You are on page 1of 23

1

Globalization, poverty and environment in Vietnam


A review of empirics, methods and policy issues

Ian Coxhead
1

University of Wisconsin-Madison
This version: July 2007

1. Motivation
A growing body of research considers the implications of globalization, or the process of
integration of economic activities, across borders, through markets (Wolf 2004), for the
welfare of resource-abundant developing economies. The aggregate benefits of globalization are
widely agreed, but distributional issues, including poverty change, and the environmental
consequences of integration with the global economy when some natural resources are subject to
open-access have received only limited attention. Poverty and environmental damage are serious
issues in a very large group of developing economies and their relationship to globalization is not
yet well understood. Following a brief introduction, section 2 of this paper surveys the literature
for the case of Vietnam, a prominent resource-abundant developing economy that has undergone
significant recent integration with global markets. Section 3 provides a sketch of a formal
methodology for modeling these issues, using the Vietnamese economy as a case study and
methodological test bench. Section 4 reviews data, modeling and policy issues.

1.1 Empirical and policy issues
Globalization in Vietnam dates from 1986, when the Vietnamese government adopted doi moi,
its response to liberalizing reforms in both the USSR and China. In just a few years the thrust of
economic policy shifted from hermetic self-sufficiency (albeit with substantial Soviet aid) to
engagement with the booming Asian and global economies, and from pervasive controls over
domestic markets to a more relaxed stance, especially in agriculture. Devaluation and the
relaxation of many trade barriers facilitated export growth. From a value less than 50% in 1992,
the share of trade in GDP had almost doubled by 2000. Other reforms paved the way for foreign
investment and joint ventures as means to attract capital, and foreign-invested firms play an
increasingly prominent role in production and job creation.
These policy reversals were accompanied by a tremendous acceleration in growth:
throughout the 1990s, the Vietnamese economy grew at an average rate in excess of 6% per year;
the headcount measure of poverty declined from 75% in 1988 to 58% in 1993, 37% in 1998, and
less than 30% in 2002 (Swinkels and Turk 2004; GSO 2002). These remarkable gains were
achieved despite serious deficiencies in infrastructure, human capital, legal institutions and other
factors commonly associated with growth miracles. In Vietnam, growth has been
contemporaneous, and for practical purposes coterminous, with globalization and the
liberalization of domestic markets. The country continues to move toward greater international
economic integration, through more open trade with China and ASEAN, expanded bilateral links

1
This paper is an adaptation of a research proposal submitted to the Ford Foundation. For
details of the project please visit www.aae.wisc.edu/gpe-vn. I thank Nguyen Van Chan and Tom
Hertel for helpful comments on earlier drafts and Diep Phan for research assistance.
2
with the US, and plans to for WTO accession. These innovations in trade policy are proceeding
together with major shifts in domestic development policy, where the formerly dominant state-
owned sector is losing market share and government support, and reliance on markets and prices
as resource allocation mechanisms is gaining ground.
The poverty decline noted above is a tremendous gain in a poor country, and the effects
of sustained economic expansion on human well-being will be profound. However, the gains
from growth have so far been quite unevenly distributed, with poverty reduction occurring very
rapidly in urban areas and the major river deltas, but much more slowly (and from higher initial
rates) in highlands, remote areas and the central coast region (Swinkels and Turk 2004; Minot
2000). Average rural incomes vary across these regions (Figure 1). Broad indicators of
inequality in the distribution of income, by region and in other socioeconomic dimensions, have
begun to rise.



While considerable scholarly attention has been devoted to measuring and explaining
poverty changes, it is less widely recognized that in Vietnam, growth and globalization also
threaten to accelerate environmental damage and natural resource (NR) depletion. In spite of
rapid changes in the structure of production and employment, the country remains heavily
dependent on income from agriculture, fisheries and other resource-based activities. Closer
integration with the global economy is a prime source of additional pressures, since Vietnam has
clear comparative advantage in resource-based products. Currently, about three-quarters of
export revenues are derived from fisheries, rice, coffee, minerals and other resource-based
industries. About one-third of new foreign investment in 1998-2000 was directed at these
sectors. Problems of deforestation, flooding and water pollution, and degradation of coastal
fishery resources threaten future growth in export sectors, a threat that the Vietnamese
government has only belatedly recognized with establishment of a Ministry of Environment and
Natural Resources late in 2002.
3
The Government of Vietnams National Socio-Economic Development Strategy 2001-10
articulates the desired approach to development as promoting rapid and sustainable
development by ensuring economic growth, accompanied by social equality and progress, and
environmental protection. (CPVN 2002) Recent evidence points to considerableeven
spectacularprogress on the first two of these goals. The effects of rapid growth on the
environment are less clear, however, and there are many signs that the trade-off of resources and
environmental quality for growth is a significant one. Can growth, poverty alleviation and
environmental protection be simultaneously achieved? What can be learned from Vietnams
case that is applicable to resource abundant developing economies in general?

1.2 Methodological issues
What are the welfare and environmental effects of a trade or trade policy shock on a specific
economy? Canonical models in international economics tell us that for a given global market
shock, the change in GDP or a similar aggregate welfare proxy will be relatively greater for
small economies (since their responses have no impact in world markets) and for economies
whose structure differs substantially from that of the world market. In general, global market
shocks affecting natural resource prices will have the largest welfare effects on small economies
that are highly resource-abundant or resource-scarce relative to the world economy as a whole.
Similarly, domestic trade policy innovations are expected to have the largest effects on
households that deviate furthest from the average in terms of consumption patterns and sources
of income. This is shown by the magnification effect of product price changes on factor
returns in standard trade models containing sector-specific factors (Jones 1971). Even relatively
simple trade models can generate surprisingly robust predictions of changes in factor returns and
(given a known pattern of asset ownership) of household incomes for a given world price or
trade policy shock.
As with effects of trade shocks across countries, the impact of a world price or policy
shock on individuals or households within an economy is distributed more (less) equally as the
population is less (more) heterogeneous. Moreover, there are multiple channels through which
the effects of a shock are transmittedproduct markets, factor markets, taxes and transfers,
remittances, risk and adjustment, and so onso the effects of a given shock on a given
household are contingent not only on the characteristics of the household, but on economic
structure, policy regimes and more (Winters 2002; Zhai and Hertel 2006). These insights are
becoming standard in the literature on trade and poverty (Hertel and Reimer 2005). Where
natural resource wealth is concerned, there is the additional challenge of augmenting the impacts
of changes in flow variables with at least some endogenous changes in stock variables, through
the use and subsequent depletion or degradation of assets used in production, such as land and
other natural resources. In some cases, moreover, related externality effects (e.g. pollution) may
be important.
To be adequate, then, a research methodology must be capable of assimilating both
economic and environmental phenomena, including trade and domestic policies, land and other
resource use decisions at the household or firm level, and environmental consequences of those
decisions. In addition, the analysis should generate decomposable welfare measures as criteria
for normative and policy judgments. For this purpose the most appropriate tool is an applied
general equilibrium (AGE) model, one that captures in algebraic form the major features of
resource endowments, producer and consumer decision-making, trade, price formation and
incomes, in an internally consistent general equilibrium framework. Carefully used, such models
4
can generate surprisingly useful insights in empirical and policy experiments. Methodologically,
however, the devil is in the details of decisions on model structure, parameterization from
specific data, and validation through tests of its capacity to replicate economic development
experience.
2. Review of literature
Much of the existing research on Vietnams economic development focuses either on the
analysis of household income and expenditure data to track trends in poverty and income
distribution, or on the use of input-output and general equilibrium simulation models to replicate
the aggregate economic effects of policy reforms and trade shocks. The literature that integrates
thesethe so-called macro-micro modeling approach (Hertel and Winters 2006; Bourguignon
and Pereira 2003)is relatively new globally, has very few applications at present in Vietnam,
and to date has not attempted to capture environmental or natural resource phenomena, despite
their clear importance to aggregate and household welfare in most developing countries.

