
movements are free and a degree of positive inte- relatively centralised.
gration helps to make the CM function reasonably A comparison of federations with respect to
well. But this neither implies a counsel of perfection economic union would require an authoritative
nor one of uniformity between the constituent analytical framework, which – as noted – is not
states, regions or provinces. In terms of ‘complete- available (see, however, chapter 17). It is worth
ness’ of a CM, one might pose questions about the noting that all federations are also monetary
interstate trade of financial services (banking and unions 18 with centralized monetary policy func-
insurance, especially) in the CM of the USA, or, tions. Only the USA has maintained a
about the inter-provincial trade of, for example, network of regional central banks in the Federal
beer in the CM of Canada. Many federations Reserve System, without, however, compromising
encounter problems in the free movement of the centralisation of monetary (and exchange rate)
professionals, because the lack of uniformity (for policy. The respective monetary unions differ with
example in diplomas) is not always compensated respect to their budgetary regimes, especially the
for by smooth mutual recognition. borrowing autonomy of regions, and the relation-
In terms of uniformity, it is crucial to appreciate ship between federal taxation, the (re-)distribution
that federalism aims to find optimal combinations of of revenues and regional spending. Monetary
unity and diversity. Where positive integration to unions in federations also diverge in their
make a CM function properly would impose unifor- attachment to price stability and the (political)
mity, the regional preferences for diversity may be independence and accountability of the central
suppressed. As a result, any federal CM exhibits banks. Finally, it should be realised that federal
numerous trade-offs between the benefits of monetary unions invariably function against
reducing regulatory discrepancies in the CM and the backdrop of elected federal governments and
the benefits of satisfying regional preferences. The federal budgets which amount to an appreciable
comparison of the CMs of different federations share of total government spending in the
therefore shows different solutions for various economy. The latter two characteristics are, thus
7976 Chapter 1 p1-17.qxd 23.05.2003 15:55 Page 19

What is Economic Integration? 19

far, absent in the European Union. Indeed, the euro


is the common currency of a monetary union of
12 countries, in an economic union of 15 countries,
without a federal government.
7976 Chapter 1 p1-17.qxd 23.05.2003 15:55 Page 20

20 Foundation

now Arts 81 & 82, EC, respectively. Those interested


in the equality of pay between men and women (old
Art. 119, EC) should now look for Art. 141, EC. The
well-known (old) Art. 235, EC (a conditional legal
base to introduce EC powers for the proper func-
tioning of the common market) has now become Art.
308, EC.

You might also like