You are on page 1of 9

The Benefits of Campaign Spending

by John J. Coleman

No. 84 September 4, 2003

Critics of American politics often say that knowledge of information relevant to their
spending on electoral campaigns harms our votes? Who benefits from campaign spending?
democracy. They charge that the money goes for Studies indicate that campaign spending
cynical, negative, and misleading advertise- does not diminish trust, efficacy, and involve-
ments that alienate the public from politics and ment, contrary to what critics charge. Moreover,
elections. spending increases public knowledge of the can-
Political scientists have collected and ana- didates, across essentially all groups in the pop-
lyzed data on the connection between campaign ulation. Less spending on campaigns is not like-
spending and civic life. The data bear on several ly to increase public trust, involvement, or atten-
questions at issue in campaign finance debates: tion. Implicit or explicit spending limits reduce
Does campaign spending reduce public trust? public knowledge during campaigns. Getting
Does it reduce levels of citizen involvement in or more money into campaigns should, on the
attention to campaigns? Does it lower citizens’ whole, be beneficial to American democracy.

John J. Coleman, professor in and associate chair of the Department of Political Science at the University of Wisconsin,
Madison, is the author of Party Decline in America: Policy, Politics, and the Fiscal State.
Campaign spend- the connection between campaign spending
ing makes an Introduction and civic life. In particular, those studies
examine the connection between spending
important contri- For more than a decade, campaign and public trust, perceptions of efficacy (the
bution to key finance has been a topic of national debate feeling that being involved in politics makes
and, in 2002, legislation. Substantial scholar- a difference), levels of involvement in and
aspects of ly and public discussion has focused on the attention paid to campaigns, and electorally
democratic life, contributions side of campaign finance: who relevant knowledge—all key components of a
such as public contributes, how much, and with what effect vibrant political community
on the making of public policy? An equally Despite the concerns of reformers, cam-
knowledge, and important but underdeveloped discussion paign spending produces generally beneficial
does not damage examines candidate spending: what benefits effects. Campaign spending makes an impor-
for democracy, if any, flow from campaign tant contribution to key aspects of democra-
public trust or spending? tic life, such as public knowledge, and does
involvement. Positions on the latter question in the not damage public trust or involvement.
public reform discussion have been clear. To
one camp, campaign spending is political
speech that deserves protection. More speech The Effect of Campaign
means more information, and more informa- Spending on Public Trust
tion produces an enlightened and active citi-
zenry. Candidates and parties rationally use
and Involvement
campaign spending to inform the public The complaints about campaign spend-
about candidates’ policy preferences. By con- ing are well-known. One frequent assertion is
tributing to the quality and quantity of pub- that high levels of spending alienate and dis-
lic discourse and by making political elites illusion the public. Does an individual’s
accountable to the governed, campaign direct experience with campaign spending
spending builds political community. affect his or her attitudes? Do large amounts
Unlimited campaign spending is a boost for of spending in their own districts turn off
democracy.1 and disillusion potential voters? Campaign
To the other camp, unlimited campaign spending does not have the dire conse-
spending undermines democratic values. quences for trust, efficacy, and involvement
Legislators spend inordinate time raising that were alleged by critics of campaign
funds to create a bipartisan incumbent pro- spending.
tection scheme that hobbles challengers and In a study of the 1994 and 1996 U.S.
grants access and favors to contributors. House elections, my coauthor and I exam-
Money is spent on cynical, negative, and mis- ined whether the level of spending in the
leading campaign advertisements. The pub- campaigns affected the public’s trust in gov-
lic becomes skeptical or, even worse, apathet- ernment and the electoral process.3 In other
ic and uninvolved, and campaign spending words, are citizens living in congressional dis-
fails to enlighten or engage the public.2 tricts where campaign spending is high likely
Researchers have explored most of the to be more cynical about politics and elec-
contentious points raised in the public dis- tions than citizens living in districts where
cussion of campaign contributions. Research spending is low? Merging the best available
on campaign spending, on the other hand, national election public opinion data (the
has been narrower than the public discus- National Election Studies, collected by the
sion, focusing largely on the extent to which Interuniversity Consortium for Political and
campaign spending contributes to electoral Social Research at the University of
victory. In this paper, I report on the results Michigan) with campaign spending data col-
of several studies I conducted that examine lected by the Federal Election Commission,