2.1 Analyses of disaggregated household data.
The impact of globalization on poverty and income distribution in Vietnam has been the subject
of considerable empirical research, especially since the release of the second round (1998) of the
Vietnam Living Standards Survey (VLSS), the national household income and expenditure
survey. Glewwe et al. (2004) present an important collection of recent studies. The work in this
volume, as well as in numerous other recent papers, makes use of two rounds of VLSS data to
document and analyze changing household incomes and expenditures, poverty, shifts in
economic structure, educational investments and migration, and the impacts of growth on health,
nutrition and the distribution of income. Papers in this literature are motivated by a broad
conceptual model of the links between trade (or others aspects of globalization) and measures of
welfare such as household income, poverty, or income distribution, but typically focus on one or
a few individual channels through which such links operate, for example agricultural product
markets (Minot and Golletti 2000; Seshan 2004) or labor markets (Gallup 2004; Jenkins 2004).
Other empirical studies characterize impediments to adjustment. The Vietnamese
economy is characterized by relatively high barriers to internal movement of goods and factors.
Price transmission is impeded by transport costs and other barriers (Le Goulven 2001, Roland-
Holst and Tarp, n.d.), and mobility in the labor market is inhibited by informational asymmetries,
risk and uncertainty, transport costs and legal restraints (Van de Walle 2004a; Le 2005). These
impediments to market clearing are thought to be important determinants of the widening income
gap between urban and rural areas, and between households with and without access to incomes
derived from the more rapidly growing sectors. As a result, the distribution of income growth
and poverty alleviation in Vietnam reveals a heavy bias toward urban and peri-urban areas, with
remoter regions and those populated by ethnic minorities showing much slower progress
(Swinkels and Turk 2004). Such regional, ethnic and sectoral discrepancies have been addressed
in part in the design of poverty alleviation programs. These, however, appear not to have been
influential (Van de Walle 2004b); rather, it is remittances from migrant workers that have been
important in spreading the benefits of export-led manufacturing growth to rural areas and
agricultural households (Cox 2004; Litchfield et al. 2003; Niimi et al. 2003).
This body of empirical work contributes valuable insights into the changing patterns of
poverty in Vietnam, but being partial equilibrium, does not provide a complete accounting for
the intersectoral effects of policy or market shocks. Moreoverand very surprisinglyno
5
published studies in this literature examine the links between growth, poverty and the natural
resource base. Environment, deforestation and other natural resource issues are not mentioned,
for example, in any of the studies collected in Glewwe et al. (2004). This is a surprising
omission in a country where well over half the population (and a far higher fraction of low-
income households) derive their income from activities that directly exploit the natural resource
base.

2.2 Input-output and general equilibrium analyses of globalization, growth and welfare
The second branch of the relevant literature takes a general equilibrium approach (AGE), using
simulation models to predict the effects of trade and policy shocks on growth, the structure of
production and employment, income distribution and poverty. These are based on various
editions of the Vietnam Social Accounting Matrix (SAM). Whereas empirical studies of the
kind just discussed take the household as the unit of analysis, virtually all AGE models use a
representative household (RH) approach, positing one or a small number of such units, and
extrapolate from policy shocks to measures of household welfare that are uniform for all
households for which each RH stands. This approach better highlights impacts of trade on the
function income distribution, especially those operating through Stolper-Samuelson type changes
in relative factor prices.
One group of studies makes use of the GTAP (Global Trade Analysis Project) model
(Hertel 1997) to examine the effects of global trade shocks and some domestic trade policy
reforms on the Vietnamese economy. Fukase and Martin (2000, 2001), for example, examine
the effects of the US granting MFN status to Vietnam, and of Vietnams accession to the
ASEAN Free Trade Area (AFTA), using a 13-sector AGE model. Granting of MFN status was
found to increase aggregate income and lead to large increases in exports of labor-intensive
manufactures such as apparel, but produced only small predicted changes in agricultural and
natural resource outputs.
In one of several country-level AGE studies, Chan et al. (2004) use a 17-sector SAM to
examine unilateral trade liberalization. This model is innovative in that it explicitly recognizes
impediments to labor mobility in the Vietnamese economy. The authors construct several
scenarios, including complete and costless mobility, segmented agricultural and industrial labor
markets, intersectoral mobility with transactions costs, and initial unemployment with fixed real
wages. Their results show the expected increases in production and exports of labor-intensive
manufactures; surprisingly, however, they too do not show any stimulus to resource-based
sectors in which Vietnam has comparative advantage. Perhaps because of this, the simulation
results with restrictions on labor mobility reveal significantly lower gains to rural poor
households by comparison with the full mobility case, in which such households presumably
share in the gains from output and job growth in labor-intensive manufactures.
As noted above, there is presently only one macro-micro model of trade liberalization
and poverty in Vietnam (Fujii and Roland-Holst 2004). This uses a 38-sector SAM linked to a
spatial data set of geographical variables and household income and expenditure, from VLSS and
the national census, to evaluate the effects of unilateral trade liberalization (UTL) and of global
trade liberalization (GTL) on poverty and income distribution. Like others of its type, this model
creates a recursive link between macro shocks and responses and their micro (household)
impacts. Trade shocks generate output price changes, and these in turn induce changes at
sectoral level in factor value marginal products, which lead to intersectoral movements of labor
and other reallocable factors along with factor price changes. The vectors of product and factor
6
price changes, together with any endogenous changes in taxes and transfers, then form the basis
for calculations of change in household incomes and expenditures. The analytical approach
permits a very detailed mapping of macro changes to poverty and incomes at household and
commune level. It finds that both UTL and GTL raise aggregate welfare and reduce poverty in
spite of generally higher inequality. Structurally, both forms of liberalization produce large
predicted increases in the output of apparel and other labor-intensive manufactures, but only the
GTL scenario also predicts an unambiguously large increase in agricultural and natural resource
output. The model imposes immobility of labor between rural and urban industries, which may
help explain the surprisingly small agricultural and natural resource sector response.
All these AGE studies underline two general stories and raise some puzzles. First, trade
liberalizationwhether unilateral or globalincreases aggregate welfare and induces substantial
changes in the structure of production and employment. Second, the implied poverty and
distributional effects of liberalization are clearly contingent on which industries expand and on
the extent to which the model permit laborthe main income source for poor householdsto
move among sectors. In light of this, it is puzzling that there has not been a more concerted
effort to obtain empirical information on the operation of Vietnamese labor markets for the
purpose of parameterizing such models. Chan et al. (2004) is the only study making a serious
effort to capture labor market phenomena. A second puzzle is why trade liberalization does not
induce a greater increase in the output of Vietnams agricultural and natural resource sectors.
Here, the simulation results appear to be at odds with trends in the Vietnamese economy in the
two decades since doi moi, over which period the country has become the worlds second largest
exporter of both rice and coffeefrom a base of net rice imports and near-zero coffee exports
to name just two examples. These anomalies motivate a re-examination of the structural
assumptions of current AGE models. In particular, the assumption of a fixed land area in
agriculture (or analogous restraints on supply growth in models without land) now comes into
sharp focus. A priori, allowing for endogenous growth in the area devoted to farming and
fisheries could have two effects relevant to our research concerns: it could better capture likely
sectoral responses to stimuli created by trade and trade liberalization, and, by allowing for
households to expand their non-labor resource base, could alter the predicted effects of such
shocks on household incomes and poverty (Coxhead and Jayasuriya 2004). These effects would
be spatially specific, in that the land frontier is not everywhere uniformly open; they would,
moreover, have implications for the depletion and degradation of environmental resources.

2.3 Trade and environment in general equilibrium
Though the GE theoretical approach to trade-environment questions is well established
(Anderson 1992; Fredriksson 1999; Copeland and Taylor 2003), the current literature in this area
has limitations where developing economies are concerned. Many analyses are highly
aggregative, combining widely different types of environmental damage into a single variable.
This approach can help elucidate basic principles, but is less useful as a guide to normative
analysis and policy formulation. Other analyses choose to deal only with a single environmental
concern, such as SO2 emissions or deforestation. Overall, there is heavy emphasis on industrial
emissions; even the otherwise comprehensive work by Copeland and Taylor (2003) omits
analysis of natural resource use and depletion. This approach is unsuitable in most of the
developing world, where resource depletion and degradation shares top billing or even outranks
industrial pollution as a leading environmental problem (Asian Development Bank 1997; Jha and
Whalley 1999). Nowhere is this more true than in tropical Asia, where deforestation rates are the
7
highest of any world region, and other trade-driven problems such as soil degradation and
conversion of coastal ecosystems to fish and shrimp farms are very prominent. A complicating
factor in such cases is that property rights over natural resources are often poorly established or
enforced, leading to conditions resembling open access.
The open access stylization has been used in a number of theoretical examinations of
trade, environment and economic welfare. Deacon (1995) presents an influential formalization
of the links between manufacturing tariff reforms and natural resource degradation in a
developing country setting. He analyzes the impact of tariff reform on deforestation in a
Ricardian model with two traded goods (a protected, import-competing manufactures and
exportable agriculture) and one intersectorally mobile factor, labor. Labor is also used to convert
open-access forest into agricultural land. Trade liberalization shrinks the manufacturing sector,
which releases labor; this in turn reduces the cost of forest conversion for agriculture, thereby
increasing deforestation. This result illustrates the proposition that an institutional failure such as
open access to a natural resource will worsen socially excessive rates of pollution or resource
degradation when trade frictions are reduced, if the country has comparative advantage in the
polluting sector (Brander and Taylor 1997). From a policy perspective, however, this result pits
environmental concerns against the conventional gains from trade liberalization; if preservation
of forest has positive value, then the Deacon result indicates a welfare tradeoff.
This tradeoff, however, is contingent on a model structure that precludes the case in
which a developing country also has comparative advantage in labor-intensive manufactures.
When this is true, the implication of an unambiguously negative relationship between trade
liberalization and environmental quality that emerges from the Deacon and Brander-Taylor
models no longer holds (Copeland 1994; Coxhead and Jayasuriya 2005). When labor is
intersectorally mobile, a boom in labor-intensive manufactures induces outmigration from
resource sectors, driving up labor costs and thus reducing deforestation and labor-intensive
agricultural activities. The lesson is that in modeling trade and environment, parsimony in model
structure may give misleading results: there is no clear and general prediction on the
environmental effects of trade liberalization, even when countries have comparative advantage in
resource products or polluting industries.

2.4 AGE analyses of trade and environment in Vietnam
There are just two published applications of AGE modeling to natural resources and the
environment in Vietnam (El Obeid et al. 2002; Dufournaud et al. 2000). Dufournaud et al. use a
highly stylized SAM-based model to examine pressures for deforestation. The paper by El Obeid
et al. is part of a large research project (Beghin et al. 2002) using common AGE frameworks to
examine trade-environment relationships in several developing countries. The model examines
13 types of pollutants (7 air, 4 water, and 2 land) whose emissions are linked to consumption,
both as intermediate goods and in final consumption. The model uses the Vietnam SAM and
contains 50 production sectors, one labor category, one representative household, and one capital
type.
In simulations, a business-as-usual scenario determines a reference growth and pollution
trajectory in the absence of environmental or other tax reforms. Three alternative scenarios are
then examined: piecemeal environmental policies, unilateral trade liberalization and a
combination of the two. Trade reform on its own is found to promote both growth and pollution,
particularly of airborne effluents. The composition effect of trade reformthat is, the shift in
the structure of production and consumption that changing relative prices induce (Antweiler et
8
al. 2001)shows that in Vietnam this measure would induce a relative increase in the
consumption and production of dirty products. Environmental taxes alone have a variable and
sometimes significant negative impact on growth, depending on the effluent targeted. Finally,
growth-environment trade-offs are minimized when free trade is combined with emissions taxes;
there is a positive impact on growth and trade, and at the same time, the country specializes in
cleaner goods for export. There is evidence of a double dividend, that is, that reforms lead both
to reduced emissions and a more efficient tax system (Bovenberg and Goulder 1996).
Both the structure of this model and its results closely resemble those obtained in other AGE
studies on this theme

(Lee and Roland Holst 1997, Dessus and Bussolo 1998, Beghin et al. 2002,
Beghin et al. 1997). In particular, it is often found that trade liberalization by itself leads to GDP
growth but increases pollution, that environmental policies alone have negative growth impacts
(although these may be small), and that a combination of reforms tends to produce a win-win
outcome, i.e., to be beneficial for both growth and the environment.
The model has some drawbacks. Its parameter values, other than those from the SAM,
are not explicitly based on Vietnamese data. It lacks spatial features, in spite of the inherently
spatial nature of its subject, and contains no mechanisms for feedback from pollution to
economic activity. Like most of the environmental AGE literature, it focuses on industry-based
air and water pollution and all but ignores natural resource issues such as deforestation, soil
degradation and erosion, and loss of watershed function. On the welfare side, it is an RH model
and thus cannot generate income distribution or poverty information. This is important not
merely because poverty eradication is itself a major policy target, but also because poverty and
the environment are intimately linked, in resource-dependent poor economies, through the
production and consumption decisions of poor households. Though these links are as yet poorly
understood, there is little debate over their importance.
Finally, policy shocks applied to the model are at best only distantly related to actual
policy concerns and options in Vietnam or elsewhere in the developing world. The simulations
impose taxes on consumption of polluting goods; these are conventional first-best policies used
to correct for environmental damage. They require that there be plausible and effective
monitoring and enforcing instruments to implement the taxes. However, it is precisely the lack
of these instruments that causes difficulties for policy makers in developing countries.
Simulations examining the use of second-best instruments might be more relevant; it would also
be appropriate to examine the environmental as well as economic effects of a broader range of
current tax policy reforms, not exclusively those directly addressing environmental problems.
This would link environmental models of this type to the broader tradition of AGE modeling as a
tool of welfare analysis (Chan, et al. 1999; Chan et al. 2004).
3. Theoretical model
3.1 The standard model
We begin with the simplest sketch of a model that captures the general equilibrium links between
globalization and trade policies, household incomes, poverty and the natural environment. This
version serves as a platform on which we will build increasingly complex variants.
Consider an economy with one representative producer and one consumer. The economy
is endowed with a vector v = (v1, , v
F
) of productive resources. These are fully employed in
production of a vector y = (y1, , y
n
) of industry outputs. The economy is assumed open to
trade but small in relation to global markets. A subset m of goods is tradable, while the
remainder, m+1, n, are non-tradable. The vector of base prices of tradable goods p
T
*
is
9
determined exogenously in the world market. International trade in goods is taxed at rates t,
giving a domestic tradables price vector p
T
with elements p
i
= p
i
*
+ t
i
for i = 1, , m. Together
with nontradables prices p
N
, these make up the domestic price vector p. Net revenues from trade
taxes are returned to the consumer in lump-sum form. Assuming profit maximization, constant
returns to scale, complete and competitive markets, and a fixed number of goods, aggregate
income is given by a maximum revenue function:
g(p, v) = max p y v { } . (1)
This has the usual properties of linear homogeneity, and is non-decreasing in p and v. By the
envelope theorem, the following derivative properties hold:

g(p, v)
p
i
= y
i
(p, v) (i = 1,..., n) and
g(p, v)
v
k
= w
k
(p, v) (k = 1,..., F) , (2)
giving industry supplies and shadow prices of inputs as functions of prices and endowments.
The consumer is assumed to derive income equal to the total earnings of factors and to
spend this entirely on goods. Her utility maximizing behavior, with indirect utility (p, m) is
captured by a minimum expenditure function
e(p, u) = min p c u { } , (3)
where u is the target utility level. Again the envelope theorem gives optimal domestic demands:
e(p, u)
p
i
= c
i
(p, u) i = 1,,n. (4)
In this model, net exports are the excess of production over domestic demand for each good.
Using subscripts on g and e to denote derivatives,
z
i
= g
p
i
(p, v) e
p
i
(p, u) = y
i
(p, v) c
i
(p, v) , i = 1,,n (5)
and z
i
> 0 (< 0) indicates that the ith good is a net export (import), and z
i
= 0 for nontradables.
Aggregate expenditure is equal to income, so in equilibrium with tariff revenues returned in
lump-sum form to the consumer, we have an aggregate budget constraint of the form
e(p, u) = g(p, v) + t ' z . (6)
The system made up by (2), (4), (5) and (6) defines a standard Walrasian model and its
solution yields general equilibrium values of factor prices, industry supplies, consumer demands,
international trade quantities, prices of non-traded goods and a measure of aggregate real
income, all as functions of an exogenous vector (p
*
, t, v). There are 3n + F + 1 equations and the
same number of endogenous variables. The comparative static properties of this model are well
known. A trade shock or policy reform alters relative product prices, and this will in turn change
relative factor prices in ways that are broadly if not precisely predictable (Lloyd 2000): factors
used intensively in sectors whose output price has risen (fallen) will tend to experience real gains
(losses), and so on. While the model is highly non-linear, it can easily be solved as a system of
linear equations by conversion to proportional changes of variables, in which form its parameters
are shares (e.g. budget shares, cost shares) obtainable from national accounts data, and
elasticities about many values of which researchers have fairly strong priors.
This structure provides a basic framework for studies of trade reform, product prices,
returns on factors, and aggregate welfare upon which additional features and relationships of
particular interest to the Vietnamese case can be built.