2
we performed a statistical analysis to deter- are less important than the general pattern of
mine whether campaign spending was linked the results: despite the assertions of critics of
to the level of public trust. The study con- campaign finance, higher campaign spend-
trolled for more than a dozen other factors ing does not generate distrust and cynicism.
that might influence public trust; that way, Another charge related to the trust issue is
we could be certain that we were isolating the that higher campaign spending tends to dis-
effects of campaign spending from the courage citizen involvement in and attention
effects of other possible factors. to campaigns. For public involvement, we
The results indicated that campaign examined whether respondents in 1994 and
spending does not contribute to public cyni- 1996 said they cared about the election, dis-
cism. When respondents were asked how cussed politics with friends and family,
often they trusted the federal government to talked to others about voting for or against a
do what is right, their answers were unaffect- specific candidate, and were interested in fol-
ed by the level of candidate spending. The lowing the campaign. In only 2 instances (of
same result held when survey respondents a possible 10) did we find that spending
were asked whether people like themselves diminished involvement, but, contrary to
had a say in what government does. Whether arguments made by critics of spending, it was
campaign spending was high or low, people higher challenger spending in 1994, not
Direct experience
were equally likely to indicate that they did incumbent spending, that decreased the like- of high levels of
have a say in what government does. Direct lihood of caring about the election or dis- spending does
experience of high levels of spending does cussing politics with friends and family.4
not increase citizens’ cynicism about govern- Again, the pattern of results is more impor- not increase citi-
ment and politics. tant than the results in those two specific zens’ cynicism
On only one question did respondents dis- instances: in general, there is no statistically
play more cynicism when spending was high: significant relationship between campaign
about govern-
when challengers spent a lot in 1994, survey spending and public involvement or atten- ment and politics.
respondents were more likely to say that the tion. The criticism that large amounts of
government wasted a lot of tax money. When campaign spending dismay the public and
incumbents spent more in 1994, however, discourage people from being interested in
respondents were more likely to give a trusting campaigns is incorrect.
response, to say that government did not Notably, the amount of incumbent
waste a lot of tax dollars. Those results are not spending had no significant effect on the
surprising given the context of the 1994 elec- public’s involvement or attention levels. The
tions. Republican challengers waged a particu- argument that citizens are turned off by
larly vigorous campaign stressing common high-spending campaigns simply does not
themes across the country, and as they spent hold up when those high-spending cam-
more, that effort bore some fruit in the public paigns are in citizens’ own districts. Scholars
perception of taxes. Incumbents, mostly have found this kind of result in many are-
Democrats, were able to counteract that by nas: people are critical of Congress, but they
spending more themselves. tend to praise their own members of
We also found two instances in which Congress; people say the nation’s education
more spending boosted trust. Increased system is in crisis, but they generally rate
incumbent spending in 1996 boosted public their local schools highly; people say crime is
perceptions that government is run for the spiraling out of control, but they say they feel
benefit of all rather than for big interests, and relatively safe in their neighborhoods.
higher challenger spending in 1996 made it Campaign spending apparently works much
less likely that people believed that many the same way: citizens may, almost by reflex,
people in the government are corrupt. Those respond negatively when asked about cam-
two findings, neither of which held in 1994, paign spending in the United States general-