3.2 Multiple households
10
We first extend the model to consider multiple households h=1, , H. These are distinguished
by household-specific asset endowments, incomes and preferences, and thus have unique
expenditure patterns and welfare in the initial equilibrium. When product and factor prices are
determined in the macro system just sketched, we can examine the effects of exogenous
changes in household assets, trade policy or global market shocks, and changes in policies such
as taxes and transfers, on the incomes and welfare of households and on aggregate poverty. In
general, the real incomes of households are dependent on their factor endowments and the
returns to those factors, as well as on preferences and the prices of consumer goods and any
applicable taxes or transfers. Define household factor endowments by vector v
h
and general
equilibrium factor returns by w(p); lump-sum taxes or in-kind transfers by T
h
; the tax rate on
factor incomes by
h
; and a consumer price index by
h
(p) = p
i

i
h
i

, where
i
h
is the share of
good i in total household expenditure. Household real disposable income is then:
r
h
=
w(p) v
h
(1+
h
)
+ T
h
[
\
|

)
j

h
(p) (7)
We can now find the effects of a variety of economic shocks on real household incomes. Define
the proportional change in each variable by a caret (e.g.,
r
h
= dr
h
/ r
h
, and so on). To reduce
clutter, assume
h
= 0. Expanding each price vector, the total change in real income for
household h is:

r
h
=
h

w
i
+

v
i
h
( )
i


i
h
+ 1
h
( )

T
h


p
j

j
h
j

i = 1, F; j = 1, , n (8)
where
i
h
is the contribution of factor i to a households total income from factors, and
h
is the
share of net household income from factor earnings. At constant prices and policies, an increase
in the household endowment of factor i raises real income by an amount proportional to the
growth of the endowment and its contribution to household income. Holding endowments
constant, a trade or trade policy shock alters some element(s) of p, and thus affects the household
both directly, and indirectly through general equilibrium changes in w. It may thus raise or
lower r
h
, depending on the magnitudes of the various price changes, the shares of factor in total
income, and expenditure shares on goods. Taxes and transfers may also change endogenously
due to altered public revenues.

3.3 Poverty changes
The real income information can be aggregated over groups of households to construct the
proportional change form of a distributionally sensitive poverty measure P

(Foster et al. 1984):


P
o
= ~o
h
(o, z)
r
h
z ~ r
h
[
\
|

)
j
h=1
q
_
r
h
for h = 1, , q poor households, (9)
where > 0 is the distributional sensitivity parameter, z is a poverty line, and the weights

h
(, z) = (z r
h
)

(z r
h
)


are -adjusted poverty gaps for household h relative to that for all
poor households (Coxhead and Warr 1995). Substituting for
r
h
from (8), equation (9) provides a
prediction of aggregate poverty change due to trade shocks or policy reforms. The subgroup
decomposability property of P


means that poverty changes can also be calculated for distinct
groups within the poor population.
11
These analytical tools support the examination of poverty data during episodes of trade
reform. Initial empirical analyses with Vietnamese data indicate the importance of a general
equilibrium approach. Minot and Goletti (2000) used subgroup data on rice farming households
distinguished by location and income and found differential effects of welfare changes due to
rice market liberalization. Litchfield et al. (2003) noted that Vietnams trade liberalization was
contemporaneous with huge expansion of products intensive in the use of labor and natural
resources (coffee, rice, handicrafts, processed foods and light manufactures) and a substantial
decline in poverty, which they found econometrically to be most intense among households
dependent on farming and unskilled labor incomes.

3.4 Factor markets
How price and policy changes affect real income for any given household will depend on its
endowments and consumption patterns as shown, but also on just which markets the household is
in, since factors and products may be distinguished by quality, distance, and other states of the
world, and arbitrage between these may work very imperfectly in a developing country context.
Several studies have identified the intersectoral mobility of unskilled labor as a key component
of the poverty alleviation effects of Vietnams reforms (e.g. Hertel et al. 2003, and for a China
study see Zhai et al. 2003), a result that is readily understood in theoretical terms by comparing a
short-run Ricardo-Viner specific factors model with the results from a long-run model with all
factors mobile. Resource (im)mobility may also have spatial or other dimensions, with
migration costs, ethnic or linguistic divisions, or other barriers to economy-wide labor market
clearing.
As noted above, most current AGE models make quite stark assumptions about the
operation of labor markets, and only a few attempt any systematic form of sensitivity analysis
with respect to labor market structure. In Vietnam as in many developing countries, household
labor allocations are made jointly with other resource use decisions; labor mobility away from
agricultural areas, for example is constrained by unwillingness to relinquish control over land,
and this limits intersectoral mobility and migration possiblities (Hertel and Zhai 2005). Some
groups are denied access to some labor markets for linguistic or cultural reasons. And in
Vietnam, a complex and rigid system of residence permits also raises the cost of relocating, in
addition to the usual transport and transactions costs (Le 2005).
It reasonable therefore to hypothesize (i) that full labor market integration is impeded by
these institutional and policy factors, and (ii) that these impediments affect the distribution of
gains and losses from global market shocks and domestic policy reforms. If these hypotheses are
supported in empirical work, then it will be necessary to incorporate explicit impediments to
intersectoral mobility and migration in the model. It is to be expected that different
specifications of labor markets will also lead to different outcomes in terms of the demand for
natural resources, poverty changes, and aggregate welfare.

3.5 Spatial resource use decisions
The model in Coxhead and Jayasuriya (2005) provides a starting point for the incorporation of
environmental phenomena. It captures the desired structural and policy characteristics of a
small, open developing economy in stylized form, and separates agriculture into two regions,
upland and lowland, each with specific economic and environmental characteristics. Land is
specific to regions; in Asia, lowland refers to fertile river deltas, which have highly developed
infrastructure and produce rice almost as a sole crop. Upland refers to sloping and often
12
mountainous land, relatively remote, with poor soils and infrastructure and less reliable yields
due to dependence on rainfall, typically used to grow a mix of staple foods and plantation crops.
While land is specific, however, capital and labor display higher degrees of interregional and
intersectoral mobility. To the upland-lowland model we add an aquaculture sector based on
coastal lagoons and estuaries and structured as for upland agriculture; in particular, we
hypothesize (iii) that that legal limitations on expansion of the total aquaculture area through
conversion of other coastal resources do not constrain decisions (Barbier and Cox 2005). Failure
to reject this hypothesis will imply another alteration in model structure.
Assume, for this exposition, that aggregate agricultural (or aquacultural) output in each
region is produced using region-specific land and labor, and that the urban/industrial region
produces a range of goods using capital and labor. Using K
r
to denote region-specific capital (in
agriculture, land; in aquaculture, impoundments), and assuming that at the upland and
aquacultural margins, K
r
is produced and maintained using labor according to K
r
= L
r
/
r
, where

r
> 0 is the unit labor requirement, we may define maximum revenue functions for each sector
or region:
Urban/Industrial (S): S(L
S
, K, p
S
) (10)
Lowland/Delta (Q): Q(L
Q
, K
Q
, p
Q
) (11)
Aquaculture (F): F(L
F

F
K
F
, K
F
, p
F
) (12)
Upland (R): R(L
R

R
K
R
, K
R
, p
R
), (13)
where p
r
is the relevant output price vector in each region. Total income in the economy is thus
given by the sum S + Q + F + R. Assume that labor is freely mobile among regions and is fixed
in total quantity:
L = L
S
+ L
Q
+ L
F
+ L
R
. (14)
This framework is suited to a wide range of analyses of changes associated with globalization.
These may be direct, since for tradables a change in producer price stems from changes in global
prices and trade policies as shown in section 3.1. They may also be indirect: for example, an
increase in investment in labor-intensive manufacturing, or a rise in the relative price of that
sectors output, raises labors marginal productivity and causes migration into the sector, both
from other manufacturing sectors and from agriculture. In the lowland agricultural region, land
area is fixed in the short-medium run, and the ability to release labor is limited by rice production
technology. In upland (coastal) regions, by contrast, total land (fishery) area is elastic due to
open access, so a change in labor costs can induce a much larger area response. This stylization
fits very closely with the realities of tropical Asia. In Thailand, for example, a boom in labor-
intensive manufacturing between 1988 and 1997 induced almost 20% of the farm labor force to
transfer to industrial jobs and brought agricultural expansion at the land frontier to an abrupt halt
(Coxhead and Jiraporn 1999). In the Philippines, rising labor costs due to expansion in labor-
intensive exportables sectors have been shown to contribute both to reduced upland land area and
also to land use substitutions from labor-intensive seasonal crops toward land-intensive
perennials such as orchards and agroforestry (Coxhead and Demeke 2004).
From this point, stylized stories of resource depletion and degradation are easy to
develop. On-site, land use choices driven by product and factor prices determine the allocation
of land or water resources across activities that are more or less environmentally damaging. In
13
upland and coastal regions, higher output prices and/or lower labor costs encourage both land
area expansion and intensification (that is, higher-frequency cultivation of existing area, for
example through a switch from perennial to annual crops, or open-capture fisheries to fish
farming). The former implies deforestation (including mangrove forest loss in the coastal area),
with associated environmental costs, and the latter, in the absence of offsetting technological or
management changes, implies more rapid degradation of existing resources.
In addition, off-site effects may occur when upstream land use decisions result in
deposition of eroded soil and agricultural chemicals into streams and rivers. Downstream, these
alter the productivity of land or aquaculture resources in ways that Coxhead and Jayasuriya
(2003) show are analogous to factor-specific technological regress, that is, they reduce the
effective (quality-adjusted) endowment of the resource. In coastal fisheries, for example, water
turbidity and chemical pollution caused by agricultural runoff reduces the productivity of the
existing resource, and rents fall accordingly; whether labor productivity also changes depends on
its capacity to migrate to other regions or sectors. If we index upland by r=3, lowland by r=2,
and coastal areas by r=1, then changes in effective resource stocks in downstream sectors due to
emissions upstream are measured by


%
K
r
= K
r
D
j
j >r

for regions j, r (15)


where D
k
is a damage function, determined by total land area and the uses of land by crop, in
each region upstream from r.
In general equilibrium, changes in the effective quantities and returns to natural resources
then alter household incomes, changing both w and v (equation (8)), and as a result, subgroup
measures of poverty are also altered (equation (9)). In sum, optimal private responses to market
signals have direct environmental effects under open access; expanded and more intensified use
of upland and aquaculture area raises household incomes in the expanding regions, but may also
reduce incomes and raise poverty elsewhere if unaccounted externalities reduce productivity
downstream. This highly stylized sketch has direct relevance in Vietnam, where in recent years
a boom in upland farm area and productionnotably, the coffee export boom of the 1990shas
been associated with rapid loss of watershed function, including rapid rises in erosion-related
water pollution and increased risk of serious flooding in lowland and coastal regions. The
numbers of people involved are not small: for example, Asias largest lagoon, on Vietnams
central coast, is home to more than half a million people whose livelihoods are gained mainly
from fisheries. It is fed by several rivers of 100km or less in length, which drain directly from
mountain areas that are undergoing massive conversion of forest land to agriculture, both
perennial (e.g. coffee) and annual (e.g. maize and vegetables).
Of course, dynamics are important to the environmental processes just described.
Dynamic optimization models allowing for on-site degradation and investments in resource
quality (Clarke 1992; LaFrance 1992) are feasible in partial equilibrium, but are much more
difficult to implement in a general equilibrium framework. The model just described provides a
vehicle for steady-state comparative statics. Not all information on dynamics is lost by such an
approach, however. The solutions to exogenous policy or market shocks will yield, among other
things, predictions of changes in rents earned by specific factors such as land and aquaculture
area. These predictions convey information about incentives to further deplete the resource base
or to invest in maintaining its future productivity, and can be used in the design of compensatory
policies.

14
3.6 Other amendments to the standard model
Lack of space prohibits a full exposition of other amendments that are clearly desirable in an
unconstrained world. For convenience, we have here posited only one intersectorally mobile
factor and have ignored intermediate goods. In a fully specified model, intermediates play an
important role, and there is scope for more mobile factorssome mobile only within regions,
others across regions. Finally, it is also important to model public sector finances. The
Vietnamese economy is typical in being characterized by many varieties of taxes and transfers,
for example, trade policies, anti-poverty programs, and some environmental taxes. It is
important to ensure a realistic representation of the government budget and policy instruments.
4. Empirical strategy
Ideally, research on globalization, poverty and environment in Vietnam should proceed by
construction of a regionally differentiated AGE data base and model, estimation of key
parameters and testing of hypotheses about the operation of markets known to be important to
general equilibrium outcomes, validation of the model performance through historical validation
exercises, and to applications to the study of global market shocks and domestic policy reforms.
With the existing data and modeling resources it is possible to construct an extended RH model,
with households (and their behavior as consumers and producers) differentiated by regions,
endowments, and initial wealth and poverty. This approach would integrated methods and data
from three existing areas of research on Vietnamese economic development, and also add one
new source. Data and analysis from the third VLSS round (2002) can be used to obtain
information on household welfare, poverty and distribution; these data can be disaggregated by
region as defined earlier, as well as by labor type and other characteristics as described below.
Two strands of current AGE work, namely studies of tax and trade policy and economic welfare,
and studies of environment and natural resource use and policy, can be integrated. Baseline data
from the 2000 Social Accounting Matrix (SAM), can be decomposed to generate specific
regional sub-economies. In addition, it is feasible to add new parameter sets based on micro
studies of important phenomena such as agricultural land and aquaculture area responses and the
economic behavior of specific groups of households by region. These micro studies are ongoing
in related research (for details, see www.aae.wisc.edu/gpe-vn).