3
ly, but when we look at how high levels of percentage jumped to 85. The percentage of
campaign spending in districts affect people respondents certain that their placement was
in those districts, we find that high spending correct also jumped from 20 to 31 to 53 at
does not diminish their involvement or these three challenger spending levels.
attention. We found similar effects for specific
issues. For example, if an incumbent spent
around $210,000 in 1996, about 36 percent
The Effect of Campaign of the public in the district would be able to
Spending on Public place the incumbent on an issue scale for
abortion. If the incumbent spent $1,500,000,
Knowledge about 53 percent of the public would be able
Critics often deride campaigns as exercis- to locate the incumbent somewhere on the
es in manipulation, but analysis of the effects abortion issue scale. The same pattern holds
of campaign spending suggests a more posi- for challengers. If a challenger spent around
tive interpretation. Higher campaign spend- $210,000, about 13 percent of the public
ing produces more knowledge about candi- would be able to place that candidate on the
dates, whether measured by knowing the abortion issue scale. At $1,500,000, however,
candidates’ names, being able to place candi- the percentage jumps to 53, the same as for
dates on ideology or issue scales (the survey incumbents. We find similar results when
respondent is, for example, asked where he or looking at defense spending and government
she would place a candidate on a seven-point services and spending, the other issue scales
ideology scale if one end of the scale is labeled available in the National Election Study.
“extremely liberal” and the other “extremely Increased spending also affects whether
conservative”), or confidence in the place- respondents report likes or dislikes about the
ment on the ideology scale. For 20 measures challenger and incumbent, again suggesting
of knowledge, we found that there was a sta- an information effect—as respondents learn
tistically significant relationship between more, they may find that there are things
spending and knowledge. On 18 of those they do or do not like about a particular can-
measures, spending boosted knowledge; only didate, or they may find that some of the
on 2 did spending decrease knowledge. The things that they thought were true about
effects of spending are overwhelmingly posi- that candidate do not in fact appear to be so.
tive, and they are particularly strong for chal- That again suggests a boost in public knowl-
lengers. That is, both incumbent and chal- edge.
Setting a cap on lenger spending produces boosts in knowl- One of the major concerns of critics of
edge, and challenger spending is more likely campaign spending is that candidates
spending by to do so. Those tendencies were essentially allowed to spend as much as they wish will
incumbents or linear, meaning that we did not see evidence misinform and confuse the public, perhaps
challengers would that knowledge boosts would fade out at any even use campaign funds to create false
particular spending level. The upshot is that impressions about their true stances on
likely produce a setting a cap on spending by incumbents or issues. We examined this charge directly in
less informed, challengers would likely produce a less our study and found that it is not persuasive.
informed, less knowledgeable electorate. By combining data on how an incumbent
less knowledge- For example, we found that when chal- has voted on bills in Congress (roll-call votes)
able electorate. lenger spending was at its mean level of with the survey respondents’ placement of
about $230,000 in 1996, about 49 percent of the incumbent on an ideology scale, we can
respondents in the relevant districts could see how accurate people are in their place-
place the challenger on a seven-point ideolo- ment of the incumbent. In other words, if a
gy scale.5 At $500,000 of spending, the per- respondent places an incumbent toward the
centage rose to 66; and at $1,000,000, the liberal end of the ideology scale, we can see