4.1 Description of the model
The basic model structure is that of a standard Walrasian AGE model as sketched above. On
production, assume each sector to produce one good except in the agricultural regions, where
joint production is possible using a common land resource (Warr and Coxhead 1993). Firms
combine intermediates and primary factors to produce output. Each intermediate is a composite
of imported and domestically produced goods, with an Armington aggregation function.
Composite labor inputs are created by aggregating over labor of different skill types and (subject
to data) other relevant characteristics. A composite primary factor input is then created through
CES aggregation, and combined (again using CES) with intermediates.
Final demand comes from households, government, investment, inventories and trade.
Household demand parameters can be estimated from VLSS data as noted above. Each distinct
household group will generate demands for goods from domestic and imported sources
(aggregated by the Armington assumption) subject to a household budget constraint. Subject to
data, it may be feasible to estimate a demand form such as Stone-Geary to account for non-linear
expenditure patterns in which subsistence requirements are satisfied prior to discretionary
15
spending on other types of goods. Government and investment will be linked to macroeconomic
variables.
In trade, we assume Vietnam to be a small country in export markets, with prices
exogenous. Imports, however, are differentiated, allowing for two-way trade and interior
solutions to consumers choices between domestic and imported goods.
Household incomes come from factor returns, taxes and transfers as shown in equation
(7). The model excludes endogenous changes in savings; households are assumed to dedicate all
of a given change in disposable income to changes in consumption. However, incomes may
change due to endogenous changes in factor assets as the result of resource depletion or the
effects of externalities. Hence there is an element of automatic or involuntary saving (or
dissaving) by households that control natural resources.
On public finance, the model will replicate the current Vietnamese fiscal system (see
Chan et al 1999), which includes taxes on corporate profits, labor incomes, sales (consumption),
trade, and other indirect measures. Government expenditures will include those devoted to anti-
poverty and environmental programs; the former are well established and can be identified by
location, but most of the latter are still the subjects of policy discussion.
Equilibrium in the model is characterized by market clearing with endogenous prices for
factors and goods, endogenous trade quantities for tradables, zero profits in production, and
binding household budget constraints. The public sector deficit and current account deficit will
be either endogenous or exogenous depending on whether we adopt a long-run or short-run
closure, with taxes, government expenditures, and other macroeconomic variables also capable
of being switched between exogenous and endogenous to satisfy the closure rule.
The poverty calculations in section 3.3 above can be computed for groups in the
population from information contained in the rest of the model. Subject to data, we posit a
feedback from poverty to resource allocation decisions, consistent with observed behavior of
poor rural households (Shively 2001).
Similarly, estimates of resource depletion rates, environmental damages and shadow
values associated with these will be derived as satellite accounts, except insofar as external and
on-site damages reduce effective factor endowments (see Bandara and Coxhead 1999).
A model of this type can be solved in linearized Johansen form, using the Gempack
software suite (Harrison and Pearson, 1996). While single-step solutions to Johansen models are
subject to linearization errors, this software suite allows for the use of multiple-step algorithms to
minimize such errors.

4.2 Data
Data requirements consist of a social accounting matrix (SAM) and a set of technological and
behavioral parameters governing the responsiveness of the economy to exogenous changes.
Social accounting matrix The most recent SAM available from the Vietnamese
Government Statistical Office (GSO) is for year 2000 and includes up to 112 sectors, 8 labor
types by skill, gender and location, and 16 household types by gender, location, sector
(farm/non-farm) and labor market participation. The goal of spatial differentiation of production
and factor markets requires a decomposition of parts of the SAM, which will be carried out using
provincial land use and related data from the GSO. These data will be used to construct weights
with which to allocate production and input use in some sectors across ecological zonesin our
case, uplands, lowlands, coastal areas and urban areas. This type of spatial decomposition has
already been undertaken, albeit for different regional definitions, in previous GSO work.
16
Extending the SAM to include environmental data is a more complex task. Some
environmental and natural resource phenomena are measured as flows, others as stocks; some
can be measured in monetary terms (for example, abatement measures or specific productivity
losses) while values for othersparticularly stocks, but also any phenomena for which markets
do not exist or do not function wellcan only be ascertained through valuation methods, a
controversial area. The default solution is to reserve all environmental calculations to a set of
satellite accounts, separate from the SAM. Flow data, however, can be incorporated in an
extended SAM in physical (rather than monetary) terms, both for assets such as forests and
minerals, and for pollutants such as industrial emissions and soil deposition in rivers, if suitable
data can be found (Alarcon et al. 2000). These accounts help quantify the resource or
environmental intensity of production and consumption activities and thus aid in assessments
of the environmental implications of changes such as trade liberalization. The intersection of
environmental rows and columns with those for production and consumption can be used to
approximate environmental feedbacks.
Elasticity data The complete elasticity data set includes several sets of elasticities of
substitution in production, consumption and trade; elasticities of transformation in multiproduct
industries; expenditure elasticities of demand; and elasticities of product and factor supply with
respect to price. Estimates of the complete parameter set do not exist for any country, let alone
for Vietnam. The standard approach in AGE modeling has been to assume values where
estimates are unavailable, or in some cases to borrow them from estimates obtained in
arguably similar economies.
For many components of this data set, data constraints require a similar strategy. In two
critical areas, however, it is possible to obtain original econometric estimates. There is an
entirely new data set containing a panel of data on land use, aquaculture area, and relevant
product prices at commune level. These data will be used to estimate the responsiveness of
agricultural land area and allocation to crops, and that of aquaculture area and allocation by
species, to product prices. These estimates will supply parameter values for an important part of
the environmental model, the responsiveness of resource users to economic signals derived from
trade or trade policy. Additional environmental data are beginning to be compiled in the newly-
formed Ministry of Environment and Natural Resources.
It will also be possible to obtain estimates of the responsiveness of households to product
and factor market shocks from the VLSS data set. This is an essential step in moving beyond the
RH model. Information on household behavior from the current VLSS can be derived only from
cross-sectional estimates, as the most recently released (2002) survey round does not build on the
households sampled in earlier rounds (1993, 1998). However, subsequent VLSS round (2004) re-
surveyed some households from the 2002 round, so it is feasible to use panel data estimators to
build in more detailed econometric information on household behavior with respect to product
markets, factor (especially labor) markets, and allocation of fixed resources such as land.

4.3 Hypothesis testing
The discussion in section 3 motivated several hypotheses, tests of will contribute to a better-
specified AGE model. These were (i) that there are impediments to intersectoral and
interregional labor mobility that are associated with household and institutional characteristics
and other economic variables; (ii) that these impediments affect the distribution of gains and
losses from trade and policy reform; and (iii) that legal constraints on land and fishery area
expansion do not inhibit decisions by producers subject to changes in market incentives (it is
17
likely that other hypotheses will present themselves in the course of our investigation of the
data). These hypotheses can be tested using the data described in section 4.2. Failure to reject
them will provide important clues as to the links between globalization, poverty and the
environment in Vietnam and will generate analogous research agendas for other similar
developing countries. The results of these hypothesis tests should also provide guidance for
innovations in AGE modeling that depart from the standard assumptions on model structure.

4.3 Model validation
For the AGE purposes, it is important to test key hypotheses underpinning functioning of factor
markets in the model, and also to estimate key elasticities imbedded in the model structure.
However, taking these steps still does not ensure that the model as a whole will be valid, i.e. that
it will provide useful predictions for the entire economy. To validate the model requires some
kind of historical experiment against which we can measure its performance. Kehoe et al. (1995)
validate their model of the Spanish economy by comparing predicted with actual changes in the
composition of the economy in the wake of tax reform. Liu et al. (2004) validate a global model
of international trade by projecting it backwards in time and asking how well it predicts observed
changes in trade shares. Valenzuela et al. (2005) compare the responsiveness of predicted
historical commodity prices in response to known supply shocks.
It is feasible to validate a model of the type described above by means of backcasting.
The specific focus of this exercise is motivated by the observation that Vietnam has experienced
strong growth of primary production and exports over the past decade. As noted, existing AGE
models underpredict this sectoral response to policy reform shocks. This discrepancy could be
due to misspecification of behavior or policies, or to external developments not considered in
previous studies. Given the importance of agricultural responses for trends in both poverty and
environmental quality, validation of model predictive power is particularly important. The
purpose of the validation exercise is to see whether the model can accurately capture the resource
boom experienced by Vietnam over the decade to 2002. This can be done by collecting data on
changes in policies, external trade and world prices, and estimating changes in unobservable total
factor productivity growth over the period. By applying these historical changes to the model as
exogenous shocks, it is possible to evaluate how well it predicts historical changes in patterns of
production, consumption and trade.
The combination of data-based econometric estimation and use of derived elasticities to
validate and improve model specification is not new as a general technique, but the model
described above will be the first to use this method to specifically obtain a better understanding
of links between trade, poverty and environment. This research should produce methodological
innovations with applicability to many countries in the developing world, where globalization is
rapid and threats to natural resources are pervasive.

4.4 Policy experiments
In light of the importance of external shocks to the evolution of poverty and environmental
quality in open developing economies, it is important to conduct a systematic exploration of their
effects using a carefully structured set of experiments. Here, the approach is somewhat different
from the historical analysis discussed above. Retrospective experiments simply take observed
data on export and import volumes and prices (regardless of source or destination) and shock the
model with the relevant changes over a historical period. Of course the historical growth in trade
is driven by a host of developments in the global economy, including economic growth as well
18
as policy reform. So, while these retrospective experiments are important for decomposing the
impact of external developments and internal reforms on poverty and the environment in a
country like Vietnam, they are of limited value in understanding the sources of the external
changes.
To explore this, two linked sets of experiments can be undertaken. The first is a set of
prospective experiments aimed at isolating the differential effects that economic growth in
different countries has on poverty and environmental degradation in Vietnam. We hypothesize
that continued rapid growth in China will limit Vietnamese exports of labor-intensive
manufactures, favoring instead the raw materials sectors, including agriculture and resource
extraction, while simultaneously encouraging additional importation of manufactured goods
from China ( Coxhead 2007). This is likely to be beneficial for rural poverty, but, in the absence
of well-defined property rights, adverse for environmental quality. On the other hand, growth in
the OECD economies is likely to favor Vietnamese exports of labor-intensive manufactures,
thereby boosting wages and drawing resources out of NR sectors. Of course reality is likely to be
much more complex, varying by partner country and Vietnams pattern of bilateral trade.
Research of the type described in this section should help us to better understand these economic
forces and their implications for Vietnam and other developing countries.
To conduct the prospective experiments, it may be possible to use a variant of the global
GTAP model (Hertel, 1997). The methodology for linking this global model to more detailed
national models in order to elicit the national impacts of global policy changes is now fairly
standard. Horridge and Zhai (2006) show how the impacts of WTO reforms in the rest of the
world can be transmitted to national models by computing commodity-specific export demand
shifts and import price changes implied by the global model. These are then implemented as
exogenous shocks to the national model, along with national commitments under the WTO
scenario. A similar approach can be taken here, only now the shocks will be endowment and
productivity growth in Vietnams trading partners. The magnitude of these shocks can be based
on annual average projected growth rates of these partner economies over the next ten years.
These forecasts can in turn be obtained from World Bank forecasts, as reflected in the GTAP
baseline.
The second set of experiments should address the reform (or expected reform) of policies
that limit the openness of the Vietnamese economy to trade. The package of domestic policy
reforms required or anticipated to prepare Vietnam for WTO accession is a prime subject for
research. If we are concerned about poverty and environmental outcomes, then research should
also address specific policies in these areas; however, the main focus should probably remain on
the direct and indirect consequences of trade liberalization and other reform measures.
Vietnams National Assembly (NA), continues to debate specific legislative measures related to
trade and WTO accession, poverty alleviation, and environmental protection. Measures adopted
by the NA can provide input to policy experiments. Such an approach will have the added
advantage of ensuring that policy experiments are relevant to contemporary Vietnamese
development debates. This relevance is central to the value of any model for economic and
environmental policy analysis.