4
whether the incumbent’s voting record has in another study published in 1999.7 There, I Incumbent and
fact been toward that end of the scale. In our examined whether incumbents could use challenger spend-
study, we produce “loose,” “moderate,” and campaign spending to distance themselves
“strict” measures of accuracy, with each pos- from the public image of their party or from ing produces a
ing a more difficult threshold before consid- their voting records. Could an incumbent more competitive
ering an individual’s placement of the run away from the party label and from his or
incumbent to be accurate. her own voting record? Specifically, I investi-
election.
The findings are encouraging. In 1996, gated whether incumbents could create a
the more incumbents spent, the more accu- more moderate image of themselves through
rate respondents were about the incumbent’s the use of campaign spending. The results
ideology according to all three of our accura- showed that incumbents could not spend
cy measures.6 If incumbents hypothetically their way to a more moderate image than
spent $0 in running for reelection, about 23 their voting record would suggest. In fact, the
percent of the public would be accurate more incumbents spent, the less likely
about their ideological placement (using, for respondents were to mistakenly place the
this example, the measure of “moderate accu- incumbent in the ideological center.8
racy” in the study). This level of accuracy Overall, spending does not make individ-
results from familiarity with the incumbent uals less knowledgeable, despite what critics
from news reports during his or her term, as imply. Instead, we see substantial evidence of
well as other cues such as the party label. spending boosting awareness, recall, ability
Spending of $1,000,000 would lead to 49 per- to perform campaign-related knowledge
cent of the public being accurate; spending of tasks, and respondent accuracy.
$1,500,000 would produce an accuracy rate
of 63 percent. This is a strong, significant
improvement in public accuracy. In 1994 Campaign Spending and
incumbent spending increased accuracy Political Inequality
according to our “moderate” measure. For
the other measures, there was no statistically One fear often voiced by critics of cam-
significant relationship: additional incum- paign spending is that such spending merely
bent spending does not make respondents perpetuates the advantages of the already
more accurate, but it does not “fool” the pub- well-off. The logic is that candidates tend to
lic and make respondents less accurate, cater their appeals to the relatively wealthy in
either. In both years, challenger spending society. The more money spent in campaigns,
tended to decrease accuracy about the the argument goes, the larger the informa-
incumbent—the more challengers spend, the tion gap between the well-off and the less-
less sure the public is about what the incum- well-off. Moreover, some citizens will pay
bent stands for. The challenger in a competi- more attention to public affairs than will
tive election wants voters to wonder how others, and candidates will target their atten-
much they really know about the incumbent; tion to those individuals. High-attention cit-
campaign spending raises that question for izens tend to have more education, higher
voters. The effect of more spending, then, is a income, and higher socioeconomic status in
more reflective and aware electorate. As general. Again, the more candidates spend,
incumbent spending pushes respondents in the larger the gap that emerges between low-
one direction, challenger spending pushes attention and high-attention citizens as can-
them in another. In short, incumbent and didates shower the attentive group with cam-
challenger spending produces a more com- paign appeals—or so the story goes. As indi-
petitive election. Limiting spending would cated above, my research has found signifi-
limit competitiveness. cant knowledge benefits from campaign
These results are consistent with those of spending. It would be alarming if those ben-

5
efits were received disproportionately by soci- advantaged and disadvantaged groups alike.
ety’s most advantaged citizens, thus exacer- That is, as challengers spent more, members
bating the gap between social classes or of both groups gained in knowledge. For
groups. example, with challenger spending at
The question of whether campaign spend- $225,000 in 1996, 57 percent of members of
ing disperses knowledge broadly across the the “cumulatively advantaged” group could
population or to more narrowly targeted place the challenger on a seven-point liberal
groups is tied to one of the most fundamen- to conservative ideology scale. Forty-seven
tal issues that has animated political science percent of non–cumulatively advantaged
scholarship for decades: does a particular (“disadvantaged”) individuals could do the
political practice enhance equality or foster same. If challenger spending increases to
inequality? This is simple, direct, and pro- $650,000, the percentages are 78 and 69 for
foundly important to democratic theory. the two groups, respectively. With spending
My research suggests that, as with cam- at $1.3 million, the percentages leap to 94
paign spending in general, the story is a rela- and 90, respectively. This example shows that
tively positive one.9 In my study, I compared increased spending produces real increases in
the effects of campaign spending for a series the knowledge of both the relatively advan-
The benefits of of group pairings, in which the first group taged and the relatively disadvantaged.
campaign spend- would be considered relatively advantaged Moreover, the disadvantaged make real gains
ing are broadly politically, economically, or socially and the on the advantaged. At $225,000, the ratio
second group would be considered relatively between the percentage of the disadvantaged
dispersed across disadvantaged. The group pairs included (47 percent) and the percentage of the advan-
advantaged and political characteristics (for example, strong taged (57 percent) able to place a challenger
partisans vs. not strong partisans, contacted on the ideology scale is .82 (in other words,
disadvantaged by party vs. not contacted by party, voters vs. the ratio of 47 percent to 57 percent is .82). At
groups alike. nonvoters) and socioeconomic characteris- $650,000, the ratio is .88. At $1.3 million, it is
tics (for example, white vs. not white, family .96. At that level of spending, the gap in
income in top 75 percent vs. family income in knowledge between the two socially disparate
bottom 25 percent, attended at least some groups has nearly evaporated.
college vs. attended no college). I also created To take another example, at $225,000 of
a cumulative measure of advantage and dis- challenger spending in 1996, 18 percent of
advantage that combined four group charac- the cumulatively advantaged could place the
teristics; the “cumulatively advantaged” are challenger on a seven-point issue scale for
advantaged in at least three of these charac- government services and spending; 13 per-
teristics (high income, college education, cent of the disadvantaged could do so. The
voter). ratio of the two is .72. At $650,000, the per-
I then examined several knowledge items centages increase to 35 and 26, respectively,
relevant to House campaigns, such as recall with a ratio of .74. At $1.3 million, the per-
of candidate names, placing candidates on centages are 67 and 58, respectively, with a
ideology scales, and placing candidates on ratio of .87. Again, the more money spent, the
issue scales. Because much of the controversy more both groups are able to perform this
in campaign spending research concerns the task. The more the challenger spends, the
fate of challengers, I focused on the impact of closer the ratio of the percentage of people in
challenger spending on knowledge about the each group that can place the challenger on
challenger, comparing the impact for people the scale. And this example shows that there
in the advantaged groups with the impact for is clearly room for even more gains in knowl-
people in the disadvantaged groups. edge as spending exceeds $1.3 million.
The results show that the benefits of cam- What both of these examples show is that
paign spending are broadly dispersed across limiting challenger spending to $225,000, or

6
$650,000, or even $1.3 million would have a groups and advocacy organizations as well as
negative consequence in terms of public candidates, my coauthor and I found that
knowledge and that the consequence would more money spent on positive ads, negative
spread across social, political, and economic ads, or ads that contrast candidates in some
groups. Many other examples can be drawn way typically does not affect the levels of pub-
from the research to make the same point: lic trust, efficacy, or election involvement.12
When more money is spent, relatively advan- A related fear has been that expensive
taged groups do gain the benefit of more campaigns are necessarily more “negative” in
knowledge, but, particularly critical for tone. That does not appear to be the case.
democratic elections, so do relatively disad- The correlation between spending on nega-
vantaged groups. Increased knowledge about tive ads and total ad spending was .12 in
the candidates does not disproportionately 1998 and statistically insignificant. That
flow to privileged sectors of society, bypass- takes into account not only candidate spend-
ing less privileged sectors. Campaign spend- ing but spending by groups and parties also.
ing has the effect (through campaign ads, The public will see more ads of all types in
contacts, and other organizational activity) expensive campaigns. On the flip side, nega-
of dispersing knowledge broadly across the tive ads will be present whether campaign
public, to relatively disadvantaged as well as spending is low or high.
advantaged groups. The more that is spent, Last, we found that more money spent on
the more equal groups become in their contrast ads—which combine positive and
knowledge levels. Low levels of spending, negative appeals—significantly boosted pub-
therefore, lock in inequality of knowledge lic knowledge; positive ads more modestly
between groups. Campaign spending, rather boosted knowledge. In sum, even if we ana-
than strengthening and entrenching political lyze spending on particular kinds of advertis-
inequality, is a democratizing force. ing, rather than spending overall, we find
that high levels of campaign spending pro-
duce generally positive effects.
Involvement and
“Negative” Politics
Conclusion
Skeptics allege that high-spending cam-
paigns often reduce voter participation by Political scientists have long thought that,
encouraging candidates to rely on “negative” in terms of competitive elections, low levels
ads. Political science research, however, tends of spending can be problematic. z Ordinarily, Campaign spend-
to dispute that point. Most studies have con- of course, incumbents have the spending
cluded that negative ads do not demobilize, advantage. Congressional incumbents are
ing, rather than
and may to some extent even mobilize, the often quite good at what they do. They have strengthening
public. The authors of a meta-analysis of name recognition; they know how to use the and entrenching
more than 50 published articles bearing on media; they know how to work on issues that
the topic report that they “uncovered little are of interest in the district; they take posi- political inequali-
evidence to warrant the fears of those who tions that are generally popular in the dis- ty, is a democra-
believe that electoral participation is imper- trict; and they know how to get things done
iled by the increasingly widespread use of for the district and for individual con-
tizing force.
negative political advertisements.”10 stituents. Challengers frequently need to
My research, based on the 1998 U.S. spend more than incumbents to overcome
House campaigns, concurs.11 Performing those nonfinancial advantages of incumben-
analyses similar to those described above for cy. Challengers allowed to spend freely might
1994 and 1996, but also including spending well topple incumbents, especially where
by political parties and special interest incumbents are weak and unpopular. When