19
References
Alarcon, J., J. van Heemst, and N. de Jong, 2000. Extending the SAM with social and environmental
indicators: an application to Bolivia, Economic Systems Research 12(4): 473-496.
Anderson, K., 1992. The standard welfare economics of policies affecting trade and the environment,
in K. Anderson and R. Blackhurst (eds), The Greening of World Trade Issues. Ann Arbor, MI:
University of Michigan Press.
Antweiler, W., B. R. Copeland, and M.S. Taylor, 2001. Is free trade good for the environment?,
American Economic Review, 91(4), pp 877-908
Asian Development Bank (ADB), 1997. Emerging Asia: Changes and Challenges. Manila: ADB.
Bandara, J.S. and I. Coxhead, 1999. Can trade liberalization have environmental benefits in developing
countries? A Sri Lankan case study. Journal of Policy Modeling 21(3):349-374.
Barbier, E.B., and M. Cox, 2004. An economic analysis of shrimp farm expansion and mangrove
conversion in Thailand, Land Economics 80 (3):389-407.
Beghin, J., et al., 1997. The trade and environment nexus in Mexican agriculture. a general equilibrium
analysis Agricultural Economics 17(2-3): 115-31.
Beghin, J., S. Dessus, D. Roland-Holst, and D. Van der Mensbrugghe, 2002. Empirical modeling of
trade and the environment, Ch. 3 in in J. Beghin, D. Roland-Holst, and D. van der Mensbrugghe, eds:
Trade and the Environment in General Equilibrium: Evidence from Developing Economies (Boston:
Kluwer Academic Publishers).
Bourguignon, F., and Silva, Luiz A. Pereira, 2003. The Impact of Economic Policies on Poverty and
Income Distribution: Evaluation Techniques and Tools. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Bovenberg, L., and L. Goulder. 1996. Optimal environmental policies in the presence of other taxes:
general equilibrium analyses, American Economic Review, 986 (4) September, 985-1000.
Brander, J. A., and M. S. Taylor, 1997. International trade and open-access renewable resources: the
small open economy case, Canadian Journal of Economics 30(3). (August): 526-552.
Central Committee of the Communist Party of Vietnam: National Socio-Economic Development Strategy
2001-10. Hanoi: CPVN.
Chan, N., M. Ghosh, and J. Whalley, 1999. Evaluating tax reform in Vietnam using general equilibrium
methods, Center for System and Information Research, Institute of Information Technology, Hanoi
(mimeo).
Chan, N., T.K. Dung, M. Ghosh, and J. Whalley, 2004. Adjustment costs in labour markets and the
distributional effects of trade liberalization: analytics and calculations for Vietnam, paper submitted to
WDI/CEPR Annual International Conference on Transition Economics, Hanoi, Vietnam, May 27-31.
Chinh, N.T., and Trinh, B., n.d. The use of I/O model for research on the relation between economic
growth and waste discharge into the environment of Red River Delta, Vietnam. Center for
Environmental Economics and Regional Development, National Economics University, Hanoi
(mimeo).
Clarke, H.R. 1992. "The supply of non-degraded agricultural land". Australian Journal of Agricultural
Economics 36(1): 31-56.
Copeland, B. R., 1994. International trade and the environment: policy reform in a polluted small open
economy, Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 26(1), January: 44-65.
20
Copeland, B.R., and M. S. Taylor, 2003. Trade and the Environment: Theory and Evidence. Princeton,
NJ; Princeton University Press.
Cox, D., 2004. Private interhousehold transfers in Vietnam, Ch. 16 in Glewwe, P., N. Agrawal and D.
Dollar (eds), 2004. Economic Growth, Poverty, and Household Welfare in Vietnam, Washington, DC:
World Bank: 567-604.
Coxhead, I., 2007. A new resource curse? Impacts of Chinas boom on comparative advantage and
resource dependence in Southeast Asia. World Development 35(7), July: 1099-1119.
Coxhead, I. and P. G. Warr, 1995. Does technical progress in agriculture alleviate poverty? a
Philippine case study. Australian Journal of Agricultural Economics 39(1): 25-54.
Coxhead, I. and S. Jayasuriya, 2003. The Open Economy and the Environment: Development, Trade and
Resources in Asia. Cheltenham, UK, and Northampton, MA, USA: Edward Elgar.
Coxhead, I., and B. Demeke, 2004. Panel data evidence on upland agricultural land use in the
Philippines: can economic policy reforms reduce environmental damage? American Journal of
Agricultural Economics 86(5), December: 1354-1360.
Coxhead, I., and J. Plangpraphan, 1999. "Economic boom, financial bust, and the decline of Thai
agriculture: was growth in the 1990s too fast?", Chulalongkorn Journal of Economics 11(1): 76-96.
Coxhead, I., and S. Jayasuriya, 2004. Development strategy, poverty, and deforestation in the
Philippines. Environment and Development Economics 9(5), October: 613-644.
Coxhead, I., and S. Jayasuriya, 2005. Trade liberalization, resource degradation and industrial pollution
in developing countries, Madison: University of Wisconsin Department of Agricultural and Applied
Economics Staff Papers No. 462 (revised, May 2005).
Deacon, R., 1995. "Assessing the relationship between government policy and deforestation", Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management 28(1): 1-18.
Dean, J., 1999. Does trade liberalization harm the environment? A new test. Manuscript, School of
Advanced International Studies, Johns Hopkins University.
Dessus, S., and M. Bussolo, 1998. Is there a trade-off between trade liberalization and pollution
abatement? a computable general equilibrium assessment applied to Costa Rica. Journal of Policy
Modeling 20(1): 11-31.
Dufournaud, C.M., M. Jerrett, J.T. Quinn, and V. Maclaren, 2000. Economy-wide effects of forest
policies: a general equilibrium assessment from Vietnam, Land Economics 76(1): 15-27
El Obeid, A., D. Van der Mensbrugghe, and S. Dessus, 2002. Outward Orientation, Growth, and the
Environment in Vietnam, Ch. 9 in J. Beghin, D. Roland-Holst, and D. van der Mensbrugghe, eds:
Trade and the Environment in General Equilibrium: Evidence from Developing Economies (Boston:
Kluwer Academic Publishers).
Foster, J., J. Greer and E. Thorbecke, 1984. "A class of decomposable poverty measures." Econometrica
52(3): 761-66.
Fredriksson, P. G., 1999. Trade, global policy and the environment, in P. G. Fredriksson (ed): Trade,
Global Policy and the Environment. Washington, D.C.: World Bank: 1-12.
Fujii, T., and D. Roland-Holst, 2004. How does Vietnams accession to the World Trade Organization
change the spatial distribution of poverty and inequality?, Department of Agricultural and Resource
Economics, University of California-Berkeley (mimeo).
21
Fukase, E., and W. Martin, 2000. The effects of the United States granting MFN status to Vietnam,
Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 136(2): 539-567.
Fukase, E., and W. Martin, 2001. A quantitative evaluation of Vietnams accession to the ASEAN Free
Trade Area, Journal of Economic Integration 16(4): 545-567.
Gallup, J.L., 2004. The wage labor market and inequality in Vietnam, Ch. 3 in Glewwe, P., N. Agrawal
and D. Dollar (eds), 2004. Economic Growth, Poverty, and Household Welfare in Vietnam,
Washington, DC: World Bank: 53-94.
Glewwe, P., N. Agrawal and D. Dollar (eds), 2004. Economic Growth, Poverty, and Household Welfare
in Vietnam, Washington, DC: World Bank.
Harrison, W.J., and K.R. Pearson, 1996. "Computing solutions for large general equilibrium models
using GEMPACK", Computational Economics 9(2): 83-127
Hertel, T., ed., 1997. Global Trade Analysis: Modeling and Applications. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge
University Press.
Hertel, T.W., M. Ivanic, P.V. Preckel, and W. Martin, 2003. Short- versus long-run implications of trade
liberalization for poverty in three developing countries, American Journal of Agricultural Economics
85(5): 1299-1306.
Hertel, T.W., and J. Reimer, 2005. Predicting the poverty impacts of trade reform. Mimeo, Purdue
University.
Hertel, T.W., and L. A. Winters (eds.), 2006. Poverty Impacts of a WTO Agreement: Putting
Development Back into the Doha Agenda, New York: Palgrave-MacMillan.
Horridge, J. M. and F. Zhai, 2006. World Market Impacts of Multilateral Trade Reforms, Chapter 3,
appendix in T. W. Hertel and L. A. Winters (eds.) Poverty Impacts of a WTO Agreement: Putting
Development Back into the Doha Agenda, New York: Palgrave-MacMillan.
Jenkins, R., 2004. Vietnam in the global economy: trade, employment and poverty, Journal of
International Development 16(1): 13-28.
Jensen, H.T., and F. Tarp, n.d., Trade liberalization and spatial inequality: methodological innovations in
Vietnamese perspective (mimeo).
Jha, R., and J. Whalley, 1999. The environmental regime in developing countries. NBER Working
Paper No. 7305.
Jones, R.W., 1971. "A three-factor model in theory, trade and history," in J.N. Bhagwati et al. (eds):
Trade, Balance of Payments and Growth: Essays in Honor of C.P. Kindleberger. Amsterdam: North-
Holland: 3-21.
Kehoe, T.J., C. Polo and F. Sancho. 1995. An Evaluation of the Performance of an Applied General
Equilibrium Model of the Spanish Economy. Economic Theory 6, 115-141.
LaFrance, J. T., 1992. "Do increased commodity prices lead to more or less soil degradation?".
Australian Journal of Agricultural Economics 36(1): 57-82.
Le Can Le, 2005. Licence for life, Vietnam Economic Times, issue 137, July: 58-59.
Le Goulven, K., 2001. Institutions and price transmission in the Vietnamese hog market, International
Food and Agribusiness Management review 2(2/4): 375-390.
Lee, H., and D. Roland-Holst, 1997. The environment and welfare implications of trade and tax policy,
Journal of Development Economics 52: 65-82.
22
Litchfield, J., N. McCulloch, N., and L. A. Winters, 2003. Agricultural trade liberalization and poverty
dynamics in three developing countries, American Journal of Agricultural Economics 85(5): 1285-
1291.
Liu, J., C. Arndt, and T.W. Hertel. 2004. Parameter Estimation and Measures of Fit in a Global, General
Equilibrium Model. Journal of Economic Integration 19(3):626-649.
Lloyd, P., 2000. Generalizing the Stolper-Samuelson theorem: a tale of two matrices. Review of
International Economics 8(4): 597-613.
Milanovic, B., 2003. The two faces of globalization: against globalization as we know it, World
Development 31(4), April, pp. 667-83.
Minot, N., 2000. Generating disaggregated poverty maps: an application to Vietnam, World
Development 28(2): 319-331.
Minot, N., and F. Golletti, 2000. Rice market liberalization and poverty in Viet Nam, Washington, DC:
IFPRI Research Report No. 114.
Niimi, Y., Vasudeva-Dutta, P., and L. A. Winters, 2003. Trade liberalization and poverty dynamics in
Vietnam, Poverty Research Unit, University of Sussex (mimeo).
Roland-Holst, D., and F. Tarp, n.d. Globalization, economic reform, and structural price transmission:
SAM decomposition techniques with an empirical application to Vietnam (mimeo).
Seshan, G., 2004. The impact of trade liberalization on household welfare in a developing country,
Department of Economics, University of Virginia (mimeo).
Shively, G. E., 2001. Poverty, consumption risk, and soil conservation. Journal of Development
Economics 65(2): 267-90
Stiglitz, J.E., 2003. Globalization and its Discontents New York: Norton.
Stiglitz, J.E., and A. Charlton, 2005. Fair Trade for All: How Trade Can Promote Development. Oxford,
UK: Oxford University Press.
Swinkels, R., and C. Turk, 2004. Poverty and remote areas: Evidence from new data and questions for
the future, World Bank, Hanoi (mimeo).
Tarp, F., D. Roland-Holst, J. Rand, and H. T. Jensen, 2002. A 2000 Social Accounting Matrix for
Vietnam. Hanoi: CIEM.
Valenzuela, E.; T. W. Hertel, R. Keeney, and J. J. Reimer, 2005. Assessing global CGE model validity
using agricultural price volatility. GTAP Working Paper No. 33, Center for Global Trade Analysis,
Purdue University. https://www.gtap.agecon.purdue.edu/resources/working_papers.asp.
Van de Walle, D., 2004a. Is the emerging non-farm economy the route out of poverty in Vietnam?
Economics of Transition 12(2): 237-74.
Van de Walle, D., 2004b. The static and dynamic incidence of Vietnams public safety net, Ch. 6 in
Glewwe, P., N. Agrawal and D. Dollar (eds), 2004. Economic Growth, Poverty, and Household
Welfare in Vietnam, Washington, DC: World Bank:189-228.
Warr, P. G. and I. Coxhead, 1993. The distributional impact of technical change in Philippine
agriculture: a general equilibrium analysis. Food Research Institute Studies, XXII(3): 253-274.
Winters, L.A., 2002. Trade, trade policy and poverty: what are the links?, The World Economy 25
(issue): 1339-1367.
Wolf, M., 2004. Why Globalization Works. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press
23
World Bank, 2000. Vietnam Development Report: Attacking Poverty. Washington, DC: World Bank.
Zhai, F., T. Hertel, and Z. Wang, 2003. Labor market distortions, rural-urban inequality and the
opening of Chinas economy. GTAP Working Paper No. 27.

You might also like