7
Campaign spend- an incumbent is weak, of course, money will What Went Wrong and Why (Secaucus, N.J.: Carol
Publishing Group, 1999).
ing enhances the tend to flow into the challenger’s campaign
more readily. Restricting that inflow makes 3. John J. Coleman and Paul F. Manna, “Congres-
quality of democ- the job of displacing the incumbent that sional Campaign Spending and the Quality of
Democracy,” Journal of Politics 62, no. 3 (2000):
racy and leads to much more difficult.
757–89. Campaign spending is not only about
Campaign spending has been not only a
a vibrant political source of complaints about the reelection of
spending on advertisements: “Campaign spending
purchases a campaign organization that in many
community. incumbents; it has also become a surrogate for a different ways communicates with the public. The
wide range of problems in the political system. quality of campaign staff, the extensiveness of the
organization, and the multiple connections
Despite the volume of the public debate, there between an organization and the media and inter-
has been little academic research focusing direct- est groups can all affect the public’s reception of
ly on the impact of campaign spending on public campaign information, and most if not all of these
trust, efficacy, involvement, and knowledge. factors are reflected in a candidate’s overall cam-
paign spending amount” (p. 764).
These are questions about our civic life that are
broader than the issue of who wins and who loses 4. We examined incumbent and challenger spend-
elections. The series of studies reported in this ing for each of five survey items for a total of 10 pos-
paper is a sustained attempt to track those link- sible relationships between campaign spending and
public involvement.
ages at the national level. The findings of those
studies show that campaign spending enhances 5. Technically, each respondent in these districts
the quality of democracy and leads to a vibrant has a .49 probability of being able to place the
political community. Spending does not dimin- challenger on the seven-point ideology scale.
ish trust, efficacy, and involvement, contrary to 6. We relied on the incumbent’s roll-call votes,
critics’ charges. Moreover, spending increases not campaign pronouncements, to measure his
public knowledge about the candidates, across or her actual ideological position. Because chal-
essentially all groups in the population, whether lengers, in most cases, do not have a voting
record, we were unable to conduct similar accura-
“advantaged” or “disadvantaged.” The policy cy tests for them. As mentioned previously, how-
implication of these findings is that low levels of ever, higher challenger spending does improve
campaign spending are not likely to increase pub- public knowledge about the challenger.
lic trust, involvement, or attention, but they will
7. John J. Coleman, “Party Images and Candidate-
tend to diminish public knowledge. Spending Centered Campaigns in 1996: What’s Money Got
limits, whether explicit or implicit, mean a reduc- to Do with It?” in The State of the Parties: The
tion in the level of public knowledge during cam- Changing Role of Contemporary American Parties, ed.
paigns. Getting more money into campaigns Daniel M. Shea and John C. Green, 3d ed.
(Lanham, Md.: Rowman and Littlefield, 1999).
should, on the whole, be beneficial, and there is a
range of methods—which would appeal differ- 8. Regarding respondent accuracy, the Coleman
ently to people of different ideological persua- and Manna study found that 13 of 15 spending
sions—by which those additional resources could coefficients were significant for 1994 (revised to take
enter the campaign finance system. Campaign into account the party label of the challenger) and
1996. My 1999 article, looking at accuracy and inac-
spending benefits democracy. curacy in a somewhat different manner (mistaken
placements in the ideological center), finds 8 of 8
spending coefficients significant. Thus, across two
Notes studies, with two different ways of looking at accu-
racy, I find significant coefficients in 21 of 23
1. For a representative sampling of this position, instances. The pattern is that incumbent spending
see the readings in Part Four of Political Money: improves accuracy about the incumbent’s ideolo-
Deregulating American Politics, Selected Writings on gy—incumbents do not run from their record.
Campaign Finance Reform, ed. Annelise Anderson Challenger spending, on the other hand, may reduce
(Stanford, Calif.: Hoover Institution Press, 2000). accuracy. That is not surprising. A challenger might
focus the public’s attention on a particular part of
2. For a general exposition of this argument, see the incumbent’s record that he or she believes is
Elizabeth Drew, The Corruption of American Politics: important (whether for strategic, ideological, moral,

8
political, or other reasons), and the public’s Brians, “Negative Campaign Advertising:
increased attention to this part of the record might Demobilizer or Mobilizer?” American Political
reduce awareness of and accuracy about other parts. Science Review 93, no. 4 (1989): 891–900. But see
Also, a challenger is introducing his or her own Stephen Ansolabehere and Shanto Iyengar, Going
issues into the campaign mix, thus redirecting pub- Negative: How Political Advertisements Shrink and
lic attention from the incumbent’s record to the Polarize the Electorate (New York: Free Press, 1995).
challenger’s stances and proposals; this could have
the effect of reducing accuracy about the incum- 11. John J. Coleman and David C. W. Parker,
bent’s record. Both of these factors would tend to “Campaign Spending, Advertising Tone, and
make the challenger a more competitive candidate. Civic Engagement,” Paper presented at the con-
ference on Measuring Advertising and Advertis-
9. John J. Coleman, “The Distribution of Cam- ing Effectiveness, Chicago, April 2000.
paign Spending Benefits across Groups,” Journal
of Politics 63 (2001): 916–34. 12. Our measure of trust combines survey respon-
dents’ answers to questions about how often they
10. Richard Lau et al., “The Effectiveness of trust the government to do what is right, how
Negative Political Advertisements: A Meta-analyt- much governments wastes tax money, whether
ic Review,” American Political Science Review 93, no. government is run for big interests or the benefit
4 (1994): 858. Other studies include Steven E. of all, how many people in government are cor-
Finkel and John G. Geer, “A Spot Check: Casting rupt, and whether the United States is headed in
Doubt on the Demobilizing Effect of Attack the right direction. The efficacy scale includes
Advertising,” American Journal of Political Science 42, whether respondents feel that people like them
no. 2 (1988): 573–95; Paul Freedman and Ken have a say in government, whether public officials
Goldstein, “Measuring Media Exposure and the care what people like them think, whether gov-
Effects of Negative Campaign Ads,” American ernment pays attention when making decisions,
Journal of Political Science 43, no 4 (1999): and whether elections make government pay
1188–1208; Ken Goldstein and Paul attention. Election involvement includes caring
Freedman,“New Evidence for New Arguments: about the House election outcome, discussing
Money and Advertising in the 1996 Senate politics with friends and family, talking to others
Elections,” Journal of Politics 62, no. 4 (2000): about candidates, whether the respondent
1087–1108; Richard Lau and Gerald M. Pomper, expresses interest in following the campaigns, and
“Accentuating the Negative? Effects of Negative whether voting can make a difference.
Campaigning in U.S. Senate Elections,” Paper
presented at the annual meeting of the American 13. I am speaking here of general tendencies
Political Science Association, Boston, September rather than what will happen in each and every
4–6, 1998; and Martin Wattenberg and Craig L. election.

Published by the Cato Institute, Cato Briefing Papers is a regular series evaluating government policies and
offering proposals for reform. Nothing in Cato Briefing Papers should be construed as necessarily reflecting
the views of the Cato Institute or as an attempt to aid or hinder the passage of any bill before Congress.
Additional copies of Cato Briefing Papers are $2.00 each ($1.00 in bulk). To order, or for a complete listing
of available studies, write the Cato Institute, 1000 Massachusetts Avenue, N.W., Washington, D.C. 20001, call
(202) 842-0200 or fax (202) 842-3490. Contact the Cato Institute for reprint permission.

You might also like